The Value Added and Operating Surplus Deflators For

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Value Added and Operating Surplus Deflators For Statistical Journal of the IAOS 34 (2018) 235–253 235 DOI 10.3233/SJI-160327 IOS Press The value added and operating surplus deflators for industries: The right price indicators that should be used to calculate the real interest rates Itsuo Sakumaa, Masako Tsujimurab;c and Kazusuke Tsujimurad;∗ aFaculty of Economics, Senshu University, Tokyo, Japan bFaculty of Economics, Rissho University, Tokyo, Japan cKeio Economic Observatory, Keio University, Tokyo, Japan dFaculty of Economics, Keio University, Tokyo, Japan Abstract. After the global financial crisis of 2008–2009, many advanced economies are suffering from a dearth of domestic investment opportunities. It has been said that lowering real interest rate is the best policy to boost the capital investment. The problem is what inflation rate they have in their mind when the entrepreneurs make investment decisions. Not only the output prices, but also the composition of inputs differ from one industry to another. Therefore, the value added deflator or even the operating surplus deflator for each industry are better alternative to calculate the real interest rate. In the first half of the paper, we examine the theoretical meaning of the value added deflators using a highly simplified symmetric input output table. In the latter half, we will use so-called SNA-IO, the input-output table published as a part of Japanese SNA, to experimentally estimate both value added and operating surplus deflators. The study reveals that if lowering interest rate depreciate the local currency, it will depress value added deflators, and in turn, will discourage capital investments. In this sense, lowering interest rate is a double-edged sword; the governments and central banks should think twice before taking such a policy. Keywords: National accounts, use table, symmetric input-output table, double deflation, GDP deflator JEL Classification: C43, C67, E31 1. Introduction (natürliche Kapitalzins) as the physical rate of return on capital investment at the time. If the market rate of With slowly growing or declining workforces, as interest on loans (Darlehnszins) is below the natural well as high capital-labor ratios, many advanced econ- rate, entrepreneurs will borrow funds and make profit omies face an apparent dearth of domestic investment by investing in capital goods. On the contrary, if the opportunities, while the ageing society calls for more market rate is above the natural rate, the entrepreneurs savings (i.e. future consumption) to prepare for the re- will be hesitant to borrow so that capital investment tirement (Bernanke [1]). Traditionally, it was thought will stagnate. However, Wicksell also asserted that, that if you wanted to boost the capital investment, the even in such a situation, the entrepreneurs are willing central bank would reduce interest rates. Wicksell [2] to invest if they face an inflation because it will in- (Chapters VIII and IX) defined natural rate of interest crease the monetary return. Therefore, he concluded that capital investment will increase as the real rate of interest, which is market rate of interest less the rate of ∗ Corresponding author: Kazusuke Tsujimura, Faculty of Eco- inflation, declines. The problem is what inflation rate nomics, Keio University, 2-15-45 Mita, Minato, Tokyo 108-8345, Japan. Tel.: +81 3 5427 1597; Fax: +81 3 5427 1640; E-mail: they have in their mind when the entrepreneurs make [email protected]. investment decisions. 1874-7655/18/$35.00 c 2018 – IOS Press and the authors. All rights reserved This article is published online with Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution Non-Commercial License (CC BY-NC 4.0). 236 I. Sakuma et al. / The value added and operating surplus deflators for industries A price index is a measure of the proportionate, or count, the value added consists of three major com- percentage, changes in a set of prices over time; usu- ponents: compensation of employees, taxes/subsidies ally it consists of per-unit transaction value of spe- on production and imports, and gross operating sur- cific product (prices) and some indicator of the pro- plus/mixed income. As paragraph 14.155 asserts, cal- portionate composition of the products (share weight) culating compensation of employees in volume terms among the group of products in question. For example, is possible if enough information is available on wage a consumer price index (CPI) measures changes in the rates and numbers employed by category of worker. prices of goods and services that households consume If it is possible, it is an easy task to obtain the defla- (ILO [3]). In an analogy, so called producer price in- tor for compensation of employees. However, it seems dex (PPI) measures changes in the prices of goods and far more difficult to know the taxes less subsidies on services that domestic producers produce. However, as production in volume terms. To obtain the deflator IMF [4] asserts, the producers are at the same time pur- for gross operating surplus, we have to overcome this chasers of goods and services because they consume critical problem. Despite all the difficulties, we tenta- other producers’ outputs as intermediate inputs – mate- tively obtained the deflator for gross operating surplus rials, components, fuels, etc. The value added deflator / mixed income for the Japanese industries to find out is a price indicator that takes this two-sidedness of the further problems we may encounter in practice. producers; it is defined as the proportion of the nom- inal value added to the real value added, which is ob- tainable by dividing both the output and the intermedi- 2. Value added deflator ate inputs in nominal terms by the appropriate price in- dices.1 The remaining problem is that the value added 2.1. Definitions deflator does not take the wage rate and other produc- tion factor cost into consideration; in this context, it is Before going into the empirical evidence, we exam- desirable to obtain the operating surplus deflator rather ine the theoretical meaning of the value added defla- than the value added deflator. This paper discusses the tors using a highly simplified use table in which one issues concerning the measurement of the deflators for industry produces only one product so that the table both value added and operating surplus for each indus- reduces to a symmetric input output table as shown in try. Table1 in current values (i.e. VAT inclusive). Note that After the tradition of the SNA 1968 (paragraphs 8.44 paragraph 5.2 of SNA 2008 basically defines industry through 8.47) and 1993 (15.162 through 15.164), the as a group of establishments engaged in the same pro- SNA 2008 discusses value added deflator in paragraphs duction activity. Let subscripts i; j = 1; : : : ; n and 14.153 through 14.157; it is defined using double de- k; l = 1; : : : ; n denote inputs and outputs respectively. flation method2 in the framework of the supply and use While Xik denotes intermediate input of i into k; Di, tables. The proportion of the domestic total of nomi- Ei, Mi and Ti indicate domestic final uses, exports, nal value added to that of real value added is casually imports and total domestic output of product i respec- referred to as GDP deflator (SNA 2008, 15.235); not tively. Vk is the gross value added generated in the pro- a few statistical authorities publish it as a part of GDP duction process of output k, which is defined as total statistics. Simple mathematics tells us that, as shown domestic output less intermediate inputs; the definition in Eq. (24) below, the GDP deflator is the weighted is equivalent to that at producer prices described in the harmonic mean of the value added deflators. However, SNA 2008, paragraph 6.78. As in the Chenery-Moses the meaning of the value added deflator for each indus- input-output model,3 which Table1 resembles to, we try is far more complicated because the weight for one assume that the domestic and imported products are in- particular item involves the prices of other items. different, and distributed among the domestic users at In addition to the value added deflator, the SNA a constant ratio that reflects the ratio of total imports to 2008 mentions the operating surplus deflator in 14.157. the domestic production. We assume that only the do- In the framework of the generation of income ac- mestic products are exported. Although the Chenery- Moses input-output model usually assumes ‘one price for one product’, we will assume that the import prices 1According to the definition of IMF [4], PPI includes not only output PPI but also input PPI and value-added PPI. 2Double deflation method is originally proposed by Fabricant [5] and sophisticated by Stone [6]. 3See Moses [7] and Chenery and Clark [8]. I. Sakuma et al. / The value added and operating surplus deflators for industries 237 Table 1 Symmetric use table at current prices Industries (production activities) Domestic Exports Imports Total domestic output 1 ··· k ··· n final uses Products 1 X11 ··· X1k ··· X1n D1 E1 −M1 T1 . .. .. i Xi1 ··· Xik ··· Xin Di Ei −Mi Ti . .. .. n Xn1 ··· Xnk ··· Xnn Dn En −Mn Tn Value Added V1 ··· Vk ··· Vn Total Output T1 ··· Tk ··· Tn Table 2 Symmetric use table presented in constant prices Industries (production activities) Domestic Exports Imports Total 1 ··· k ··· n final uses domestic output pd1 Products 1 p1x11 ··· p1x1k ··· p1x1n p1d1 1+τ e1 −pm1m1 pd1t1 . .. .. pdi i pixi1 ··· pixik ··· pixin pidi 1+τ ei −pmimi pd iti . .. .. pdn n pnxn1 ··· pnxnk ··· pnxnn pndn 1+τ en −pmnmn pd ntn Value Added pv1v1 ··· pvkvk ··· pvnvn Total Output pd1t1 ··· pdktk ··· pdntn are different from domestic prices following the obser- The above assumption tells us that the domestic and vations by Diewert and Nakamura [9] and Reinsdorf imported products are supplied to the domestic users at and Yuskavage [10] that the former affects the latter.
Recommended publications
  • A PORTRAIT of TRADE in VALUE-ADDED OVER FOUR DECADES Robert C
    A PORTRAIT OF TRADE IN VALUE-ADDED OVER FOUR DECADES Robert C. Johnson and Guillermo Noguera* Abstract—We combine data on trade, production, and input use to document We show that changes in trade frictions, particularly fric- changes in the value-added content of trade between 1970 and 2009. The ratio of value-added to gross exports fell by roughly 10 percentage points tions for manufactured inputs, play a key role in explaining worldwide. The ratio declined 20 percentage points in manufacturing, but all five stylized facts. rose in nonmanufacturing sectors. Declines also differ across countries and To track value-added trade over time, we combine time trade partners: they are larger for fast-growing countries, for nearby trade partners, and among partners that adopt regional trade agreements. Using series data on trade, production, and input use to con- a multisector structural gravity model with input-output linkages, we show struct an annual sequence of global bilateral input-output that changes in trade frictions play a dominant role in explaining all these tables covering 42 countries back to 1970. These synthetic facts. tables track shipments of final and intermediate goods within and between countries. Using this framework, we compute I. Introduction value-added exports: the amount of value added from a given source country that is consumed in each destination ECENT decades have seen the emergence of global (i.e., embodied in final goods absorbed in that destination) supply chains. Echoing Feenstra (1998), rising trade R (Johnson & Noguera, 2012a). Value-added exports mea- integration has coincided with the simultaneous disintegra- sure international transactions in a manner consistent with tion of production across borders.
    [Show full text]
  • Volume 3: Value-Added
    re Volume 3 Value-Added Tax Office of- the Secretary Department of the Treasury November '1984 TABLE OF CONTENTS Volume Three Page Chapter 1: INTRODUCTION 1 Chapter 2: THE NATURE OF THE VALUE-ADDED TAX I. Introduction TI. Alternative Forms of Tax A. Gross Product Type B. Income Type C. Consumption Type 111. Alternative Methods of Calculation: Subtraction, Credit, Addition 7 A. Subtraction Method 7 8. Credit Method 8 C. Addition Method 8 D. Analysis and Summary 10 IV. Border Tax Adjustments 11 V. Value-Added Tax versus Retail Sales Tax 13 VI. Summary 16 Chapter -3: EVALUATION OF A VALUE-ADDED TAX 17 I. Introduction 17 11. Economic Effects 17 A. Neutrality 17 B. saving 19 C. Equity 19 D. Prices 20 E. Balance of Trade 21 III. Political Concerns 23 A. Growth of Government 23 B. Impact on Income Tax 26 C. State-Local Tax Base 26 Iv. European Adoption and Experience 27 Chapter 4: ALTERNATIVE TYPES OF SALES TAXATION 29 I. Introduction 29 11. Analytic Framework 29 A. Consumption Neutrality 29 E. Production and Distribution Neutrality 30 111. Value-Added Tax 31 IV. Retail Sales Tax 31 V. Manufacturers and Other Pre-retail Taxes 33 VI. Personal Exemption Value-Added Tax 35 VII. Summary 38 iii Page Chapter 5: MAJOR DESIGN ISSUES 39 I. Introduction 39 11. Zero Rating versus Exemption 39 A. Commodities 39 B. Transactions 40 C. Firms 40 D. Consequences of zero Rating or Exemption 41 E. Tax Credit versus Subtraction Method 42 111. The Issue of Regressivity 43 A. Adjustment of Government Transfer Payments 43 B.
    [Show full text]
  • Operating Surplus (Income from Property)
    Class No.9: Unit 1 (National Income and related aggregates) Objective: After the class/ content you will become familiar with the components of operating surplus (income from property) Operating surplus: It is an income generated from property (rent + interest) and income from entrepreneurship (profit). Royalty is included in rent. Alternatively, it is the sum of rent, interest and profit. We can also define ‘It is Net value added at FC (i.e. domestic income) minus Compensation of employees (traditionally called wages) and mixed income of self-employed.’ Factor income (NDPFc) Mixed income of self Compensation of employees Operating surplus employed Income from property Income from entrepreneurship Rent Royalty interest Profit dividend profit tax Undistributed profit (Note: Interest on National Debt is not the part of Interest from property and thus it is ignored) Components of operating surplus: (1) Income from Property: It is an income generated from the property in form of rent, interest and royalty. (i) Rent: It is any periodic payment to an owner or factor of production in excess of the costs needed to bring that factor into production. It also refers as ‘Economic surplus’ as it is received by landlord without any effort. (ii) Royalty: A royalty is a legally-binding payment made to an individual, for using his or her originally- created assets, including copyrighted works, franchises, and natural resources. For example, use of mineral deposit such as coal, oil etc. Royalty is also associated with musicians, who receive such payments whenever their originally-recorded songs are played on the radio or television, used in movies, performed at concerts, bars, and restaurants, or consumed via streaming services.
    [Show full text]
  • Modeling the Economic Surplus in a SAM
    Modeling the Economic Surplus in a SAM Framework Erik K. Olsen Dept. of Economics Univ. of Missouri Kansas City 5100 Rockhill Rd. Kansas City, MO 64110 [email protected] June 21, 2011 1 Introduction The concept of an economic surplus is something that Marxian and Sra¢ an economics share in common. Both theories recognize the importance of an eco- nomic surplus that is produced and subsequently utilized for various purposes, but they each de…ne this surplus in very di¤erent ways. The surplus of Sra¢ an theory is the net product of the economy as de…ned in conventional national accounts. The surplus in Marxian theory is de…ned through its class theory. Draft prepared for 2011 Association for Heterodox Economics conference, Nottingham Trent University. 1 From the Marxist perspective the surplus created by production provides the resources that support the array of nonproduction activities associated with the capitalist enterprise as well as for many activities and individuals that may be quite distant. Shareholders of a corporation, for example, receive an in- come derived from the surplus created in production, but this is simply one of many potential uses. Identifying the connection between the surplus created in production and the subsequent recipients is the task of Marxian class theory, and this provides a means to understand how the surplus created in production plays a role in the reproduction of the economic system itself. This emphasis on a complex class structure that is part of the fabric of the economy is what distinguishes Marxian class theory from the Sra¢ an one, and it is also what distinguishes their two di¤erent theories of surplus.
    [Show full text]
  • Productivity Dispersion, Between-Firm Competition and the Labor Share
    Productivity Dispersion, Between-firm Competition and the Labor Share Preliminary and incomplete version, please do not cite. Emilien´ Gouin-Bonenfant∗ August 2017 Abstract: In this paper, I study how the pass-through of productivity to wages depends on the distribution of productivity across firms. Using administrative data covering the universe of Canadian corporations, I document high concentration of value added within highly productive, low-labor-share firms. Impor- tantly, these large firms do not have a higher capital-output ratio and achieve a low labor share despite paying above average salaries. To interpret these findings, I develop a tractable firm dynamics model (a` la Hopenhayn[1992]) with search frictions and wage posting in the labor market ( a` la Burdett and Mortensen [1998]). In the model, more productive firms offer higher wages in order to increase their market share by poaching workers from lower paying firms. As in the data, most firms have a high labor share, routinely above one, yet the aggregate labor share is low due to the disproportionate effect of a small fraction of large, extremely productive “superstar firms”. The model predicts that the pass-through of aggregate labor pro- ductivity to average wages is lower when productivity dispersion across firm is high, meaning that all else equal, an increase in productivity dispersion decreases the aggregate labor share. The mechanism is that an increase in the productivity differential between high and low productivity firms increases profit margins at high productivity firms, who become effectively shielded from wage competition. I test the model’s pre- diction and mechanism using cross-country data and find support, thus suggesting that the measured rise in productivity dispersion has contributed to the decline of the global labor share.
    [Show full text]
  • 17 National Accounts and Economic Statistics STD/NAES(2005)
    For Official Use STD/NAES(2005)17 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 29-Sep-2005 ___________________________________________________________________________________________ English - Or. English STATISTICS DIRECTORATE For Official Use STD/NAES(2005)17 National Accounts and Economic Statistics COST OF CAPITAL SERVICES AND THE NATIONAL ACCOUNTS UPDATE OF THE 1993 SNA - ISSUE No. 15 ISSUES PAPER FOR THE JULY 2005 AEG MEETING This paper has been prepared by Paul Schreyer, W. Erwin Diewert and Anne Harrison WORKING PARTY ON NATIONAL STATISTICS To be held on 11 - 14 October 2005 Tour Europe - Paris La Défense Beginning at 9:30 a.m. on the first day English - Or. English JT00190606 Document complet disponible sur OLIS dans son format d'origine Complete document available on OLIS in its original format STD/NAES(2005)17 COST OF CAPITAL SERVICES AND THE NATIONAL ACCOUNTS SNA/M1.05/04 UPDATE OF THE 1993 SNA - ISSUE No. 15 ISSUES PAPER FOR THE JULY 2005 AEG MEETING Paul Schreyer W. Erwin Diewert Anne Harrison EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Background 1. The topic of capital services has been discussed in various Canberra II Group meetings, including those of October 2003, April 2004, September 2004 and April 2005. It has also been discussed in meetings in Eurostat, at the OECD national accounts meeting and at the AEG meeting in December 2004. At its latest meeting in April 2005, the Canberra II Group supported the recommendations in the paper by Schreyer, Diewert and Harrison (2005) with some minor modifications. 2. The main messages to emerge from all of the meetings listed above is clear; few countries at present have a sufficiently detailed capital stock database to present robust capital service figures and even of those which do, not all are yet ready to publish these data as part of the main national accounts.
    [Show full text]
  • Gross Domestic Product and Agriculture Value Added 1970–2019 Global and Regional Trends Gross Domestic Product and Agriculture Value Added 1970–2019
    006X [Print] 0078 [Online] - - ISSN ISSN 2709 ISSN 2709 FAOSTAT ANALYTICAL BRIEF 23 Gross domestic product and agriculture value added 1970–2019 Global and regional trends Gross domestic product and agriculture value added 1970–2019. Global and regional trends FAOSTAT Analytical Brief 23 HIGHLIGHTS The global gross domestic product* (GDP) grew from USD 66.4 trillion in 2011 to USD 83.5 trillion in 2019, at an average annual rate of 3.0 percent. Over the same period, the global value added of the agriculture sector** rose from USD 2.8 trillion to USD 3.5 trillion, at an average rate of 2.9 percent. Investment in capital, measured by the share of the gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) in GDP, remained relatively stable, ranging from 24.1 percent to 25.7 percent between 2011 and 2019. The share of agriculture value added in GDP remained stable between 4.23 percent in 2011 and 4.27 percent in 2019. * All values in the paper are measured in 2015 constant USD. ** The agriculture sector includes agriculture, forestry and fishing. FAOSTAT DOMAIN NAME GLOBAL AND REGIONAL Global GDP increased by 3.2 percent annually on average from USD 18 trillion in 1970 to USD 83.5 trillion in 2019. However, during the last decade, its increase slowed a little to 3.0 percent annually on average, from USD 66.4 trillion to USD 83.5 trillion. Europe’s GDP growth rate of 1.3 percent in between 1991 and 2000 was the smallest during the whole period: this significant decrease is mainly due to the impact of the collapse of the Soviet Union.
    [Show full text]
  • Did JP Morgan's Men Add Value?
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Inside the Business Enterprise: Historical Perspectives on the Use of Information Volume Author/Editor: Peter Temin, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press, 1991 Volume ISBN: 0-226-79202-1 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/temi91-1 Conference Date: October 26-27, 1990 Publication Date: January 1991 Chapter Title: Did J. P. Morgan's Men Add Value? An Economist's Perspective on Financial Capitalism Chapter Author: J. Bradford DeLong Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c7182 Chapter pages in book: (p. 205 - 250) 6 Did J. P. Morgan’s Men Add Value? An Economist’s Perspective on Financial Capitalism J. Bradford De Long 6.1 Introduction The pre-World War I period saw the heyday of “financial capitalism” in the United States: securities issues in particular and the investment banking busi- ness in general were concentrated in the hands of a very few investment bank- ers-of which the partnership of J. P. Morgan and Company was by far the largest and most prominent-who played substantial roles on corporate boards of directors. This form of association between finance and industry had costs: it created conflicts of interest that investment bankers could exploit for their own profit. It also had benefits, at least from the owners’ perspective:’ investment banker representation on boards allowed bankers to assess the per- formance of firm managers, quickly replace managers whose performance was unsatisfactory, and signal to investors that a company was fundamentally sound.
    [Show full text]
  • For Official Use STD/NA(99)54
    For Official Use STD/NA(99)54 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques OLIS : 01-Sep-1999 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Dist. : 02-Sep-1999 __________________________________________________________________________________________ Or. Eng. STATISTICS DIRECTORATE For Official Use STD/NA(99)54 National Accounts REVISION DUTCH NATIONAL ACCOUNTS; FIRST RESULTS AND BACKGROUNDS Agenda item 13 Statistics Netherlands OECD MEETING OF NATIONAL ACCOUNTS EXPERTS Château de la Muette, Paris 21-24 September 1999 Beginning at 9:30 a.m. on the first day Or. Eng. 80957 Document complet disponible sur OLIS dans son format d'origine Complete document available on OLIS in its original format STD/NA(99)54 REVISION DUTCH NATIONAL ACCOUNTS; FIRST RESULTS AND BACKGROUNDS Gert Buiten, Jacqueline van den Hof and Peter van de Ven Summary and introduction As in many other countries, the national accounts of The Netherlands have been revised, in accordance with the new worldwide System of National Accounts (SNA) 1993, and its European equivalent, the European System of National and Regional Accounts (ESA) 1995. As a consequence, the new national accounts data give a better picture of a number of recent developments, like the expanding importance of services, automation, information and knowledge. In addition, new statistical insights and results have been incorporated. The revision has implications for the macro-economic description and for a number of policy indicators. For the year 1995, Gross Domestic Product (GDP) has been adjusted upwards by 26.4 billion guilders, an increase of 4.1%. The upward adjustment is largely caused by the implementation of the new international guidelines. The net national income (NNI) has increased less (1.1%), since a large part of the changes concerns an upward adjustment of consumption of fixed capital.
    [Show full text]
  • Why the Fairtax Won't Work
    (C) Tax Analysts 2007. All rights reserved. does not claim copyright in any public domain or third party content. Why the FairTax Won’t Work an aging society could be borne with relative ease.1 Unfortunately, the administrative problems inherent in By Bruce Bartlett this proposal make it impossible to take seriously. People know how the current tax system operates. They receive gross wages from their employers and automatically have income and payroll taxes withheld Bruce Bartlett was formerly Treasury deputy assis- from their paychecks. A worker may see that his em- tant secretary for economic policy and executive di- ployer pays him $1,000 per week, but he has only $800 to rector of the congressional Joint Economic Committee. spend because of all the taxes. In this article, he criticizes the FairTax, a tax reform FairTax advocates repeatedly claim that their proposal proposal supported by former Arkansas Gov. Mike would allow all workers to keep 100 percent of their Huckabee, a candidate for the Republican presidential paychecks. The clear implication is that withholding nomination. The proposal alleges that a 23 percent would simply disappear. The worker now netting $800 national retail sales tax collected by the states would per week would immediately get a $200 raise and start be sufficient to replace all federal taxes. That would taking home the full $1,000 gross wage that he is paid. allow for abolition of the IRS and other benefits, Instead of paying income and payroll taxes, workers supporters claim. would pay their taxes when they buy things. The FairTax would impose a 23 percent tax on all goods and services.
    [Show full text]
  • STAN ISIC Rev. 3 Variables
    Variables in STAN To meet basic requirements of international research and analysis in areas such as productivity, competitiveness and general structural change, STAN provides the variables presented in the table below. Summary of variables provided in STAN Description STAN code Old STAN code Production (gross output), current prices PROD PROD Production (gross output), volumes PRDK PRODK Production (Gross Output), deflators PRDP Intermediate inputs, current prices INTI INTI Intermediate inputs, volumes INTK INTIK Intermediate inputs, deflators INTP Value added, current prices VALU VALU Value added, volumes VALK VALUK Value Added, deflators VALP Labour costs (compensation of employees) LABR LABR Wages and salaries WAGE WAGE Number of persons engaged (total employment) EMPN EMPN Number of employees EMPE EMPE Self-employed SELF Full-time equivalents - total engaged FTEN EMPN_FTE Full-time equivalents - employees FTEE EMPE_FTE Hours worked - total engaged HRSN HOURS Hours worked - employees HRSE HOURS Gross fixed capital formation, current prices GFCF GFCF Gross fixed capital formation, volumes GFCK GFCFK Gross Fixed Capital Formation, deflators GFCP Gross capital stock, volumes CPGK CAPK Net capital stock, volumes CPNK CPNK Exports of goods at current prices EXPO EXPO Imports of goods at current prices IMPO IMPO Value added at factor costs, current prices VAFC Other taxes less subsidies on production OTXS Gross operating surplus and mixed income GOPS OPS Net operating surplus and mixed income NOPS OPS Consumption of fixed capital CFCC CFC STAN data are expressed : ● in national currency for current price data (PROD, VALU, GFCF, LABR, EXPO etc.) i.e. in Euros for EMU countries ; see OECD Statistics Newsletter no.4., p.6.
    [Show full text]
  • Abstract Labor: Substance Or Form
    ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM? A CRITIQUE OF THE VALUE-FORM INTERPRETATION OF MARX’S THEORY by Fred Moseley Universidad Autonoma Metropolitana (Mexico City) Mount Holyoke College (Massachusetts) May 1997 Our analysis has shown that the form of value, that is the expression of the value of a commodity, arises from the nature of commodity value, as opposed to value and its magnitude arising from their mode of expression as exchange-value. Marx (C. I. 152) It is not money that renders commodities commensurable. Quite the contrary. Because all commodities, as values, are objective human labor and therefore themselves commensurable, their values can be communally measured in one and the same commodity. Mon ey is the necessary form of appearance of the measure of value immanent in commodities - labor-time. Marx (C.I. 188) ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM? A CRITIQUE OF THE VALUE-FORM INTERPRETATION OF MARX’S THEORY In the Introduction to our first book, I wrote: All the authors agree that Marx attempted in Section 1 of Chapter 1 of Capital to derive abstract labor as the "substance of value," which exists prior to exchange - although it is not observable - and which determines the exchange values of com modities. But there is significant disagreement over the validity file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/mhcuserxp/Desktop/VALUEFRM.htm (1 of 15)10/15/2005 2:29:42 PM ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM and necessity of Marx’s derivation. Indeed this disagreement is probably the most significant one amount the authors. This controversy has a long history beginning with Boehm-Bawerk.
    [Show full text]