<<

A Service of

Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics

Grau, Aaron; Odening, Martin; Ritter, Matthias

Working Paper Land price diffusion across borders: The case of

FORLand-Working Paper, No. 03 (2018)

Provided in Cooperation with: DFG Research Unit 2569 FORLand "Agricultural Land Markets – Efficiency and Regulation", Humboldt-Universität

Suggested Citation: Grau, Aaron; Odening, Martin; Ritter, Matthias (2018) : Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany, FORLand-Working Paper, No. 03 (2018), Humboldt- Universität zu Berlin, DFG Research Unit 2569 FORLand "Agricultural Land Markets - Efficiency and Regulation", Berlin, http://dx.doi.org/10.18452/19263

This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/213057

Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use:

Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes.

Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.

https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/de/ www.econstor.eu

– Land Markets Agricultural

Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

Aaron Grau, Martin Odening, Matthias Ritter

Efficiency and Regulation Efficiency FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018)

Published by DFG Research Unit 2569 FORLand, Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin Unter den Linden 6, D-10099 Berlin https://www.forland.hu-berlin.de

Tel +49 (30) 2093 46845, Email [email protected]

Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

Aaron Grau ∗, Martin Odening ∗∗, Matthias Ritter ∗∗∗

June 2018

Abstract

Land market regulations are often justified by the assumption that activities of foreign and non- agricultural investors drive up land prices in countries with low land price levels. However, empirical knowledge about the dynamics of agricultural land prices across borders is sparse. Using the as a natural experiment, we study the effect of the former on the dynamics of agricultural land prices in East and . We apply a land price diffusion model with an error correction specification that estimates to what extent agricultural land markets are spatially integrated. A novel feature of our model is its ability to distinguish price diffusion within states and across state borders. We find that local agricultural land markets in Germany are linked by a long-run equilibrium relationship. Spatial market integration, however, does not hold among all counties in our study area. Regarding our main research question, we provide evidence for a persistent border effect given that the fraction of spatially integrated counties is larger within states than across the former border. Moreover, we observe non-significant error correction terms for many counties along the former border. From a policy perspective, it is striking to realize that even 25 years after German reunification, pronounced land price differences persist. It is quite likely that price diffusion through existing borders within the EU would take even more time given language barriers, different administrative procedures for land acquisitions, different tax systems, and information asymmetries between domestic and foreign market participants.

Keywords: Agricultural land markets; price diffusion; spatial dependence; border effect

JEL codes: Q24, C23

Acknowledgements

Financial support from the German Research Foundation (DFG) through Research Unit 2569 “Agricultural Land Markets – Efficiency and Regulation” is gratefully acknowledged. The authors also thank Oberer Gutachterausschuss für Grundstückswerte in Niedersachsen and Gutachter- ausschuss für Grundstückswerte in Sachsen-Anhalt for providing the data used in the analysis.

∗ Aaron Grau, [email protected] ∗∗ Martin Odening, [email protected] ∗∗∗ Matthias Ritter, [email protected] All authors are at Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin, Faculty of Life Sciences, Department of Agricultural Economics, Unter den Linden 6, D-10099 Berlin.

Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

1 Introduction

Recent surges in agricultural land prices and ongoing changes in land use due to urban sprawl, renewable energy production, and growing demands from non-agricultural investors have triggered debates on the effectiveness of existing land market regulations. Although boom and bust cycles are not new to land markets, current changes in the market are considered to result from a new constellation of driving forces. For instance, it is conjectured that the increased demand for land by financial investors has increased land rental and sales prices. These developments have led to demands for stricter regulations of land markets in many countries, including developed countries (cf. Kay et al., 2015). In 2010, the UK Government Office of Science stressed the need to balance competing pressures on land use and to roll out new land use policies (Government Office for Science, 2010). Four years later, Belgium laid the foundation for new land market instruments, such as a land observatory, land bank, and updated preemption rights. Belgium also tightened land market regulations, which had previously been liberal. Likewise, in Germany, the Federal Ministry and the State Ministries of currently aim for a broad distribution of land ownership, the prevention of dominant land market positions on the supply and demand side, the capping of land rental and sales prices, prioritizing agricultural use of farmland, and establishing greater transparency for land markets (Bund-Länder-Arbeitsgruppe “Bodenmarktpolitik”, 2015). Although these goals are fairly general, they fall in line with the trend toward stricter land market regulations. The proposed measures envision restricting market access for actors who treat land as an investment asset and do not have farming interests, while simultaneously prioritizing land purchases by farmers and facilitating farm succession and start-ups.

Remarkably, it is mainly the new EU Member States, which carry the legacy of weaker land market institutions from their socialist past, that opt for particularly strong regulations (cf. Swinnen et al., 2016). For example, new land market regulations aiming to restrict the purchase of agricultural land by foreigners and non-farmers was released in Slovakia (Lazíková and Bandlerová, 2015). In 2016, passed the Act on the Structuring of the Agricultural System, which postponed exemptions from EU laws regarding the acquisition of land. The bill proposes to stop the sale of state-owned land for the next five years and includes very strict rules on who can sell and buy privately-owned land. The objective of the new law is to ensure that farmland remains in the hands of Polish farmers after the transition period. , Hungary, Latvia, and Lithuania followed suit with regulations directly or indirectly restricting the free movement of capital and freedom of establishment.

Most of the aforementioned attempts to regulate land markets have been motivated by the apprehension that in countries with low land price levels, farmers will encounter a drastic price surge unless land markets are protected against demand by foreign and non-agricultural investors. This assumption, however, lacks empirical evidence. Little is known about the spatio- temporal behavior of agricultural land prices and virtually no empirical study exists that investigates the diffusion of agricultural land prices across borders. In other words, we do not know how fast land prices in two neighboring countries with different price levels would converge if there were no restrictions on the acquisition of land. The main objective of this paper is to address this research gap. Our empirical analysis is conducted for West and , i.e., we study the effect of the former intra-German border on the dynamics of

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 3 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany agricultural land prices. The German reunification constitutes a natural experiment on the establishment and evolution of land markets that allows us to study market integration. It is well-known that a gap exists between land prices in West and East Germany, but little is known about how this gap evolves over time and if the same land price dynamics prevail in both parts of Germany. After reunification, regions in Western Germany (especially near the former border between West and East Germany) lost their remoteness since they were suddenly situated in the center of Europe and thus became more attractive. On the other hand, the supply of cheaper land increased and redirected demand to regions in Eastern Germany, so that the effect of the reunification on land prices remains unclear.

To the best of our knowledge, there are only few studies that test for spatial market integration in the context of agricultural land. 1 Carmona and Roses (2012) investigate the spatial integration of Spanish land markets between 1904 and 1934 from a historical perspective. Their analysis is based on aggregated data and does not take into account heterogeneity of land characteristics and structural breaks in the price series that may bias the test results. More recently, Yang et al. (2017, 2018) explore the spatial pattern of land price development. Based on county-level data for the German state Lower , they employ stationarity tests and unit root tests to examine whether relative prices between counties converge. Using a sequential testing procedure allows Yang et al. (2017, 2018) to identify several distinct convergence clusters. The closest study to ours investigates the impact of a language border on spatio-temporal price diffusion of house prices in Belgium (Helgers and Buyst, 2016). Starting with a pairwise approach to provide insight into the degree of integration among housing prices, the study estimates a bivariate VAR model with error correcting coefficients. The results indicate that the fraction of pairs for which the regional house price differentials are stationary is higher within a linguistic area than between these areas. Although there are many structural similarities between house markets and land markets, which allow the transfer of methods across these two fields, one should also recognize the differences between these two markets. First, while agricultural land is mainly a production factor, houses have the character of a consumption good. This makes house prices more dependent on buyers’ preferences and incomes. Second, potential buyers of houses are usually more mobile than farmers, making it more likely for house prices to converge. Finally, the supply of land follows a different mechanism than the supply of houses. Thus, one cannot readily adopt findings from real estate markets to agricultural land markets.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: The following section introduces the spatial price diffusion model and explains the logic of identifying a “border effect”; Section 3 provides some background information about the study region, the relevant land market environment after reunification, and the derivation of the data; Section 4 presents and discusses the empirical results; and Section 5 concludes.

1 There is, however, a rich literature on spatial price convergence in real estate markets, particularly in housing markets (cf. Hiebert and Roma (2010) for an overview).

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 4 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

2 A land price diffusion model with a border effect

At the heart of our research lies the question of whether land prices in Germany are integrated through time and space and converge in absence of barriers, such as the former German border. Consequently, the desired empirical application requires a model that allows for the incorporation of time and space. This can be achieved by a price diffusion model as proposed by Holly et al. (2011). In general, a price diffusion model is based on a Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) since cointegration is a necessity for price convergence in the long-run. The VECM accounts for this cointegration relationship by correcting the short-run responses of prices by deviations from a stable long-run equilibrium.

At first glance, to test the integration of land prices in a study area consisting of regions would imply to test for ( 1)/2 cointegration relationships. Nevertheless, one price of a 𝑁𝑁 cointegration vector can always be expressed by one other price or a combination of 𝑁𝑁 𝑁𝑁 − cointegrated prices (Holly et al., 2011). Thus, it is feasible to apply a neighbor approach that reduces the rank of the cointegration vector to unity and the number of equations to be estimated to . In this parsimonious representation, the cointegration relationship is reduced neighbor to the price , of region and a weighted average price of region ’s neighbors , = 𝑁𝑁 , , , with = 1 if row-standardization is applied. The weights measure 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡 𝑖𝑖 𝑖𝑖 𝑗𝑗 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡 connectivity𝑁𝑁 through𝑁𝑁 proximity in geographic, economic, or social terms. Stacking all of the ∑𝑗𝑗=1 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑝𝑝𝑗𝑗 𝑡𝑡 ∑𝑗𝑗=1 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 weights in a matrix with the diagonal elements equal to zero gives a spatial weight matrix , which incorporates the dimension of space into the model. Another benefit of this approach is 𝑊𝑊 that no benchmark region has to be selected a priori in the cointegration system (Abbott and De Vita, 2013). The regional price diffusion model can be formulated into a VECM:

neighbor , = + , + 𝑘𝑘 , , , + 𝑚𝑚 , , , + + , (1) ∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡 𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡−1 � 𝛾𝛾𝑖𝑖 1 𝑝𝑝∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡−𝑝𝑝 � 𝛾𝛾𝑖𝑖 2 𝑝𝑝∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡−𝑝𝑝 𝜆𝜆𝑖𝑖𝑧𝑧𝑡𝑡 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝑝𝑝=1 𝑝𝑝=1 neighbor where , is the land price in region at time , , is a weighted average land price in neighboring regions, is a vector of exogenous common factors that affect all region prices, 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡 𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡 is an error term, and is the difference operator. The term is a region specific constant 𝑧𝑧𝑡𝑡 term to capture unobserved individual effects. The parameter vectors , , , , , , and 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ∆ 𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖 capture the short-run responses of , to own price lags, weighted neighbor price lags, 𝛾𝛾𝑖𝑖 1 𝑝𝑝 𝛾𝛾𝑖𝑖 2 𝑝𝑝 𝜆𝜆𝑖𝑖 and the common factors, respectively. measures the adjustment speed of corrections given ∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡 𝑘𝑘 𝑚𝑚 that random deviations , in the long-run equilibrium relationship between land prices 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 occur. Error correction requires to be negative. A flexible form of the cointegration 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡−1 relationship that includes a constant and a trend is given by 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 neighbor , = , , , (2) 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡−1 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡−1 − 𝛽𝛽0𝑖𝑖 − 𝛽𝛽1𝑖𝑖𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡−1 − 𝛽𝛽2𝑖𝑖𝑡𝑡𝑖𝑖 where s are parameters defining the cointegration relationship between price pairs. While cointegration is sufficient to establish a long-run price relationship, further parameter 𝛽𝛽 restrictions have to be fulfilled to assert prices convergence among neighboring regions (Abbott and De Vita, 2013; Yang et al., 2017). If equals unity and the trend parameter and constant equal zero, prices of neighboring regions converge to the same level 𝛽𝛽1𝑖𝑖 𝛽𝛽2𝑖𝑖 𝛽𝛽0𝑖𝑖 FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 5 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

(absolute convergence). If is instead positive, prices converge toward a constant difference (relative convergence) (Waights, 2018). 𝛽𝛽0𝑖𝑖 To examine whether a predetermined barrier, such as a border, affects the diffusion of prices, we follow Helgers and Buyst (2016) by splitting neighboring prices into two groups. One group same is the weighted price consisting of regions on the same side of the border, , = same opp = , , and the other group of regions on the opposite side of the border, 𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡, 𝑁𝑁 opp 𝑝𝑝̅ , . Therein weights are based on the individual elements of the original ∑𝑗𝑗=1 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝑝𝑝𝑗𝑗 𝑡𝑡 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡 weight𝑁𝑁 ing matrix with the difference that the individual elements of same ( opp) are set to ∑𝑗𝑗=1 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝑝𝑝𝑗𝑗 𝑡𝑡 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 zero if region lies on the opposite (same) side of the border as region . Again, same and 𝑊𝑊 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 opp are row-standardized. In contrast to Helgers and Buyst (2016), we refrain from including 𝑗𝑗 𝑖𝑖 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 a dominant region in the model since a dominant region is less likely to exist in agricultural 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 land markets (Yang et al., 2018). With this regrouping, the price diffusion model (1) is transformed into:

same , = + , , , + , , , + 𝑘𝑘 , , , + 𝑚𝑚 , , ,

∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡 𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 1𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑖𝑖 1 𝑡𝑡−1 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 2𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑖𝑖 2 𝑡𝑡−1 � 𝛾𝛾𝑖𝑖 1 𝑝𝑝∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡−𝑝𝑝 � 𝛾𝛾𝑖𝑖 2 𝑝𝑝∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡−𝑝𝑝 (3) 𝑝𝑝=1 𝑝𝑝=1 opp + 𝑞𝑞 , , , + + . � 𝛾𝛾𝑖𝑖 3 𝑞𝑞∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡−𝑝𝑝 𝜆𝜆𝑖𝑖𝑧𝑧𝑡𝑡 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝑝𝑝=1

Herein, , , captures deviations from the long-run relationship between region ’s land same price and the𝑖𝑖 1 𝑡𝑡 −1within state average neighbors’ land price , . Accordingly, , , 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 opp 𝑖𝑖 corresponds to deviations from the across state neighbors’ land price . Equation (3) 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡−1 , 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑖𝑖 2 𝑡𝑡−1 allows the empirical investigation of whether a border effect is present in land price diffusion. 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡−1 A border effect can exist under two different circumstances. The first is if deviations from the long-run equilibrium with the weighted average land price of neighboring regions are not corrected ( , 0 ). The second is if deviations from the average weighted land price of neighbors within the same state are corrected faster than the average weighted land price of 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 2 ≥ neighboring regions across the border ( , < , ). This leads to the following hypotheses:

𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 1 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 2 Hypothesis 1: The former border does not slow down the long-run price diffusion process of region with neighbors across the border compared to neighbors within the state. Thus, deviations in the cointegration relationship with neighbors across the former border are 𝑖𝑖 corrected faster or at the same speed as with neighbors on the same side of the border ( , , ).

𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 1 ≥ 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 2 Hypothesis 2: The former border prohibits any correction toward a long-run equilibrium between region ’s land price and the land price of neighboring regions across the border ( , 0). 𝑖𝑖 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 2 ≥ If hypothesis 1 is rejected, the former border still affects land price diffusion for region with its neighboring land markets across the border. If hypothesis 2 is rejected, land price changes 𝑖𝑖 diffuse across the former border. Thus, we can deduce that if hypothesis 1 is not rejected and hypothesis 2 is rejected, land price diffusion to and from region to its neighbors across the former border is not blocked or slowed down, i.e., there is evidence supporting no border effect. 𝑖𝑖

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 6 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

Vice versa, if hypothesis 1 is rejected and hypothesis 2 is not rejected, we can conclude that land price diffusion to and from region to its neighbors across the former border is slowed down and possibly completely blocked, i.e., there is evidence supporting a border effect. 𝑖𝑖 Assuming independence of the error terms, the regional VECM equations (3) can be estimated with Ordinary Least Squares (OLS). The seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) 𝑁𝑁 allows for the estimation of an unrestricted covariance matrix with possible contem- poraneous correlation between the individual region equations, Cov( , ) 0 for . 𝛦𝛦𝑡𝑡 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝜀𝜀𝑗𝑗𝑗𝑗 ≠ 𝑖𝑖 ≠ 𝑗𝑗 While the system of regional VECM equations is a parsimonious representation of cointegration relationships and allows one to test whether the former German border still 𝑁𝑁 affects long-run land price diffusion, it cannot display the full complexity of the spatio-temporal land price diffusion process and restricts the analysis to regions adjacent to the former border. Regional land markets, however, can be linked over far distances and react to one another, even though no direct cointegration relationship exists due to short-run dynamics and temporal and spatial spillover effects. The price diffusion model in a VECM form is the basis for deriving impulse response function (IRF) specifications. Through impulse response analysis, it is possible to investigate the diffusion of shocks to one region in a regional system over time and space (Holly et al., 2011). To derive IRFs, the original system of regional VECM equations with a border effect (3) is stacked and rewritten in matrix notation: 𝑁𝑁

= + + 𝑙𝑙 + + (4)

∆𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡 𝐶𝐶 𝛱𝛱𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡−1 � 𝛤𝛤𝑝𝑝∆𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡−𝑝𝑝 𝛬𝛬𝑍𝑍𝑡𝑡 𝛦𝛦𝑡𝑡 𝑝𝑝=1 + , , + , , + , , + , , 𝑐𝑐1 𝜙𝜙1 1𝛽𝛽01 1 𝜙𝜙1 2𝛽𝛽01 2 with = ⎡ ⎤, 𝑐𝑐2 𝜙𝜙2 1𝛽𝛽02 1 𝜙𝜙2 2𝛽𝛽02 2 ⎢ + , , + , , ⎥ 𝐶𝐶 + ⋮ + ⎢ 𝑁𝑁−1 𝑁𝑁−1 1, 0𝑁𝑁−,1 1 𝑁𝑁, −1 2 , 0𝑁𝑁−1 2⎥ , + , ⎢𝑐𝑐 0 𝜙𝜙 𝛽𝛽 0𝜙𝜙 𝛽𝛽 ⎥ 0 𝑁𝑁 𝑁𝑁 1 0𝑁𝑁 1 𝑁𝑁 2 0𝑁𝑁 2 0 ⎣ , + 𝑐𝑐 , 𝜙𝜙 𝛽𝛽 𝜙𝜙0 𝛽𝛽 ⎦ 0 𝜙𝜙1 1 𝜙𝜙1 2 ⋯ = ⎡ ⎤ 𝜙𝜙2 1 𝜙𝜙2 2 ⋯ ⎢ 0 0 , + , 0 ⎥ 𝛱𝛱 0⋮ 0⋮ ⋱ 0⋮ +⋮ − ⎢ 𝑁𝑁−1 1 𝑁𝑁−1 2 , , ⎥ ⎢ same ⋯ 𝜙𝜙 opp𝜙𝜙 ⎥ , , + , , 𝑁𝑁 1 𝑁𝑁 2 ⎣ ⋯ ′ 𝜙𝜙 𝜙𝜙 ⎦ same′ + opp 𝜙𝜙1,1𝛽𝛽11,1𝑤𝑤1 𝜙𝜙1,2𝛽𝛽11,2𝑤𝑤1 ⎡ ′ ′ ⎤ , and 2 1 12 1 2 2 2 12 2 2 ⎢ 𝜙𝜙 𝛽𝛽 𝑤𝑤same 𝜙𝜙 𝛽𝛽 𝑤𝑤 opp ⎥ ⎢ , , + , , ⎥ ⎢ ′ ⋮ ′⎥ same + opp ⎢𝜙𝜙𝑁𝑁−1 1𝛽𝛽,1𝑁𝑁−1,1𝑤𝑤𝑁𝑁−1 𝜙𝜙𝑁𝑁−, 1 2𝛽𝛽1, 𝑁𝑁−1 2𝑤𝑤𝑁𝑁−1 ⎥ ⎢ ′ ′ same⎥ + opp , 0 𝑁𝑁 1 1𝑁𝑁 1 0𝑁𝑁 0 𝑁𝑁 2 1𝑁𝑁 2 𝑁𝑁, , ⎣ 𝜙𝜙 𝛽𝛽 𝑤𝑤 𝜙𝜙 𝛽𝛽 𝑤𝑤 ⎦ ′ same′ opp 0 , 0 0 1,2𝑝𝑝 1 + 1,3𝑝𝑝 1 𝛾𝛾1 1𝑝𝑝 ⋯ 𝛾𝛾 𝑤𝑤 𝛾𝛾 𝑤𝑤 = + ⎡ ′ ′ ⎤. ⎡ 2 1𝑝𝑝 ⎤ ⎢ 2 2𝑝𝑝 2 2 3𝑝𝑝 2 ⎥ 0 𝛾𝛾 0 ⋯ 0 𝛾𝛾 𝑤𝑤same 𝛾𝛾 𝑤𝑤 opp ⎢ , ⎥ ⎢ , + , ⎥ 𝑝𝑝 ⎢ ⎥ 𝛤𝛤 0⋮ 0⋮ ⋱ 0⋮ ⋮ ⎢ ′ ⋮ ′⎥ ⎢ 𝑁𝑁−1 1𝑝𝑝 , ⎥ same + opp ⋯ 𝛾𝛾 ⎢𝛾𝛾𝑁𝑁−1,2𝑝𝑝𝑤𝑤𝑁𝑁−1 𝛾𝛾𝑁𝑁−, 1 3𝑝𝑝𝑤𝑤𝑁𝑁−1 ⎥ ⎢ ⎥ ′ ′ ⎣ ⋯ 𝛾𝛾𝑁𝑁 1𝑝𝑝⎦ ⎢ ⎥ ⎣ 𝛾𝛾𝑁𝑁 2𝑝𝑝𝑤𝑤𝑁𝑁 𝛾𝛾𝑁𝑁 3𝑝𝑝𝑤𝑤𝑁𝑁 ⎦

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 7 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

The price vector = , , , , … , , comprises all regions’ land prices and thus all ′ endogenous time series. is the × cointegration matrix to parameterize the long-run 𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡 �𝑝𝑝1 𝑡𝑡 𝑝𝑝2 𝑡𝑡 𝑝𝑝𝑁𝑁 𝑡𝑡� 𝑁𝑁 spatial relationship in , while the × matrix captures the short-run responses to past 2 𝛱𝛱 𝑁𝑁 𝑁𝑁 same same same same same changes in . The spatial𝑡𝑡 weight vectors 𝑝𝑝 = , , … , , and opp opp opp 𝑃𝑃 opp opp𝑝𝑝 𝑁𝑁 𝛤𝛤 ′ ′ ′ ′ ′𝑝𝑝 = 𝑡𝑡 , , … , , are the 𝑖𝑖N rows of1 the correspon2 ding𝑁𝑁−1 spatial𝑁𝑁 weight ′ 𝑃𝑃 ′ ′ ′ ′ 𝑤𝑤 �𝑤𝑤 𝑤𝑤 𝑤𝑤 𝑤𝑤 � same opp matrices𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖 � 𝑤𝑤1 𝑤𝑤 and2 𝑤𝑤.𝑁𝑁 −1 𝑤𝑤𝑁𝑁 �

The vector𝑊𝑊 autoregression𝑊𝑊 (VAR) representation of (4) is

= + + + + + ( ) + + , (5)

𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡 𝐶𝐶 𝛷𝛷1𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡−1 𝛷𝛷2𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡−2 ⋯ 𝛷𝛷𝑝𝑝𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡−𝑝𝑝 𝛷𝛷𝑝𝑝+1𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡− 𝑝𝑝+1 𝛬𝛬𝑍𝑍𝑡𝑡 𝛦𝛦𝑡𝑡 where the parameter matrices = + + , = , and = are compounds of the VECM coefficient matrices. Hence, the temporal effects of the VAR s are 𝛷𝛷1 𝐼𝐼𝑁𝑁 𝛱𝛱 𝛤𝛤1 𝛷𝛷𝑝𝑝 𝛤𝛤𝑝𝑝 − 𝛤𝛤𝑝𝑝−1 𝛷𝛷𝑝𝑝+1 −𝛤𝛤𝑝𝑝 also dependent on spatial relationships introduced through the spatial weight matrices same 𝛷𝛷 and opp. The generalized impulse response function (GIRF) for a one unit (one standard 𝑊𝑊 error) shock originating in region at time step intervals ahead can be calculated after 𝑊𝑊 𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑖 Pesaran and Shin (1998) by 𝑖𝑖 ℎ

ℎ (ℎ) = for ℎ = 0,1, … , , (6) 𝛹𝛹 𝛴𝛴𝑒𝑒𝑖𝑖 𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑖 𝐻𝐻 �𝜎𝜎𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 where is the covariance matrix, is a × 1 vector of zeros with exclusion of its th element set to unity, and are the diagonal elements of the covariance matrix. The s are calculated 𝛴𝛴 𝑒𝑒𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑁 𝑖𝑖 recursively with the help of the VAR coefficients by 𝜎𝜎𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝛹𝛹

ℎ = ℎ + ℎ + + ℎ + ℎ ( ), (7)

𝛹𝛹 𝛷𝛷1𝛹𝛹 −1 𝛷𝛷2𝛹𝛹 −2 ⋯ 𝛷𝛷𝑝𝑝𝛹𝛹 −𝑝𝑝 𝛷𝛷𝑝𝑝+1𝛹𝛹 − 𝑝𝑝+1 with = and = 0 for all < 0 (Pesaran and Shin, 1998). The GIRF approach is a better representation of dynamic spatial integration since a shock originating in region will 𝛹𝛹0 𝐼𝐼𝑁𝑁 𝛹𝛹ℎ ℎ eventually progress to the non-neighboring region via spatial linkage through other regions 𝑖𝑖 (Abbott and De Vita, 2013). 𝑗𝑗

3 Study Region and Data

3.1 The border region of and Saxony-Anhalt

During the division of Germany from 1945 to 1990, the two sides divided by the inner German border were exposed to different political and economic systems. This difference also applied to agricultural land markets. Whereas a free land market was established in West Germany, East Germany was characterized by expropriation and collectivization of land. In 1989, East German agriculture consisted of 464 state-owned farms called Volkseigene Güter (VEGs, People-Owned Properties) and 3,844 collective farms called Landwirtschaftliche Produktionsgenossenschaften (LPGs, Agricultural Production Cooperatives) (Jochimsen

2 p is the maximum of the lag numbers k, q, and m of the lagged own and neighbors’ price differences suggested by Schwarz Criterion (BIC).

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 8 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

2010). After reunification in 1990, the property rights in East Germany had to be clarified and former owners were indemnified according to the Entschädigungs- und Ausgleichsleistungs- gesetz (Indemnification and Compensation Act). The Landwirtschaftsanpassungsgesetz (Law on the Adjustment of Agriculture) regulated the decollectivization process and transformation of LPGs toward other legal forms. State-owned land was privatized through the Treuhandanstalt (1990–1992) and the Bodenverwertungs- und -verwaltungs GmbH (BVVG, since 1992). After 1990, many farmers from West Germany or other Western European countries bought or rented land in former East Germany at prices that were considerably lower than in former West Germany (Koester, 2000). This privatization process was recently prolonged to 2030 since the BVVG still holds 136,700 ha of agricultural land in East Germany (BMWi, 2017).

Almost 30 years after the reunification, it could be expected that the open border led to an equalization of conditions on both sides. In this study, we focus on the border region between the state of Lower Saxony (in former West Germany) and the state of Saxony-Anhalt (in former East Germany). After a reform of the counties in Saxony-Anhalt in 2007 (Kreisreform), the border region between Saxony-Anhalt and Lower Saxony now consists of four counties on the former east side and six counties on the former west side. With around 415 km, almost one- third of the former inner German border is covered in this analysis.

Table 1 shows similarities and differences between the counties in east and west: The number of farms per county is comparable on both sides of the border (approximately 500 per county), but farms, on average, are more than two times larger in Saxony-Anhalt. This is a result of the history of LPGs: Nowadays, farms in former East Germany are often still organized as cooperatives. In fact, in the former East German border counties, 24% to 47% of the agricultural area is operated by legal persons, whereas this percentage is almost zero in former West German border counties. Joint ownership leads to information asymmetries and could prevent Western farmers from buying land on the Eastern side of the former border due to higher transaction costs. At the same time, however, access to information is facilitated for land sold by the BVVG since it uses public auctions. The BVVG is an important player on the East German land market: It has sold between 21% and 58% of the total transacted agricultural land in the Eastern border counties after reunification.

Similar production structures on both sides of the border could also lead to an assimilation of prices. For example, production is quite strong in the south of both border regions where 50% of the available arable land is used for wheat growing. Moreover, there is a cross-border cluster in Lüchow- and on the western side and in Altmarkkreis and Börde on the eastern side. Livestock densities are, in general, higher on the eastern side and decrease from north to south.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 9 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

Table 1: Descriptive statistics for the border counties (sorted from north to south)

Border Number Avg. Share of Area hold Share BVVG (% of Wheat area Potato area Livestock Price Price length of farms farm arable by transacted (ha) (% of (ha) (% of density 2016 growth (km) size land juridical agricultural land arab. land) arab. land) (livestock (€/ha) 2007–2016 (ha) person sold by BVVG) units/ha arab. land) Lower Saxony Lüchow-Dannenberg 107 587 103 80% n/a – 8,045 5,559 0.37 16,409 127% (17%) (11.5%) Uelzen 15 693 108 90% n/a – 14,454 13,239 0.29 27,761 174% (21%) (19.6%) 71 817 95 83% n/a – 9,585 7,553 0.30 25,519 205% (15%) (11.7%) 122 359 115 91% n/a – 16,924 153 0.09 29,360 144% (45%) (0.4%) Wolfenbüttel 32 403 126 96% n/a – 26,603 60 0.05 29,355 85% (54%) (0.1%) 69 289 95 87% n/a – 12,511 23 0.20 26,032 67% (53%) (0.1%) Saxony-Anhalt 21 579 269 70% 39% 58% 27,958 482 0.39 10,755 203% (25%) (0.4%) 161 491 256 75% 47% 33% 13,069 2,008 0.43 9,886 174% (14%) (2.1%) Börde 114 546 277 89% 24% 21% 50,814 4,569 0.36 18,001 167% (38%) (3.4%) 120 341 303 87% 42% 35% 44,511 742 0.23 18,494 144% (49%) (0.8%)

Data sources: The data for the number and size of farms, the share of arable land, the area held by a juridical person, the wheat and potato growing areas, the livestock density, and the prices for agricultural land in 2007 and 2016 are from the Statistical Office of Lower Saxony and the Statistical Office of Saxony-Anhalt. The area held by a juridical person is not provided by the Statistical Office of Lower Saxony due to the low number of cases and the resulting confidentiality of the information. The border length and share of BVVG in the counties of Saxony-Anhalt are based on own calculations.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 10 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

Agricultural land prices in 2016, however, strongly differ with around 25,000 €/ha in Lower Saxony and 15,000 €/ha in Saxony-Anhalt. The percentage increase from 2007 to 2016 is, in general, slightly larger in Saxony-Anhalt. Figure 1 shows that the absolute gap between prices in former East and West Germany rises, so that a tendency of eastern counties to catch up to their western neighbors cannot be observed. The figure also shows that there is only a small overlap of the time series for eastern and western counties and a rather homogenous price development, especially for the eastern counties. These numbers provide a mixed picture. While production structures show similarities across the border, prices seem to evolve differently. In our empirical analysis, we will scrutinize whether the border still influences price development and if there are regional differences between counties in former East and West Germany.

Figure 1: Price development of agricultural land in border counties in Lower Saxony (NI, solid) and Saxony-Anhalt (ST, broken line)

35,000 Lüchow-Dannenberg

Uelzen 30,000 Gifhorn

25,000 Helmstedt /ha) € Wolfenbüttel 20,000 Goslar

Mean NI-Border 15,000

Stendal

10,000

Price of agricultural ( of land Price Altmarkkreis Salzwedel Börde 5,000 Harz

0 Mean ST-Border 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

Source: authors’ presentation based on data from the Statistical Office of Lower Saxony and the Statistical Office of Saxony-Anhalt.

3.2 Data

The empirical analysis is based on a comprehensive dataset of sale transactions of arable land between 1994 and 2015 in Lower Saxony and Saxony-Anhalt provided by Oberer Gutachterausschuss für Grundstückswerte in Niedersachsen and Gutachterausschuss für Grundstückswerte in Sachsen-Anhalt. It includes information on the price, size, soil quality, and location of sold plots. To conduct the analysis, these data have to be converted into a balanced panel.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 11 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

Using transaction data has two advantages compared to county averages provided by statistical offices. First, we can derive quarterly instead of yearly average prices and hence obtain a larger panel. Second, the reform of the counties in Saxony-Anhalt in 2007 led to a fusion and reshaping of counties.3 Through the transaction data, we can create consistent time series for the counties in the pre-reform shape and hence also increase the regional dimension of the panel.

The focus of the study is to evaluate a possible effect of the former German border on land price diffusion. Consequently, to keep the number of regional units at a manageable level, counties in Saxony-Anhalt and Lower Saxony more distant than the 2nd neighbors of border regions are excluded.4 Figure 2 displays the former border and all 37 counties included in the analysis. The twelve border counties, as the name implies, lie directly at the former border (six on each side).

Figure 2: Counties included and excluded as well as the geographic location of value and geographic mean centers; the shape of the counties corresponds to the situation before 2007.

Source: authors’ presentation.

3 The reform of the counties in 2007 had the following consequences for the border region: Bördekreis and merged into Börde; , , , and a small part of Aschersleben-Staßfurt became one county called Harz; and Altmarkkreis Salzwedel and Stendal remained the same. 4 It could be argued that the empirical application should be confined to border regions. This would, however, prevent the analysis of spillover and spatial effects.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 12 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

Land price transaction data cannot simply be aggregated to county level cross-section data since land is a heterogeneous factor (Yang et al. 2017). To homogenize the transaction data, we apply the following hedonic regression to all transactions ( = 1, … , 82 672):

ln = + + quality + size𝑘𝑘 + , (8)

𝑝𝑝𝑘𝑘 𝛿𝛿0𝑖𝑖 𝛿𝛿1𝑖𝑖𝑡𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝛿𝛿2 𝑘𝑘 𝛿𝛿3 𝑘𝑘 𝜂𝜂𝑘𝑘 which accounts for soil quality and the size of the transferred plot. 5 The regression also includes a county-specific constant and time trend to account for county-individual effects that otherwise could bias the estimated effects of size and quality. The hedonic 𝛿𝛿0𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡𝑖𝑖 regression is estimated via OLS. Then, the 5% observations with the largest and smallest residuals are removed and (8) is re-estimated. As expected, soil quality and the size of the transferred land have a positive effect on the price of arable land ( = 0.012, = 0.003). With 𝜂𝜂̂𝑘𝑘 these coefficients at hand, log land prices are adjusted to average soil quality and average 𝛿𝛿̂2 𝛿𝛿̂3 size:

ln = ln quality quality size size (9) ∗ 𝑝𝑝𝑘𝑘 𝑝𝑝𝑘𝑘 − 𝛿𝛿̂2� 𝑘𝑘 − ���������� − 𝛿𝛿̂3� 𝑘𝑘 − ������� where quality and size denote the sample means of soil quality and plot size, respectively. The adjusted transaction prices are then averaged to quarterly county-level data. The resulting ��������� ����� time series are smoothed to eliminate∗ outliers, which can occur due to infrequent transactions 𝑝𝑝𝑘𝑘 for some counties and time periods. A standard exponential moving average of up to four time periods before t are applied.6 The resulting panel dataset with average prices in 37 counties from the first quarter of 1994 to the fourth quarter of 2015 (37 × 88 = 3,256 observations) is used to estimate the price diffusion model. Equation (3) allows the incorporation of common factors that might influence the development of land prices across the study region. We follow Helgers and Buyst (2016) and add the change in real GDP growth for the same time period as a possible explanatory variable for the price development at county-level within the entire study region.

To get a tentative idea of whether there is spatial integration of land markets among the 37 counties, we run unit root tests for log land price pairs ( , , ) including a constant term to allow for relative convergence. Descriptive statistics of the Augmented Dickey-Fuller test 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡 − 𝑝𝑝𝑗𝑗 𝑡𝑡 results at a significance level of 5% are presented in Table 2. The results show that 61.1% of all price pairs are stationary and converge in the long-run, at least in relative terms. However, the share of stationary pairs is higher within states, with about 67% for both Lower Saxony and Saxony-Anhalt. In contrast, market integration across state borders is notably lower with only 54.8%. This finding suggests that the former German border still manifests itself as a barrier to land price diffusion.

5 Soil quality is measured by ‘Ackerzahl’, a German evaluation scheme for the quality of agricultural land based on criteria such as soil type, climate, and topography. It has a value that ranges from one (‘very poor’) to 120 (‘very good’). ( ) 6 = with = . 𝑝𝑝 ( 𝑛𝑛) 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖+∑𝑛𝑛=1 1− α 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−𝑛𝑛 1 𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝑝𝑝 𝑛𝑛 𝑝𝑝 1+∑𝑛𝑛=1 1− α α 𝑝𝑝+1 FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 13 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

Table 2: Augmented Dickey-Fuller test results for counties’ land price pairs ( , , ) including a constant with p-value ≤ 0.05 𝒑𝒑𝒊𝒊 𝒕𝒕 − 𝒑𝒑𝒋𝒋 𝒕𝒕 Stationary Non-stationary Total number % number % All counties 407 61.1 259 38.9 666 Saxony-Anhalt 71 67.6 34 32.4 105 Lower Saxony 155 67.1 76 32.9 231 Within states 226 67.3 110 32.7 336 Across the border 181 54.8 149 45.2 330 Source: Authors’ calculations.

4 Empirical application

4.1 Model specification

To model the spatial relationship between the counties and to estimate the pairwise VECM, a spatial weighting matrix representing spatial dependencies has to be chosen a priori. Although its specification is arbitrary, it is influential for the results of the price diffusion model (Meen, 1996). Hence, we apply several widely used weighting matrices in our empirical application. Most spatial weight matrices rely either on neighborhood expressed in binary terms, namely, = 1 for a (direct) bordering county and zero otherwise, or in the distance measured from a selected point which is frequently the main market in the county. Since it is usually assumed 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 that spatial market integration increases with proximity, inverse distance weighting is = alternatively used to measure the connectivity of counties: distance between and . More 1 𝑛𝑛 specifically, we consider four different candidates of spatial𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 weight� matrices.𝑖𝑖 Two𝑗𝑗 � inverse distance matrices with = 1 and = 2, respectively, a simple binary neighborhood matrix (‘binary’), and a so-called ‘binary/distance2’ matrix, which is the product of the ‘binary’ and 𝑛𝑛 𝑛𝑛 ‘1/distance2’ matrix. The latter matrix extends on the simple binary relationship, but limits the influence to first neighbors. Distance is measured between value mean centres of the land transactions for Saxony-Anhalt where geographic coordinates for all transactions are available. For Lower Saxony, where no coordinates are available, the geographic mean of a county is used as its centre.

To select the weight matrix among the four candidates, we apply Moran’s , which is a measure of spatial autocorrelation. The higher Moran’s is, the higher spatial autocorrelation is within 𝐼𝐼 the data. Figure 3 displays the results of Moran’s for all four spatial weight matrices over the 𝐼𝐼 observation period. Apparently, the inverse distance and distance decay matrices show lower 𝐼𝐼 Moran’s values than the binary based ones, which almost coincide for all time periods. While the pure binary matrix achieves the highest values for all time intervals until about 2010, the 𝐼𝐼 mixed binary-distance matrix slightly surpasses the binary’s value afterwards. We proceed with both binary configurations of the spatial weight matrix and compare their results.7 Note that Moran’s values are rather stable over time irrespective of the spatial weight matrix. This is a

𝐼𝐼 7 The specification of the spatial weight matrix also affects the number of parameters to be estimated in the price diffusion model. Binary matrices restrict , , and , to equations of border 𝑜𝑜𝑜𝑜𝑜𝑜 counties, whereas a distance based matrix does not make this restriction and results in N , and 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑖𝑖 2 𝑡𝑡−1 ∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡−𝑝𝑝 × , parameter estimates. 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 2 𝑖𝑖 3 𝑁𝑁 𝑞𝑞 𝛾𝛾 FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 14 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany first indication that the underlying price diffusion process does not exhibit drastic changes during the sample period.

Figure 3: Moran's I

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Apart from the choice of a spatial weight matrix, restrictions set in the long-run relationship (2) will also affect the estimation results. Therefore, two model variations are estimated considering the cases of convergence ( = 1) and non-convergence ( 1). Moreover, we compare models with and without inclusion of common factors. Finally, we estimate model 𝛽𝛽1𝑖𝑖 𝛽𝛽1𝑖𝑖 ≠ variants with a border effect (3) and without a border effect (1) to address our main research question. This differentiation leads to 2 2 2 2 = 16 model specifications. To choose the model that best represents the data generating process among these specifications, Akaike ∗ ∗ ∗ Information Criterion (AIC) values were calculated. Table 3 reports the AIC and weighted AIC ( AIC) values for each of the 16 specifications.8 All models were estimated with seemingly Δ unrelated regression (SUR), since the Breusch-Pagan Lagrange test rejected the null 𝜔𝜔 hypothesis of no correlation between the error terms. While AIC ranks the model specifications, AIC states the probability of a specification being the best model for the data Δ relative to alternative specifications (Burnham and Anderson, 2004). 𝜔𝜔 At first glance, models that separate neighborhood prices into two groups (within states and across states) are preferable according to the model selection criteria. This is a further indication that the former border still influences the diffusion of land prices in Germany. The two top ranked models together have a 99.85% probability of being the best model among the candidates. These two specifications both restrict the cointegration parameter to equal unity

8 AIC and AIC are defined as AIC = AIC min AIC for the th model specification and

AIC = exp( AIC /2)/ exp( AIC /2𝑖𝑖 ). 𝑖𝑖 𝑖𝑖 𝛥𝛥 𝜔𝜔 ∆ − 𝑖𝑖 𝑖𝑖 𝑘𝑘 ω 𝑖𝑖 − 𝑖𝑖 ∑𝑖𝑖=1FORLand− -Working𝑖𝑖 Paper 03 (2018) - 15 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany and assume convergence in logarithmic prices, incorporate a common factor, and separate neighboring prices into two groups representing the border effect. While AIC allows to distinguish between convergence and non-convergence in long-run price relationships, it 𝛥𝛥 cannot separate relative and absolute convergence. However, regression results for the individual error correction terms (Eq. (3)) reveal that the constant is statistically different from zero at the 5% significance level in 46 out of 49 cases, implying that relative convergence 𝛽𝛽0𝑖𝑖 prevails in the study region.

Table 3: AIC results for different model specifications

Spatial weight Border Common matrix effect factor Convergence AIC AIC binary/distance2 yes yes yes 0.00 57.01% binary yes yes yes 𝚫𝚫0.57 42.84%𝝎𝝎 binary yes yes no 11.88 0.15% binary/distance2 yes yes no 20.52 0.00% binary no yes no 37.75 0.00% binary/distance2 yes no yes 38.55 0.00% binary/distance2 no yes no 46.03 0.00% binary/distance2 yes no no 50.74 0.00% binary yes no yes 51.55 0.00% binary/distance2 no no no 67.86 0.00% binary yes no no 73.29 0.00% binary no no no 73.42 0.00% binary/distance2 no yes yes 117.37 0.00% binary no yes yes 122.51 0.00% binary/distance2 no no yes 159.90 0.00% binary no no yes 171.15 0.00% Source: Authors’ calculations.

As in the case of the Moran’s analysis, the analysis of AIC is not fully conclusive with respect to the specification of the spatial weight matrix, even though the model with a binary distance 𝐼𝐼 𝜔𝜔 matrix is 1.33 times more probable to be the suitable specification. Hence, in what follows we focus on reporting the results of the binary distance matrix, but the estimation results for the binary weight matrix is presented in the Appendix to document the robustness of the model (Table A1).

4.2 Estimation results

Table 4 reports the shares of significant parameters for the price diffusion equations for the SUR estimation results. In line with the previous unit root tests, we observe a large share of 𝑁𝑁 significant adjustment coefficients pointing at a long-run equilibrium of land prices with their neighbor counties’ prices: 31 regional land prices are cointegrated with the neighbors’ average price, either within state, across the former border, or both. The average speed of adjustment for all is rather slow ( 0.23) , but is comparable to studies in the real estate market (e.g., Helgers and Buyst, 2016; Holly et al., 2011). Regarding our main research question, the − asymmetry of significant adjustment coefficients is noteworthy. The share of significant adjustment coefficients of counties on the same side of the former border, , , varies between 65% and 78%, depending on the model specification and estimation procedure, while the share 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 1

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 16 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany of their counterparts across the border, , , is considerably lower (17% – 42%). This is yet another clue for the existence of a border effect. 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 2 Table 4: Share of significant parameters for the N price diffusion equations (p-value smaller or equal to 0.05)

, , , , ,

2 SUR binary/distance 75.7%𝝓𝝓𝒊𝒊 𝟏𝟏 33.3%𝝓𝝓𝒊𝒊 𝟐𝟐 64.9%𝜸𝜸𝒊𝒊 𝟏𝟏 48.2%𝜸𝜸𝒊𝒊 𝟐𝟐 26.7%𝜸𝜸𝒊𝒊 𝟑𝟑 62.2%𝝀𝝀𝒊𝒊 SUR binary 78.4% 41.6% 70.3% 28.0% 26.7% 51.4% Source: Authors’ calculations.

Details of the SUR-estimation results of the price diffusion equations (3) for 12 border counties as well as the average results for the remaining counties’ equations of each state are reported in Table 5. Apart from the estimates of the adjustment speeds , the effect of short-run deviations in the price time series , the effect of the common factor , and the number of time 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 same opp lags based on the suggestions of the Schwarz criterion , , and for , , , , and , , 𝛾𝛾𝑖𝑖 𝜆𝜆 respectively, are depicted. In case of higher order lags, the table reports the parameter of the 𝑘𝑘 𝑚𝑚 𝑞𝑞 ∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑡 ∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡 ∆𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖̅ 𝑡𝑡 first lagged variable only.

Inspection of Table 5 reveals regional differences in land price diffusion. In most cases (8 out of 12), , is larger (in absolute terms) than its counterpart , , i.e., border counties’ prices adjust faster to a long-run equilibrium with neighbors in the same state compared to neighbors 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 1 𝜙𝜙𝑖𝑖 2 across the former border. Moreover, non-border counties show a higher level of land market integration than border counties in terms of their adjustment speed parameters. A possible explanation is that former border counties were located in the periphery of West and East Germany. This remoteness led to a decoupling from the economic development of the rest of the country (Lehn and Bahrs, 2018; Redding and Sturm, 2008).

Short-run dynamics from the regional price diffusion equations are captured by lagged variables based on differences in the own price and neighbors’ average price within the state and across the former border. The coefficient of the changes in the lagged own price is significant in almost all border county equations (10 out of 12) and has a negative sign. The spatial pattern of short-run dynamics is more heterogeneous compared to long-run estimates, but differences between the two groups of neighbors exist. The parameter estimates for changes in the lagged land price for within state neighbors , are of a greater magnitude (0.12), on average, for the former border counties compared to the parameters , for across 𝛾𝛾𝑖𝑖 2 border lagged land price differences (0.04). The overall effect of these rather heterogeneous 𝛾𝛾𝑖𝑖 3 parameters is captured by the GIRFs, which are presented below.

Shocks in (real) GDP growth are included in the model as a common factor for all regional price equations. The corresponding parameters are statistically significant for more than 50% of the estimated equations. However, sign and size of estimates vary considerably among 𝜆𝜆 counties. A similar finding is reported by Helgers and Buyst (2016). 𝜆𝜆

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 17 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

Table 5: Estimation results of border counties’ price diffusion equations (3) with a binary/distance2 spatial matrix (standard errors in brackets)

, p-value , p-value , p-value , p-value , p-value p-value / / , , ,

Saxony Anhalt 𝒊𝒊 𝟐𝟐 𝝓𝝓𝒊𝒊 𝟏𝟏 𝝓𝝓𝒊𝒊 𝟐𝟐 𝜸𝜸𝒊𝒊 𝟏𝟏 𝜸𝜸𝒊𝒊 𝟐𝟐 𝜸𝜸𝒊𝒊 𝟑𝟑 𝝀𝝀 𝒌𝒌 𝒎𝒎 𝒒𝒒 𝝓𝝓𝒊𝒊 𝟏𝟏 ≤ 𝝓𝝓𝒊𝒊 𝟐𝟐 𝟎𝟎 ≤ 𝝓𝝓 Bördekreis -0.22 0.01 -0.01 0.77 -0.27 <0.01 0.26 0.05 0.03 0.54 0.26 0.01 1/4/1 -2.24 -0.31 (-0.08) (-0.04) (-0.09) (-0.14) (-0.05) (-0.09) Halberstadt -0.45 <0.01 0.15 <0.01 -0.28 <0.01 -0.02 0.87 0.02 0.84 0.32 0.04 1/1/1 -5.47 2.90 (-0.10) (-0.05) (-0.09) (-0.12) (-0.11) (-0.16) Ohrekreis -0.52 <0.01 0.00 0.95 -0.43 <0.01 0.30 0.08 -0.26 0.01 -0.43 <0.01 1/4/1 -4.20 -0.06 (-0.10) (-0.07) (-0.10) (-0.17) (-0.09) (-0.14) Stendal -0.05 0.22 -0.04 0.21 -0.06 0.39 0.18 0.04 0.09 <0.01 0.06 0.34 1/1/1 -0.26 -1.25 (-0.04) (-0.03) (-0.07) (-0.09) (-0.03) (-0.07) Wernigerode -0.13 0.10 0.00 0.95 -0.30 <0.01 0.50 <0.01 0.02 0.72 -0.08 0.57 1/1/1 -1.57 0.07 (-0.08) (-0.03) (-0.10) (-0.11) (-0.04) (-0.14) Altmarkreis-Salzwedel 0.07 0.08 -0.50 <0.01 -0.25 <0.01 0.08 0.46 0.27 <0.01 -0.47 <0.01 1/1/1 7.22 -7.39 (-0.04) (-0.07) (-0.08) (-0.11) (-0.07) (-0.10) Rest of Saxony-Anhalt -0.31 -0.28 0.13 0.01 Lower Saxony Gifhorn -0.10 0.29 -0.15 0.13 -0.21 0.02 0.55 <0.01 -0.19 0.19 0.58 <0.01 1/1/1 0.44 -1.53 (-0.09) (-0.10) (-0.09) (-0.16) (-0.15) (-0.13) Goslar -0.47 <0.01 0.15 0.22 -0.24 0.02 0.77 0.04 -0.22 0.41 0.03 0.93 1/1/1 -3.32 1.24 (-0.14) (-0.12) (-0.10) (-0.39) (-0.27) (-0.29) Helmstedt -0.09 0.29 -0.37 <0.01 -0.21 0.04 -0.06 0.69 -0.01 0.98 -0.64 <0.01 1/1/4 1.96 -3.27 (-0.09) (-0.11) (-0.10) (-0.14) (-0.18) (-0.20) Wolfenbüttel -0.04 0.46 -0.09 0.04 0.02 0.81 -0.11 0.21 -0.03 0.75 -0.27 0.07 1/1/1 0.57 -2.10 (-0.06) (-0.04) (-0.09) (-0.09) (-0.08) (-0.15) Lüchow-Dannenberg -0.23 0.03 -0.22 0.10 -0.41 <0.01 0.08 0.47 0.36 0.10 0.58 <0.01 1/1/1 -0.02 -1.62 (-0.10) (-0.14) (-0.09) (-0.11) (-0.22) (-0.17) Uelzen -0.22 0.02 -0.18 0.06 -0.45 <0.01 0.15 0.22 0.35 0.01 0.01 0.94 1/1/1 -0.33 -1.91 (-0.10) (-0.09) (-0.09) (-0.12) (-0.13) (-0.17) Rest of Lower Saxony -0.29 -0.14 0.23 0.02 Source: Authors’ calculation. Note: The critical value for hypothesis testing for alpha = 0.05 is -1.64.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 18 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

To examine the presence of a border effect more explicitly, we empirically test the two hypotheses from Section 2. This test procedure leads to the following classification: counties with a border effect (reject hypothesis 1 and fail to reject hypothesis 2), counties with no border effect (fail to reject hypothesis 1 and reject hypothesis 2), and counties that cannot be assigned to one of the former groups (fail to reject both hypothesis). The spatial distribution of these categories is displayed in Figure 4.

Figure 4: County groups based on SUR estimation results and hypotheses testing

Source: Authors’ presentation.

Land prices of the ‘border effect’ group do not converge in the long-run with land prices from neighboring counties’ that are across the former border or they converge more slowly compared to within state neighbors. This group is comprised of Bördekreis, Goslar, Halberstadt, and Ohrekreis. Most counties are located in Saxony-Anhalt and form a regional cluster at the southern intersection of both states (with the exception of Wernigerode). This finding may be traced to high levels of joint ownership and the relative low share of BVVG administrated transactions in these counties, which, in turn, may lead to larger information asymmetries and higher transaction costs for West German buyers (see Table 1).

The hypothesis of a border effect can be rejected for four counties. In the northern parts of the two states, these are the counties of Uelzen and Altmarkkreis-Salzwedel. One reason could be similar production structures in the form of a potato cluster and intensive livestock production (see Table 1). The remaining two counties of the ‘no border effect’ group, Helmstedt and Wolfenbüttel, are located to the West of counties that belong to the ‘border effect’ group.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 19 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

The SUR estimation results (see Table 5) also reveal that these two counties interact across the border, but not within the state. A possible explanation is that the two largest in the Eastern part of Lower Saxony, and , make up most of the border in terms of within state neighbors of Helmstedt and Wolfenbüttel. This could form a barrier that hinders land price interaction with the rest of Lower Saxony. On the other hand, both counties contain large wheat production areas, similar to counties across the former border, what might explain a long-run adaptation to land prices across the former border.

For the last group of counties (Gifhorn, Lüchow-Dannenberg, Stendal, and Wernigerode), neither hypothesis can be rejected. In the case of the counties Stendal and Wernigerode, the situation is even more complex. Neither county has an adjustment speed parameter with a p- value equal or less than 0.05, indicating that their land prices do not adjust to any neighbors’ price in the long-run. Because both counties are located at a border with other German federal states, these neighboring markets might be of greater importance to their prices’ development than any other neighbor considered in this analysis.

Variations of the estimation procedure and the weighting matrix document the robustness of our results. The SUR results for both spatial weight matrices are very close in terms of magnitude, p-value, and resulting hypotheses test results. However, slight differences exist. The largest change in estimates is observed in Gifhorn county. In the first specification, according to the two hypotheses tests, the county enters the group of ‘undecided’ counties, but the model with simple binary spatial weight matrices leads to hypothesis 2 being rejected and the conclusion that ‘no border effect’ influences Gifhorn’s land market price development. Uelzen, on the other side, fails to reject hypothesis 2 with the second binary spatial weight matrix configuration applied, thus moving from the category that clearly rejects the border effect to the category ‘undecided’. Furthermore, Wernigerode now rejects the hypothesis of no border effect and consequently joins the ‘border effect’ group, painting a more clear and continuous boundary for the former East German counties from Wernigerode in the southern part of Saxony-Anhalt to Ohrekreis in the northern part.

Finally, we depict GIRFs to visualize the spatio-temporal effect of a price shock in the study region. Figure 5 displays four scenarios. The horizon was set to 40 (quarters), thus the GIRFs display the reaction of a standardized shock (one standard deviation) in county across 𝐻𝐻 the study region over ten years. The origin of the price shock in county shows a value of unity 𝑖𝑖 at = 1. The shock then triggers reactions of varying magnitude in the land price of the other 𝑖𝑖 counties. The other counties are ordered by distance from the shock county, namely, to 𝑡𝑡 (with a negative value) are counties in Lower Saxony (the Western state) and to the right (with a positive value) are counties in Saxony-Anhalt (the Eastern state).

The first graph in the top left of Figure 5 shows the IRFs based on a shock in Halberstadt, whose land market is affected by the former border according to our previous classification. The spatio-temporal model revealed that Halberstadt’s land price converges in the long-run with within state neighbors and diverges in the long-run with across border neighbors. Hence, we see that a shock to Halberstadt causes a permanent positive increase in prices for most of its neighboring counties in Saxony-Anhalt.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 20 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

The graph in the top right of Figure 5 displays the case of Altmarkkreis-Salzwedel, which is an example from the group without a border effect. A shock to the county’s land price leads to a strong reaction and permanent price increases within the same state and across the former border.

Figure 5: GIRFs for selected border counties with normalized shocks of one standard deviation

𝝈𝝈

Source: Authors’ calculations.

The graph at the bottom left of Figure 5 shows the case of Lüchow-Dannenberg, which is a county that is ambiguous with regard to a border effect. A shock to the county’s land market results in moderate reactions in all other counties. Interestingly, the IRFs indicate the border’s presence. Land prices in Saxony-Anhalt, which show reactions to the shock, quickly return to their pre-shock level. In contrast, land prices in Lower Saxony, even though their amplitude is rather low, take a much longer time to return to their pre-shock level or even remain at a slightly increased level for the entire time horizon, such as the as the price in Lüchow-Dannenberg.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 21 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

The bottom right of Figure 5 shows the case of Göttingen county, which is not directly located at the former border. The IRF of Göttingen shows that even though a border effect is not included in its spatio-temporal equation (3) due to the binary nature of the spatial weight matrices, a price shock in Göttingen indirectly influences prices on the other side of the border via neighbors’ neighbors and via the correlated error term. Nevertheless, there are clear differences in the reaction between within state and across the border counties to a one standard deviation shock to its land market price. While counties within Lower Saxony react strongly and are permanently affected, counties in Saxony-Anhalt display almost no change or only brief deviations.

The GIRFs confirm the results of the price diffusion model with a border effect (3). The former German border still affects land price diffusion in Germany, not just in counties’ land markets located directly at the former border. While most counties in the southern part of the study region are only integrated with within state land markets, a number of counties, particularly those in the northern study region with similar production structures, converge with across neighbors’ prices in the long-run and are sometimes separated from their own states’ overall land price diffusion process.

5 Conclusions

This article examines whether there is a diffusion of agricultural land prices across the former border separating East and West Germany. The research question was motivated by concerns among policymakers in several EU countries that in unregulated land markets, the activities of foreign investors may cause high prices to spill over into neighboring countries that initially have lower land price levels. On the other hand, the European Commission recently appealed to EU Member States to adjust their land market regulations according to European Law, which requires the free movement of capital within the EU (European Commission, 2016). To shed some light on this controversial discussion, we consider the German reunification as a case study on land price development in two different states after the border was removed. We apply a land price diffusion model with an error correction specification that estimates to what extent agricultural land markets are spatially integrated. A novel feature of our model is its ability to distinguish price diffusion within states and across state borders. We find that local agricultural land markets in Germany are spatially integrated, i.e., prices in one county are linked with prices in neighboring counties by a long-run equilibrium relationship. Spatial market integration, however, does not hold among all counties in our study area. In line with earlier studies, there is evidence for convergence clubs, which differ in their land price dynamics.

With regard to our main research question, we find evidence for a persistent border effect given that the fraction of spatially integrated counties is larger within states than across the former border. Moreover, for many counties along the former border, we observe non-significant error correction terms for prices of neighboring counties across the former border. It is noteworthy that the former border does not act as a strict barrier for price alignment between former East and West Germany. In fact, it is permeable at several locations. In some cases, it even happens that counties share similar land price dynamics with neighbors across the border, but not with neighbors within the same state. By virtue of its reduced form character, our model cannot provide a clear answer on what is behind this border effect and why it appears to be local. We conjecture that differences in farm size structures, long-lasting rental contracts, local market

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 22 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany power, non-transparency of sellable land plots and information asymmetries regarding the property status of land may explain non-convergence and stickiness of land prices in parts of East and West Germany. Providing empirical evidence for the role of these economic factors is a promising direction for further research.

Our results are not only interesting from a historical perspective, but they are also relevant for a better understanding of the functioning of agricultural markets. From a policy perspective, it is striking to realize that even 25 years after German reunification, pronounced land price differences persist. Even if regional land markets across the former border are integrated, land prices converge rather slowly and only in relative terms, i.e., land prices do not reach the same level. It is quite likely that price diffusion through existing borders within the EU would take even more time given language barriers, different administrative procedures for land acquisitions, different tax systems, and more pronounced information asymmetries between domestic and foreign market participants. Therefore, proposals for stricter land market regulations aiming at the protection of local farmers and capping of land prices through the discrimination of foreign buyers appear questionable.

6 References Abbott, A., and de Vita, G. ‘Testing for Long-Run Convergence across Regional House Prices in the UK: A Pairwise Approach’. Applied Economics, Vol. 45 (10), (2013) pp. 1227-38. BMWI. Jahresbericht der Bundesregierung zum Stand der Deutschen Einheit 2017, August 2017 (2017). https://www.bmwi.de/Redaktion/DE/Publikationen/Neue- Laender/jahresbericht-zum-stand-der-deutschen-einheit-2017.html (last accessed 20 June 2018). Bund-Länder-Arbeitsgruppe „Bodenmarktpolitik“. Landwirtschaftliche Bodenmarktpolitik: Allgemeine Situation und Handlungsoptionen. Abschlussbericht (2015). Burnham, K. P., and Anderson, D. R. ‘Multimodel inference: Understanding AIC and BIC in Model Selection’. Sociological Methods & Research, Vol. 33, (2004) pp. 261-304. Carmona, J., and Roses, J.R. ‘Land markets and agrarian backwardness’. European Review of Economic History, Vol. 16 (1), (2012) pp. 74-96. European Commission. ‘Agricultural Land Prices and Rents data for the ’ (2016). http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/agriculture/methodology (last accessed 20 June 2018). Government Office for Science. Foresight Land Use Futures Project, Final Project Report, (, 2010). https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/288843/1 0-631-land-use-futures.pdf (last accessed 20 June 2018). Helgers, R., and Buyst, E. ‘Spatial and Temporal Diffusion of Housing Prices in the Presence of a Linguistic Border: Evidence from Belgium’. Spatial Economic Analysis, Vol. 11 (1), (2016) pp. 92-122. Hiebert, P., and Roma, M. ‘Relative House Price Dynamics Across Euro Area and US Cities: Convergence or Divergence?’. ECB Working Paper No. 1206 (2010). Jochimsen, H. ‘20 Jahre Grüner Aufbau Ost‘. Berichte über Landwirtschaft, Vol. 88 (2), (2010) pp. 203-246. Holly, S., Pesaran, M.H., and Yamagata, T. ‘The spatial and temporal diffusion of house prices in the UK’. Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 69, (2011) pp. 2-23.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 23 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

Kay, S., Peuch, J., and Franco, J. Extent of Farmland Grabbing in the EU. Study on behalf of the European Parliament’s Committee on Agriculture and Development, PE 540.369 (Brussels, 2015). Koester, U. ‘Market Integration: How it Works’. In: Burrell, A., and Oskam, A. (eds.). Agricultural Policy and Enlargement of the European Union (Wageningen University Press, the , 2010), pp. 21-34. Lazíková, J., and Bandlerová, A. ‘New Rules for Acquisition of Agricultural Land – Case of Slovakia’. EU Agrarian Law, Vol. 4 (1), (2015), pp. 18-27. Lehn, F., and Bahrs, E. ‘Analysis of factors influencing standard farmland values with regard to stronger interventions in the German farmland market’. Land Use Policy, Vol. 73, (2018) pp. 138-146. Meen, G. ‘Spatial aggregation, spatial dependence and predictability in the UK housing market’. Housing Studies, Vol. 11 (3), (1996) pp. 345-372. Pesaran, H.H., and Shin, Y. ‘Generalized impulse response analysis in linear multivariate models’. Economic Letters, Vol. 58 (1), (1998) pp. 17-29. Redding, S.J., and Sturm, D.M. ‘The Costs of Remoteness: Evidence from German Division and Reunification’. American Economic Review, Vol. 98 (5), (2008) pp. 1766-1797. Swinnen, J., van Herck, K., and Vranken, L. ‘The Diversity of Land Market Regulations in Europe, and (some of) its Causes’. Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 52 (2), (2016) pp. 186-205. Waights, S. ‘Does the law of one price hold for hedonic prices’. Urban Studies, (2018). https://doi.org/10.1177/0042098017749403 (last accessed 20 June 2018). Yang, X., Odening, M., and Ritter, M. The Spatial and Temporal Diffusion of Agricultural Land Prices, FORLand-Working Paper 01 (Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin, 2018). http://dx.doi.org/10.18452/18720. Yang, X., Ritter, M., and Odening, M. ‘Testing for Regional Convergence of Agricultural Land Prices’. Land Use Policy, Vol. 64, (2017) pp. 64-75.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 24 - Aaron Grau; Martin Odening; Matthias Ritter Land price diffusion across borders: The case of Germany

7 Appendix

Table A1: Estimation results of border counties’ price diffusion equations (3) with a binary spatial matrix (standard errors in brackets)

, p-value , p-value , p-value , p-value , p-value p-value / / , , , Saxony-Anhalt 𝒊𝒊 𝟏𝟏 𝒊𝒊 𝟐𝟐 𝒊𝒊 𝟏𝟏 𝒊𝒊 𝟐𝟐 𝒊𝒊 𝟑𝟑 𝒊𝒊 𝟏𝟏 𝒊𝒊 𝟐𝟐 𝒊𝒊 𝟐𝟐 Bördekreis -𝝓𝝓0.23 <0.01 -𝝓𝝓0.01 0.78 -𝜸𝜸0.28 <0.01 0.29𝜸𝜸 0.03 0.04𝜸𝜸 0.41 0.26𝝀𝝀 <0.01 𝒌𝒌1/4/1𝒎𝒎 𝒒𝒒 𝝓𝝓 -2.49≤ 𝝓𝝓 𝟎𝟎 -≤0.29𝝓𝝓 (-0.08) (-0.04) (-0.09) (-0.13) (-0.05) (-0.09) Halberstadt -0.54 <0.01 0.22 <0.01 -0.31 <0.01 -0.04 0.82 0.06 0.57 0.16 0.27 1/1/1 -5.63 3.60 (-0.12) (-0.06) (-0.09) (-0.18) (-0.10) (-0.15) Ohrekreis -0.46 <0.01 0.00 1.00 -0.39 <0.01 0.33 0.14 -0.23 0.05 -0.23 0.07 1/4/1 -2.56 0.00 (-0.14) (-0.12) (-0.09) (-0.22) (-0.12) (-0.13) Stendal -0.07 0.11 -0.03 0.34 -0.05 0.50 0.16 0.07 0.08 0.01 0.08 0.22 1/1/1 -0.77 -0.96 (-0.04) (-0.03) (-0.07) (-0.09) (-0.03) (-0.07) Wernigerode -0.27 <0.01 0.02 0.41 -0.29 <0.01 0.53 <0.01 0.02 0.59 -0.11 0.39 1/1/1 -3.52 0.83 (-0.08) (-0.03) (-0.09) (-0.13) (-0.04) (-0.12) Altmarkreis-Salzwedel 0.13 <0.01 -0.62 <0.01 -0.31 <0.01 0.05 0.63 0.33 <0.01 -0.53 <0.01 1/1/1 9.08 -8.89 (-0.04) (-0.07) (-0.07) (-0.10) (-0.07) (-0.10) Rest of Saxony-Anhalt -0.33 -0.29 0.14 0.00 Lower Saxony Gifhorn -0.03 0.79 -0.27 0.02 -0.21 0.01 0.47 <0.01 -0.05 0.74 0.59 <0.01 1/1/1 1.64 -2.42 (-0.10) (-0.11) (-0.09) (-0.16) (-0.15) (-0.13) Goslar -0.53 <0.01 0.16 0.18 -0.22 0.03 0.63 0.16 -0.38 0.16 0.13 0.68 1/1/1 -3.47 1.33 (-0.16) (-0.12) (-0.10) (-0.45) (-0.27) (-0.31) Helmstedt -0.11 0.30 -0.32 0.01 -0.20 0.05 0.01 0.97 -0.01 0.95 -0.63 <0.01 1/1/4 1.35 -2.59 (-0.10) (-0.13) (-0.10) (-0.14) (-0.18) (-0.19) Wolfenbüttel -0.08 0.20 -0.08 0.03 0.01 0.87 -0.10 0.29 -0.04 0.59 -0.26 0.07 1/1/1 0.10 -2.20 (-0.06) (-0.04) (-0.08) (-0.09) (-0.08) (-0.14) Lüchow-Dannenberg -0.27 0.01 -0.12 0.34 -0.35 <0.01 0.16 0.11 0.42 0.09 0.40 <0.01 1/1/1 -0.92 -0.97 (-0.10) (-0.13) (-0.09) (-0.10) (-0.25) (-0.14) Uelzen -0.21 0.05 -0.14 0.18 -0.37 <0.01 0.01 0.96 0.31 0.02 0.00 0.99 1/1/1 -0.52 -1.33 (-0.11) (-0.10) (-0.09) (-0.17) (-0.13) (-0.19) Rest of Lower Saxony -0.27 -0.12 0.28 0.05 Source: Authors’ calculation. Note: The critical value for hypothesis testing for alpha = 0.05 is -1.64.

FORLand-Working Paper 03 (2018) - 25 -