Constraints and Resistance to the Wave of Democratic Reforms in Ireland Since 2011
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Camille Bedock (European University Institute of Florence) Conference 'Political Legitimacy and the Paradox of Regulation', January 24-25, 2013, Leiden Workshop: Crowd-pleasers or key janglers? The impact of drops in political legitimacy on democratic reform and their consequences Institutional muffling: constraints and resistance to the wave of democratic reforms in Ireland since 2011 Ireland has been one of the European countries in which the economic crisis struck more severely since 2009, with far-reaching economic, social, but also political consequences for the country, such as the virtual annihilation of the economic sovereignty of the country for a decade following the EU-IMF bailout. This meant that the ability to deliver output-legitimacy (Scharpf 1999) for Irish political parties was severely pruned. Moreover, the decline in political support for the institutions and the political actors plummeted since 2007, turning Ireland into one of the European countries where the level of distrust of institutions and parties is the highest. As a result of the mobilization of various actors of the civil society to promote a more democratic and transparent political system, the issue of “political reforms” has been put at the forefront of the campaign of 2011 for all major political parties, with a strong emphasis with the will to empower citizens and prevent future crisis by reforming Irish governance. A number of promises were made after the new Fine Gael- Labour coalition came into power, including the abolition of the upper House (the Seanad) and the creation of a Constitutional convention that would discuss a number of institutional provisions including the electoral system, the presidential term, gay marriage, or voting age. Hence, Ireland seemed to reunite in 2011 all of the conditions for major institutional reforms to happen: complete political alternation, very low level of political support, but also strong focus on the topic of institutional change and mobilization on the issue. However, the Irish case appears at first sight as a paradox, since the extent of institutional reforms undertaken since 2011 is, in fact, relatively limited compared to the initial promises. The puzzle this paper addresses is therefore the following: why did Ireland not reform more its institutions since 2011? Ireland offers the perfect ground to understand the link between low output-legitimacy, drop of political support, and democratic reforms in Western Europe. This paper deals with the emergence, the nature, and the extent of the bundle of institutional reforms that were undertaken 1 Institutional muffling: constraints and resistance to the wave of democratic reforms in Ireland since 2011 after the new Fine Gael-Labour coalition came into power in 2011, through a case-study based on a number of interviews and varied secondary sources (reports, press articles, parliamentary debates,etc). The paper shows evidence that the way the process of reform unraveled and was acted upon by the politicians provides an answer to the abovementioned paradox. The agenda on institutional reform was both imposed to Irish elites and used by them in times of economic crisis and electoral recomposition during their campaign, but realities of government made it fade. Indeed, the issue of institutional reform is both not very salient, and actually difficult easier to promote than to implement. Hence, reforms of the formal democratic institutions implemented in Ireland since 2011 were limited to consensual issues not requiring a referendum. We can summarize what has happened since 2011 under the general label of institutional muffling: limiting actual reforms to easier and consensual aspects, “scapegoating” by putting the blame on certain institutions (the Seanad) and putting off the agenda reforms implying dissent to later stages (by delaying the constitutional convention and controlling its agenda). In the end, Irish elites acted more as “key-janglers” rather than “crowd-pleasers”, by adopting consensual and not costly reforms rather than truly empowering the Irish citizens. The first section of the paper focuses first on the conditions of emergence of the debate on institutional reform in Ireland, showing that the economic crisis provided a clear “push” to the issue after decades of stasis, providing a clear narrative linking the crisis with a faulty institutional system. In the second section, I focus on the promises made by the new Fine Gael-Labour coalition entering power in 2011 and the construction of a scattered bundle of reforms, i.e. a process characterized by the concomitant apparition of several dimensions of institutional reforms in the agenda, but “broken down” into multiple issues. In the third section, I review what has been implemented or not since 2011, showing evidence that actual reforms were limited to consensual issues, whereas more difficult ones were dealt with by scapegoating and kicking to touch of the major issues. In the fourth section, I discuss preliminary theoretical lessons that can be drawn from the Irish case regarding the dynamics of reforms forced upon political elites in contexts of low legitimacy. Section 1: Child of the crisis: the origins of the debate on “political reform” in Ireland The debate on “political reform”, as it is entitled in Ireland, has developed in a context of unprecedented political and economic crisis which shook the very roots of the Irish party system during the election of 2011. The narrative that formed is a child of the crisis, leading to give responsibility to the political system for the gravity of the storm experienced by Ireland in the last 2 Institutional muffling: constraints and resistance to the wave of democratic reforms in Ireland since 2011 few years. This is in sharp contrast with the high degree of stability of Irish formal institutions since the adoption of the constitution in 1937, but also by a high degree of stability of its party system before 2011. It would be misleading to attribute entirely the emergence of the debate on political reform to the crisis, since a low intensity debate developed since the beginning of the 1990s on certain aspects of the political system. Yet, it remained confined to the margins of a wider debate about certain problematic constitutional provisions, until the economic crisis put the Irish political institutions to the forefront. Institutional reform before 2011 in Ireland: (not so) much noise for nothing? Even if this is not directly the topic of this paper, the remarkable stability of Irish institutions since 1937 is a notable and inescapable fact when one deals with institutional change in Ireland. A few major (and non-exhaustive) reasons can be advanced to explain this. First, the fact that the constitution of 1937 was a text of institutional reconciliation between political forces that had been deeply opposed during the process of independence. Second, the requirement to use a referendum to proceed to major institutional changes in Ireland, a tool that had prove quite risky in the past.1 Finally, and more importantly, the uninterrupted domination of one major political actor over Irish political life in the previous decades, Fianna Fáil. Yet, since the 1990s, the unraveling of a debate on political corruption started to ask the question of the inadequacies of the Irish institutions and led to certain reforms regarding transparency, while certain aspects of institutional reforms were discussed in the shadow of a wider debate on the constitution. Debates on reforms of the Irish institutional system before 2011 took mainly two forms: the consequences of the revelations of tribunals of investigation2 on corruption and transparency, and a tedious and very long list of reports on various aspects of the constitution initiated in the aftermath of the report of the Constitutional Review group released in 1996. 1 From 1972 onwards, out of the 31 amendments that were put to the people of Ireland for approval, only 23 were accepted (Gallagher in Coakley and Gallagher 2010, 80). This means, in other words, than no less than one fourth were rejected. Only five of them were on matters directly related to minor modifications of the organization of the political system.1 Regarding institutions, important provisions introduced by the government were not accepted by the citizens. Among the most notable examples, two attempts to replace PR-STV by the British First Past the Post electoral system were rejected by the voters in 1959 and 1968. 2 Tribunals are a somewhat strange device of Irish judicial and political life, and a direct heir of the British tradition and of the Irish Free State (O’Neill 2000). They are established by ministers after the agreement of both Houses of the Oireachtas, invested with the powers, privileges and rights of the Irish High Court, and formed of independent member(s) appointed by the Oireachtas establish facts and, if needed, allegations over any matter of “urgent public importance”. See Tribunals of Enquiry (Evidence) Act, 1921, and the amended legislation: Tribunals of Enquiry (Evidence) (Amendment) Act, 1979. The tribunals are not part of a traditional adversary legal system, but inquisitorial in essence (O’Neill 2000, 202). The tribunals cannot make more than establishing the truth, they are not entitled to sanction legally anyone for its actions. 3 Institutional muffling: constraints and resistance to the wave of democratic reforms in Ireland since 2011 The series of independent enquiries led by the tribunals since the beginning of the 1990s showed evidence of the pervasiveness of corrupt or non-ethical behavior at every layer of Irish political life, and of the deference and conniving relationship between business and politics in Ireland (Byrne 2012, 144). The political answers to these enquiries can be found in the multiplication of legislations over ethics and transparency adopted by cabinets of all political sensibilities since 1995, with no less than 25 pieces of legislations between 1995 and 2005 (Hugues et al. 2007, 383; Byrne 2012, 194).