Behavioral Economics and the Impracticability Doctrine

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Behavioral Economics and the Impracticability Doctrine Yeshiva University, Cardozo School of Law LARC @ Cardozo Law Articles Faculty 2005 Rendered Impracticable: Behavioral Economics and the Impracticability Doctrine Aaron Wright Benjamin N. Cardozo School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://larc.cardozo.yu.edu/faculty-articles Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Aaron Wright, Rendered Impracticable: Behavioral Economics and the Impracticability Doctrine, 26 Cardozo Law Review 2183 (2005). Available at: https://larc.cardozo.yu.edu/faculty-articles/203 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty at LARC @ Cardozo Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Articles by an authorized administrator of LARC @ Cardozo Law. For more information, please contact [email protected], [email protected]. RENDERED IMPRACTICABLE: BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS AND THE IMPRACTICABILITY DOCTRINE Aaron J. Wright* INTRODUCTION Impracticability is about change.^ The doctrine reconciles changed circumstances, discharging contractual obligations when events surrounding the contract vary dramatically from expectations.^ Ideally, impracticability sets parameters for such circumstances, including how drastic the change must be to justify discharge.^ Yet despite centuries of development, the eurrent impractieability doctrine lacks a theoretical foundation, leading to inconsistent ease holdings^ and doctrinal * Editor in Chief, Cardozo Law Review, J.D. Candidate (June 2005); Tufts University, B.A. I would like to thank Professor Paul Shupack for instilling in me a passion for contract law and Professor Dan Crane for his thoughtful guidance. Moreover, I would like to thank Mike Reisman, Rob Lefkowitz, Peter Melamed, and Benjamin Friedman for their superior editmg. would also like to thank my mother, sister, and father for being a constant source of inspiration and love, and importantly Alissa for her boundless love and unquestioned support, especially during the past year. , ^ 1 Cook V. Deltona Corp., 753 F.2d 1552, 1558 (11th Cir. 1985) ("[Cjhange is what impossibility is about."). .,. , AW, 2 See infra Part 1 for an elaborate history of the impracticability doctrine, and ttie circumstances under which the impracticability doctrine excuses contractual obligations 3 For a variety of theories discussing when discharge should be granted, see Andrew Kull, Mistake, Frustration, and the Windfall Principle of Contract Remedies, 43 HASTINGS L J. 1 (1991)' Pietro Trimarchi, Commercial Impracticability in Contract Law: An Economic Analysis, 11 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 63 (1991); Michelle J. White, Contract Breach and Contract Discharge Due to Impossibility: A Unified Theory, 17 J. LEGAL STUD. 353 (1988); Victor R Goldberg, Impossibility and Related Excuses, 144 J. INSTITUTIONAL & THEORETICAL ECON. 100 (1988); Paula Walter, Commercial Impracticability in Contracts, 61 ST. JOHN'S L. REV. 225 (1987); Robert A. Hillman, An Analysis of the Cessation of Contractual Relations, 68 CORNELL L REV. 617 (1983); John Henry Schlegel, Of Nuts, and Ships, and Sealing Wax, Suez, and Frustrating Things—The Doctrine of Impossibility of Performance, 23 RUTGERS L. REV. 419 (1969); E. Allan Famsworth, Disputes Over Omission in Contracts, 68 COLUM. L. REV. (1968)' Harold J Herman, Excuse for Nonperformance in the Light of Contract Practices in International Trade, 63 COLUM. L. REV. 1413 (1963). For a detailed analysis of examining whether discharge is ever warranted, see Alan O. Sykes, The Doctrine of Commercial Impracticability in a Second-Best World, 19 }. LEGAL STUD. 42 (1990). 4 See generally John D. Wladis, Impracticability as Risk Allocation: The Effect of Changed Circumstances Upon Contract Obligations for the Sale of Goods, 22 OA. L. REV. 503, 600-25 2183 2184 CARDOZO LAW REVIEW [Vol. 26:5 confusion.5 Today, courts rarely find circumstances satisfying the modem requirements of impracticability.^ The rigid requirements of foreseeability and the common law concept of impossibility limit the impracticability doctrine's ability to provide "flexible adjustment machinery,"^ leading scholars to lament that "the court must exercise its equity powers and pray for the wisdom of Solomon" when dealing with the mle.^ Legal economists have examined the impracticability doctrine since the late 1960s.9 Applying traditional miero-economic theory, these scholars have questioned whether the impracticability doctrine promotes efficient exchanges by lowering transaction costs associated with bargaining.'" In 1977, two such approaches appeared consecutively in the Journal of Legal Studies, reaching two contrary results. In an influential article written by Richard Posner and Andrew (1988) (listing an extensive table of cases that involve factually similar factual situations which resulted in different judicial outcomes). 5 See Stephen J. Sirianni, The Developing Law of Contractual Impracticability and Impossibility: Part I, 14 UCC L.J. 30, 31 (1981) (stating that "[jjudicial developments of the doctrine [of impossibility] under Section 2-615 of the Uniform Commercial Code and the common law is largely incoherent"). As aptly explained by James White and Robert Summers: In spite of attempts by all of the contract scholars ... it remains impossible to predict with accuracy how the [impracticability doctrine] will apply to a variety of relatively common cases. Both the cases and the Code commentary are full of weasel words such as "severe" shortage, "marked" increase, "basic" assiunptions, and "force majeure." 1 JAMES J. WHITE & ROBERT S. SUMMERS, UNIFORM COMMERCIAL CODE § 3-10 (4th ed. 1995). 6 Steven L. Schooner explains: Until [1980]. challenges invoking section 2-615's protection made for an almost unbroken succession of failures The recovery obstacles posed by the Code prove equally insurmountable to those encountered at common law. Judged in hindsight, foreseeability and risk allocation appear obvious and the occurrence of a contingency so often seems not extraordinary. Steven L. Schooner, Impossibility of Performance in Public Contracts: An Economic Analysis, 16 PUB. CONT. L.J. 229, 235 n.39 (1986) (citations omitted). 7 U.C.C. § 2-615, cmt. 5 (1996). 8 6 ARTHUR L. CORBIN, CORBIN ON CONTRACTS: A COMPREHENSIVE TREATISE ON THE WORKING RULES OF CONTRACT LAW § 1333 (rev. ed. 1962). 9 See generally Robert L. Birmingham, A Second Look at the Suez Canal Cases: Excuse for Nonperformance of Contractual Obligations in the Light of Economic Theory, 20 HASTINGS L.J. 1393 (1969); Note, The Economic Implications of the Doctrine of Impossibility, 26 HASTINGS L.J. 1251 (1975); Paul L. Joskow, Commercial Impossibility, the Uranium Market and the Westinghouse Case, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 119 (1977); Richard A. Posner & Andrew M. Rosenfield, Impossibility and Related Doctrines in Contract Law: An Economic Analysis, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 83 (1977); Christopher J. Bruce, An Economic Analysis of the Impossibility Doctrine, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 311 (1982). Each analysis acknowledges the contributions of predecessors, while adding unique interpretations and analysis. 19 One main purpose of law and economics is to examine legal doctrine and evaluate its economic efficiency, which is accomplished in the context of contract law by lowering the transaction costs of bargaining. See RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 23-28 (6th ed. 2003) (asserting that an economic analysis of the law explains rules of law by examining their relative economic efficiency, under a theory dubbed the "efficiency theory of the common law"). 2005] RENDERED IMPRACTICABLE 2185 Rosenfield, the authors rejected the current rule encapsulated under Uniform Commercial Code (U.C.C.) § 2-615, proposing in its place the "superior risk bearer" model. Paul Joskow, in contrast, used the same micro-economic insights to support § 2-615 and argued that the rule strikes a balance between the rigid rule of enforcing all contracts and a lenient excuse doctrine. However, recent scholarship from the emerging field of behavioral economics has altered our understanding of the way people traditionally imderstand risk assessment and rationality. Over the past twenty-five See Posner & Rosenfield, supra note 9, at 89-92. Generally, the superior risk bearer is the party that is the more efficient bearer of a particular risk, regardless of the party's ability to prevent the risk fi'om materializing. Id. at 90. Details of the superior risk bearer model are found infra Part III. 12 See Joskow, supra note 9, at 154-55, 163. Joskow discusses how a well designed impracticability doctrine reduces transaction costs associated with contracting by reducing litigation costs and preventing extensive negotiations. After a micro-economic analysis, Joskow asserts that U.C.C § 2-615 is such a doctrine. Joskow's interpretation of U.C.C. § 2-615's foreseeability test is fotmd in Part II infra. 13 The field of behavioral law and economics is quickly emerging. Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky provide a detailed overview of this field in CHOICES, VALUES, AND FRAMES (Daniel Kahneman & Amos Tversky eds., 2000), as does Cass Sunstein in BEHAVIORAL LAW AND ECONOMICS (2000). Other prominent articles include: Christine Jolls et al., A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1471 (1998); Russell B. Korobkin & Thomas S. Ulen, Law and Behavioral Science: Removing the Rationality Assumption From Law and Economics, 88 CAL. L. REV. 1051 (2002). Scholars have increasingly applied behavioral economics to contract law. See, e.g., Robert A. Hillman, The Limits of Behavioral Decision
Recommended publications
  • 26 Chap 26.Qxp
    Chapter 26 CONTRACT CLAUSES MANAGING, ALLOCATING, AND TRANSFERRING CONSTRUCTION PROJECT RISKS C. Michael Shull III, Esq., Editor and Author (2007 Supplement) Holland & Hart LLP Douglas A. Karet, Esq., Editor and Author (2005 Supplement); Author (2003 Supplement) Holloway Brabec & Karet PC Buck S. Beltzer, Esq., P.E., Author (2005 Supplement) Holland & Hart LLP Robert E. Benson, Esq., Editor and Author (2003 Supplement) Holland & Hart LLP SYNOPSIS § 26.1 INTRODUCTION § 26.1.1—Overview § 26.1.2—Types Of Risks To Which Parties To A Construction Contract Can Be Exposed, And Which Risks Can Be Managed, Allocated, And Transferred § 26.1.3—The “Means” Of Parties Managing, Allocating, And Transferring Construction Project Risks § 26.1.4—Methods Of Management, Allocation, And Transfer Of Construction Project Risks By Contract § 26.1.5—The Meaningful Considerations About Risk Transfer Clauses § 26.2 PROCEDURAL CLAUSES FOR MANAGEMENT, ALLOCATION, AND TRANSFER OF RISKS § 26.2.1—Overview § 26.2.2—Choice Of Law Clauses § 26.2.3—Forum Selection Clauses § 26.2.4—Notice Of Claim Clauses § 26.2.5—Contractual Statutes Of Limitation § 26.2.6—Clauses Defining Commencement Of Statute Of Limitations § 26.2.7—Mediation Clauses § 26.2.8—Arbitration Clauses (10/07) 26-1 The Practitioner’s Guide to Colorado Construction Law § 26.2.9—Waiver Of Trial By Jury § 26.2.10—No Discovery Clauses § 26.2.11—Change Order Requirements § 26.2.12—Warranties § 26.2.13—Summary Of Procedural Clauses § 26.3 DAMAGE LIMITATION CLAUSES § 26.3.1—Overview § 26.3.2—Limitations On Types
    [Show full text]
  • Force Majeure and Common Law Defenses | a National Survey | Shook, Hardy & Bacon
    2020 — Force Majeure SHOOK SHB.COM and Common Law Defenses A National Survey APRIL 2020 — Force Majeure and Common Law Defenses A National Survey Contractual force majeure provisions allocate risk of nonperformance due to events beyond the parties’ control. The occurrence of a force majeure event is akin to an affirmative defense to one’s obligations. This survey identifies issues to consider in light of controlling state law. Then we summarize the relevant law of the 50 states and the District of Columbia. 2020 — Shook Force Majeure Amy Cho Thomas J. Partner Dammrich, II 312.704.7744 Partner Task Force [email protected] 312.704.7721 [email protected] Bill Martucci Lynn Murray Dave Schoenfeld Tom Sullivan Norma Bennett Partner Partner Partner Partner Of Counsel 202.639.5640 312.704.7766 312.704.7723 215.575.3130 713.546.5649 [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] SHOOK SHB.COM Melissa Sonali Jeanne Janchar Kali Backer Erin Bolden Nott Davis Gunawardhana Of Counsel Associate Associate Of Counsel Of Counsel 816.559.2170 303.285.5303 312.704.7716 617.531.1673 202.639.5643 [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] John Constance Bria Davis Erika Dirk Emily Pedersen Lischen Reeves Associate Associate Associate Associate Associate 816.559.2017 816.559.0397 312.704.7768 816.559.2662 816.559.2056 [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] Katelyn Romeo Jon Studer Ever Tápia Matt Williams Associate Associate Vergara Associate 215.575.3114 312.704.7736 Associate 415.544.1932 [email protected] [email protected] 816.559.2946 [email protected] [email protected] ATLANTA | BOSTON | CHICAGO | DENVER | HOUSTON | KANSAS CITY | LONDON | LOS ANGELES MIAMI | ORANGE COUNTY | PHILADELPHIA | SAN FRANCISCO | SEATTLE | TAMPA | WASHINGTON, D.C.
    [Show full text]
  • Commercial Impracticability - an Overview
    Duquesne Law Review Volume 13 Number 3 Article 5 1975 Commercial Impracticability - An Overview Robert Sommer Follow this and additional works at: https://dsc.duq.edu/dlr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Robert Sommer, Commercial Impracticability - An Overview, 13 Duq. L. Rev. 521 (1975). Available at: https://dsc.duq.edu/dlr/vol13/iss3/5 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Duquesne Scholarship Collection. It has been accepted for inclusion in Duquesne Law Review by an authorized editor of Duquesne Scholarship Collection. Commercial Impracticability-An Overview Robert Sommer* As shortages become more severe and prices continue to climb, both suppliers and purchasers are confronted with increasingly more burdensome performance arising from long-term, set-price contracts. As performance becomes more burdensome, greater num- bers of beleaguered promisors will turn to § 2-615 of the Uniform Commercial Code in hopes of excusing nonperformance. The pur- pose of this article is to discuss the doctrine of impracticability as codified in § 2-615. This article will discuss the historical antece- dents of the doctrine of impracticability, the mechanics set up by the Code to regulate the operation of the doctrine, case law applying the Code mechanics and, finally, a few questions left unanswered by the Code. I. HISTORICAL BACKGROUND A. Overview The early common law excused performance of duties imposed by law on grounds of impossibility but refused to excuse performance of contractual obligations on the same grounds.' The theory was that a promise was absolute unless, and only to the extent, qualified by the promisor.
    [Show full text]
  • In Defense of the Impossibility Defense Gerhard Wagner Georg-August University of Goettingen
    Loyola University Chicago Law Journal Volume 27 Article 4 Issue 1 Fall 1995 1995 In Defense of the Impossibility Defense Gerhard Wagner Georg-August University of Goettingen Follow this and additional works at: http://lawecommons.luc.edu/luclj Part of the Contracts Commons Recommended Citation Gerhard Wagner, In Defense of the Impossibility Defense, 27 Loy. U. Chi. L. J. 55 (1995). Available at: http://lawecommons.luc.edu/luclj/vol27/iss1/4 This Essay is brought to you for free and open access by LAW eCommons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Loyola University Chicago Law Journal by an authorized administrator of LAW eCommons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Essay In Defense of the Impossibility Defense GerhardWagner* I. INTRODUCTION Generally, the common law follows the rule of pacta sunt servanda' under which contractual obligations are absolutely binding on the parties. 2 The impossibility defense is an exception to this general rule.3 Under the impossibility defense, a promisor may default with- out incurring liability for the promisee's expectation damages.4 * Akademischer Rat (Junior Lecturer) at Georg-August University of Goettingen, Germany; J.D., 1989, University of Goettingen; L.L.M., 1995, University of Chicago. The author is deeply indebted to Richard Craswell of the University of Chicago Law School for many helpful comments on an earlier draft of this Essay. 1. "Pacta sunt servanda" means "agreements (and stipulations) of the parties (to a contract) must be observed." BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY 1109 (6th ed. 1990). 2. For an erudite discussion of pacta sunt servanda, see generally Richard Hyland, Pacta Sunt Servanda: A Meditation, 34 VA.
    [Show full text]
  • Good Faith and Reasonable Expectations
    Good Faith and Reasonable Expectations Jay M. Feinman* I. INTRODUCTION The recognition that there is an obligation of good faith in every contract has been regarded as one of the most important advances in contract law in the twentieth century. Nevertheless, a half-century after the doctrine’s incorporation into the Restatement (Second) of Contracts and the Uniform Commercial Code, great controversy and confusion remain about it. Recent articles describe the doctrine as “a revered relic,” “a (nearly) empty vessel,” and “an underenforced legal norm.”1 A scholarly dispute about the nature of the doctrine framed more than thirty years ago has hardly been advanced, much less resolved.2 More importantly, although nearly every court has announced its support of the doctrine, often using similar language and familiar sources, many judicial opinions are confusing or confused.3 The controversy and confusion stem from a fundamental misunderstanding about the nature of the good faith obligation. That misunderstanding is a belief that good faith is a special doctrine that does not easily fit within the structure of contract law. Indeed, the doctrine is seen as potentially dangerous, threatening to undermine more fundamental doctrines and the transactions that they are designed to uphold. As a result, good * Distinguished Professor of Law, Rutgers School of Law‒Camden. The author thanks David Campbell and especially Danielle Kie Hart for their comments. This article is for Arkansas lawyer David Solomon and his son, Ray. 1. See generally Harold Dubroff, The Implied Covenant of Good Faith in Contract Interpretation and Gap-Filling: Reviling a Revered Relic, 80 ST.
    [Show full text]
  • 98-720C • PRECISION PINE & TIMBER, INC., V. the UNITED STATES
    In the United States Court of Federal Claims No. 98-720 C Filed September 14, 2007 ____________________________________ ) Timber sale contracts, expectancy damages, PRECISION PINE & TIMBER, INC., ) consequential damages, lost volume seller, ) cover damages, “hole in the profit pipeline”, Plaintiff, ) burden of proof, offset, collateral v. ) undertakings; overrun factor; conversion ) factor; product mix; economic THE UNITED STATES, ) impracticability; gross profit; net profit; ) manufacturing overhead; administrative Defendant. ) overhead ____________________________________) Alan I. Saltman, Saltman & Stevens, P.C., Washington, D.C., for plaintiff. Richard W. Goeken and Bryan T. Bunting, Saltman & Stevens, P.C., Washington, D.C., of counsel. David A. Harrington, Trial Attorney, Marla T. Conneely, Trial Attorney, Kathryn A. Bleecker, Assistant Director, David M. Cohen, Director, Commercial Litigation Branch, Civil Division, Peter D. Keisler, Assistant Attorney General, United States Department of Justice, Washington, D.C., for defendant. Lori Polin Jones and Patricia L. Disert, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Washington, D.C., of counsel. OPINION AND ORDER GEORGE W. MILLER, Judge. This matter is before the Court following the Court’s previous Opinion and Order, 72 Fed. Cl. 460 (2006), requiring the parties to submit to the Court supplemental post-trial briefing with respect to plaintiff’s modified lost volume seller theory of damage recovery, and on plaintiff’s motion of October 17, 2006, styled as a “Motion for Relief from Limited Aspects of the Court’s Order and Opinion of September 19” (docket entry 431, Oct. 17, 2006) and treated by the Court as a motion for reconsideration of the September 2006 Opinion pursuant to Rule 59(a)(1) of the Rules of the United States Court of Federal Claims (“RCFC”).
    [Show full text]
  • Derivative Instruments and Hedging Activities
    www.pwc.com 2015 Derivative instruments and hedging activities www.pwc.com Derivative instruments and hedging activities 2013 Second edition, July 2015 Copyright © 2013-2015 PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP, a Delaware limited liability partnership. All rights reserved. PwC refers to the United States member firm, and may sometimes refer to the PwC network. Each member firm is a separate legal entity. Please see www.pwc.com/structure for further details. This publication has been prepared for general information on matters of interest only, and does not constitute professional advice on facts and circumstances specific to any person or entity. You should not act upon the information contained in this publication without obtaining specific professional advice. No representation or warranty (express or implied) is given as to the accuracy or completeness of the information contained in this publication. The information contained in this material was not intended or written to be used, and cannot be used, for purposes of avoiding penalties or sanctions imposed by any government or other regulatory body. PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP, its members, employees and agents shall not be responsible for any loss sustained by any person or entity who relies on this publication. The content of this publication is based on information available as of March 31, 2013. Accordingly, certain aspects of this publication may be superseded as new guidance or interpretations emerge. Financial statement preparers and other users of this publication are therefore cautioned to stay abreast of and carefully evaluate subsequent authoritative and interpretative guidance that is issued. This publication has been updated to reflect new and updated authoritative and interpretative guidance since the 2012 edition.
    [Show full text]
  • Risk Allocation in Commercial Contracts
    Risk Allocation in Commercial Contracts Go to: Force Majeure Clauses | Indemnification Clauses | Limitations on Liability | Insurance Requirements | Payment Terms and Guaranties | Termination Rights | UCC Product Warranties in Sale of Goods Agreements | Other Contractual Remedies | Related Content Reviewed on: 05/22/2019 This practice note discusses common risk allocation mechanisms used in commercial contracts. It includes a discussion of how parties to an agreement can allocate risk by incorporating some or all of the following: a force majeure clause, an indemnification, a limitation on liability, termination rights, a Uniform Commercial Code (UCC) product warranty, detailed payment terms and guaranties, insurance obligations, and other contractual remedies. Practical guidance is included throughout this practice note. For more related information, see Avoiding Key Risk Allocation Pitfalls When Drafting Commercial Contracts, and Indemnification and other Contractual Provisions Checklist. Force Majeure Clauses Force majeure clauses are an effective risk allocation tool and are permitted by both the UCC and the Restatement (Second) of Contracts. These provisions excuse a party’s late performance or nonperformance for reasons outside its reasonable control. Force majeure clauses often require the affected party to (1) notify the other party in writing of the event of force majeure as soon as practically possible, and (2) use reasonable efforts to limit its impact on performance. Force majeure events can be natural or man-made, and generally include, by way of example: fire, earthquake, terrorist attacks, war, strikes, acts of God, and government orders. For related force majeure clauses, see Force Majeure Clauses. Scope The scope of a force majeure provision should be carefully considered by the parties’ respective counsel in order to fairly allocate risk.
    [Show full text]
  • Unconscionability As a Sword: the Case for an Affirmative Cause of Action
    Unconscionability as a Sword: The Case for an Affirmative Cause of Action Brady Williams* Consumers are drowning in a sea of one-sided fine print. To combat contractual overreach, consumers need an arsenal of effective remedies. To that end, the doctrine of unconscionability provides a crucial defense against the inequities of rigid contract enforcement. However, the prevailing view that unconscionability operates merely as a “shield” and not a “sword” leaves countless victims of oppressive contracts unable to assert the doctrine as an affirmative claim. This crippling interpretation betrays unconscionability’s equitable roots and absolves merchants who have already obtained their ill-gotten gains. But this need not be so. Using California consumer credit law as a backdrop, this Note argues that the doctrine of unconscionability must be recrafted into an offensive sword that provides affirmative relief to victims of unconscionable contracts. While some consumers may already assert unconscionability under California’s Consumers Legal Remedies Act, courts have narrowly construed the Act to exempt many forms of consumer credit. As a result, thousands of debtors have remained powerless to challenge their credit terms as unconscionable unless first sued by a creditor. However, this Note explains how a recent landmark ruling by the California Supreme Court has confirmed a novel legal theory that broadly empowers consumers—including debtors—to assert unconscionability under the State’s Unfair Competition Law. Finally, this Note argues that unconscionability’s historical roots in courts of equity—as well as its treatment by the DOI: https://doi.org/10.15779/Z382B8VC3W Copyright © 2019 California Law Review, Inc. California Law Review, Inc.
    [Show full text]
  • Impracticability Under the U.C.C. for Wartime Contracts
    ADAPTING U.C.C. § 2-615 EXCUSE FOR CIVILIAN-MILITARY CONTRACTORS IN WARTIME Jennifer S. Martin* Abstract When should a civilian seller of goods who delays delivery or cancels altogether under a wartime contract be able to claim excuse under U.C.C. Article 2? The unprecedented extent of the U.S. military’s use of contractors abroad calls for a rethinking of U.C.C. impracticability, as private parties face wartime risks once encountered solely by the government. The traditional approach typically denies the seller the right to excuse the failure of delivery in instances where the wartime risk might be categorized as foreseeable or is expressly or impliedly allocated to the seller. This analysis forces a dilemma upon the seller facing threats of serious injury or death. At the same time, the civilian seller typically does not enjoy the same privileges regarding use of force that government provisioners once exercised. This Article proposes a new paradigm—one that would hold sellers to deliver goods in most circumstances, but would make excuse available to sellers through an analysis of functions that are inherently governmental. This analysis grants excuse where the risks associated with wartime contingencies requiring a military response are inherently governmental and, therefore, remain with the government. The rationale balances the interests of civilians performing wartime contracts and the military’s need for goods and control of the wartime theater that would warrant excusing contractors during wartime from performance in cases of extreme hazard to a contractor’s employees. * Visiting Associate Professor of Law, University of Louisville Louis D.
    [Show full text]
  • Benesch Women in Construction Spring 2020
    Spring 2020 WomenBreaking Ground in Construction A publication of Benesch Friedlander Benesch’s Construction Law Coplan & Aronoff LLP’s Construction Group Webinar Series Benesch’s Construction Law Practice prides itself on being the construction law group that educates In this issue: the industry. We present nearly 100 seminars each year at industry conferences and meetings to our Construction Contract Impacts as a clients in their offices. Given the impact and pandemic of COVID-19, we are joining many colleges and Result of COVID-19: Force Majeure, universities in moving our educational programs online in order to best facilitate learning opportunities for Impossibility, and Impracticability members of the construction industry. Gender-Based Discrimination in the April 2 will begin our webinar series as we more comprehensively address Force Majeure clauses in Construction Industry and What relation to the current COVID-19 crisis facing our nation as a whole. Employers Should Be Doing Indemnity: A Complex Puzzle That Can The Effects of Substance Abuse on the Construction Industry Be Solved Thursday, April 9, 2020 | 12:00 p.m. – 1:00 p.m. ET No Contract, No Problem Presented by: RICHARD D. KALSON, Partner, Benesch The Spearin Doctrine: Providing a CLICK HERE to register. Recovery Mechanism for Contractor’s Differing Site Condition Claims for 101 Years Gender Considerations in Construction - A Primer on Gender- Do You Know What Your CGL Policy Based Discrimination and Women-Owned Business Enterprise Covers? Regulations Contractors and Subcontractors Continue Thursday, April 16, 2020 | 12:00 p.m. – 1:00 p.m. ET to Squander Claims By Not Properly Preserving Physical Evidence Presented by: CHERYL DONAHUE, Associate, Benesch; MARGO WOLF O’DONNELL, Partner, Benesch SUSAN M.
    [Show full text]
  • Download PDF (811.8
    11 Hardship I Impracticability I Unconscionability I Unforeseeability Hardship Clauses Fluctuations in exchange rates can have disturbing and even cat­ astrophic effects on contracts, particularly if performance is necessary over a long period or at a time far ahead. As a consequence, what are known as hardship clauses have become common. 1 A hardship clause can be described as a term of a contract under which the con­ tract can be reviewed if a change in circumstances occurs that fun­ damentally modifies the initial balance between the obligations of the parties, so that performance, though not impossible, becomes un­ usually onerous for one party. The clause defines hardship for the purpose of the contract in which it appears and provides a procedure for adapting the contract if hard­ ship as defined occurs. Hardship clauses can be distinguished from doctrines familiar to the law that can be subsumed under the heading of imprevision or frustration. These doctrines apply to situations in which a fundamental disturbance occurs in the economic balance of a contract as the result of supervening events that were unforeseeable, 1 Bruno Oppetit, "L'adaptation des contrats internationaux aux changements de cir­ constances: Ia clause de 'Hardship'," Journal du Droit International (Paris), No. 1 (1974), pp. 794-814; "Contrats economiques internationaux: Les Hardship clauses," Droit et Pratique du Commerce International (Paris), Vol. 1, No. 3 (September 1975), pp. 512-17; "Hardship Clauses," Droit et Pratique du Commerce International (Paris), Vol. 2, No. 1 (March 1976), pp. 51-88; Harold Ullmann, "Droit et Pratique des Clauses de Hardship dans le Systeme Juridique Americain," Revue de Droit des Affaires Internationales, No.
    [Show full text]