The Politics of Delegation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Politics of Delegation The Politics of Delegation: Constitutional Structure, Bureaucratic Discretion, and the Development of Competition Policy in the United States and the European Union, 1890-2017 The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Foster, Chase Michael. 2019. The Politics of Delegation: Constitutional Structure, Bureaucratic Discretion, and the Development of Competition Policy in the United States and the European Union, 1890-2017. Doctoral dissertation, Harvard University, Graduate School of Arts & Sciences. Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:41121359 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA The Politics of Delegation: Constitutional Structure, Bureaucratic Discretion, and the Development of Competition Policy in the United States and the European Union, 1890-2017 A dissertation presented by Chase Michael Foster to The Department of Government in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the subject of Government Harvard University Cambridge, Massachusetts January 2019 ©2019 Chase Michael Foster All rights reserved. The Politics of Delegation: Constitutional Structure, Bureaucratic Discretion, and the Development of Competition Policy in the United States and the European Union, 1890-2017 Abstract Over the last three decades, European competition enforcement has become both more intensive and extensive. Meanwhile, American antitrust enforcement has stagnated. Why has the European Union, a supranational organization created by governments with long histories of organized cartels and state direction of the economy become the world’s competition policy leader? And why is the United States, the birthplace of antitrust, and a polity with less of a cartel and industrial policy tradition, now a competition policy laggard? I argue that the divergent pattern has depended on differences in the construction of administrative power in each system. In Europe, a broad zone of bureaucratic discretion allowed the European Commission to intensify competition policy enforcement following the diffusion of neoliberal economic ideas during the final decades of the 20th century. In the United States, antitrust regulators had similar policy preferences but were comparatively constrained: by their narrow legislative mandate, the adversarial legal enforcement system, and extensive ongoing political controls that limited bureaucratic autonomy. Drawing from archival material, comprehensive enforcement data, and an extensive secondary literature in history, economics, sociology, and law, I use systematic process analysis to demonstrate that the dissimilarity in the design of bureaucratic discretion in the competition policy field is rooted in the distinct political origins of each regulatory regime, and the way in which bureaucratic delegation was shaped by the constitutional organization of power within each political system. The agrarian populist origins of the American antitrust laws, together with the congressional dominance of lawmaking under the U.S. Constitution, led to the establishment of a regulatory regime characterized by a narrow zone of bureaucratic discretion and a judicial system of enforcement. In Europe, by iii contrast, the integrationist origins of competition law, combined with the executive-dominated organization of political power under the European Treaties, led to the creation of a comparatively broad zone of bureaucratic discretion, including the establishment of an administrative system of enforcement, and the delegation of significant policymaking and enforcement autonomy to the European Commission. A close analysis of institutional design choices over more than a century of political development, points to some of the ways that the organization of powers within each political system has systematically conditioned subsequent reforms, leading to the maintenance and reinforcement of the core institutional features of each regulatory regime. Through a comparative analysis of the pattern of competition enforcement within key sectors from 1975 to 2017, I highlight also some of the consequences of the design of bureaucratic discretion for regulatory capacity. With little risk of political intervention or judicial sanction, the Commission has been able to use competition law to systematically reform economic development policy, promote regulatory liberalization, and restructure the behavior of dominant firms—in the process, creating a more integrated and competitive European economy. By contrast, the more limited discretionary authority possessed by U.S. regulators has tied antitrust enforcement to electoral outcomes and judicial opinion, limiting the ability of federal regulators to use antitrust law to support liberalization and public subsidy reform, and thereby allowing dominant firms and subnational governments to maintain significant barriers to competition in the American economy. iv Table of Contents Acknowledgments………………………………………………………………………………vi Introduction………………………………………………………………………………………1 Chapter One: The Divergent Trajectories of American and European Competition Enforcement: An Empirical Analysis…………...………………………………………………………………. 32 Chapter Two: Bureaucratic Delegation and the Institutional Organization of American and European Competition Law………………………………………………………………………44 Chapter Three: Explaining Differences in Bureaucratic Discretion: Theoretical Perspectives……. 67 Chapter Four: Industrial Development and the Madisonian Constitution: The Origins and Institutionalization of American Antitrust, 1890-1950…………………………………………… 84 Chapter Five: Credible Commitments and European Integration: The Origins and Institutionalization of European Competition Law, 1950-1990…………………………….…… 137 Chapter Six: Constitutional Structure, Bureaucratic Delegation, and Varieties of Regulatory Liberalization, 1975-2017…………………………………………………………….…………. 186 Conclusion ………………………...…………………………………………………………… 236 Works Cited………………………………………………………………….…………….….…254 v Acknowledgments This project began with a simple puzzle. I wanted to understand why European competition law seemed to constrain the anti-competitive behavior of global multi-national companies more than American antitrust. The predominant view, particularly within the legal literature, was that the divergence related to law and economics: American antitrust was more narrowly concerned with consumer welfare than European competition law, which was also infused with political goals— thus, the reason European and American enforcement differed. My research demonstrated that this could not be the entire explanation since, within many areas of competition policy, the economic analysis was similar across the two systems. I concluded that an institutionalist theory was needed to explain the distinct trajectories. Further, to understand the design of regulatory institutions, it was necessary to analyze the political origins of each regulatory regime, and the political coalitions that shaped their establishment and institutionalization. Thus, my journey down more than a century of history, exploring periods and places as varied as the populist agrarian movements in the 19th century United States, and the birth of the European Coal and Steel Community in postwar Europe. And thus, my efforts, some more successful than others, to trace the links between these foundational moments and the practices of regulators today. As the project progressed, I realized that, to understand these historical developments, I also needed to grasp the technical details of competition law. This meant turning to lawyers and law review articles to learn the intricacies of American antitrust and European competition law, as well as the rules governing enforcement and judicial review within each legal system. Understanding competition policy also necessitated engaging with economics—to understand the theories and methodologies that inform enforcement. So, what started out as a political science project, became increasingly interdisciplinary, incorporating the work of historians, legal scholars, and economists as much as political scientists and economic sociologists. Completing such a project has required extensive support from family, friends, and colleagues. Thank you first to my dissertation committee members: Peter Hall, Jeff Frieden, Dan Carpenter, and Kathy Thelen. My thinking about the relationship between political coalitions and economic institutions, and the historical threads between the institutions of the past and the present, has been deeply influenced by Kathy’s scholarship and advice. Dan’s course on bureaucratic politics, which I took my first semester of graduate school, set me on a path dependent process of studying the regulatory state. Ever since, his research and recommendations have been fundamental to my understanding of its political development. As a teacher, collaborator and mentor, Jeff taught me how to develop theoretically-motivated research questions and explanations, and to articulate clear arguments in article-length form. This project has benefited tremendously from his incisive critiques and tireless effort to find the economic interests lurking behind every regulatory enforcement action. Very little of this dissertation would have been
Recommended publications
  • Building a Conceptual Theory of Anti-Competition Laws in Public-Private Partnerships
    Building a conceptual theory of anti-competition laws in public-private partnerships By Joshua Edgar B.A., Kansas State University, 2017 A THESIS Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree MASTER OF ARTS Department of Political Science College of Arts and Sciences KANSAS STATE UNIVERSITY Manhattan, Kansas 2021 Approved by: Major Professor Dr. Brianne Heidbreder COPYRIGHT ©Joshua Edgar 2021 Abstract The growing economic presence of public-private partnerships in the market has led to an increased monopolization and subsequent reduction in competition in sectors such as infrastructure, utilities, and health services. Much of this can be contributed to the principal- agent problems that arise between the government and its constituents. Previous research has demonstrated the strain that anti-competitive practices place on the market, but little research on competition has been directed towards understanding how the active participation of public sector actors affect competition when in league with their private sector counterparts. Using data from public-private infrastructure projects in the United States, a monte carlo test on public-private infrastructure expenditures, the data of which is then set into a cooperative game-theory to determine changes in the public actor’s preferential outcome in the presence of increased risk. This quantitative analysis is then placed within a conceptual framework which demonstrates that many of the principal-agent problems can be overcome by the inclusion of anti-completion regulations.
    [Show full text]
  • The European Payments Union and the Origins of Triffin's Regional Approach Towards International Monetary Integration
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Maes, Ivo; Pasotti, Ilaria Working Paper The European Payments Union and the origins of Triffin's regional approach towards international monetary integration NBB Working Paper, No. 301 Provided in Cooperation with: National Bank of Belgium, Brussels Suggested Citation: Maes, Ivo; Pasotti, Ilaria (2016) : The European Payments Union and the origins of Triffin's regional approach towards international monetary integration, NBB Working Paper, No. 301, National Bank of Belgium, Brussels This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/173757 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen
    [Show full text]
  • Debtors to Balance
    > v, , \\ Albert H. Huntington, Jr. 6621 Gordon .Avtnue Falli Church, V«. 22046 ttA/r'ttdffvO U40U-,'y /\A>W(A?AsiAfr(jMW' -+ v Ao? f- JFW /~rns\/'iAM<i<i<tt/ 0y\ \ I, u <J 3. To oMU<J~ I 0 57 v — / * J-.fa C uwyjziis/ / 'c'a Lremmaw MATNUtOtTlON •M rfMN C« aiO NMM UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT Memorandum A/AID, Mr. C. Tyler Wood : Hay 4, 1972 : . PPC/SR, Albert H. Huntington', Jr. SUBJECT: Information You Requested on U.S. Assistance to Germany During FY 1946-1952, Germany's Membership in OEEC, EPU, etc. Enclosed are extra copies of the FY 1970 "Green Book" for Governor Harriman, and the FY 1971 preliminary release. We have the complete FY 1971 book in typing now. I have set up a special table showing U.S. aid to Germany by year and program durin? FY 1946-1952, and enclose it. Germany is one of the more complicated situations because of the early postwar relief and GARIOA programs, a part of which were retroactively converted from grant to loan. The Berlin aspect also adds a complication; the notes on the Berlin page in the "Green Book" were reviewed (and amended) by Eleanor Dulles, who handled the Berlin desk in State for several years. Hastily, on other points of interest on which you .wanted help if we could get it in a hurry: 1. A Marshall Flan table is attached, showing Germany in relation to the total and to other recipients. All of these Marshall Plan loans to Germany have long since been repaid.
    [Show full text]
  • Public-Private Divide in Parker State-Action Immunity Sina Safvati
    Public-Private Divide in Parker State-Action Immunity EVIEW R Sina Safvati ABSTRACT LA LAW LA LAW C The U.S. Supreme Court’s jurisprudence on Parker state-action immunity from federal U antitrust laws has remained largely muddled since its inception. The Court recently attempted to bring clarity to the doctrine in North Carolina Board of Dental Examiners v. FTC, holding that state occupational licensing boards with a controlling number of active market participants are subject to the same active supervision requirement as private actors performing state governmental functions. Given that most state licensing boards are comprised of active market participants in the industry they are charged with regulating, state licensing boards can no longer assume they are immune from antitrust suits. In response, states have been scrambling to reassess the composition and oversight of their regulatory bodies in order to reduce antitrust liability for board members. In addition, litigants are bringing more claims against these boards for alleged antitrust violations. Lower courts are left with the task of determining whether these boards are closer to private actors or to prototypical state agencies. For those boards classified as private, lower courts are left with the task of determining whether the regulatory regimes overseeing the boards’ anticompetitive conduct satisfy the active supervision requirement. In light of these rapid developments, however, doctrinal confusion about Parker immunity persists. This confusion largely stems from the Court’s failure to formally adopt a rule of decision incorporating the two bedrock principles that have explained Parker immunity doctrine since its inception: financial disinterest and political accountability.
    [Show full text]
  • Plain Ambiguities in the Clear Articulation Requirement for State Action Antitrust Immunity: the Ac Se of State Agencies C Douglas Floyd
    Boston College Law Review Volume 41 Article 2 Issue 5 Number 5 9-1-2000 Plain Ambiguities in the Clear Articulation Requirement for State Action Antitrust Immunity: The aC se of State Agencies C Douglas Floyd Follow this and additional works at: http://lawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/bclr Part of the Administrative Law Commons, and the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons Recommended Citation C D. Floyd, Plain Ambiguities in the Clear Articulation Requirement for State Action Antitrust Immunity: The Case of State Agencies, 41 B.C.L. Rev. 1059 (2000), http://lawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/bclr/vol41/iss5/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at Digital Commons @ Boston College Law School. It has been accepted for inclusion in Boston College Law Review by an authorized editor of Digital Commons @ Boston College Law School. For more information, please contact [email protected]. PLAIN AMBIGUITIES IN THE CLEAR ARTICULATION REQUIREMENT FOR STATE. ACTION ANTITRUST IMMUNITY: THE CASE OF STATE AGENCIES C. DOUGLAS FLOYD* Abstract: This Article focuses on the application of the state action antitrust inimunity doctrine of Parker v. Brown to the regulatory programs of state administrative agencies having statewide jurisdiction. It concludes that state agencies should be subject to significantly different requirements for antitrust immunity than are local governmental units. This Article also addresses unresolved issues that frequently recur in the context of state administrative action, such as the effect of retroactive intetpretations of state policy by a state agency, whether the clear articulation and active supervision requirements for antitrust immunity play any separate role in the context of administrative policy making, and whether any distinctions should be drawn among the processes of rulemaking, adjudication, and tariff approval in applying the Parker doctrine.
    [Show full text]
  • Lessons from the European Payments Union for Post-Soviet Currency Arrangements
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Schmieding, Holger Working Paper — Digitized Version No need for a monetary halfway house: Lessons from the European Payments Union for post-Soviet currency arrangements Kieler Diskussionsbeiträge, No. 189 Provided in Cooperation with: Kiel Institute for the World Economy (IfW) Suggested Citation: Schmieding, Holger (1992) : No need for a monetary halfway house: Lessons from the European Payments Union for post-Soviet currency arrangements, Kieler Diskussionsbeiträge, No. 189, ISBN 3894560282, Institut für Weltwirtschaft (IfW), Kiel This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/48095 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under
    [Show full text]
  • Interview with Jacob J. Kaplan
    Library of Congress Interview with Jacob J. Kaplan The Association for Diplomatic Studies and Training Foreign Affairs Oral History Project Foreign Assistance Series JACOB J. KAPLAN Interviewed by: W. Haven North Initial interview date: March 22, 1999 Copyright 1999 ADST Q: March 22, 1999 the interview is with Jacob J. Kaplan. Let's start off with a brief summary of your association with Foreign Assistance and AID. An overview of a career with foreign assistance KAPLAN: My association with foreign assistance goes back to my arrival in Washington in 1943. I was assigned to OSS and put to work evaluating European food supplies. That soon led to moving to London to participate in a Combined Working Party on European Food Supplies, preparing estimates of food the Army would have to bring along to Europe to feed the people. Subsequently, I joined the State Department at the end of the war and quickly became involved in the preparations of the Marshall Plan. I left once the Marshall Plan had been submitted to Congress to take up a position at Yale. I decided after a couple of years that I really wanted to get back into public service. I joined ECA and worked in ECA in Washington and Paris. Then I came back to the State Department, which had taken over the function I was performing in Paris. I was Assistant Coordinator for Program under Douglas Dillon and then George Ball. Then I was a member of the group that put AID together, the President's Foreign Aid Task Force. I then became head Interview with Jacob J.
    [Show full text]
  • The Inability of the Bretton Woods Monetary System and the British Search for a New International Economic Framework in the 1950'S
    Working Paper Series E-2012-01 The inability of the Bretton Woods monetary system and the British Search for a new international economic framework in the 1950's Mei Kudo (Institute of International and Cultural Studies, Tsuda College) ©2012 Mei Kudo. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit is given to the source. 1 The inability of the Bretton Woods monetary system and the British Search for a new international economic framework in the 1950’s1 Mei Kudo (Institute of International and Cultural Studies, Tsuda College) Summary How is the reality of the Bretton Woods system and “embedded liberalism” ideology immediately after the Second World War II? What is the meaning of European integration in relation to the international economic regime? To approach these questions, this paper, taking the two UK proposals of floating rate and sterling convertibility – “Operation Robot” and “Collective Approach” – , argues, because of the ineffectiveness of both Keynesian policy and the IMF, in the 1950’s, some of the UK policy-makers try to apply more market-oriented policy to resolve balance of payments crisis, but rejected by those who thought market solution expose the welfare state in danger. This paper also analyses reaction from the continental Europeans. Although they too recognized the limit of the IMF, and Marjolin was even looking for new Atlantic framework, their idea was not corresponded to the “Collective Approach”. What they want was the convertibility through existing EPU framework, which is more reliable and effective than the IMF.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Act Report Full
    Appendix A. Antitrust Timeline [00.16.3] [08.14] [01.1] [01.3] [02.1] [02.1] [01.6] [02.2] [02.1] [01.7] [01.8] [01.9] [08.8] [01.10] [08.3] [01.15] [01.11] [08.9] [01.12] [08.11] [01.13] [02.1] [02.1] [08.20] [01.14] [02.1] [08.15] [08.20] [02.1] [08.17] [08.21] [08.1] [02.1] [08.21] [08.1] [08.21] [08.5] [08.7] [08.16] [08.4] [08.10] [08.13] [08.19] [08.12] [08.18] Appendix B. Case Annotations For more comprehensive summaries and additional case summaries, please visit the research database accompanying this report at: https://drive.google.com/drive/u/1/folders/0B- Sc0KR7f1Flflpub09BUmtoNWJzTzhrbGV0YlFJSVJzdkE3RmNWNmFiSm5MVV9tOFFiT2s In chronological order: United States v E.C. Knight Co (1895), 156 US 1 The United States claimed that, in order for the American Sugar Refining Company to obtain complete control of the price of sugar in the United States, that the company, and John E. Searles, Jr., acting for it, entered into an unlawful and fraudulent scheme to purchase the stock, machinery, and real estate of the other four corporations defendant for the purpose of restraining interstate trade. It was found that on or about March 4, 1892, Searles entered into contracts with the defendant Knight Company, the Spreckels Company, the Franklin Company and with the Delaware Sugar House [p3]. The argument is that the power to control the manufacturing of refined sugar is a monopoly over a necessary of life, to the enjoyment of which by a large part of the population of the United States interstate commerce is indispensable, and that, therefore, the general government, in the exercise of the power to regulate commerce, may repress such monopoly directly, and set aside the instruments which have created it [p12].
    [Show full text]
  • State Action Antitrust Exemption Collides with Deregulation: Rehabilitating the Foreseeability Doctrine
    Texas A&M University School of Law Texas A&M Law Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 1-2006 State Action Antitrust Exemption Collides with Deregulation: Rehabilitating the Foreseeability Doctrine Elizabeth Trujillo Texas A&M University School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/facscholar Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Energy and Utilities Law Commons, and the Law and Economics Commons Recommended Citation Elizabeth Trujillo, State Action Antitrust Exemption Collides with Deregulation: Rehabilitating the Foreseeability Doctrine, 11 Fordham J. Corp. & Fin. L. 349 (2006). Available at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/facscholar/796 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Texas A&M Law Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Texas A&M Law Scholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. STATE ACTION ANTITRUST EXEMPTION COLLIDES WITH DEREGULATION: REHABILITATING THE FORESEEABILITY DOCTRINE Elizabeth Trujillo* INTRODUCTION A capitalist society with policies established to "regulate" the promotion of competition in traditionally regulated industries such as the electrical market seems counterintuitive. Yet, it is a reality in the United States. In particular, traditionally rate-regulated industries, such as electricity, have been "deregulated." In this context, deregulation means opening up certain components of the industry to competition. However, regulatory mechanisms in place to prevent abuses of the competitive process are also driving this competition, resulting in a "regulated deregulation." 1 Specifically, recent initiatives to "deregulate" the electricity markets have highlighted that free markets thrive where competitive * Visiting Professor, Florida State University College of Law, 2005-2006; Assistant Professor of Law, University of Detroit Mercy School of Law.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust and Democracy: a Case Study from German Fascism
    University of Michigan Law School University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository Law & Economics Working Papers 4-17-2018 Antitrust and Democracy: A Case Study from German Fascism Daniel A. Crane University of Michigan - Ann Arbor, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/law_econ_current Part of the Law and Economics Commons Working Paper Citation Crane, Daniel A., "Antitrust and Democracy: A Case Study from German Fascism" (2018). Law & Economics Working Papers. 155. https://repository.law.umich.edu/law_econ_current/155 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Law & Economics Working Papers by an authorized administrator of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Crane: ANTITRUST AND DEMOCRACY: A CASE STUDY FROM GERMAN FASCISM Daniel A. Crane† Nearly forty years ago, Bob Pitofsky wrote, in his classic article The Political Content of Antitrust, that it is “bad history, bad policy, and bad law to exclude certain political values in interpreting the antitrust laws.”1 Pitofsky argued that pervasive monopoly threatened democratic values in three ways: “[F]irst, . excessive concentration of economic power will breed antidemocratic political pressures . [S]econd, . individual and business freedom [can be enhanced] by reducing the range within which private discretion by a few in the economic
    [Show full text]
  • Western Europe's Growth Prospects
    Western Europe’s Growth Prospects: an Historical Perspective Nicholas Crafts Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy Research Centre, University of Warwick December 2011 Abstract This paper surveys the recent history of Western European growth. It concludes that this experience has been disappointing and that further reforms are desirable in many countries. The requirement for reform comes both from achieving ‘close-to-frontier’ status and from the opportunities provided by the new technological era. The paper goes on to consider the effects that the current crisis may have on medium-term growth rates. The lesson from the 1930s is that, if the current crisis leads to a similarly bad downturn, the policy reaction in terms of greater state intervention will not be conducive to improved growth prospects. Keywords: catch-up growth; general purpose technology; social capability; supply-side policy JEL Classifications: N14; O52 1. Introduction It is well-known that Western European growth performance was lack-lustre from the mid-1990s up to the start of the current financial crisis. This was a far cry from the so-called Golden Age of the early postwar years and was for the average country a period of falling behind rather than catching up the United States. It was a surprise to many that relative productivity performance deteriorated because it appeared that, on the whole, supply-side policy had improved. Yet, while American productivity growth accelerated, European productivity growth slowed down. Of course, since the Golden Age there have been big changes in the global economic environment. Among the most prominent are rapid globalization combined with a new world division of labour associated with the rise of Asia, the advent of a new general purpose technology (GPT) based on information and communication technologies (ICT) and the return of financial crises after a period of unusual stability.
    [Show full text]