The Input-Output Table and Integrated Economic Accounts

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Input-Output Table and Integrated Economic Accounts Chapter 10 THE INPUT-OUTPUT TABLE AND INTEGRATED ECONOMIC ACCOUNTS 1. The supply-and-use tables (SUTs) 2. The aggregate supply and final uses tables 3. Intermediate use table (IUT) 4. The input-output table 5. The use of the input-output table for economic analysis 6. From the sum of the values added to GDP 7. The integrated economic account (IEA) 8. The transition from GDP to national income THE INPUT-OUTPUT TABLE AND INTEGRATED 10 ECONOMIC ACCOUNTS CHAPTER 10 The Input-output Table and Integrated Economic Accounts According to Edmond Malinvaud, one of the most distinguished contemporary French economists, the national accounts are “the presentation, in a rigorous accounting framework, of all the quantitative information relating to the nation’s economic activity”.* Here, the importance of the words “rigorous accounting framework” must be stressed. In fact, any macroeconomist carries in his head a simplified model of the economy in which everything made by someone is used by someone else, anything exported by someone is imported by someone else, anything saved by someone is invested by someone else, and so on. However, basic statistics are not presented in a “rigorous accounting framework”. They never precisely tie in together. For example, for a given product, the figures for total output are not going to correspond to the figures for total use. The reason for this is simply that output statistics are compiled differently from those of use: the statistical questionnaires are not addressed to the same people; the classifications are different; statisticians apply different methods; and so on. Some people have even ironically formulated a “theorem” that states if two statisticians are given the same set of data, the aggregate results they provide will necessarily be different! For these reasons, macroeconomists appreciate that national accounts constitute one of the rare cases in which statisticians provide tables that are (almost) completely consistent. X I. The totals are equal to the sum of the parts, the resources are equal to the uses, and so on. The simple model carried by macroeconomists in their heads is therefore given concrete shape, and it is this that gives national accounts their I. “Almost” because there potency. nevertheless remain certain inconsistencies known Even so, it has to be remembered that there are no miracles in as “statistical discrepancies” statistics. To obtain consistent tables, national accountants have been that will be discussed later obliged to cut here, to re-evaluate there – often arbitrarily – even though in this chapter. Some of these they use the best possible methods. The high level of consistency among we already saw in Chapter 8 tables in the national accounts (to within a few million of the national as the difference between the currency) should not be allowed to mask what is still only limited accuracy “B9” in the non-financial (see Chapter 11). Some statisticians take the view, however, that it is the accounts and the “B9” in the attempt to achieve consistency in the statistics that is one of the driving- financial accounts. forces for better quality. This consistency is obtained by using several global tables that we consider in this chapter. * Initiation à la comptabilité nationale, INSEE, 1973. We drew heavily on this text for Section 5 of this chapter. 266 UNDERSTANDING NATIONAL ACCOUNTS – ISBN 92-64-02566-9 – © OECD 2006 THE INPUT-OUTPUT TABLE AND INTEGRATED ECONOMIC ACCOUNTS 10 1. The supply-and-use tables (SUTs) 1. The supply-and-use tables (SUTs) In the national accounts, the first set of global tables is known as the “supply-and-use tables” (SUTs). A table of this kind applies to each product of the classification, for instance software. The equilibrium for this product can be stated as follows: Equation 1: Output + Imports = Supply = Uses = Intermediate consumption + Final consumption + GFCF + Changes in inventories + Exports First, let us interpret this equation in terms of numbers. The equation then signifies that the number of software programmes produced plus the number of software programmes imported is necessarily equal to the sum of the numbers of software programmes purchased by the user firms. The software is either for: 1) intermediate consumption (the small “disposable” programmes); 2) investment (the large professional programmes); 3) consumption by households (games software, in particular); 4) stocked as inventories by the software-producing firms in the form of work in progress; or 5) exported. This is an absolute equality: the resources (another name for “supply”) are necessarily equal to the uses, by definition. This explains why national accountants also refer to this equation as an accounting identity. They make constant use of it, mainly to derive one item based on results for the others. For example, suppose there were no statistics concerning changes in inventories of software programmes. No matter: if statistics are available for the other items, the “change in inventories” item can be obtained by making intelligent use of the accounting identity and deriving it as the balance of the other items: Change in inventories = Supply – Intermediate consumption – Final consumption – GFCF – Exports In this way, we kill two birds with one stone: we obtain an estimate of the changes in inventories, and at the same time we verify the accounting identity. This example was not chosen at random because in certain countries, like France, this is the way changes in inventories are obtained. Incidentally, this illustrates a paradox of the national accounts, namely that those compiling them are not necessarily anxious to have statistics on every single item in the supply-and-use tables. For one thing, it is certain that in this case the statistics will not spontaneously “tie up”. It will be necessary to choose which of the figures to trim, and this is no easy exercise. Therefore, it should not be thought that the accounting identity method is perfect. If changes in inventories are calculated as the balance between resources and other uses, all the errors of evaluation in any of these items will find their way into the change in inventories, with possibly pernicious results. It is therefore better in this case to have direct statistics in order to make corrections “by hand” of the supply-use balance. As can be seen, while in theory the equilibrium between resources and uses is indisputable, its verification in practice forms part of the “art” of the national accountant. Box 1 explains the statistical sources of the SUTs. UNDERSTANDING NATIONAL ACCOUNTS – ISBN 92-64-02566-9 – © OECD 2006 267 THE INPUT-OUTPUT TABLE AND INTEGRATED 10 ECONOMIC ACCOUNTS 1. The supply-and-use tables (SUTs) Box 1. Sources for the supply-and-use tables Chapters 1, 3 and 4 have already described the sources for each of the items in the supply and use tables in the case of France. We shall therefore give here only a brief reminder of what these are, still in the case of France. Market output is derived principally from sales statistics. Figures for merchandise imports and exports are taken from customs figures. Imports and exports of services mainly come from the Balance of Payments statistics of the Banque de France. Non-market output and consumption by general government come from the public accounts. The allocation of uses on the “domestic market” (defined as output + imports – exports) depends on the nature of the product. When the product is an investment, the use will be GFCF. When it is not an investment good, it is either household consumption or intermediate consumption. The nature of the product generally makes it possible to decide whether the sales constitute solely or mainly household consumption, or, by contrast, intermediate consumption. However, in cases where the nature of the product is not a sufficient criterion, bold assumptions have to be made to allocate the sales between final consumption and intermediate consumption. It is the intermediate consumption that is the most difficult to identify. This is because systematic surveys of firms – making it possible to know the nature of their purchases – are no longer done in France. Many of the cells in the intermediate consumption matrix are therefore estimated on the basis of information regarding the past. This is why INSEE, the French statistical office, is reluctant to publish intermediate use tables at detailed level. The changes in inventories are sometimes calculated as the difference between other items. The estimates are compiled, product by product, at the 472 level of the product classification, meaning that there are 472 SUTs. These are then aggregated and compared with the global estimates derived from statistical processing of the company accounts transmitted by firms to the tax authorities. The art of the national accountant then lies in matching the global estimates and the detailed estimates to obtain the high degree of consistency shown by tables in the national accounts. This operation is known as “arbitration” (see Chapter 11). Interpreting the accounting identity in terms of the number of software programmes was clearly simplistic. In practice, SUTs are drawn up in monetary terms, i.e. the amount of software programmes bought or sold in millions of national currency – in other words, the quantities multiplied by the prices. When these prices are those of the current period, one speaks of a supply-and-use table at current prices; when they are valued at the prices of a different period (often the previous year), one speaks of II. The accounting identity a supply-and-use table at constant prices. We saw in Chapter 2 the holds only in volume based importance of constant-price data in the national accounts, since they are on constant prices. It does fundamental to the calculation of GDP growth in volume. not hold using chain-linked volumes, which lead to In both cases, whether at current prices or constant prices, the non­additivity (see Chapter 2).
Recommended publications
  • Calculation of Owner-Occupied Dwelling Services In
    Calculation of Owner-Occupied Dwelling Services in Georgia Abstract Output of owner-occupied dwellings (OOD) is included within the production boundary according to the System of National Accounts. Different methods may be selected for measuring OOD services due to housing market development level. The paper presents estimation of services produced by OODs based on a User Cost Method, which replaced a self-assessment method in 2019 year in the National Accounts of Georgia during the general revision of time series. Key words: Owner-Occupied Dwellings, Imputed rent, User Cost Method Author: Levan Karsaulidze – Head of National Accounts Department, National Statistics Office of Georgia Introduction Imputed rents, representing services produced by owner-occupied dwellings (OOD), has always been included within the production boundary of National Account and are part of the official GDP estimates of Georgia as well. In 2019 transition to the SNA 2008 was implemented1 in the National Accounts of Georgia from the SNA 1993, accompanied with a general revision of time series. Along with other major changes related to the newly adopted methodology, user-cost method was implemented for measuring imputed rents for owner occupied houses, while self-assessment method was used until 2019 year. The paper describes a methodological background and detailed calculation steps for measuring imputed rents of OODs in Georgia, based on the user-cost method, briefly summarizes widely used approaches for estimating services of OODs and provides arguments for adopting the use-cost method for the country. Final results are presented in the last part of the paper. 1. Methodological Framework Methodology for measuring imputed rents of owner-occupied dwellings differs by country based on a rental market development level.
    [Show full text]
  • Conceptual Framework
    Chapter 2 CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK 2.1. Introduction .............................................................................................................................................. 19 2.2. Production Boundaries ........................................................................................................................... 19 2.3. Transactions and Other Flows................................................................................................................ 22 2.4. Units and Classifications of Units .......................................................................................................... 23 2.4.1. Institutional Units, Sectors and Subsectors ...............................................................................23 2.4.2. Kind of Activity Units, Local Units and Establishments ........................................................... 25 2.5. Economic Territory and Residence ....................................................................................................... 25 2.6. Current Price and Volume Measures..................................................................................................... 25 2.7. Labour Related Concepts....................................................................................................................... 26 2.8. The Production Approach....................................................................................................................... 28 2.8.1. Introduction...................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • 1. General Background of the Survey 1.1 Introduction the Economic
    1. General Background of the Survey 1.1 Introduction The Economic Sector in Jordan is considered one of the most important sectors that contribute to the Gross Domestic Product (GDP), and in the employment of manpower. Due to this importance, the Department of Statistics conducts an annual sample survey for the establishments engaged in this sector. The survey covers all establishments. The importance of this survey arises from the detailed data that it provides, such as the number of establishments, compensation of employees, paid up capital, material inputs, other production expenditures, gross output, value added and size of investment. These data provide economic indicators and help in preparing the National Accounts of the Country. 1.2 Objectives of the Survey The overall aim of the survey is to provide data on, or for the calculation of the following items by type of activity: a. Number of establishments. b. Compensation of employees whether in cash or in kind. c. Gross output and intermediate consumption. d. Size of investment and capital formation during the year. e. To compute the contribution to the GDP. f. Providing data for further economic analysis. 1.3 Survey Coverage The Survey covers all establishments classified in one of the economic divisions of the International Standard Industrial Classification for all Economic Activities, Third Revision, (ISIC3). 1.4 Sample Design In designing the sample of this survey, the stratified random sampling method was used. Moreover, the sample was selected on the regional level, where, the survey universe in each region was divided into different strata . 2. Preparatory Stage 2.1 Survey Main Documents The documents include, the survey questionnaire, the instructions manual and the coding manual.
    [Show full text]
  • L1A Production Accounts
    PFTAC GDP Compilation and Forecasting Workshop Measuring GDP by production Suva, Fiji October 17-21, 2016 Session Outline • The production account • The production boundary • The production account and value added • Output • Intermediate consumption • Data sources 2 Production account • Starting point for the sequence of accounts • Compiled for – institutional units, sectors, industries and also for the total economy • Examples: . Production account for agriculture, manufacturing industries, etc. Production account for financial corporations (banks, insurance companies, etc.), general government sector 3 Production • Production is an activity in which an enterprise uses inputs to produce outputs. • It is a process carried out under the responsibility, control and management of an institutional unit . Where labour and assets are used to transform inputs of goods and services into outputs of other goods and services. It does not cover purely natural processes without any human involvement or direction (e.g. natural fish stocks, wild forests) • The production account describes this transformation and the additional value created through the production process. 4 Production account • Output from production - resources • Intermediate consumption and consumption of fixed capital - uses • Value added is the balancing item – intended to measure the value created by production • At the economy level, resources include taxes less subsidies on products as well . Sum of GVA by sectors+T&S on prods = GDP 5 Products • Products are goods and services
    [Show full text]
  • National Accounts Methods to Achieve Exhaustiveness
    Chapter 5 NATIONAL ACCOUNTS METHODS TO ACHIEVE EXHAUSTIVENESS 5.1. Introduction .............................................................................................................................................. 69 5.2. Production Approach: General Methods .............................................................................................. 70 5.2.1. Introduction................................................................................................................................... 70 5.2.2. Supply Based Methods ............................................................................................................... 71 5.2.3. Labour Input Method................................................................................................................... 72 5.2.4. Demand Based Methods............................................................................................................. 73 5.2.5. Income Based Methods............................................................................................................... 74 5.2.6. Commodity Flow Method............................................................................................................ 74 5.3. Production Approach: Industry Specific Methods............................................................................... 75 Agriculture........................................................................................................................................ 75 Mining and quarrying......................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Operating Surplus (Income from Property)
    Class No.9: Unit 1 (National Income and related aggregates) Objective: After the class/ content you will become familiar with the components of operating surplus (income from property) Operating surplus: It is an income generated from property (rent + interest) and income from entrepreneurship (profit). Royalty is included in rent. Alternatively, it is the sum of rent, interest and profit. We can also define ‘It is Net value added at FC (i.e. domestic income) minus Compensation of employees (traditionally called wages) and mixed income of self-employed.’ Factor income (NDPFc) Mixed income of self Compensation of employees Operating surplus employed Income from property Income from entrepreneurship Rent Royalty interest Profit dividend profit tax Undistributed profit (Note: Interest on National Debt is not the part of Interest from property and thus it is ignored) Components of operating surplus: (1) Income from Property: It is an income generated from the property in form of rent, interest and royalty. (i) Rent: It is any periodic payment to an owner or factor of production in excess of the costs needed to bring that factor into production. It also refers as ‘Economic surplus’ as it is received by landlord without any effort. (ii) Royalty: A royalty is a legally-binding payment made to an individual, for using his or her originally- created assets, including copyrighted works, franchises, and natural resources. For example, use of mineral deposit such as coal, oil etc. Royalty is also associated with musicians, who receive such payments whenever their originally-recorded songs are played on the radio or television, used in movies, performed at concerts, bars, and restaurants, or consumed via streaming services.
    [Show full text]
  • Modeling the Economic Surplus in a SAM
    Modeling the Economic Surplus in a SAM Framework Erik K. Olsen Dept. of Economics Univ. of Missouri Kansas City 5100 Rockhill Rd. Kansas City, MO 64110 [email protected] June 21, 2011 1 Introduction The concept of an economic surplus is something that Marxian and Sra¢ an economics share in common. Both theories recognize the importance of an eco- nomic surplus that is produced and subsequently utilized for various purposes, but they each de…ne this surplus in very di¤erent ways. The surplus of Sra¢ an theory is the net product of the economy as de…ned in conventional national accounts. The surplus in Marxian theory is de…ned through its class theory. Draft prepared for 2011 Association for Heterodox Economics conference, Nottingham Trent University. 1 From the Marxist perspective the surplus created by production provides the resources that support the array of nonproduction activities associated with the capitalist enterprise as well as for many activities and individuals that may be quite distant. Shareholders of a corporation, for example, receive an in- come derived from the surplus created in production, but this is simply one of many potential uses. Identifying the connection between the surplus created in production and the subsequent recipients is the task of Marxian class theory, and this provides a means to understand how the surplus created in production plays a role in the reproduction of the economic system itself. This emphasis on a complex class structure that is part of the fabric of the economy is what distinguishes Marxian class theory from the Sra¢ an one, and it is also what distinguishes their two di¤erent theories of surplus.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomic Accounts
    VWL II – Makroökonomie WS2001/02 Dr. Ana B. Ania Macroeconomic Accounts The system of national accounts Macroeconomic accounting deals with aggregates and accounting identities, that is with macroeco- nomic magnitudes and how they relate to each other by definition. Macroeconomic accounting does not explain how each magnitude changes as a result of a change in other magnitudes. This will be the task of macroeconomic analysis, that we will look at in the next units of the course. In this first unit, we just deal with definitions. All that we say will therefore always hold by definition. The purpose of the system of national accounts is to keep record of the transactions that take place in any economy for the purpose of measuring productive activity and income generated in the economy. Since 1998 all countries should conform the new system of national accounts of the UN—System of National Accounts 1993 (SNA93). Additionally, the Eurostat (Central Statistical Agency of the EU) has produced a standard for members of the EU in accordance with SNA93 called the European System of Accounts 1995 (ESA95). The exposition here will be in accordance with these new systems. Institutional units In the view of the system of national accounts an economy is a system of decision-making units that interact with each other and perform economic transactions. The basic decision-making unit is called an institutional unit, which is any entity capable of owning assets, incurring liabilities, engaging in economic activities and transactions. Institutional units are either households or legal persons like cor- porations, governmental agencies, associations.
    [Show full text]
  • National Accounts Concepts and Definitions
    THE JAMAICAN SYSTEM OF NATIONAL ACCOUNTS CONCEPTS AND DEFINITIONS OVERVIEW OF THE SYSTEM The revision of the Jamaican System of National Accounts is based on the United Nations System of National Accounts 1993 (1993 SNA). This appendix presents a description of the conceptual framework for the national accounts system and briefly outlines the sources used in the compilation of the national accounts. The 1993 SNA is a comprehensive, accounting framework within which economic data can be presented on the operation of the nation’s economy in much the same way as business accounts describe the operation of an enterprise. It is an integrated set of economic accounts, balance sheets and other tables describing all economic flows and stocks taking place within a country. It is based on a set of internationally agreed concepts, definitions, classifications and accounting rules within which economic data can be presented. The system is built around a sequence of interconnected flow accounts which record different types of activities taking place in the economy. It is based on a double entry system of accounting in which each transaction must be recorded twice within the same unit, once as a resource and the other as a use. Each account has a balancing item which is the residual between the total resources and total uses recorded on the two sides of the account. The balancing item from one account is carried forward as the first item on the following account. The accounts can be implemented at different levels of aggregation, from the level of the unit to the level of the national economy.
    [Show full text]
  • National Income and Product Accounts
    LECTURE NOTES_PARUL JAIN National Income and Product Accounts • National income and product accounts are data collected and published by the government describing the various components of national income and output in the economy. • The Department of Commerce is responsible for producing and maintaining the “National Income and Product Accounts” that keep track of GDP. LECTURE NOTES_PARUL JAIN Need for National Income Accounting • Indicates Economic Growth: – it indicates performance and the level of economic growth in an economy. The data on national income and per capita display the true picture of the health of an economy. If both are increasing continuously, it surely reflects an increase in economic welfare, otherwise not. • Helps in Policy Formulation: – Statistical data on national income not only helps in making economic analysis but also helps in policy formulation. Moreover it not only helps in formulating fiscal policy, monetary policy, foreign trade policy but also helps in making modifications and amendments wherever necessary. LECTURE NOTES_PARUL JAIN Need for National Income Accounting • Helpful in Making Comparisons – it helps us in comparing national income and per capita income of our country with those of other countries. This may lead us to make suitable changes in our plans and approach to achieve rapid economic development of our country. • Helpful to Trade Unions – National accounts throw light on distribution of factor incomes which is very helpful to trade unions and other labour organizations in making rational analysis of the remuneration the laborers are getting. • Distribution of income – National income accounting describes distribution of national income in terms of factors like interest, rent, profit & wages.
    [Show full text]
  • 17 National Accounts and Economic Statistics STD/NAES(2005)
    For Official Use STD/NAES(2005)17 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 29-Sep-2005 ___________________________________________________________________________________________ English - Or. English STATISTICS DIRECTORATE For Official Use STD/NAES(2005)17 National Accounts and Economic Statistics COST OF CAPITAL SERVICES AND THE NATIONAL ACCOUNTS UPDATE OF THE 1993 SNA - ISSUE No. 15 ISSUES PAPER FOR THE JULY 2005 AEG MEETING This paper has been prepared by Paul Schreyer, W. Erwin Diewert and Anne Harrison WORKING PARTY ON NATIONAL STATISTICS To be held on 11 - 14 October 2005 Tour Europe - Paris La Défense Beginning at 9:30 a.m. on the first day English - Or. English JT00190606 Document complet disponible sur OLIS dans son format d'origine Complete document available on OLIS in its original format STD/NAES(2005)17 COST OF CAPITAL SERVICES AND THE NATIONAL ACCOUNTS SNA/M1.05/04 UPDATE OF THE 1993 SNA - ISSUE No. 15 ISSUES PAPER FOR THE JULY 2005 AEG MEETING Paul Schreyer W. Erwin Diewert Anne Harrison EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Background 1. The topic of capital services has been discussed in various Canberra II Group meetings, including those of October 2003, April 2004, September 2004 and April 2005. It has also been discussed in meetings in Eurostat, at the OECD national accounts meeting and at the AEG meeting in December 2004. At its latest meeting in April 2005, the Canberra II Group supported the recommendations in the paper by Schreyer, Diewert and Harrison (2005) with some minor modifications. 2. The main messages to emerge from all of the meetings listed above is clear; few countries at present have a sufficiently detailed capital stock database to present robust capital service figures and even of those which do, not all are yet ready to publish these data as part of the main national accounts.
    [Show full text]
  • Production: What It Includes and Excludes 1
    Chapter 4 PRODUCTION: WHAT IT INCLUDES AND EXCLUDES 1. The production frontier 2. The illegal economy and the underground economy 3. Measurement of output and of value added: the general case 4. The measurement of output and of value added: special cases 5. Nomenclatures and classifications 4 PRODUCTION: WHAT IT INCLUDES AND EXCLUDES CHAPTER 4 Production: What it Includes and Excludes Production is what leads to “output” (as it is termed in the national accounts), creating jobs, generating income for workers and owners of capital, and resulting in the goods and services found in our stores. Output is a central concept in economics. It is essentially used by economists in volume terms (i.e. not at current prices). Output results from the three factors of production: labour, capital and intermediate consumption (inputs). Standard macroeconomic presentations often use a measure based on value added (rather than output) making it possible to dispense with intermediate consumption and hence show only labour and capital as the factors of production. When modelling the growth of output in volume (or, rather, the growth of value added when intermediate consumption has been deducted from both sides of the equation), OECD economists use the following formula: Y’ = [f(L, K) x MFP]‘, Y’ is the growth rate of value added; L stands for labour and K for capital; f is the production function; and the sign ‘ means the derivative. The term “MFP” stands for “multifactor productivity”, which is that part of the change in value added that cannot be attributed to changes in the volume of labour or to capital inputs in production.
    [Show full text]