Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence from Trust Games

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence from Trust Games University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Operations, Information and Decisions Papers Wharton Faculty Research 5-1999 Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence From Trust Games Rachel Croson University of Pennsylvania Nancy Buchan Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.upenn.edu/oid_papers Part of the Education Economics Commons, Income Distribution Commons, and the Other Education Commons Recommended Citation Croson, R., & Buchan, N. (1999). Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence From Trust Games. American Economic Review, 89 (2), 386-391. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.2.386 This paper is posted at ScholarlyCommons. https://repository.upenn.edu/oid_papers/292 For more information, please contact [email protected]. Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence From Trust Games Disciplines Education Economics | Income Distribution | Other Education This journal article is available at ScholarlyCommons: https://repository.upenn.edu/oid_papers/292 Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence from Trust Games By RACHEL CROSON AND NANCY BUCHAN* Gender is rarely included as a factor in eco- sending money, proposers are trusting that nomics models. However, recent work in their partners will return some money to them. experimental economics, as well as in psy- In addition, 24 out of 32 of responders who chology and political science, suggests that received money returned some (the average gender is an important determinant of eco- amount returned was $4.66). In returning nomic and strategic behavior. money, responders are reciprocating the pro- We examine gender differences in bargain- poser's actions. ing using the ``trust game'' introduced by In this paper we look for gender differences Joyce Berg et al. (1995).1 In this two-person in this game. We use data previously collected game, the ``proposer'' is given a choice of from four countries (the United States, China, sending some, all, or none of his or her $10 Japan, and Korea) and report gender differ- experimental payment to an anonymous part- ences in proposer (trusting) behavior and re- ner, the ``responder.'' The experimenter tri- sponder (reciprocating) behavior. We ®nd no ples any money sent. The responder then signi®cant effect of gender on amount sent by chooses how much of his or her total wealth proposers (trust behavior). However, we ®nd (his or her $10 experimental payment plus the that women return (reciprocate) signi®cantly tripled money) to return to the proposer. Any more of their wealth than men, both in the money the responder does not return may be United States and internationally. kept (thus the responder is playing a dictator game with his or her endowment plus three I. The Impact of Gender in times the amount the proposer sent ) . The Previous Experiments unique subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium is for the proposer to send no money and for the Catherine Eckel and Philip Grossman responder to return none. (1999) review a budding literature on gender For U.S. subjects, Berg et al. found that 30 in experimental economics. For purposes of of 32 proposers deviated from this economic this paper, we focus on their discussion of dif- equilibrium and sent some money to their part- ferences in bargaining. ners (the average amount sent was $5.16). In In ultimatum games in the laboratory, gen- der has been observed to in¯uence a variety of decisions.2 Eckel and Grossman (1998b) dem- onstrate chivalry (men accept lower offers * Operations and Information Management Depart- from women than from men) and solidarity ment, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, (women accept lower offers from women than Philadelphia, PA 19104-6366, and School of Business, from men). Sara Solnick (1998) ®nds, in con- University of Wisconsin, Madison, WI 53706-0394, re- spectively. Data in this paper were originally collected for trast, that players of both sexes demand more a cross-cultural experimental study, reported in Buchan et al. (1998). The authors thank Eric Johnson for his help and support, as well as Bingfu Chen, Wujin Chu, and Hotatka Katahira, and their research assistants, for their 2 In the ultimatum game, one player (the proposer) help in collecting the data for this research. makes an offer to another (the responder) of how to divide 1 This game is similar to the trust game in David Kreps a ®xed amount of money. The responder can accept or (1990) and the peasant±dictator game in John Van Huyck reject the proposer's offer. If the offer is accepted, the et al. (1995). All have the same prediction that play money is divided as proposed; if the offer is rejected, both should end immediately, even though strict Pareto im- players earn zero. The unique subgame-perfect equilib- provements to payoffs can be found in later stages. For a rium of this game is for the proposer to offer the responder detailed comparison of the games see Berg et al. (1995). « and for the responder to accept. 386 / 3y16 my69 Mp 386 Friday Dec 10 08:21 AM LP±AER my69 VOL. 89 NO. 2 GENDER AND ECONOMIC TRANSACTIONS 387 from women than from men. Both studies icant gender difference in the riskless reci- found that offers were lower to women than procity decisions and no difference in the risky to men, and that offers from women and men trusting decisions. were not signi®cantly different. Other researchers have investigated gender ef- II. Experimental Design and Procedure fects in the dictator game.3 Eckel and Grossman (1998a) found that women give more than men The experimental design used in this study in these games, while Gary Bolton and Elena involves an examination of culture, commu- Katok (1995) found no signi®cant difference. nication, and the social distance between play- James Andreoni and Lise Vesterlund (1998) ers. For purposes of this study, these factors compared gender behavior in dictator games as are treated as nuisance variables, and are con- the monetary value of the tokens being divided trolled for in the analysis. A complete dis- was varied among players. They found that cussion of the experimental design and women gave more overall and were more likely procedures can be found in Buchan et al. to divide tokens evenly despite different mone- (1998); here we present a shortened version. tary values, while men became less generous as Experimental instructions are available from the value of their tokens increased relative to the the authors upon request. value of the responder's tokens. Finally, Eckel Subjects are randomly assigned to the roles and Grossman (1996) examined gender differ- of proposer or responder and are directed to ences in a punishment game, where subjects separate rooms. There they receive instruc- could choose to divide evenly a $10 (or $12) tions for the trust game and are paid their en- pie with someone who had previously been un- dowment in local currency. Proposers are generous with another subject, or an $8 pie with instructed to place any money they wish to someone who had previously been generous. send to their partner in an envelope. Monitors They found that women were at least as likely collect the envelopes and take them to the ex- as men to punish ungenerous counterparts by perimenter, in a different room, who records choosing to divide the $8 pie. the amount of money sent. She then triples the As Eckel and Grossman (1999) have ob- amounts sent by proposers, places the tripled served, the ®ndings regarding gender seem to money into envelopes, and sends these enve- be conditional on the level of risk present in lopes into the respondents' room via another the experiment. In decisions where risk is in- monitor. The respondents receive their enve- volved, such as for the proposer in ultimatum lopes, and decide how much of their own ex- games, there appear to be no systematic dif- perimental fee plus any tripled money received ferences in behavior across genders. However, to return to their partners. Monitors collect the for decisions involving no risk, such as for dic- envelopes from the responders and give them tators or ``punishers,'' women tend to be more to the experimenter. The experimenter records generous and socially oriented in their behav- any amounts returned, places the money back ior. In this paper, we examine behavior in an into the proposers' original envelopes, and experiment involving both risky and riskless sends them back to the proposers' room for decisions. Proposers take a risk by sending distribution. The experiment is then con- money to the responder. Responders face no cluded; subjects turn in a post-experimental risk when deciding how much money, if any, questionnaire and leave with their earnings. to return. Our results are consistent with Eckel This procedure, though elaborate, ensures a and Grossman's distinction. We ®nd a signif- double-blind experiment. Throughout the ex- periment, subjects remain unaware of their partners' identities (and thus their genders), and the experimenter who is recording 3 In the dictator game, one player, the allocator, is given amounts sent and returned is also unaware of a ®xed amount of money to divide between himself and the subjects' identities. The anonymity af- another player, the recipient. The allocator chooses a di- vision, and the money is divided as proposed. This is not forded by this procedure helps to reduce in- a game in the formal sense, but rather an individual de- clinations on part of subjects to ``please the cision problem. experimenter'' (i.e., to behave in what they / 3y16 my69 Mp 387 Friday Dec 10 08:21 AM LP±AER my69 388 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1999 believe is the manner expected by the experi- TABLE 1ÐGENDER BY ROLE AND COUNTRY menter). Thus a double-blind experiment pro- Number of subjects vides an environment in which self-interested Role and behavior is as uninhibited as possible within a gender China Japan Korea United States Total controlled setting (Elizabeth Hoffman et al., Proposers 1994).
Recommended publications
  • Cooperation in a Peer Production Economy Experimental Evidence from Wikipedia*
    Cooperation in a Peer Production Economy Experimental Evidence from Wikipedia* Yann Algan† Yochai Benkler‡ Mayo Fuster Morell§ Jérôme Hergueux¶ July 2013 Abstract The impressive success of peer production – a large-scale collaborative model of production primarily based on voluntary contributions – is difficult to explain through the assumptions of standard economic theory. The aim of this paper is to study the prosocial foundations of cooperation in this new peer production economy. We provide the first field test of existing economic theories of prosocial motives for contributing to real-world public goods. We use an online experiment coupled with observational data to elicit social preferences within a diverse sample of 850 Wikipedia contributors, and seek to use to those measures to predict subjects’ field contributions to the Wikipedia project. We find that subjects’ field contributions to Wikipedia are strongly related to their level of reciprocity in a conditional Public Goods game and in a Trust game and to their revealed preference for social image within the Wikipedia community, but not to their level of altruism either in a standard or in a directed Dictator game. Our results have important theoretical and practical implications, as we show that reciprocity and social image are both strong motives for sustaining cooperation in peer production environments, while altruism is not. JEL classification: H41, C93, D01, Z13 Keywords: Field Experiment, Public Goods, Social Preferences, Peer Production, Internet * We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the European Research Council (ERC Starting Grant) and logistical support from the Sciences Po médialab and the Wikimedia Foundation. We are grateful to Anne l’Hôte and Romain Guillebert for outsdanding research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • An Experimental Investigation of Electoral Delegation and the Provision of Public Goods
    An Experimental Investigation of Electoral Delegation and the Provision of Public Goods John R. Hamman Florida State University Roberto A. Weber University of Zurich Jonathan Woon University of Pittsburgh How effectively do democratic institutions provide public goods? Despite the incentives an elected leader has to free ride or impose majority tyranny, our experiment demonstrates that electoral delegation results in full provision of the public good. Analysis of the experimental data suggests that the result is primarily due to electoral selection: groups elect prosocial leaders and replace those who do not implement full contribution outcomes. However, we also observe outcomes in which a minimum winning coalition exploits the contributions of the remaining players. A second experiment demonstrates that when electoral delegation must be endogenously implemented, individuals voluntarily cede authority to an elected agent only when preplay communication is permitted. Our combined results demonstrate that democratic delegation helps groups overcome the free-rider problem and generally leads to outcomes that are often both efficient and equitable. ocial scientists have long recognized individuals’ to Hobbes’ ideal vision of an absolute sovereign, decision strong incentives to “free ride” on the contribu- makers in modern democratic governments wield their S tionsofotherswhenpublicgoodsareprovided power temporarily, subject to popular approval, and reg- through decentralized, voluntary institutions (Dawes ular elections give citizens the opportunity to select new 1980; Hardin 1968; Lindahl 1919; Olson 1965; Samuelson leaders. 1954). As a result of such individual incentives, society will We explore the extent to which delegation through tend to underproduce public goods and will sometimes repeated elections can solve the free-rider problem by even fail to produce them at all.
    [Show full text]
  • Predictions and Nudges: What Behavioral Economics Has to Offer the Humanities, and Vice-Versa
    Book Review Predictions and Nudges: What Behavioral Economics Has to Offer the Humanities, and Vice-Versa Richard H. Thaler and Cass R. Sunstein, Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2008. Pp. 304. $26.00. Dan Ariely, Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces That Shape Our Decisions. New York: HarperCollins, 2008. Pp. 280. $25.95. Anne C. Dailey* Peter Siegelman** Rationalists, wearing square hats, Think, in square rooms, Looking at the floor, Looking at the ceiling. They confine themselves To right-angled triangles. If they tried rhomboids, Cones, waving lines, ellipses- As, for example, the ellipse of the half-moon- Rationalists would wear sombreros.1 Evangeline Starr Professor of Law and Associate Dean for Academic Affairs, University of Connecticut School of Law. ** Roger Sherman Professor of Law, University of Connecticut School of Law. We thank Ellen Siegelman for helpful comments. 1. Wallace Stevens, Six Significant Landscapes, VI, HARMONIUM (1916). Yale Journal of Law & the Humanities, Vol. 21, Iss. 2 [2009], Art. 6 Yale Journal of Law & the Humanities [21:2 The informed law and humanities reader can hardly fail to be aware that the field of economics has undergone a "behavioral revolution" over the past several decades, and that this revolution has spilled over into the legal academy. Open an economics journal these days and you are likely to find any number of articles billing themselves as "behavioral" in orientation. Similarly, law reviews are filled with articles bearing titles ranging from "A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics"'2 to "Harnessing Altruistic Theory and Behavioral Law and Economics to Rein in Executive Salaries" 3 and "Some Lessons for Law from Behavioral Economics About Stockbrokers and Sophisticated Customers.
    [Show full text]
  • A Summary of Papers on Fieldexperiments.Com
    A SUMMARY OF PAPERS ON FIELDEXPERIMENTS.COM: ALL FIELD EXPERIMENTS POSTED John A. List1 January 2019 Back in 2000, I was moved by Charlie Holt’s website that collated exactly 2000 (mostly) laboratory experiments. That site continues to be quite helpful for my students, colleagues, and me when we have a need to trace the great work that experimentalists have done over the years in the lab. Need insights on multi-unit auctions, “visit Charlie’s site” I often say to my students and colleagues. That site compelled me several years ago to create my own bibliographical site http://www.fieldexperiments.com, which lists publications and discussion papers in experimental economics that make use of the "field" in some manner. The site remains quite active, with an open source that allows scholars to post their own work, and to download hundreds of field experimental papers. With the growth of field experiments, I felt it apropos to provide a site that collated papers using field experiments--both published and working. In my own work I have reserved the term "field experiment" for those cases where I observed subjects in their naturally occurring environments. I explicitly, therefore, discriminated between explorations in this environment and laboratory studies that used non-standard subject pools. In a JEL paper (Harrison and List, 2004), such important differences are accounted for via qualifiers. I followed this nomenclature on the site by placing studies into three groups: 1. Artefactual field experiments, which are the same as conventional lab experiments but with a non-standard subject pool (i.e., non-students).
    [Show full text]
  • Removing the Rationality Assumption from Law and Economics
    California Law Review VOL. 88 JULY 2000 No. 4 Copyright © 2000 by California Law Review, Inc. Law and Behavioral Science: Removing the Rationality Assumption from Law and Economics Russell B. Korobkint Thomas S. Ulen$ Introduction ............................................................................................1053 I. The Uses and Shortcomings of Rational Choice Theory ................ 1060 A. Conceptions of Rational Choice Theory ................................... 1060 1. The Definitional Version .................................................... 1061 2. The Expected Utility Version ............................................ 1062 3. The Self-Interest Version ..................................... 1064 4. The Wealth Maximization Version .................................... 1066 Copyright © 2000 Russell B. Korobkin and Thomas S. Ulen t Associate Professor, University of Illinois College of Law and University of Illinois Institute of Government and Public Affairs. Visiting Professor, UCLA School of Law (2000-01). J.D., B.A., Stanford University. * Alumni Distinguished Professor, University of Illinois College of Law and Professor, University of Illinois Institute of Government and Public Affairs. Ph.D., Stanford University, M.A., Oxford University, B.A., Dartmouth College. We would like to thank the faculty and staff of the Max Planck Institute for Research into Economic Systems in Jena, Germany, for providing support and a stimulating environment in which to complete an early draft of this work. We also thank Robert Ashford,
    [Show full text]
  • Unbundling Risk Lee Anne Fennell
    University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Coase-Sandor Working Paper Series in Law and Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics Economics 2010 Unbundling Risk Lee Anne Fennell Follow this and additional works at: https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/law_and_economics Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Lee Anne Fennell, "Unbundling Risk" (John M. Olin Program in Law and Economics Working Paper No. 518, 2010). This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics at Chicago Unbound. It has been accepted for inclusion in Coase-Sandor Working Paper Series in Law and Economics by an authorized administrator of Chicago Unbound. For more information, please contact [email protected]. CHICAGO JOHN M. OLIN LAW & ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER NO. 518 (2D SERIES) PUBLIC LAW AND LEGAL THEORY WORKING PAPER NO. 304 UNBUNDLING RISK Lee Anne Fennell THE LAW SCHOOL THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO April 2010 This paper can be downloaded without charge at the John M. Olin Program in Law and Economics Working Paper Series: http://www.law.uchicago.edu/Lawecon/index.html and at the Public Law and Legal Theory Working Paper Series: http://www.law.uchicago.edu/academics/publiclaw/index.html and The Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection. 60 DUKE L.J. (forthcoming Mar. 2011) DRAFT 4/7/10 UNBUNDLING RISK Lee Anne Fennell* In a 1963 lecture, Kenneth Arrow posited a world featuring complete markets in risk that would permit anyone “to bet, at fixed odds, any amount he wishes on the occurrence of any event which will affect his welfare in any way.”1 Under such a system, no human endeavor or experience would come with a fixed quantum of risk or insurance immutably bundled with it; rather, risk would be an à la carte element that could be bought and sold in any increment to suit the tastes and needs of each individual.
    [Show full text]
  • The Case Against Copyright: a Comparative Institutional Analysis of Intellectual Property Regimes
    GW Law Faculty Publications & Other Works Faculty Scholarship 2004 The Case Against Copyright: A Comparative Institutional Analysis of Intellectual Property Regimes F. Scott Kieff George Washington University Law School, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.gwu.edu/faculty_publications Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Kieff, F. Scott, "The Case Against Copyright: A Comparative Institutional Analysis of Intellectual Property Regimes" (2004). GW Law Faculty Publications & Other Works. 561. https://scholarship.law.gwu.edu/faculty_publications/561 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in GW Law Faculty Publications & Other Works by an authorized administrator of Scholarly Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. (Working Draft) THE CASE AGAINST COPYRIGHT: A COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY REGIMES F. SCott KiEff * © 2004. F. Scott Kieff. All Rights Reserved. Abstract Contemporary debates over intellectual property (“IP”) generally evidence positions that appear to line up at opposite ends of the same axis, with one side arguing for more rights for IP owners under each major regime – patent, trademark, and copyright – and the other side arguing for fewer. Approaching from what some may see as a “more” IP view, this paper offers the counterintuitive suggestion to consider abolishing one of these IP regimes – copyright, at least with respect to the entertainment industry, which represents one of that regime’s most commercially significant users. This realization is in fact consistent with the underlying view because the view is not accurately seen as even being directed to the “more” or “less” debate; and instead is focused on means as much as ends.
    [Show full text]
  • Policy and Choice: Public Finance Through the Lens of Behavioral
    advance Praise For POLICY and CHOICE Mullai Congdon • Kling “Policy and Choice is a must-read for students of public finance. If you want to learn N William J. Congdon is a research director in Traditional public ἀnance provides a powerful how the emerging field of behavioral economics can help lead to better policy, there is atha the Brookings Institution’s Economic Studies framework for policy analysis, but it relies on a nothing better.” program, where he studies how best to apply model of human behavior that the new science , Harvard University, former chairman of the President’s Council of N. GreGory MaNkiw N behavioral economics to public policy. Economic Advisers, and author of Principles of Economics of behavioral economics increasingly calls into question. In Policy and Choice economists Jeἀrey R. Kling is the associate director for William Congdon, Jeffrey Kling, and Sendhil economic analysis at the Congressional Budget “This fantastic volume will become the standard reference for those interested in understanding the impact of behavioral economics on government tax and spending Mullainathan argue that public ἀnance not only Office, where he contributes to all aspects of the POLICY policies. The authors take a stream of research which had highlighted particular can incorporate many lessons of behavioral eco- agency’s analytic work. He is a former deputy ‘nudges’ and turn it into a comprehensive framework for thinking about policy in a nomics but also can serve as a solid foundation director of Economic Studies at Brookings. more realistic world where psychology is incorporated into economic decisionmaking. from which to apply insights from psychology Sendhil Mullainathan is a professor of This excellent book will be widely used and cited.” to questions of economic policy.
    [Show full text]
  • CSWEP ISSUE FOCUS Interview with 2017 Proactive Efforts to Increase Bell Award Winner Diversity and Inclusion Rachel T
    Published three times annually by the American Economic Association’s Committee on the Status of Women news in the Economics Profession. 2018 ISSUE III IN THISCSWEP ISSUE FOCUS Interview with 2017 Proactive Efforts to Increase Bell Award Winner Diversity and Inclusion Rachel T. A. Croson Introduction by Elizabeth Klee . 3 A Perspective from the Federal Tanya Rosenblat Reserve Board by Daniel Coveitz & Karen Pence . .4 Rachel T. A. Croson, Dean of the College of Social Science and MSU Foundation Applying Lessons from First- Professor of Economics at Michigan Generation Students to Women in State University is the recipient of the Economics by Fernanda Nechio.. .5 2017 Carolyn Shaw Bell Award. Given Countering Gender Bias and annually since 1998 by the Ameri- Improving Gender Balance can Economic Association’s (AEA) increasing our understanding of how by David Romer & Justin Wolfers . .7 Committee on the Status of Women in women can advance in the economics From the CSWEP Chair the Economics Profession (CSWEP), profession, or mentoring others. the Bell Award recognizes and honors Dr. Croson earned her undergradu- Chair’s Letter by Shelly Lundberg. .2 an individual who has furthered the sta- ate degree from the University of Penn- tus of women in the economics profes- sylvania, with a double major in Eco- Honors & Announcements sion through example, achievements, nomics and Philosophy and a minor in Interview with Bell Award Winner continues on page 9 Rachel T . A . Croson by Tanya Rosenblat . 1 Brag Box . 20 Judith Chevalier is Next Chair of CSWEP Calls . 14 CSWEP Sessions . .16 In January 2019, Professor Judith Professor Chevalier is the author Chevalier will take the helm of the AEA of numerous articles in the areas of fi- Committee on the Status of Women nance, industrial organization, market- in the Economics Profession.
    [Show full text]
  • Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems†
    American Economic Review 100 (June 2010): 641–672 http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi 10.1257/aer.100.3.641 = Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems† By Elinor Ostrom* Contemporary research on the outcomes of diverse institutional arrangements for governing common-pool resources CPRs and public goods at multiple scales builds on classical economic ( ) theory while developing new theory to explain phenomena that do not fit in a dichotomous world of “the market” and “the state.” Scholars are slowly shifting from positing simple systems to using more complex frameworks, theories, and models to understand the diversity of puzzles and problems facing humans interacting in contemporary societies. The humans we study have complex motivational structures and establish diverse private-for-profit, governmental, and com- munity institutional arrangements that operate at multiple scales to generate productive and inno- vative as well as destructive and perverse outcomes Douglass C. North 1990, 2005 . ( ) In this article, I will describe the intellectual journey that I have taken the last half century from when I began graduate studies in the late 1950s. The early efforts to understand the poly- centric water industry in California were formative for me. In addition to working with Vincent Ostrom and Charles M. Tiebout as they formulated the concept of polycentric systems for gov- erning metropolitan areas, I studied the efforts of a large group of private and public water producers facing the problem of an overdrafted groundwater basin on the coast and watching saltwater intrusion threaten the possibility of long term use. Then, in the 1970s, I participated with colleagues in the study of polycentric police industries serving US metropolitan areas to find that the dominant theory underlying massive reform proposals was incorrect.
    [Show full text]
  • Loss Aversion and Seller Behavior
    Loss Aversion and Seller Behavior: Evidence from the Housing Market by David Genesove and Christopher Mayer* March 1, 2000 *Genesove: Department of Economics, Hebrew University of Jerusalem and N.B.E.R. Mayer: The Wharton School of Business, University of Pennsylvania. We are especially indebted to Debbie Taylor for providing LINK's weekly listing files and many helpful suggestions. We also wish to thank Paul Anglin, Rachel Croson, Gary Engelhardt, Don Haurin, Laurie Hodrick, Glenn Hubbard, Gur Huberman, Bob Shiller, Richard Thaler, and seminar participants at various institutions for many helpful and insightful comments. The excellent research assistance of Margaret Enis, Meeta Anand, Rupa Patel, Karen Therien, and Per Juvkam-Wold is also acknowledged. Loss Aversion and Seller Behavior: Evidence from the Housing Market We show that loss aversion is an important feature in explaining sellers’ behavior in the housing market. Data from the 1990-97 boom-bust cycle in downtown Boston show that condominium owners subject to nominal losses 1) set higher asking prices of 25-35 percent of the difference between the expected selling price of a property and their original purchase price; 2) attain higher selling prices of 3-18 percent of that difference; and 3) exhibit a much lower hazard rate of sale than other sellers. The list price results are roughly twice as large for owner- occupants as investors, although they hold for both groups. We also show that the larger the prospective loss, the smaller the marginal mark-up of list price over expected selling. These findings are consistent with the shape of the value function in prospect theory as first proposed by Kahneman and Tversky (1979).
    [Show full text]
  • A Century of American Economic Review
    A Century of American Economic Review ∗ Benno Torgler and Marco Piatti Abstract: Using information collected from American Economic Review publications of the last 100 years, we try to provide answers to various questions: Which are the top AER publishing institutions and countries? Which are the top AER papers based on citation success? How frequently is someone able to publish in AER? How equally is citation success distributed? Who are the top AER publishing authors? What is the level of cooperation among the authors? What drives the alphabetical name ordering? What are the individual characteristics of the AER authors, editors, editorial board members, and referees? How frequently do women publish in AER? What is the relationship between academic age, publication performance, and citation success? What are the paper characteristics? What influences the level of technique used in articles? Do connections have an influence on citation success? Who receives awards? Can awards increase the probability of publishing in AER at a later stage? JEL Classification: A10, A110, B00, B31, B40, I23, N01, J00, Z00 Keywords: American Economic Review, publishing economics, rankings, cooperation, authors, editors, board members, referees, connections, awards, paper characteristics, economic history, history of economic thought ∗For this article, a third party tossed a coin to determine the order of the authors’ names. Both are affiliated with the School of Economics and Finance, Queensland University of Technology, GPO Box 2434, Brisbane, QLD 4001, Australia. Benno Torgler is also affiliated with CREMA—Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts (Switzerland); CESifo (Germany); and the National Centre for Econometric Research (Australia).
    [Show full text]