Cartels & Leniency 2019

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Cartels & Leniency 2019 ICLG The International Comparative Legal Guide to: Cartels & Leniency 2019 12th Edition A practical cross-border insight into cartels and leniency Published by Global Legal Group, with contributions from: AGON PARTNERS King & Wood Mallesons AKD Mamo TCV Advocates Aramis MinterEllisonRuddWatts Arnold & Porter Kaye Scholer LLP ML Abogados Bán, S. Szabó & Partners Morais Leitão, Galvão Teles, Soares da Silva & Borenius Attorneys Ltd Associados, R. L. Cassels Brock & Blackwell LLP Nagashima Ohno & Tsunematsu Crowell & Moring Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP Cyril Amarchand Mangaldas Preslmayr Rechtsanwälte OG Debarliev Dameski & Kelesoska, Attorneys at Law Rahmat Lim & Partners Drew & Napier LLC Shearman & Sterling LLP ELIG Gürkaynak Attorneys-at-Law Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom LLP Hannes Snellman Wilmer Cutler Pickering Hale and Dorr LLP The International Comparative Legal Guide to: Cartels & Leniency 2019 General Chapters: 1 Cartel Updates: Recent Trends in Fine Calculations and Cartel Liability – Elvira Aliende Rodriguez & Geert Goeteyn, Shearman & Sterling LLP 1 2 The Proposed Whistleblowers Directive – Ingrid Vandenborre & Thorsten Goetz, Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom LLP 6 Contributing Editors 3 Navigating the Tensions Between Leniency Cooperation and the Risk of Private Follow-On Geert Goeteyn, Matthew Damage Claims in Cartel Cases – Niels Ersbøll & Jane Wessel, Arnold & Porter Kaye Scholer LLP 12 Readings & Elvira Aliende Rodriguez, Shearman & 4 Disincentives to Leniency: Expect Fewer Golden Eggs if You Harass the Goose – Frédéric Louis, Sterling LLP Wilmer Cutler Pickering Hale and Dorr LLP 18 Sales Director Florjan Osmani Country Question and Answer Chapters: Account Director 5 Australia King & Wood Mallesons: Sharon Henrick & Wayne Leach 23 Oliver Smith Sales Support Manager 6 Austria Preslmayr Rechtsanwälte OG: Dieter Hauck 33 Toni Hayward 7 Belgium Crowell & Moring: Thomas De Meese 40 Sub Editor Oliver Chang 8 Canada Cassels Brock & Blackwell LLP: W. Michael G. Osborne & Chris Hersh 46 Senior Editors Suzie Levy 9 China King & Wood Mallesons: Susan Ning & Kate Peng 53 Caroline Collingwood 10 Ecuador ML Abogados: María Teresa Lara & Ricardo Montalvo 62 CEO Dror Levy 11 European Union Shearman & Sterling LLP: Elvira Aliende Rodriguez & Geert Goeteyn 70 Group Consulting Editor 12 Finland Borenius Attorneys Ltd: Ilkka Aalto-Setälä & Henrik Koivuniemi 80 Alan Falach Publisher 13 France Aramis: Aurélien Condomines & Pierre Galmiche 87 Rory Smith 14 Germany Shearman & Sterling LLP: Mathias Stöcker 94 Published by Global Legal Group Ltd. 15 Hungary Bán, S. Szabó & Partners: Chrysta Bán & Álmos Papp 102 59 Tanner Street London SE1 3PL, UK 16 India Cyril Amarchand Mangaldas: Avaantika Kakkar & Bharat Budholia 109 Tel: +44 20 7367 0720 Fax: +44 20 7407 5255 17 Italy Shearman & Sterling LLP: Paolisa Nebbia 116 Email: [email protected] URL: www.glgroup.co.uk 18 Japan Nagashima Ohno & Tsunematsu: Yusuke Kaeriyama & Takayuki Nakata 123 GLG Cover Design 19 Macedonia Debarliev Dameski & Kelesoska, Attorneys at Law: Dragan Dameski & F&F Studio Design Jasmina Ilieva Jovanovik 128 GLG Cover Image Source iStockphoto 20 Malaysia Rahmat Lim & Partners: Raymond Yong & Penny Wong 136 Printed by 21 Malta Mamo TCV Advocates: Annalies Muscat & Laura Spiteri 142 Ashford Colour Press Ltd October 2018 22 Netherlands AKD: Joost Houdijk & Robbert Jaspers 150 Copyright © 2018 23 New Zealand MinterEllisonRuddWatts: Jennifer Hambleton & Alisaundre van Ammers 157 Global Legal Group Ltd. All rights reserved 24 Portugal Morais Leitão, Galvão Teles, Soares da Silva & Associados, R. L.: No photocopying Luís do Nascimento Ferreira & Inês Gouveia 164 ISBN 978-1-912509-39-3 ISSN 1756-1027 25 Singapore Drew & Napier LLC: Chong Kin Lim & Dr. Corinne Chew 176 Strategic Partners 26 Spain King & Wood Mallesons: Ramón García-Gallardo 183 27 Sweden Hannes Snellman: Peter Forsberg & Haris Catovic 199 28 Switzerland AGON PARTNERS: Patrick L. Krauskopf & Fabio Babey 206 29 Turkey ELIG Gürkaynak Attorneys-at-Law: Gönenç Gürkaynak & Öznur İnanılır 212 30 United Kingdom Shearman & Sterling LLP: Matthew Readings & Ruba Noorali 221 31 USA Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP: Charles F. (Rick) Rule & Joseph J. Bial 229 Further copies of this book and others in the series can be ordered from the publisher. Please call +44 20 7367 0720 Disclaimer This publication is for general information purposes only. It does not purport to provide comprehensive full legal or other advice. Global Legal Group Ltd. and the contributors accept no responsibility for losses that may arise from reliance upon information contained in this publication. This publication is intended to give an indication of legal issues upon which you may need advice. Full legal advice should be taken from a qualified professional when dealing with specific situations. WWW.ICLG.COM Chapter 31 USA Charles F. (Rick) Rule Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP Joseph J. Bial found certain types of agreements to be illegal per se because 1 The Legislative Framework of the Cartel of the harmful effect these arrangements have on competition. Prohibition These agreements include, but are not limited to, price fixing, bid-rigging, and market division. The government has recently shown a willingness to criminalise conduct that 1.1 What is the legal basis and general nature of the previously was pursued civilly. For example, the government cartel prohibition, e.g. is it civil and/or criminal? has stated that it intends to pursue “no-poach” agreements criminally, although it is unclear if the government’s public Corporations and individuals may face both civil and criminal statements adequately put companies and their employees penalties under the United States federal antitrust laws, which on notice of the change. If an agreement is per se illegal, prohibit economic agreements that unreasonably restrain free the defendant is foreclosed from arguing either against trade. Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits “[e]very contract, the agreement’s alleged adverse effects on competition or for the agreement’s procompetitive justifications. With combination, in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in very few exceptions, per se violations are the subject of restraint of trade of commerce among the several states, or with criminal investigations and prosecutions. Other agreements, foreign nations”. Section 4 of the Clayton Act enables private such as joint ventures or participation in standard-setting parties (including state and local governments) to bring civil actions organisations, that are not per se illegal, are subject to the for damages because of Sherman Act violations. rule of reason. Because of difficulty in proving beyond a reasonable doubt that conduct is unreasonable compared to its procompetitive effects, the Department of Justice (“DOJ”) 1.2 What are the specific substantive provisions for the typically only prosecutes per se violations criminally. cartel prohibition? Effect on Interstate and/or Foreign Commerce. Only agreements that take place in or affect interstate or foreign To convict a defendant for a criminal violation under Section 1, the commerce are subject to federal antitrust laws. The interstate government must prove four elements beyond a reasonable doubt: commerce test is met if products or services related to the (1) an agreement or concerted action; (2) between two or more agreement move across the borders of any state within potential competitors; (3) in an unreasonable restraint of trade; and the United States. The foreign commerce requirement is (4) in or affecting interstate commerce or commerce with foreign described in question 1.6. nations. As stated, the government must prove all four of the above Agreement or Concerted Action. An agreement, defined elements in a criminal prosecution beyond a reasonable doubt. The as an understanding or meeting of the minds between government also must prove that either the agreement itself or an act competitors, is the “essence” of a Sherman Act violation. in furtherance of the agreement occurred within the federal district The agreement does not need to be express or involve overt where the criminal indictment is returned for trial. In a civil case, actions; tacit understandings are sufficient (although still each element must be proven by a preponderance of the evidence. subject to the reasonable doubt standard identified above). Evidence used to prove this element of the offence may include direct evidence such as testimony from participants 1.3 Who enforces the cartel prohibition? or other witnesses and communications with competitors, or circumstantial evidence such as identical bidding behaviour. The Antitrust Division of the DOJ (the “Division”) is the sole Between Competitors. The parties must do business in the enforcer of the antitrust laws with respect to criminal violations same product and geographic market in order to qualify of the cartel prohibition. The Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) as competitors. Products do not have to be identical to be can challenge certain coordinating conduct pursuant to Section considered part of the same market; a product market consists of all goods or services that buyers view as close substitutes. 1, but if it uncovers evidence of a criminal cartel violation in its To qualify as a competitor, companies do not have to actively investigations, it ordinarily will refer the matter to the Division. In participate in the market, but they must be capable of addition,
Recommended publications
  • Building a Conceptual Theory of Anti-Competition Laws in Public-Private Partnerships
    Building a conceptual theory of anti-competition laws in public-private partnerships By Joshua Edgar B.A., Kansas State University, 2017 A THESIS Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree MASTER OF ARTS Department of Political Science College of Arts and Sciences KANSAS STATE UNIVERSITY Manhattan, Kansas 2021 Approved by: Major Professor Dr. Brianne Heidbreder COPYRIGHT ©Joshua Edgar 2021 Abstract The growing economic presence of public-private partnerships in the market has led to an increased monopolization and subsequent reduction in competition in sectors such as infrastructure, utilities, and health services. Much of this can be contributed to the principal- agent problems that arise between the government and its constituents. Previous research has demonstrated the strain that anti-competitive practices place on the market, but little research on competition has been directed towards understanding how the active participation of public sector actors affect competition when in league with their private sector counterparts. Using data from public-private infrastructure projects in the United States, a monte carlo test on public-private infrastructure expenditures, the data of which is then set into a cooperative game-theory to determine changes in the public actor’s preferential outcome in the presence of increased risk. This quantitative analysis is then placed within a conceptual framework which demonstrates that many of the principal-agent problems can be overcome by the inclusion of anti-completion regulations.
    [Show full text]
  • Public-Private Divide in Parker State-Action Immunity Sina Safvati
    Public-Private Divide in Parker State-Action Immunity EVIEW R Sina Safvati ABSTRACT LA LAW LA LAW C The U.S. Supreme Court’s jurisprudence on Parker state-action immunity from federal U antitrust laws has remained largely muddled since its inception. The Court recently attempted to bring clarity to the doctrine in North Carolina Board of Dental Examiners v. FTC, holding that state occupational licensing boards with a controlling number of active market participants are subject to the same active supervision requirement as private actors performing state governmental functions. Given that most state licensing boards are comprised of active market participants in the industry they are charged with regulating, state licensing boards can no longer assume they are immune from antitrust suits. In response, states have been scrambling to reassess the composition and oversight of their regulatory bodies in order to reduce antitrust liability for board members. In addition, litigants are bringing more claims against these boards for alleged antitrust violations. Lower courts are left with the task of determining whether these boards are closer to private actors or to prototypical state agencies. For those boards classified as private, lower courts are left with the task of determining whether the regulatory regimes overseeing the boards’ anticompetitive conduct satisfy the active supervision requirement. In light of these rapid developments, however, doctrinal confusion about Parker immunity persists. This confusion largely stems from the Court’s failure to formally adopt a rule of decision incorporating the two bedrock principles that have explained Parker immunity doctrine since its inception: financial disinterest and political accountability.
    [Show full text]
  • Plain Ambiguities in the Clear Articulation Requirement for State Action Antitrust Immunity: the Ac Se of State Agencies C Douglas Floyd
    Boston College Law Review Volume 41 Article 2 Issue 5 Number 5 9-1-2000 Plain Ambiguities in the Clear Articulation Requirement for State Action Antitrust Immunity: The aC se of State Agencies C Douglas Floyd Follow this and additional works at: http://lawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/bclr Part of the Administrative Law Commons, and the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons Recommended Citation C D. Floyd, Plain Ambiguities in the Clear Articulation Requirement for State Action Antitrust Immunity: The Case of State Agencies, 41 B.C.L. Rev. 1059 (2000), http://lawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/bclr/vol41/iss5/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at Digital Commons @ Boston College Law School. It has been accepted for inclusion in Boston College Law Review by an authorized editor of Digital Commons @ Boston College Law School. For more information, please contact [email protected]. PLAIN AMBIGUITIES IN THE CLEAR ARTICULATION REQUIREMENT FOR STATE. ACTION ANTITRUST IMMUNITY: THE CASE OF STATE AGENCIES C. DOUGLAS FLOYD* Abstract: This Article focuses on the application of the state action antitrust inimunity doctrine of Parker v. Brown to the regulatory programs of state administrative agencies having statewide jurisdiction. It concludes that state agencies should be subject to significantly different requirements for antitrust immunity than are local governmental units. This Article also addresses unresolved issues that frequently recur in the context of state administrative action, such as the effect of retroactive intetpretations of state policy by a state agency, whether the clear articulation and active supervision requirements for antitrust immunity play any separate role in the context of administrative policy making, and whether any distinctions should be drawn among the processes of rulemaking, adjudication, and tariff approval in applying the Parker doctrine.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Act Report Full
    Appendix A. Antitrust Timeline [00.16.3] [08.14] [01.1] [01.3] [02.1] [02.1] [01.6] [02.2] [02.1] [01.7] [01.8] [01.9] [08.8] [01.10] [08.3] [01.15] [01.11] [08.9] [01.12] [08.11] [01.13] [02.1] [02.1] [08.20] [01.14] [02.1] [08.15] [08.20] [02.1] [08.17] [08.21] [08.1] [02.1] [08.21] [08.1] [08.21] [08.5] [08.7] [08.16] [08.4] [08.10] [08.13] [08.19] [08.12] [08.18] Appendix B. Case Annotations For more comprehensive summaries and additional case summaries, please visit the research database accompanying this report at: https://drive.google.com/drive/u/1/folders/0B- Sc0KR7f1Flflpub09BUmtoNWJzTzhrbGV0YlFJSVJzdkE3RmNWNmFiSm5MVV9tOFFiT2s In chronological order: United States v E.C. Knight Co (1895), 156 US 1 The United States claimed that, in order for the American Sugar Refining Company to obtain complete control of the price of sugar in the United States, that the company, and John E. Searles, Jr., acting for it, entered into an unlawful and fraudulent scheme to purchase the stock, machinery, and real estate of the other four corporations defendant for the purpose of restraining interstate trade. It was found that on or about March 4, 1892, Searles entered into contracts with the defendant Knight Company, the Spreckels Company, the Franklin Company and with the Delaware Sugar House [p3]. The argument is that the power to control the manufacturing of refined sugar is a monopoly over a necessary of life, to the enjoyment of which by a large part of the population of the United States interstate commerce is indispensable, and that, therefore, the general government, in the exercise of the power to regulate commerce, may repress such monopoly directly, and set aside the instruments which have created it [p12].
    [Show full text]
  • State Action Antitrust Exemption Collides with Deregulation: Rehabilitating the Foreseeability Doctrine
    Texas A&M University School of Law Texas A&M Law Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 1-2006 State Action Antitrust Exemption Collides with Deregulation: Rehabilitating the Foreseeability Doctrine Elizabeth Trujillo Texas A&M University School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/facscholar Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Energy and Utilities Law Commons, and the Law and Economics Commons Recommended Citation Elizabeth Trujillo, State Action Antitrust Exemption Collides with Deregulation: Rehabilitating the Foreseeability Doctrine, 11 Fordham J. Corp. & Fin. L. 349 (2006). Available at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/facscholar/796 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Texas A&M Law Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Texas A&M Law Scholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. STATE ACTION ANTITRUST EXEMPTION COLLIDES WITH DEREGULATION: REHABILITATING THE FORESEEABILITY DOCTRINE Elizabeth Trujillo* INTRODUCTION A capitalist society with policies established to "regulate" the promotion of competition in traditionally regulated industries such as the electrical market seems counterintuitive. Yet, it is a reality in the United States. In particular, traditionally rate-regulated industries, such as electricity, have been "deregulated." In this context, deregulation means opening up certain components of the industry to competition. However, regulatory mechanisms in place to prevent abuses of the competitive process are also driving this competition, resulting in a "regulated deregulation." 1 Specifically, recent initiatives to "deregulate" the electricity markets have highlighted that free markets thrive where competitive * Visiting Professor, Florida State University College of Law, 2005-2006; Assistant Professor of Law, University of Detroit Mercy School of Law.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust and Democracy: a Case Study from German Fascism
    University of Michigan Law School University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository Law & Economics Working Papers 4-17-2018 Antitrust and Democracy: A Case Study from German Fascism Daniel A. Crane University of Michigan - Ann Arbor, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/law_econ_current Part of the Law and Economics Commons Working Paper Citation Crane, Daniel A., "Antitrust and Democracy: A Case Study from German Fascism" (2018). Law & Economics Working Papers. 155. https://repository.law.umich.edu/law_econ_current/155 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Law & Economics Working Papers by an authorized administrator of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Crane: ANTITRUST AND DEMOCRACY: A CASE STUDY FROM GERMAN FASCISM Daniel A. Crane† Nearly forty years ago, Bob Pitofsky wrote, in his classic article The Political Content of Antitrust, that it is “bad history, bad policy, and bad law to exclude certain political values in interpreting the antitrust laws.”1 Pitofsky argued that pervasive monopoly threatened democratic values in three ways: “[F]irst, . excessive concentration of economic power will breed antidemocratic political pressures . [S]econd, . individual and business freedom [can be enhanced] by reducing the range within which private discretion by a few in the economic
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Act Report Full
    The Sherman Antitrust Act and the Profession of Architecture Peggy Deamer May, 2016 Index I. Introduction II. Antitrust Laws: Histories A. General B. The Professions C. Architecture III. Antitrust Laws: Concepts Consent Decrees, Codes of Ethics, and the Learned Profession IV. Probes A. The Learned Profession Exemption B. The State Exemption C. The Differing Professions D. The Political Nature of Antitrust Rulings V. Legal Forms of Moderating Fees and Wages and Modifying Competition A. 3rd Party Surveys B. Legislation C. Unions VI. Conclusion VII. Appendix A. Antitrust Timeline B. Case Annotations C. AIA Consent Decree 1972 (with letter) D. AIA Consent Decree 1990 E. AIA Statement of Services & Charges of the Architect (1960) F. 2002 AIA Antitrust Compliance Guidelines G. Glossary of Antitrust Terms H. Bibliography I. Introduction This is a report on how antitrust laws have affected the architectural profession. This research was motivated by the thought that the American Institute of Architects (AIA) and the profession of architecture in general have been more negatively affected by antitrust law than the other professions. It seemed that large law firms, for example, agree on a certain salary for associates, ostensibly wage collusion under antitrust law; and realtors seemed to have an “understood” 6% fee structure, ostensibly fee collusion.1 Was it the case that the two antitrust proceedings against the AIA in 1972 and 1990 - which penalized the AIA for inhibiting competition among member architects - had made the profession more conservative with regard to discussion of fees and wages than had other proceedings affecting other professions? Having learned from Robert Ivy, CEO of AIA National, that these consent decrees were the reason that the AIA could not be more aggressive in advocating for higher architectural fees, this was a pertinent question.
    [Show full text]
  • Does Competition Ordinance Result in Consumer Protection
    Does Competition Ordinance Result In Consumer Protection By Qaiser Javed Mian (Director Research/Faculty member Punjab Judicial Academy) There can be “prohibited” anti-competitive behaviour and there can be “permitted” anti-competitive behaviour. In U.SA, what is called Anti-Trust Law, in other Countries, it is called Competition Law and/or Anti-Monopoly Law 1 and/or Consumer Protection Law. According to Philip Areeda, U.S. Anti-Trust Law, “…contains a basic distinction between concerted and “independent” 2 action” , which in other words refers to distinction between “single – firm” and “multi-firm” conduct in the context of “encouraging competition”, and save the “businesses” and/or “consumers”. Antitrust law seeks fair competition on the belief that “free trade” benefits not only the consumer, but also the economy and business. The restraints imposed by this law can be divided into four categories: (i) agreements between competitors (ii) contractual arrangements between sellers and buyers (iii) creating and maintaining of monopoly power, and (iv) mergers. While U.S.A has “The Sherman Antitrust Act” (1890)” named for Senator Johan Sherman as a first measure passed by the U.S. Congress to “regulate interstate commerce” as well, Clayton Act, 1914) and “Robinson Patman Act (1936)”, Pakistan had “Monopolies And Restrictive Trade Practices (Control And Prevention) Ordinance, (V of 1970)”, Competition Ordinance (LII of 2007)” as amended from time to time and “The Punjab Consumer Protection Act (Pb. Act II of 2005)” while the other Provinces have not yet started applying Consumer Protection Law. India promulgated “The Consumer Protection Act, 1986” and Rules 1987 which includes “goods” as well as “services”.
    [Show full text]
  • Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards up Close Rebecca Haw Allensworth
    Vanderbilt University Law School Scholarship@Vanderbilt Law Vanderbilt Law School Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship 2017 Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards Up Close Rebecca Haw Allensworth Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.vanderbilt.edu/faculty-publications Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, and the Commercial Law Commons Recommended Citation Rebecca Haw Allensworth, Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards Up Close, 105 California Law Review. 1567 (2017) Available at: https://scholarship.law.vanderbilt.edu/faculty-publications/11 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Scholarship@Vanderbilt Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Vanderbilt Law School Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of Scholarship@Vanderbilt Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. +(,1 2 1/,1( Citation: Rebecca Haw Allensworth, Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards up Close, 105 Cal. L. Rev. 1567 (2017) Provided by: Vanderbilt University Law School Content downloaded/printed from HeinOnline Mon Feb 5 15:44:56 2018 -- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and Conditions of the license agreement available at http://heinonline.org/HOL/License -- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text. -- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your HeinOnline license, please use: Copyright Information
    [Show full text]
  • 1-Allensworth-34.Pdf
    California Law Review VOL. 105 DECEMBER 2017 NO. 6 Copyright © 2017 by California Law Review, Inc., a California Nonprofit Corporation Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards Up Close Rebecca Haw Allensworth* The dark side of occupational licensing—its tendency to raise prices to consumers with dubious effects on service quality, its enormous payout to licensees, and its ability to shut many willing workers out of the workforce—has begun to receive significant attention. But little has been said about the legal institutions that create and administer this web of professional entry and practice rules. State-level licensing boards regulate nearly one-third of American workers, yet, until now, there has been no systematic attempt to understand who serves on these boards and how they operate. This Article undertakes an ambitious and comprehensive study of all 1,790 licensing boards in the U.S. and identifies their statutory membership. The results are clear: nearly all of them are controlled by professionals holding a license issued by the board itself. DOI: https://dx.doi.org/10.15779/Z38CJ87K75 Copyright © 2017 California Law Review, Inc. California Law Review, Inc. (CLR) is a California nonprofit corporation. CLR and the authors are solely responsible for the content of their publications. * Professor of Law, Vanderbilt Law School; J.D., Harvard Law School; M.Phil, University of Cambridge; B.A., Yale University. Thank you to Lora Chowdhury, Laura Dolbow, Demetrios Festa, Francesco Forin, Janelle Grigaitis, Michael Moore, Stephanie Onyekwere, Jason Palmer, and Carolyn Webb for excellent research assistance. Thank you to Andrea Alexander for managing the empirical project, and to Francesco Forin for extensive help with citations and editing.
    [Show full text]
  • Judicial Review As Midcal Active Supervision: Immunizing Private Parties from Antitrust Liability
    Fordham Law Review Volume 57 Issue 3 Article 3 1988 Judicial Review as Midcal Active Supervision: Immunizing Private Parties from Antitrust Liability Michal Dlouhy Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/flr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Michal Dlouhy, Judicial Review as Midcal Active Supervision: Immunizing Private Parties from Antitrust Liability, 57 Fordham L. Rev. 403 (1988). Available at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/flr/vol57/iss3/3 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. It has been accepted for inclusion in Fordham Law Review by an authorized editor of FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. For more information, please contact [email protected]. NOTES JUDICIAL REVIEW AS MIDCAL ACTIVE SUPERVISION: IMMUNIZING PRIVATE PARTIES FROM ANTITRUST LIABILITY INTRODUCTION The Parker v. Brown' state action doctrine2 may immunize3 a private party4 from liability under federal antitrust laws.5 Private conduct is im- mune, however, only when it satisfies the two-pronged test developed in CaliforniaRetail Liquor Dealers Ass'n v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc.6 The challenged conduct must be pursuant to a "clearly articulated and affirm- atively expressed" state policy, and it must be " 'actively supervised' by 1. 317 U.S. 341 (1943) (immunizing actions of a raisin cartel from liability under the Sherman Act, 26 Stat. 209 (1890) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7 (1982 & Supp. IV 1986))). 2. The Parker state action doctrine provides that the Sherman Act was not intended to restrain state action or official action directed by a state.
    [Show full text]
  • Sanders Brown Opinion
    FOR PUBLICATION UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT � STEVE SANDERS, Individually and as Class Representative, Plaintiff-Appellant, v. EDMUND G. BROWN Jr.,* in his No. 05-15676 official capacity as Attorney � D.C. No. General of the State of California; CV-04-02281-SI PHILIP MORRIS USA, INC.; R.J. OPINION REYNOLDS TOBACCO COMPANY; BROWN & WILLIAMSON TOBACCO CORP.; LORILLARD TOBACCO COMPANY, Defendants-Appellees. � Appeal from the United States District Court for the Northern District of California Susan Yvonne Illston, District Judge, Presiding Argued and Submitted February 15, 2007—Stanford, California Filed September 26, 2007 Before: Betty B. Fletcher, Richard R. Clifton, and Sandra S. Ikuta, Circuit Judges. Opinion by Judge Clifton *Edmund G. Brown Jr. is substituted for his predecessor, Bill Lockyer, as Attorney General of the State of California, pursuant to Fed. R. App. P. 43(c)(2). 13205 13208 SANDERS v. BROWN COUNSEL A. William Urquhart, Thad A. Davis, Kent J. Bullard, Kath­ leen M. Sullivan (argued), Quinn Emanuel Urquhart Oliver & Hedges, LLP, Los Angeles and Redwood Shores, California; for the appellant. Attorney General Edmund G. Brown Jr., Chief Assistant Attorney General Tom Greene, Senior Assistant Attorney General Dennis Eckhart, Deputy Attorney General Margaret SANDERS v. BROWN 13209 Spencer, Deputy Attorney General Karen Leaf (argued), State of California, Sacramento, California; Darryl Snider (argued), James F. Speyer, Eric Shapland, Heller Ehrman LLP, Los Angeles, California; for the appellees. OPINION CLIFTON, Circuit Judge: This case involves an indirect legal challenge to the mas­ sive settlement agreement between the nation’s largest tobacco companies and the attorneys general of 46 states and several territories.
    [Show full text]