Lessons from the European Payments Union for Post-Soviet Currency Arrangements

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Lessons from the European Payments Union for Post-Soviet Currency Arrangements A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Schmieding, Holger Working Paper — Digitized Version No need for a monetary halfway house: Lessons from the European Payments Union for post-Soviet currency arrangements Kieler Diskussionsbeiträge, No. 189 Provided in Cooperation with: Kiel Institute for the World Economy (IfW) Suggested Citation: Schmieding, Holger (1992) : No need for a monetary halfway house: Lessons from the European Payments Union for post-Soviet currency arrangements, Kieler Diskussionsbeiträge, No. 189, ISBN 3894560282, Institut für Weltwirtschaft (IfW), Kiel This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/48095 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu KIELER DISKUSSIONSBEITRAGE KIEL DISCUSSION PAPERS No Need for a Monetary Halfway House Lessons from the European Payments Union for Post-Soviet Currency Arrangements by Holger Schmieding L CONTENTS The Soviet ruble has become the common currency for 14 independent states with their own policies on credit expansion and budget deficits. The built-in inflationary bias of the present arrangement can be redressed if the common ruble makes way for separate cur- rencies. However, if major successor states of the Soviet Union switch to their own monies, trade between the former Soviet republics may be further disrupted as long as the new currencies are not convertible for current transactions. The European Payments Union (EPU) of the 1950s is often presented as a model for the successor states of the Soviet Union with separate currencies. However, the EPU clear- ing mechanism and its facility for soft credits were mere second-best devices to mitigate the harm that was caused by the inconvertibility and the collective overvaluation of the West European currencies against the dollar. In the 1950s, a sufficient devaluation of West European currencies would have removed the rationale for restrictions on trade and payments and would thus have made the EPU obsolete. Today, the former Soviet repub- lics need not waste their time in a payments union, i.e. in a halfway house on the road to convertibility, unless they opted for a gross overvaluation of their currencies. In recent years, Poland, Hungary and Czechoslovakia have made their currencies conver- tible at least for most current transactions of their residents. This minimum convertibility has promoted their integration into the worldwide division of labour; it has been main- tained because exchange rate policy has not led to a sustained misalignment. Instead of copying Western Europe's post-war mistake, the post-Soviet republics should follow the example of the East-Central European countries and make their currencies convertible at realistic and sufficiently flexible exchange rates. Regardless of their currency arrangements, the successor states of the Soviet Union have to transform their banking systems and establish an efficient system to clear payments between banks. Technical help from abroad could promote this process. However, the states need no mechanism that discriminates between interstate payments and pay- ments between the states and third countries. Proponents of a special post-Soviet payments arrangement sometimes argue that such an institution would promote the cooperation between the successor states of the Soviet Union; it would thus be politically useful regardless of economic considerations. How- ever, the strained political relations between many post-Soviet countries suggest that the readiness for a reliable cooperation is limited. Hence, special arrangements that inflate rather than economize on the need for cooperation are likely to be unstable. INSTITUT FUR W E L T W I R T S C H A F T KIEL AUGUST 1992 ISSN 0455-0420 Contents I. Introduction 3 II. The General Rationale for a Payments Union 4 III. The Experience of the European Payments Union 5 1. The Overvaluation of West European Currencies 6 2. The Functions of the EPU 7 3. The Evolution of the EPU 9 4. Evaluation 11 a. Expansion of Trade 11 b. Trade Liberalisation and Currency Convertibility 11 IV. A Post-Soviet Payments Union? 12 1. Is Convertibility Infeasible? 13 2. The Examples of Poland, Hungary and Czechoslovakia 16 3. Are the Ex-Soviet Republics Special Cases? 19 V. A Mixed Payments Union? 21 VI. A Payments Mechanism for Convertible Currencies? 23 VII. The Politics of Payments Arrangements 24 VIII. Recommendations 26 Bibliography 27 Deutsche Bibliothek - Cataloguing-in-Publication Data Schmieding, Holger: No need for a monetary halfway house : lessons from the European Payments Union for post-soviet currency arrangements / by Holger Schmieding. Institut fur Weltwirtschaft Kiel. - Kiel : Inst. fur Weltwirtschaft, 1992 (Kiel discussion papers ; 189) ISBN 3-89456-028-2 NE: Kieler Diskussionsbeitrage © Institut fur Weltwirtschaft an der Universitat Kiel Postfach 43 09, D-2300 Kiel 1 Alle Rechte vorbehalten Ohne ausdruckliche Genehmigung ist es auch nicht gestattet, den Band oder Teile daraus auf photomechanischem Wege (Photokopie, Mikrokopie) zu vervielfaltigen Printed in Germany ISSN 0455 - 0420 Bibliothek des Institute fur Weltwirtschaft Km\ I. Introduction With the peaceful collapse of the Soviet empire and the concurrent dissolution of the Soviet central bank, the ruble turned into the common currency of 15 independent successor states with their own central banks. Only Estonia has so far cut the links to the ruble and introduced its own separate money. On the macro- economic level, even the most stability-oriented successor states are hard put to resist the temptation to join the inflation race and expand the central-bank-financed deficits of their state budgets and state firms be- yond any reasonable limits. Although the erosion of the ruble as a medium of exchange and store of value harms all its users, the biggest chunk of the inflation tax accrues to the republic which boosts the money supply most. On the microeconomic level, the old mechanism to guarantee, clear and settle ruble payments has vanished with the central Soviet institutions. The resulting uncertainties and delays are already con- tributing to the rapid decline in the division of labour within and among the independent successor states of the Soviet Union ("republics" for short). According to Russian estimates, Russian deliveries to other re- publics in January 1992, for instance, fell 25-30 per cent short of their January 1991 levels [IMF, 1992, p. 7]. The way to stop the competition for the ruble inflation tax is obvious: The common currency has to be abolished if an effective re-centralisation of monetary policy is impossible or politically undesirable. As soon as major successor states follow the Estonian example and replace the Soviet ruble by their own monies however, the microeconomic problem may become even far more acute. In the worst-case scenario, trade among the republics may shrink substantially in the absence of any new method to settle inter-repub- lican payments. If, for instance, each republic tried to balance bilateral trade flows at the lower side of the bilateral exports or imports, the volume of inter-republican trade would decline to 44 per cent of its previ- ous value.1 Even worse, such bilateral trade restrictions could induce a chain reaction of mutual retaliation and thus a further reduction in inter-republican exchanges [Dornbusch, 1992]. This would be all the more unfortunate as all successor states are heavily dependent on their mutual trade, the huge and oil-rich Russian Federation less so than the smaller republics. To avoid such a dismal outcome, various authors have proposed to establish a payments union among the ex-Soviet republics. Even the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development has joined the chorus. This paper examines whether the successor states of the Soviet Union should indeed enter into special payments arrangements. It assumes the likely case that major republics such as the Ukraine intro- duce their own monies. The paper is organised as follows. First, the general rationale for a payments union, the oft-cited ex- ample of the European Payments Union (EPU) of the 1950s and the arguments for and against a post-Soviet payments union along the lines of the EPU are analysed (Sections II, III and IV respectively). Thereafter, the possible rationale for a payments union among republics with very different degrees of third-money convertibility and for a payments mechanism for republics whose
Recommended publications
  • The European Payments Union and the Origins of Triffin's Regional Approach Towards International Monetary Integration
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Maes, Ivo; Pasotti, Ilaria Working Paper The European Payments Union and the origins of Triffin's regional approach towards international monetary integration NBB Working Paper, No. 301 Provided in Cooperation with: National Bank of Belgium, Brussels Suggested Citation: Maes, Ivo; Pasotti, Ilaria (2016) : The European Payments Union and the origins of Triffin's regional approach towards international monetary integration, NBB Working Paper, No. 301, National Bank of Belgium, Brussels This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/173757 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen
    [Show full text]
  • Debtors to Balance
    > v, , \\ Albert H. Huntington, Jr. 6621 Gordon .Avtnue Falli Church, V«. 22046 ttA/r'ttdffvO U40U-,'y /\A>W(A?AsiAfr(jMW' -+ v Ao? f- JFW /~rns\/'iAM<i<i<tt/ 0y\ \ I, u <J 3. To oMU<J~ I 0 57 v — / * J-.fa C uwyjziis/ / 'c'a Lremmaw MATNUtOtTlON •M rfMN C« aiO NMM UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT Memorandum A/AID, Mr. C. Tyler Wood : Hay 4, 1972 : . PPC/SR, Albert H. Huntington', Jr. SUBJECT: Information You Requested on U.S. Assistance to Germany During FY 1946-1952, Germany's Membership in OEEC, EPU, etc. Enclosed are extra copies of the FY 1970 "Green Book" for Governor Harriman, and the FY 1971 preliminary release. We have the complete FY 1971 book in typing now. I have set up a special table showing U.S. aid to Germany by year and program durin? FY 1946-1952, and enclose it. Germany is one of the more complicated situations because of the early postwar relief and GARIOA programs, a part of which were retroactively converted from grant to loan. The Berlin aspect also adds a complication; the notes on the Berlin page in the "Green Book" were reviewed (and amended) by Eleanor Dulles, who handled the Berlin desk in State for several years. Hastily, on other points of interest on which you .wanted help if we could get it in a hurry: 1. A Marshall Flan table is attached, showing Germany in relation to the total and to other recipients. All of these Marshall Plan loans to Germany have long since been repaid.
    [Show full text]
  • Interview with Jacob J. Kaplan
    Library of Congress Interview with Jacob J. Kaplan The Association for Diplomatic Studies and Training Foreign Affairs Oral History Project Foreign Assistance Series JACOB J. KAPLAN Interviewed by: W. Haven North Initial interview date: March 22, 1999 Copyright 1999 ADST Q: March 22, 1999 the interview is with Jacob J. Kaplan. Let's start off with a brief summary of your association with Foreign Assistance and AID. An overview of a career with foreign assistance KAPLAN: My association with foreign assistance goes back to my arrival in Washington in 1943. I was assigned to OSS and put to work evaluating European food supplies. That soon led to moving to London to participate in a Combined Working Party on European Food Supplies, preparing estimates of food the Army would have to bring along to Europe to feed the people. Subsequently, I joined the State Department at the end of the war and quickly became involved in the preparations of the Marshall Plan. I left once the Marshall Plan had been submitted to Congress to take up a position at Yale. I decided after a couple of years that I really wanted to get back into public service. I joined ECA and worked in ECA in Washington and Paris. Then I came back to the State Department, which had taken over the function I was performing in Paris. I was Assistant Coordinator for Program under Douglas Dillon and then George Ball. Then I was a member of the group that put AID together, the President's Foreign Aid Task Force. I then became head Interview with Jacob J.
    [Show full text]
  • The Inability of the Bretton Woods Monetary System and the British Search for a New International Economic Framework in the 1950'S
    Working Paper Series E-2012-01 The inability of the Bretton Woods monetary system and the British Search for a new international economic framework in the 1950's Mei Kudo (Institute of International and Cultural Studies, Tsuda College) ©2012 Mei Kudo. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit is given to the source. 1 The inability of the Bretton Woods monetary system and the British Search for a new international economic framework in the 1950’s1 Mei Kudo (Institute of International and Cultural Studies, Tsuda College) Summary How is the reality of the Bretton Woods system and “embedded liberalism” ideology immediately after the Second World War II? What is the meaning of European integration in relation to the international economic regime? To approach these questions, this paper, taking the two UK proposals of floating rate and sterling convertibility – “Operation Robot” and “Collective Approach” – , argues, because of the ineffectiveness of both Keynesian policy and the IMF, in the 1950’s, some of the UK policy-makers try to apply more market-oriented policy to resolve balance of payments crisis, but rejected by those who thought market solution expose the welfare state in danger. This paper also analyses reaction from the continental Europeans. Although they too recognized the limit of the IMF, and Marjolin was even looking for new Atlantic framework, their idea was not corresponded to the “Collective Approach”. What they want was the convertibility through existing EPU framework, which is more reliable and effective than the IMF.
    [Show full text]
  • Western Europe's Growth Prospects
    Western Europe’s Growth Prospects: an Historical Perspective Nicholas Crafts Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy Research Centre, University of Warwick December 2011 Abstract This paper surveys the recent history of Western European growth. It concludes that this experience has been disappointing and that further reforms are desirable in many countries. The requirement for reform comes both from achieving ‘close-to-frontier’ status and from the opportunities provided by the new technological era. The paper goes on to consider the effects that the current crisis may have on medium-term growth rates. The lesson from the 1930s is that, if the current crisis leads to a similarly bad downturn, the policy reaction in terms of greater state intervention will not be conducive to improved growth prospects. Keywords: catch-up growth; general purpose technology; social capability; supply-side policy JEL Classifications: N14; O52 1. Introduction It is well-known that Western European growth performance was lack-lustre from the mid-1990s up to the start of the current financial crisis. This was a far cry from the so-called Golden Age of the early postwar years and was for the average country a period of falling behind rather than catching up the United States. It was a surprise to many that relative productivity performance deteriorated because it appeared that, on the whole, supply-side policy had improved. Yet, while American productivity growth accelerated, European productivity growth slowed down. Of course, since the Golden Age there have been big changes in the global economic environment. Among the most prominent are rapid globalization combined with a new world division of labour associated with the rise of Asia, the advent of a new general purpose technology (GPT) based on information and communication technologies (ICT) and the return of financial crises after a period of unusual stability.
    [Show full text]
  • From Bretton Woods to Brussels: a Legal Analysis of the Exchange-Rate Arrangements of the International Monetary Fund and the European Community
    Fordham Law Review Volume 62 Issue 7 Article 9 1994 From Bretton Woods to Brussels: A Legal Analysis of the Exchange-Rate Arrangements of the International Monetary Fund and the European Community Richard Myrus Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/flr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Richard Myrus, From Bretton Woods to Brussels: A Legal Analysis of the Exchange-Rate Arrangements of the International Monetary Fund and the European Community, 62 Fordham L. Rev. 2095 (1994). Available at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/flr/vol62/iss7/9 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. It has been accepted for inclusion in Fordham Law Review by an authorized editor of FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. For more information, please contact [email protected]. FROM BRETTON WOODS TO BRUSSELS: A LEGAL ANALYSIS OF THE EXCHANGE-RATE ARRANGEMENTS OF THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND AND THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY RICHARD MYR US INTRODUCTION Exchange rates represent the price at which the currency of one coun- try can be purchased with the currency of another.t These rates indi- rectly affect the costs of the goods, capital, and services that flow across national borders.2 According to Joseph Gold, former General Counsel of the International Monetary Fund, "[fqor most countries, there is no single price which has such an important influence on both the financial world-in terms of asset values and rates of return, and on the real world-in terms of production, trade and employment.
    [Show full text]
  • The Marshall Plan and the Establishment of the OEEC
    The Marshall Plan and the establishment of the OEEC Source: CVCE. European NAvigator. Étienne Deschamps. Copyright: (c) CVCE.EU by UNI.LU All rights of reproduction, of public communication, of adaptation, of distribution or of dissemination via Internet, internal network or any other means are strictly reserved in all countries. Consult the legal notice and the terms and conditions of use regarding this site. URL: http://www.cvce.eu/obj/the_marshall_plan_and_the_establishment_of_the_oeec- en-7cbc25dd-0c8d-49b1-924c-53edb2a59248.html Last updated: 11/05/2021 1/3 The Marshall Plan and the establishment of the OEEC At the end of the war, the United Nations (UN), whose founding Charter was signed in San Francisco in June 1945, provided aid in various ways to the European countries ruined by the war. Europe was faced with serious food shortages and had to maintain various rationing schemes. It was also short of dollars and therefore had to limit imports of civil and military equipment. The United Nations Relief and Rehabilitation Agency (UNRRA), founded in November 1943, brought emergency individual aid packages to the European countries, especially humanitarian aid. But this programme was haphazard and would not have much impact on the economy of the entire region. Intra-European trade was hindered by a lack of foreign exchange and required an international authority capable of efectively organising trade worldwide. The United States, whose interests lay in promoting such trade in order to increase its own exports, decided to help the European economy via a large-scale structural recovery programme. The United States wanted to protect American prosperity and stave of the threat of national overproduction.
    [Show full text]
  • The European Payments Union and the Origins of Triffin’S Regional Approach Towards International Monetary Integration
    The European Payments Union and the origins of Triffin’s regional approach towards international monetary integration Working Paper Research by Ivo Maes and Ilaria Pasotti September 2016 No 301 Editor Jan Smets, Governor of the National Bank of Belgium Statement of purpose: The purpose of these working papers is to promote the circulation of research results (Research Series) and analytical studies (Documents Series) made within the National Bank of Belgium or presented by external economists in seminars, conferences and conventions organised by the Bank. The aim is therefore to provide a platform for discussion. The opinions expressed are strictly those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bank of Belgium. Orders For orders and information on subscriptions and reductions: National Bank of Belgium, Documentation - Publications service, boulevard de Berlaimont 14, 1000 Brussels Tel +32 2 221 20 33 - Fax +32 2 21 30 42 The Working Papers are available on the website of the Bank: http://www.nbb.be © National Bank of Belgium, Brussels All rights reserved. Reproduction for educational and non-commercial purposes is permitted provided that the source is acknowledged. ISSN: 1375-680X (print) ISSN: 1784-2476 (online) NBB WORKING PAPER No. 301 – SEPTEMBER 2016 Abstract Robert Triffin (1911-1993) played an important role in the international monetary debates in the postwar period. He was known as one of the main advocates of a multipolar international monetary system. In this paper we analyse the origins of Triffin’s “regional” approach towards international monetary integration. We argue that Triffin’s experience with the European Payments Union (EPU) played hereby a crucial role.
    [Show full text]
  • Post-War Reconstruction and Development in the Golden Age of Capitalism
    Chapter II Post-war reconstruction and development in the Golden Age of Capitalism Key messages • The World Economic and Social Survey was an early proponent of development as a process of large-scale struc- tural and institutional change for the promotion of high standards of living, full employment and social progress. Starting from the first edition, issued in January 1948, the Survey recognized the need for coordinated interna- tional action to accelerate economic growth, facilitate the cross-border flow of goods and services and support effective utilization of resources in the context of an expanding and integrated world economy. • The expansion of international trade and a functioning payments system were recognized as two critical factors for development in the post-Second World War period. However, large fluctuations in commodity prices and, cor- respondingly, in foreign exchange earnings were a source of economic instability for many developing countries back then and this has continued to be the case right up to the present. • In the 1950s, the flexibility that European countries were afforded in meeting their International Monetary Fund- related obligations enabled the successful creation of the multilateral international payments system. Six years after the initial commitment, most Western Europe countries had eliminated foreign exchange restrictions and established current account convertibility. A similar flexibility in debt negotiations was important for the facilita- tion of a rapid recovery in Europe in the post-Second World War period as well as in Latin America in the 1930s. • International solidarity has played an important role in development and reconstruction. Western European countries received resources equivalent to 1 per cent of the gross national product of the United States of Amer- ica in the period from 1948 to 1952 through the Marshall Plan.
    [Show full text]
  • German Monetary Policy in the Second Half of the Twentieth Century
    German Monetary History in the Second Half of the Twentieth Century: From the Deutsche Mark to the Euro Robert L. Hetzel tarting in January 2002, citizens of the European Monetary Union (EMU) replaced their national currencies with the Euro, issued by the S European Central Bank (ECB). Europeans created a new pan-European central bank as a symbol of a future united Europe. However, what historical process explains the broad monetary policy of the ECB, that is, its objective of price stability and its strategy for achieving that objective? The short answer is that its founders designed the ECB to look like the Bundesbank. How then did the Bundesbank evolve? To answer that question, I survey German monetary policy in the second half of the twentieth century. I divide this history into three main sections.1 The first treats the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates. The second treats the floating exchange rate period that began in 1973. It chronicles the Bundesbank’s ultimate deci- sion to accord primacy to reducing inflation rather than unemployment. The last explains how the Bundesbank dealt with the pressures created by move- ment toward a single European currency. The evolution of the Bundesbank into an institution now identified as a modern central bank is fundamental to the article. A modern central bank This article follows Hetzel (2002), which summarizes German monetary policy in the first half of the twentieth century. The author gratefully acknowledges helpful comments from Michael Dotsey, Martin M. Fase, Andreas Hornstein, Thomas Humphrey, Joachim Scheide, and Alex Wolman. The views expressed in this article are those of the author and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Aspects of European Monetary Integration After World War II By
    Political Aspects of European Monetary Integration After World War II by Horst Ungerer* Paper presented on Mag 13, 1995. ECSA Conference, Charleston S.C. I. After World War II, an all-encompassing effort was undertaken to eliminate for the future the risk of war between European countries which twice in this century had spread to the whole world. From the beginning, also economic cooperation arid monetary integration were politically motivated--by tying the European countries together in a common institutional framework and by rebuilding their economies in a mutual coordinated effort. The objective was to avert large-scale social misery, in the past a fertile breeding ground for' nationalistic and antagonistic feelings and policies. As the Cold War started to unfold, another important reason was to strengthen resistance to communism in Western Europe. Yet, the history of European economic cooperation and monetary integration is most frequently described and analayzed in economic terms. The expansion of foreign trade and the removal of custom barriers, the elimination of payment restrictions and the granting of credit lines lend themselves more easily to description and analysis in quantitative terms. Improved political cooperation and stability and the overcoming of political rivalry eludes precise analysis. Policies to rebuild the war-shattered economies of Europe concentrated on the onehand on the creation of a world-wide economic order by establishing the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade(GATT), as a stand-in for the never realized International Trade Organization, and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development . (the World Bank) which initially was mainly intended to assist in the rebuilding of the European economies.
    [Show full text]
  • Quaderni Dell'ufficio Ricerche Storiche
    Quaderni dell’Ufficio Ricerche Storiche Italy and the Political Economy of Cooperation: the Marshall Plan and the European Payments Union by Juan Carlos Martinez Oliva Number 6 - April 2003 The purpose of the Quaderni dell’Ufficio Ricerche Storiche is to promote the circulation of working papers prepared within the Bank of Italy or presented in Bank seminars by outside speakers with the aim of stimulating comments and suggestions. The views expressed in the articles are those of the authors and do not involve the responsibility of the Bank. Editorial Board: FILIPPO CESARANO, SERGIO CARDARELLI, STEFANO FENOALTEA, ALFREDO GIGLIOBIANCO, JUAN CARLOS MARTINEZ OLIVA; GIULIANA FERRETTI (Editorial Assistant). ITALY AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF COOPERATION: THE MARSHALL PLAN AND THE EUROPEAN PAYMENTS UNION by Juan Carlos Martinez Oliva* Abstract Following the Second World War the Marshall Plan backed the creation of the Organization for European Economic Cooperation, which led in 1950 to the European Payments Union. Thanks to well-engineered rules, the Union fulfilled its mandate, achieving currency convertibility and trade liberalization in Europe in only eight years. This paper examines the orientations of Italian policy-makers in that early period of European cooperation. Various historical sources, including some newly released official documents, show that in those years Italy's leaders aimed at closer European cooperation and integration. They viewed cooperation as the way to institute a fair, non-discriminatory set of rules that would attenuate differences among countries; whenever possible, however, they also sought to further domestic purposes and maintain a reasonable degree of independence. Relations with the United States were particularly intense in those years, reflecting Italy's need for economic assistance and political support and the central role of the US at the early stage of European cooperation.
    [Show full text]