For Peer Review Journal: Journal of the History of Economic Thought
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Cambridge University Press Dunn's "The Economics of John Kenneth Galbraith" For Peer Review Journal: Journal of the History of Economic Thought Manuscript ID: Draft Manuscript Type: Review Article [email protected] Page 1 of 8 Cambridge University Press 1 2 3 Book Review for the Journal of the History of Economic Thought 4 5 6 7 By Cameron M. Weber, PhD student in economics and history at the New School for Social 8 9 Research and Adjunct Faculty, FIT/SUNY and St. John’s University, New York. 10 11 12 February 2013 13 14 15 Email: [email protected], homepage: cameroneconomics.com 16 17 18 For Peer Review 19 Book reviewed: Stephen P. Dunn. The Economics of John Kenneth Galbraith: Introduction, 20 21 Persuasion and Rehabilitation . (Cambridge, New York, Melbourne, Madrid, Cape Town, 22 23 Singapore, Sao Paulo, Delhi, Dubai, Tokyo, Mexico City: Cambridge University Press, 2010), 24 25 26 pp. xx, 477, US$115.00, ISBN 978-0521-51876-5. 27 28 29 Review: 30 31 32 Stephen Dunn describes this book as having its main goal to show that John Kenneth Galbraith’s 33 34 35 (JKG’s) thought has been under-appreciated by both Post-Keynesians and Institutionalists in the 36 37 history of economic thought. But in reality the book is really of two parts, the first is Dunn’s 38 39 very detailed and engaging description of JKG’s thought without tying-in in any systematic way 40 41 42 followers or precursors, the second is to relate JKG’s influence on those that followed him, 43 44 especially in Post-Keynesian Economics. It is only under this first part that the book fully 45 46 succeeds, more on this to follow. 47 48 49 50 Dunn divides JKG’s thought into to two main currents, the first is his “major trilogy” (p. 295) of 51 52 the corporatization of the American economy. This trilogy being The Affluent Society (1958), 53 54 The New Industrial State (1967) and Economics and the Public Purpose (1973). It is in these 55 56 57 volumes that JKG proposes his theories of the “bimodal” economy where the large corporations 58 59 60 [email protected] Cambridge University Press Page 2 of 8 2 1 2 3 (one-half of the economy) hold smaller businesses, the other half of the economy, in a 4 5 6 “subservient” (p. 354) position due to the social power created by the “technostructure” in the 7 8 large corporations. This current also includes JKG’s well-known “social imbalance” narrative 9 10 11 where society spends too much on personal consumption while there is the “under production of 12 13 merit and public goods” (p. 89). It is the corporate technostructure which has harnessed the 14 15 awesome technological powers of modern capitalism to produce “socially irrelevant 16 17 18 commodities” (p. 89) while,For unfortunately, Peer power Review over this technology is not in the hands of 19 20 those who provide public goods (Galbraith’s main concerns were environmental degradation, 21 22 militarization, lack of public housing, healthcare and transportation, and, an education system 23 24 25 focused too much on economic production). 26 27 28 The second thesis, where Dunn attempts to show how JKG’s thought has been influential on 29 30 subsequent Post-Keynesians, plays less of a role in the book and in fact only is discussed in 31 32 33 detail not until the last quarter of the book. The major works in this narrative are The Great 34 35 Crash, 1929 (1955), Money (1975) and A Short History of Financial Euphoria (1990). It is here 36 37 that we are introduced to the Post-Keynesian tropes of endogenous (and non-neutral) money, the 38 39 40 wage-price spiral, imperfect competition and excess capacity (only of course in the dominant 41 42 large corporations), the failure of Say’s Law in bringing adequate employment without 43 44 government fiscal policy demand management, and, the fallacy of composition where debt at the 45 46 47 macro (State) level cannot be compared to that of the household if that public debt is used to 48 49 ensure adequate levels of employment, especially for public works during periods of recession 50 51 52 and depression. 53 54 55 The two currents of the book then are held together under the “bimodal” theory. As one example 56 57 we find that retained earnings reduce risk faced by the large corporations from the endogenous 58 59 60 [email protected] Page 3 of 8 Cambridge University Press 3 1 2 3 money instabilities created by a monopolized-centralized monetary authority, whereas 4 5 6 manipulation of the interest rate can influence economic activity in the “market” (smaller 7 8 businesses) as opposed to the “planning system” (the dominant large corporations). 9 10 11 Where the book might have been improved in Dunn’s attempt to place JKG in the historical 12 13 14 lineage of Post- Keynesian economic thought is in the chapter called “Money and the real 15 16 world”. It is here that Dunn describes JKG’s ideas relating to today’s current Post-Keynesian 17 18 tropes as espoused by,For for example, Peer Victoria Chick, Review Paul Davidson, Paul Krugman, Hyman P. 19 20 21 Minsky, Malcolm C. Sawyer, Paul Shiller and Dunn himself. (There is a curious lack of 22 23 reference to Robert Frank in this book, someone whose views on consumerism and normative 24 25 26 prescription closely follow JKG, though there are the necessary references to Veblen). Dunn 27 28 describes JKG’s ideas well, while mostly only giving relevant citations to these follow-on Post- 29 30 Keynesian thinkers. What is missing in this chapter is analysis as to how JKG’s ideas actually 31 32 33 influenced these following thinkers. Describing JKG’s ideas, then adding citations for further 34 35 readings does not complete the argument that Dunn states he sets out to achieve. For a 36 37 knowledgeable Post-Keynesian this approach might be sufficient but for a historian of economic 38 39 40 thought new to and interested in, such a popular figure as JKG, this is insufficient and perhaps 41 42 disappointing. 43 44 45 This being said, however, in the next chapter mostly about financial booms and busts called “A 46 47 48 man for our times” Dunn is much more careful and thorough while at the same time using 49 50 sparkling narrative in describing the commonalities (and some critique) amongst Post- 51 52 Keynesians on the instability of endogenous money capitalism. It appears that Dunn is more 53 54 55 interested in the analysis of this instability as opposed to more general Post-Keynesian economic 56 57 theory. Whether or not one agrees that “greed”, “speculation”, “hubris”, “deregulation” and the 58 59 60 [email protected] Cambridge University Press Page 4 of 8 4 1 2 3 herd-like behavior of the “animal spirits” create recession- and depression-causing business- 4 5 6 cycles, Dunn here has done well in presenting JKG’s influence upon Galbraithian descendants 7 8 (including Paul Krugman and Joseph Stiglitz). In this chapter we learn as well that financial 9 10 11 institutions deemed “too big to fail” are part of the dominant sector in JKG’s bimodal theory 12 13 (that is until/if they are allowed to go bankrupt and become liquidated). 14 15 16 Dunn spends most of the book on describing the “planning system” used by corporations to 17 18 minimize market risk, Fordescribing howPeer these corporat Reviewions have the ability, through monopolistic 19 20 21 power, to manipulate, in fact “victimize” (p. 63) the consumer into buying their product. The 22 23 planning system of these corporations (the tobacco, pharmaceutical, agro-business and 24 25 26 automobile industries are described in the most detail) give them power over the consumer to 27 28 where it is not price competition (nor consumer sovereignty) that determines supply and demand. 29 30 31 Large corporations support Keynesian demand management (government spending in times of 32 33 34 economic downturn) in order to keep demand high enough to produce at their capacity 35 36 (technological advance and concomitant investment leads to over-capacity), yet we find that 37 38 Galbraith admits that these fiscal stimulus policies help the dominant sector over the general 39 40 41 good. Large corporations, especially those in the military-industrial complex and those receiving 42 43 the necessary stimulus spending (some corporations seek “a protective response from the state”, 44 45 p. 61) have social and economic powers over the other half of the economy which is dependent 46 47 48 upon the market alone for survival. 49 50 51 Dunn proposes that this corporate “planning system” adds to what was missing in pre- 52 53 Galbraithian Keynesianism; a microfoundation for stability to compliment the macrofoundations 54 55 56 of the stability of monetary and fiscal policy. However, others may not agree with this as this 57 58 59 60 [email protected] Page 5 of 8 Cambridge University Press 5 1 2 3 was perhaps accomplished by Ronald Coase in 1937, albeit of course Coase is not considered of 4 5 6 the Post-Keynesian school. Dunn places JKG’s work in reference to that of Coase, but, at least 7 8 to this reviewer, credits JKG with too much originality viz-a-viz Coase. 9 10 11 In Galbraith’s “Revised Sequence” where it is not the consumer who is sovereign it is the 12 13 14 dominant large corporate sector who receives the fiscal stimulus spending (and benefits of the 15 16 “multiplier”) needed to keep producing towards capacity while not having to lower prices and 17 18 profits and who gain throughFor the wealthPeer created undReviewer capitalism and the affluent society.