Gross Domestic Product and Agriculture Value Added 1970–2019 Global and Regional Trends Gross Domestic Product and Agriculture Value Added 1970–2019

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Gross Domestic Product and Agriculture Value Added 1970–2019 Global and Regional Trends Gross Domestic Product and Agriculture Value Added 1970–2019 006X [Print] 0078 [Online] - - ISSN ISSN 2709 ISSN 2709 FAOSTAT ANALYTICAL BRIEF 23 Gross domestic product and agriculture value added 1970–2019 Global and regional trends Gross domestic product and agriculture value added 1970–2019. Global and regional trends FAOSTAT Analytical Brief 23 HIGHLIGHTS The global gross domestic product* (GDP) grew from USD 66.4 trillion in 2011 to USD 83.5 trillion in 2019, at an average annual rate of 3.0 percent. Over the same period, the global value added of the agriculture sector** rose from USD 2.8 trillion to USD 3.5 trillion, at an average rate of 2.9 percent. Investment in capital, measured by the share of the gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) in GDP, remained relatively stable, ranging from 24.1 percent to 25.7 percent between 2011 and 2019. The share of agriculture value added in GDP remained stable between 4.23 percent in 2011 and 4.27 percent in 2019. * All values in the paper are measured in 2015 constant USD. ** The agriculture sector includes agriculture, forestry and fishing. FAOSTAT DOMAIN NAME GLOBAL AND REGIONAL Global GDP increased by 3.2 percent annually on average from USD 18 trillion in 1970 to USD 83.5 trillion in 2019. However, during the last decade, its increase slowed a little to 3.0 percent annually on average, from USD 66.4 trillion to USD 83.5 trillion. Europe’s GDP growth rate of 1.3 percent in between 1991 and 2000 was the smallest during the whole period: this significant decrease is mainly due to the impact of the collapse of the Soviet Union. The drop in Africa’s GDP growth between 1981 and 2000 stems from a combination of internal conflicts, adverse weather conditions and a deterioration in the terms of trade, while the reduction experienced between 2011 and 2019 is largely due to the dramatic contraction of Libya’s GDP between 2013 and 2016. Throughout the 1970–2019 period, Asia showed the highest growth rate during each decade, sharing the top spot with Africa during the 2000s (Figure 1 and Table 1). Figure 1. Global and regional GDP, 1970–2019 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 USD USD 2015 trillion 20 10 0 1970 1977 1984 1991 1998 2005 2012 2019 Africa Americas Asia Europe Oceania World Source: United Nations Statistics Division (UNSD) and Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) for the calculation of regional trends of macro indicators. Table 1: Regional growth rate of GDP, annual average (percent) 1971–1980 1981–1990 1991–2000 2001–2010 2011–2019 1971–2019 Africa 4.4 1.9 2.4 5.5 2.9 3.4 Americas 3.8 2.9 3.3 2.0 2.0 2.8 Asia 5.2 5.1 4.3 5.5 5.0 5.0 Europe 3.4 2.8 1.3 1.7 1.6 2.2 Oceania 2.8 2.8 3.5 3.1 2.5 2.9 World 3.9 3.3 2.8 3.0 3.0 3.2 Source: UNSD and FAO for the calculation of regional trends of macro indicators. Asia’s contribution to global GDP increased greatly from 32.3 percent in 2011 to 37.6 percent in 2019, with Eastern Asia (which includes China, Japan and the Republic of Korea) accounting for 25.1 percent of global GDP in 2019. Throughout this period, Europe’s share in world GDP shrank from 27.7 percent to 24.8 percent, and America’s share decreased from 34.9 percent to 32.5 percent. The contribution of Africa and Oceania to global GDP remained stable at 3.1 percent and 2 percent respectively (Figure 2). Gross domestic product and agriculture value added 1970–2019. Global and regional trends FAOSTAT Analytical Brief 23 Figure 2. Regional contribution to global GDP, 1970–2019 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1970 1977 1984 1991 1998 2005 2012 2019 Africa Americas Asia Europe Oceania Source: UNSD and FAO for the calculation of regional trends of macro indicators. World GDP per capita increased by 14.8 percent, from USD 9 459.0 in 2011 to USD 10 860.3 in 2019. Over the same period, Asia experienced the highest increase, of 35.3 percent, followed by Europe (11.3 percent), Oceania (6.8 percent), the Americas (9.0 percent) and Africa (5.6 percent) (Table 2). Table 2. Regional GDP per capita (USD) 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2019 Africa 1 244.9 1 455.0 1 424.4 1 402.3 1 939.3 1 983.7 Americas 13 475.8 16 407.2 18 490.6 22 251.4 24 279.5 26 793.0 Asia 1 346.5 1 799.7 2 431.9 3 194.7 4 840.2 6 863.6 Europe 7 821.7 10 239.3 15 607.2 21 041.3 24 448.8 27 691.0 Oceania 19 494.6 22 067.2 24 827.3 30 364.4 34 888.9 37 987.8 World 4 498.9 5 478.7 6 616.5 7 775.6 9 270.6 10 860.3 Source: UNSD and FAO for the calculation of regional trends of macro indicators. INVESTMENT DRIVES GDP GROWTH Investment in capital, measured by the gross fixed capital formation (GFCF), was a key driver of GDP growth globally. It increased by 416 percent, or 3.4 percent per year on average, thus more than the 3.2 percent average annual growth rate of GDP. Over the last decade, GFCF went up 34 percent from USD 15.97 trillion in 2011. (Figure 3). Figure 3. Global and regional gross fixed capital formation, 1970–2019 25 20 15 10 USD USD trillion 5 0 1970 1977 1984 1991 1998 2005 2012 2019 Africa Americas Asia Europe Oceania World Source: UNSD and FAO for the calculation of regional trends of macro indicators. Asia witnessed the highest increase in investment in the last decade, from USD 6.82 trillion in 2011 to USD 10.4 trillion in 2019, thus increasing the region’s share in global investment from 42.7 percent to 48.7 percent, with Eastern Asia alone accounting for 35.5 percent of global GFCF in 2019. The share of all the other regions in the world total decreased for the same period (Figure 4). Gross domestic product and agriculture value added 1970–2019. Global and regional trends FAOSTAT Analytical Brief 23 Figure 4. Regional contribution to global gross fixed capital formation, 1970–2019 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1970 1977 1984 1991 1998 2005 2012 2019 Africa Americas Asia Europe Oceania Source: UNSD and FAO for the calculation of regional trends of macro indicators. The investment ratio, which is the ratio of GFCF to GDP, remained relatively stable globally between 1970 and 2019, ranging between 21.8 percent and 24.8 percent. Overall, it is the lowest in the Americas, with an average value of 19.4 percent during the period and very small fluctuations. It steadily declined in Europe, while it kept increasing each decade in Asia and Oceania. Africa experienced a decline between the 1970s and the 1990s, but grew again during the 2000s and 2010s (Table 3). Table 3. Regional investment ratio (GFCF share of GDP), annual average (percent) 1970–1980 1981–1990 1991–2000 2001–2010 2011–2019 1970–2019 Africa 29.4 23.9 20.5 20.9 21.9 23.5 Americas 18.8 18.4 19.1 20.5 20.6 19.4 Asia 26.2 26.7 27.9 28.6 32.8 28.3 Europe 25.9 23.4 20.7 20.9 20.4 22.4 Oceania 17.2 19.5 19.8 24.9 25.9 21.3 World 23.1 22.1 21.8 23.0 25.0 23.0 Source: UNSD and FAO for the calculation of regional trends of macro indicators. THE SHARE OF AGRICULTURE VALUE ADDED IN GDP KEEPS DECLINING Global agriculture value added rose from USD 0.95 trillion in 1970 to USD 3.5 trillion in 2019, while the sector’s contribution to GDP fell from 5.3 percent to 4.2 percent (Figure 5). This relative decline was due to a faster growth of non-agricultural activities than agriculture. The sector, however, affects the quality of the environment and food security beyond what is captured by its contribution to the overall GDP. Figure 5. Global agriculture value added and contribution to GDP, 1970–2019 4.0 6% 3.5 5% 3.0 4% 2.5 2.0 3% 1.5 2% USD USD 2015 trillion 1.0 1% 0.5 0.0 0% 1970 1977 1984 1991 1998 2005 2012 2019 Agriculture Value Added Agriculture Value Added Share of GDP Source: UNSD and FAO for the calculation of regional trends of macro indicators. During the last decade, Asia was the main contributor to the global value added of agriculture, accounting for 61.8 percent in 2011 and 63.7 percent in 2019, driven by the contribution of Eastern Asia with 34.8 percent and Southern Asia with 16.7 percent in 2019. In contrast, the share of Europe significantly declined from 11.2 percent in 2011 to 9.5 percent in 2019. The changes to the contribution of other regions were more limited: from 10.7 percent to 11.5 percent for Africa, from 14.7 percent to 14.1 percent for the Americas, and from 1.6 percent to 1.2 percent for Oceania (Figure 6).
Recommended publications
  • A PORTRAIT of TRADE in VALUE-ADDED OVER FOUR DECADES Robert C
    A PORTRAIT OF TRADE IN VALUE-ADDED OVER FOUR DECADES Robert C. Johnson and Guillermo Noguera* Abstract—We combine data on trade, production, and input use to document We show that changes in trade frictions, particularly fric- changes in the value-added content of trade between 1970 and 2009. The ratio of value-added to gross exports fell by roughly 10 percentage points tions for manufactured inputs, play a key role in explaining worldwide. The ratio declined 20 percentage points in manufacturing, but all five stylized facts. rose in nonmanufacturing sectors. Declines also differ across countries and To track value-added trade over time, we combine time trade partners: they are larger for fast-growing countries, for nearby trade partners, and among partners that adopt regional trade agreements. Using series data on trade, production, and input use to con- a multisector structural gravity model with input-output linkages, we show struct an annual sequence of global bilateral input-output that changes in trade frictions play a dominant role in explaining all these tables covering 42 countries back to 1970. These synthetic facts. tables track shipments of final and intermediate goods within and between countries. Using this framework, we compute I. Introduction value-added exports: the amount of value added from a given source country that is consumed in each destination ECENT decades have seen the emergence of global (i.e., embodied in final goods absorbed in that destination) supply chains. Echoing Feenstra (1998), rising trade R (Johnson & Noguera, 2012a). Value-added exports mea- integration has coincided with the simultaneous disintegra- sure international transactions in a manner consistent with tion of production across borders.
    [Show full text]
  • Capital Expenditures and Gross Fixed Capital Formation in Nigeria
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by International Institute for Science, Technology and Education (IISTE): E-Journals Research Journal of Finance and Accounting www.iiste.org ISSN 2222-1697 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2847 (Online) Vol.6, No.12, 2015 Capital Expenditures and Gross Fixed Capital Formation in Nigeria *Kanu, Success Ikechi Ph.D and Nwaimo, Chilaka Emmanuel Ph.D Department of Management technology (FMT), Federal university of technology, Owerri (FUTO) P.M.B 1526, Owerri,, Imo State, Nigeria. Abstract This paper explores the relationship between capital expenditures and gross fixed capital formation in Nigeria. The study made use of secondary data covering the period 1981 to 2011. A least square regression analysis was carried out on a time series data, and to avert the emergence of spurious results, unit root tests were conducted. Other econometric tools of co- integration, Vector Auto Regression technique as well as Granger causality tests were deployed to ascertain the order of co integration and the level of relationships existing between the dependent and independent variables. Findings of study reveal that while Capital Expenditures (CAPEX) maintained a negative significant relationship with Gross Fixed Capital Formation (GFCF) in Nigeria at both 1% and 5% Alpha levels; Imports and National Savings had a positive significant relationship with GFCF at both the short and long runs. It was equally observed that the lagged value of GFCF had no significant impact on GFCF in the preceding year. Outcome of study did not come as a surprise, seeing that a functional classification of Nigeria’s expenditure profile for the period under review reveals that; outlays on capital expenditure accounted for only about 32% of total expenditures, while the remaining balance of 68 % went to recurrent expenditures.
    [Show full text]
  • Volume 3: Value-Added
    re Volume 3 Value-Added Tax Office of- the Secretary Department of the Treasury November '1984 TABLE OF CONTENTS Volume Three Page Chapter 1: INTRODUCTION 1 Chapter 2: THE NATURE OF THE VALUE-ADDED TAX I. Introduction TI. Alternative Forms of Tax A. Gross Product Type B. Income Type C. Consumption Type 111. Alternative Methods of Calculation: Subtraction, Credit, Addition 7 A. Subtraction Method 7 8. Credit Method 8 C. Addition Method 8 D. Analysis and Summary 10 IV. Border Tax Adjustments 11 V. Value-Added Tax versus Retail Sales Tax 13 VI. Summary 16 Chapter -3: EVALUATION OF A VALUE-ADDED TAX 17 I. Introduction 17 11. Economic Effects 17 A. Neutrality 17 B. saving 19 C. Equity 19 D. Prices 20 E. Balance of Trade 21 III. Political Concerns 23 A. Growth of Government 23 B. Impact on Income Tax 26 C. State-Local Tax Base 26 Iv. European Adoption and Experience 27 Chapter 4: ALTERNATIVE TYPES OF SALES TAXATION 29 I. Introduction 29 11. Analytic Framework 29 A. Consumption Neutrality 29 E. Production and Distribution Neutrality 30 111. Value-Added Tax 31 IV. Retail Sales Tax 31 V. Manufacturers and Other Pre-retail Taxes 33 VI. Personal Exemption Value-Added Tax 35 VII. Summary 38 iii Page Chapter 5: MAJOR DESIGN ISSUES 39 I. Introduction 39 11. Zero Rating versus Exemption 39 A. Commodities 39 B. Transactions 40 C. Firms 40 D. Consequences of zero Rating or Exemption 41 E. Tax Credit versus Subtraction Method 42 111. The Issue of Regressivity 43 A. Adjustment of Government Transfer Payments 43 B.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Financial Services: Capital Markets
    Updated January 4, 2021 Introduction to Financial Services: Capital Markets This In Focus provides an overview of U.S. capital markets, stocks and bonds to enable investors to make informed Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) regulation, decisions on whether to invest and at what price level to and related policy issues. compensate for their risks. Banking regulators, by contrast, focus more on safety and soundness to avoid bank failure. Market Composition This is largely because bank deposits are often ultimately Capital markets are where securities like stocks and bonds guaranteed by the taxpayers, whereas in capital markets, are issued and traded. U.S. capital markets instruments investors generally assume all the risk of loss. include (1) stocks, also called equities or shares, referring to ownership of a firm; (2) bonds, also called fixed income or Public and Private Securities Offerings. The SEC debt securities, referring to the indebtedness or creditorship requires that offers and sales of securities, such as stocks of a firm or a government entity; and (3) shares of and bonds, either be registered with the SEC or undertaken investment funds, which are forms of pooled investment pursuant to a specific exemption. The goal of registration is vehicles that consolidate money from investors. to ensure that investors receive key information on the securities being offered. Registered offerings, often called As a main segment of the financial system, capital markets public offerings, are available to all types of investors. By provide the largest sources of financing for U.S. contrast, securities offerings that are exempt from certain nonfinancial companies.
    [Show full text]
  • Ajai Chopra and Charles Collyns Long-Term Growth I Response to the 1991 Crisis I Results of Adjustment I Fiscal Initiatives 2 Structural Reforms 2 the Road Ahead 3
    OCCASIO NAL PAPE R 134 India: Economic Reform and Growth Ajai Chopra, Charles Collyns, Richard Hemming, and Karen Parker with Woosik Chu and Oliver Fratzscher INTERNAT IONAL MONETARY FUND Washington DC December 1995 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution © 1995 International Monetary Fund Cataloging-in-Publication Data India: economic reform and growth/Ajai Chopra ... [et a1.].­ Washington, D.C. :International Monetary Fund, 1995 p. em.- (Occasional Paper, ISSN 0251-6365; 134) Includes bibliographical references. ISBN l-55775-539-6 l. India - Economic policy- 1980- . 2. Structural adjustment (Economic policy)- India. 3.Investments- India. I.Chopra, Ajai. II.Series: Occasional paper (InternationalMonetary Fund) ; no. 134. HC 435.2.163 1995 Price: US$15.00 (US$12.00 to full-time faculty members and students at universities and colleges) Please send orders to: International Monetary Fund, Publication Services 700 19th Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A. Tel.: (202) 623-7430 Telefax: (202) 623-7201 Internet: [email protected] recycled paper ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Contents Page Preface vii Abbreviations ix Overview Ajai Chopra and Charles Collyns Long-Term Growth I Response to the 1991 Crisis I Results of Adjustment I Fiscal Initiatives 2 Structural Reforms 2 The Road Ahead 3 II long-Term GrowthTrends 4 Ajai Chopra Output, Investment, and Macroeconomic Conditions 4 Education, Labor, Employment, and Poverty 7 Growth, Accumulation, and Productivity 9 Results of India-Specific Studies 13
    [Show full text]
  • Money Supply, Inflation and Capital Accumulation in Nigeria
    Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development www.iiste.org ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.4, No.4, 2013 Money Supply, Inflation and Capital Accumulation in Nigeria Dayo Benedict Olanipekun 1* Kemi Funlayo Akeju 1,2 1 Department of Economics, University of Ibadan, Ibadan, Oyo State, Nigeria. 2 Department of Economics, Ekiti State University, Ado Ekiti, Ekiti State, Nigeria. *e-mail: [email protected] Abstract This study examines the relationship between money supply, inflation and capital accumulation in Nigeria between 1970 and 2010. The study investigated the long run relationship of the variables using Johasen cointegration test. As a follow up to this, Error Correction Model was conducted on the variables to capture their short run disequilibrium behavior. Cointegration test reveals that variables employed in the study share long run relationship. The result of the Error Correction Model indicates that money supply (both broad and narrow) has a positive relationship to capital accumulation in Nigeria. It implies that government should direct finances on investment in other to stimulate economic growth in the country. Also the intention of government on inflation targeting should not neglect the contribution of money growth to capital accumulation. Keywords: Money growth, Inflation, Capital accumulation, Cointegration test, Error Correction Model and Stability test. 1. Introduction Money supply exerts considerable influence on economic activities in both developing and developed countries. The relationships between money growth, inflation and capital accumulation are core issues in developing counties due to the need to achieve a sustainable economic growth and development. Achieving a very low inflation rate has been the primary goal of monetary policy makers in many developing countries including Nigeria but most of the government policies to generate low inflation end up accelerating it.
    [Show full text]
  • Partisan Politics, the Welfare State, and Three Worlds of Human Capital
    Comparative Political Studies Volume XX Number X Month XXXX xx-xx © 2008 Sage Publications 10.1177/0010414007313117 Partisan Politics, the Welfare http://cps.sagepub.com hosted at State, and Three Worlds of http://online.sagepub.com Human Capital Formation Torben Iversen Harvard University, Cambridge, MA John D. Stephens University of North Carolina–Chapel Hill The authors propose a synthesis of power resources theory and welfare production regime theory to explain differences in human capital formation across advanced democracies. Emphasizing the mutually reinforcing relation- ships between social insurance, skill formation, and spending on public educa- tion, they distinguish three distinct worlds of human capital formation: one characterized by redistribution and heavy investment in public education and industry-specific and occupation-specific vocational skills; one characterized by high social insurance and vocational training in firm-specific and industry- specific skills but less spending on public education; and one characterized by heavy private investment in general skills but modest spending on public edu- cation and redistribution. They trace the three worlds to historical differences in the organization of capitalism, electoral institutions, and partisan politics, emphasizing the distinct character of political coalition formation underpinning each of the three models. They also discuss the implications for inequality and labor market stratification across time and space. Keywords: education; skills; welfare states; redistribution;
    [Show full text]
  • Productivity Dispersion, Between-Firm Competition and the Labor Share
    Productivity Dispersion, Between-firm Competition and the Labor Share Preliminary and incomplete version, please do not cite. Emilien´ Gouin-Bonenfant∗ August 2017 Abstract: In this paper, I study how the pass-through of productivity to wages depends on the distribution of productivity across firms. Using administrative data covering the universe of Canadian corporations, I document high concentration of value added within highly productive, low-labor-share firms. Impor- tantly, these large firms do not have a higher capital-output ratio and achieve a low labor share despite paying above average salaries. To interpret these findings, I develop a tractable firm dynamics model (a` la Hopenhayn[1992]) with search frictions and wage posting in the labor market ( a` la Burdett and Mortensen [1998]). In the model, more productive firms offer higher wages in order to increase their market share by poaching workers from lower paying firms. As in the data, most firms have a high labor share, routinely above one, yet the aggregate labor share is low due to the disproportionate effect of a small fraction of large, extremely productive “superstar firms”. The model predicts that the pass-through of aggregate labor pro- ductivity to average wages is lower when productivity dispersion across firm is high, meaning that all else equal, an increase in productivity dispersion decreases the aggregate labor share. The mechanism is that an increase in the productivity differential between high and low productivity firms increases profit margins at high productivity firms, who become effectively shielded from wage competition. I test the model’s pre- diction and mechanism using cross-country data and find support, thus suggesting that the measured rise in productivity dispersion has contributed to the decline of the global labor share.
    [Show full text]
  • In the Process of Privatisation
    BCN IC HPBRS COMMISSIOTII OI THE EUROPEAIII COMMUITIITIES DI R ECTORATE.GEiIERAL FOR ECOiIOMIC ATIID FIiIAiICIAI AFFAI RS Number 98 November L992 The Role of the Banking Sector in the Process of Privatisation Domenico Mario Nuti* "Economic Papers" are written by the Sfaff of the Directorate- General for Economic and Financial Affairs, or by experts working in assoc iatiOn with them. The "Papers" are intended to increase awareness of the technical work being done by the staff and to seek comments and suggesfions for f urther analyses. They may not be quoted without authorisation. Views expressed represent exclusively the positions of the author and do not necessa rily correspond with those of the Commission of the European Communities. Comments and enquiries shou/d be addressed to: The Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, Commission of the European Communities, 200, rue de la Loi 1049 Brussels, Belgium ECONOMIC PAPERS Number98 November 1992 The Role of the Banking Sector in the Process of Privatisation Domenico Mario Nuti* • University of Rome "La Sapienza". At present Economic Adviser at the Commission of the European Communities. • An earlier draft of this paper was presented at the meeting of the OECD Advisory Group on Privatisation, on "The role of financial institutions in the privatisation process", Warsaw, 8-10 July 1992. Acknowledgements for useful comments are due to participants, especially to Hans Blommestein, Grant Kirkpatrick, Sir Adam Ridley, Ted Rybczynski and Jerzy Thieme. W488/92-EN This paper exists in English only. C CECA- CEE- CEEA, Bruxelles-Luxembourg, 1992. 1. Introduction. The progress of privatisation, broadly understood to include both the transfer of state assets to private owners and the autonomous growth of old and new private enterprises, depends crucially on a variety of functions to be performed by banks and other financial intermediaries.
    [Show full text]
  • Purchasing Power Parities and Real Expenditures a Summary Report
    Purchasing Power Parities and Real Expenditures A Summary Report This report presents the summary results of purchasing power parties (PPP) in the 2011 International Comparison Program in Asia and the Pacific and background information on the concepts that underpin the results. The PPPs are disaggregated by major economic aggregates and enable cross-country comparison on total gross domestic expenditure, which reflects size of economies; per capita real gross domestic expenditure which identifies economies that are rich; real per capita actual final consumption which measures economic well-being; gross fixed capital formation which reflects investment levels; and price level indexes which indicate relative cost of living by economy. About the Asian Development Bank ADB’s vision is an Asia and Pacific region free of poverty. Its mission is to help its developing member countries reduce poverty and improve the quality of life of their people. Despite the region’s many successes, it remains home to two-thirds of the world’s poor: 1.7 billion people who live on less than $2 a day, with 828 million struggling on less than $1.25 a day. ADB is committed to reducing poverty through inclusive economic growth, environmentally sustainable growth, and regional integration. Based in Manila, ADB is owned by 67 members, including 48 from the region. Its main instruments for helping its developing member countries are policy dialogue, loans, equity investments, guarantees, grants, and technical assistance. 2011 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON PROGRAM IN ASIA AND THE PACIFIC PURCHASING POWER PARITIES AND REAL EXPENDITURES A SUMMARY REPORT ASIAN DEVELOPMENT BANK 6 ADB Avenue, Mandaluyong City 2011 1550 Metro Manila, Philippines 9789292 544805 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT BANK www.adb.org ASIA AND THE PACIFIC PPP-Cover-Blue-ADB-Branding.indd 1 28/03/2014 9:28:08 AM 2011 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON PROGRAM IN ASIA AND THE PACIFIC PURCHASING POWER PARITIES AND REAL EXPENDITURES A SUMMARY REPORT 2011 ASIA AND THE PACIFIC © 2014 Asian Development Bank All rights reserved.
    [Show full text]
  • Capital Formation, Saving and Economic Progress
    184 Capital Formation, Saving and Economic Progress By T K WHITAKER, M SO (EOON ) (Read before the Society on 25th May, 1956) Introduction In this paper I assemble some facts and considerations legardmg the relation of capital formation and saving to the raising of real incomes m Ireland In other words, my concern is with national development and with some of the means necessary to attain it in our particular circumstances The views expressed are purely personal I have biought the salient statistics into the text and put most of the tabular matter in. an appendix Comparative advances in real incomes Qnr\pp>rr± hflc! been expressed nbout the CGm^strctti^slv slo™ r^sc in real income per head in Ireland over the past thirty years The varying degree to which economies were damaged during the war makes it difficult to interpret comparisons which stretch back to- pre-war times It will suffice to take 1949 as a starting point, for three reasons First, it is accepted that by then the countries with which we have most contact and in which developments have most influence on our economic and social conceptions had recovered from the effects of the war Second, it was about that time that we began particularly to look to a greatly enlarged State capital programme as a means of economic progress Third, it is recent experience and trends which are of most relevance to an examination of current problems In attempting to compare economic progress here and m other countries since 1949, one must rely on statistics which, though not gaii&fai/tuij', die
    [Show full text]
  • Did JP Morgan's Men Add Value?
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Inside the Business Enterprise: Historical Perspectives on the Use of Information Volume Author/Editor: Peter Temin, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press, 1991 Volume ISBN: 0-226-79202-1 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/temi91-1 Conference Date: October 26-27, 1990 Publication Date: January 1991 Chapter Title: Did J. P. Morgan's Men Add Value? An Economist's Perspective on Financial Capitalism Chapter Author: J. Bradford DeLong Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c7182 Chapter pages in book: (p. 205 - 250) 6 Did J. P. Morgan’s Men Add Value? An Economist’s Perspective on Financial Capitalism J. Bradford De Long 6.1 Introduction The pre-World War I period saw the heyday of “financial capitalism” in the United States: securities issues in particular and the investment banking busi- ness in general were concentrated in the hands of a very few investment bank- ers-of which the partnership of J. P. Morgan and Company was by far the largest and most prominent-who played substantial roles on corporate boards of directors. This form of association between finance and industry had costs: it created conflicts of interest that investment bankers could exploit for their own profit. It also had benefits, at least from the owners’ perspective:’ investment banker representation on boards allowed bankers to assess the per- formance of firm managers, quickly replace managers whose performance was unsatisfactory, and signal to investors that a company was fundamentally sound.
    [Show full text]