Clayton Act Against Monopolization by Tying, 287 Dealership, 256

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Clayton Act Against Monopolization by Tying, 287 Dealership, 256 Cambridge University Press 052179031X - Antitrust Law: Economic Theory and Common Law Evolution Keith N. Hylton Index More information Index A.A.Poultry Farms, Inc.v.Rose Acre Clayton Act against Farms, Inc., 216–18 monopolization by tying, 287 abusive business, 167, 171 dealership, 256, 260, 264 conduct-focused test of, 187, 188, exclusivity, 262–4 188n13, 193 inference doctrine development intent to monopolize for, 187, 188, for, 132–40, 145 193, 194 inferred versus not, 141 refusal to deal by, 187, 247 Interstate circuit and, 133–8 Section 2 violation for, 188, 190 noncompete, 33–4, 100, 103, 257, access. See also essential facility 264 local association, 180 resale price, 269 problems of open, 208–11 termination of (vertical restraints), up-front fee for, 212 270–1, 272–3, 275–6 acquittals, false, 130–1, 189, 214, 220, unilateral contract theory for, 351, 375 138–40, 158 administrative concerns unilateral contract theory rejection courts errors and, 130–1 for, 140–3, 158 economic reasonableness v., vertical restraint, 270–8 xiii–xv, 92, 106–7, 116, 171 vertical restraints and exclusivity, per-se rule and, 122 262–4 Administrative Procedure Act, 48 airline industry, as example of adverse selection, 5–6, 24 parallel pricing, 73 Aghion, Phillipe, 199n30, 200–1 Akerlof, George, 24–5 agreement(s), 28, 75, 132–3, 222 Albrecht v.The Herald Co., 123n17, to boycott, 166, 168, 169–70, 184 262, 262n21, 262n23, 273, cheating on collusive, 145, 153–4 277 379 © Cambridge University Press www.cambridge.org Cambridge University Press 052179031X - Antitrust Law: Economic Theory and Common Law Evolution Keith N. Hylton Index More information 380 Index Alcoa.See United States v.Aluminum Associated Press v.United States, Co.of America (Alcoa) 177–81, 182, 184, 208–10 Allied Tube & Conduit Corp.v. association Indian Head, Inc., 361–3, 366 dissemination of information and, allocation 146–9 horizontal, 126 as extragovernmental agency, 170, territorial, 118, 119 171, 179–80 Ambook Enterprises v.Time, 141n26 new competition practice of, 146 American Column & Lumber Co.v. price fixing in, 106, 118–19, 121 United States, 145–9, 149–52, price-setting cooperative, 120 154 product standard setting by American Tobacco Growers, Inc.v. private, 361–2 Neal, 208, 210, 211 protection of access for local, 180 American Tobacco v.United States, restraint of trade and bylaws of, 77, 139–40, 158, 195 177–8 anticompetitive theory veto in, 178, 180, 181 tying, after Chicago School and, Atlantic Richfield Co.(ARCO) v. 281–3, 288 USA Petroleum Co., 218, tying and difficulty with, 307–10 262n23 tying, Chicago School and, 279–81 atomism, 40, 190 vertical mergers and, 335 perfect competition and, 4, 8 Antitrust Division. See Justice attempt, at monopolization Department Clayton Act and, 287 antitrust law. See also Clayton Act; dangerous probability requirement Sherman Act of, 244–5, 246, 248–51, 263 Antitrust Paradox (Bork), xii definition of, 244 Appalachian Coals v.United States, evidence, objective, in, 245, 250 107–9, 111 evidence of unfair tactics in, 247, apprehension 249 enforcement and probability of, exclusion of competitors with, 247 50, 51 right/refusal to deal in, 246–8, Areeda, Philip, 220–1, 230, 248n15 246n7, 263–4 Arizona v.Maricopa County Medical specific intent of, 245, 246, 247–51 Society, 122–5, 122n17, 126n23 the Swift formula and modern Arrow-Hart & Hegman Electric Co.v. doctrine of, 244–8 FTC, 318n24 violation of, 244 ASCAP, 120–2 attorneys’ fees, and deterrence, 58 Aspen Skiing Co.v.Aspen Highlands author, opinion of, xi Skiing Corp., 203–6, 207, 210, Automatic Radio Mfg.Co, v.Ford 228, 231n2 Motor Co., 295n42 © Cambridge University Press www.cambridge.org Cambridge University Press 052179031X - Antitrust Law: Economic Theory and Common Law Evolution Keith N. Hylton Index More information Index 381 Bain, Joe, 16 Associate Press and, 177–81 bargaining, 159–60, 342–3 competition effected by, 170–1, barriers, 23. See also entry 174–5 artificial (privately created), 15–16 conspiracy’s proof/rule of reason natural barrier to, 16 for, 166, 167, 168, 169–70 Barry Wright Corp.v.ITT Grinnell direct-selling wholesalers, retailers Corp., xv, 199n32, 214–15, 219, and, 167 224 efficiency defenses for, 176 basing point pricing, 81 eliminating of firms by, 174–6 cases, 155–9 exclusionary plan and, 173–4, 177, competition and, 162–5 180 cross-hauling and, 162 exclusions, rule of reason and, definition of, 154–5 181–2 delivered pricing system and, free option arrangement, members 158–9, 161–2 and, 167–8 economics, 160–5 Klor’s paradox, boycott doctrine and kinked demand curve, 163 and, 174–7 freight absorption and, 162 no effect on competition and, most favored customer clause and, 172–4 159–60 in noncompetitive political arena, per-se rule not, 158–9, 164 359, 360, 363–4, 365, 366, 369 Bauer & Cie v.O’Donnell, 261 per-se rule and, 166, 169–70, 171, Becker, Gary, 44 173, 177, 179–82, 184, 185 Bendix Corp., 348–9, 350 post-BMI/Sylvania and, 172, 181–5 benefit, potential competition, 345 post-Socony, 170–7 Berkey Photo v.Eastman Kodak Co., pre-Socony, 166–70 203 price-fixing, 169, 171 Bertrand, Joseph, 76–7, 76n15, 83–5, proof versus conspiracy to, 171 150 public harm and, 173–6, 184 Blair, Roger, xvi restriction of distributors freedom blanket license arrangement, 120–1 prohibited in, 168–9 block booking, 292 rule of reason and, 166–70, 173–4, BMI. See Broadcast Music Inc.v. 182, 183, 184–5 Columbia Broadcasting System brand loyalty, 73 Bobbs-Merrill Co.v.Strauss , 261, brand name, 25–6 261n19 Brandeis, Justice, 148, 152 Bolton, Patrick, 199n30, 200–1 Breyer, Judge, 215 boycotts, 29, 155, 157, 166, 168, 169–70 Breyer, Justice, xv agreement to, 166, 168, 169–70, bribes, 8, 358, 367, 369 184, 264 bright line rule, 215, 220–1, 320 © Cambridge University Press www.cambridge.org Cambridge University Press 052179031X - Antitrust Law: Economic Theory and Common Law Evolution Keith N. Hylton Index More information 382 Index Broadcast Music Inc.(BMI) v. buyers Columbia Broadcasting System, lying by, 72 120–2, 124–5, 128–9, 166, 172, 182, 184, 289 California Motor Transport Co.v. Brooke Group Ltd.v.Brown & Trucking Unlimited, 356–7, 363, Williamson Tobacco Corp., 214, 368–71 219 California Retail Liquor Dealers Assn Brown Shoe Co.v.United States, 311, v.Midcal Aluminum, 372, 374 318–20, 321, 322, 323, 325, 327, California v.American Stores Co., 338–41 55n24 Brunswick Corp.v.Pueblo Bowl-O- California.v.ARC , 63n40 Mat,63 cartels, 18n13, 99n17. See also Buffalo Courier-Express, Inc.v. boycotts; collusion Buffalo Evening News, Inc., basic theory of, 68–71 217n64 collusion and, 69–73 Bureau of Competition, 48, 50n10 conscious parallelism for, 73–89 Bureau of Consumer Protection, 48 conspiracy doctrine, conscious Bureau of Economics, 50n10 parallelism and, 75, 87, 89 Burger, Justice, 119 cooperative elements of, 122 business. See also corporation enforcement, 70–1, 87–8, 136, 146, anticipation by, 76 337 capacity constrained, 115 inferring conspiracy for, 87–9 failure of competitor, 320, 327, 339 influence government for internal capital market for, 312, regulated price by, 367 312n7 informal exchange relationships in, lack of resources of, 320 71 larger relationship to smaller, 204, instability of, 68–9, 76n14, 159, 160, 320 216 material reserves for, 327–8 interdependence theory and, 76–7, protection of small, 40–2, 192–3, 81–2, 86, 87 320–1, 323, 339 intraenterprise conspiracy and, 74, right/refusal to deal in, 246–8, 78–80 246n7, 263–4, 270 lying by buyers of, 72 risk taking compensation for, market share of, 72 231–2, 269–70, 293, 295 monitoring of, 71–3, 86, 87–8, 136 self-dealing in, 337 output versus price agreements size, 188, 190, 193, 204 with, 72 vertically integrated, 203 price-fixing, 17–18, 62, 68–9, 80n27, Business Electronics v.Sharp 87, 107–8, 253, 256, 338 Electronics, 275–7 sales, 107–8 © Cambridge University Press www.cambridge.org Cambridge University Press 052179031X - Antitrust Law: Economic Theory and Common Law Evolution Keith N. Hylton Index More information Index 383 stable, 71n3, 73 rule of reason and, 305, 317 casebook, drawback of, xi Section 7, competition CBS, 120–1, 128 substantially reduced and, 56–7, Cellophane.See United States v.E.I. 318, 319–20, 322, 323, 325, 330, du Pont De Nemours & Co. 335, 338, 339, 347, 350 (Cellophane) Sherman Act and, 47, 54 Cement Institute.See Federal Trade stock transfers and, 318, 335, Commission v.Cement Institute 335n9, 336 Cement Manufacturers Protective tying and, 285–6, 290, 293, 294 Assn. v.United States, 167–9, vertical mergers and, 335–6 171–2, 178, 181 Cline v.Frink Dairy Co,31 Central Shade Roller Co.v.Cushman, Clorox.See Federal Trade 101n20 Commission v.Proctor & chain-store paradox, 225–6, 226n76 Gamble Co.(Clorox) , 344–8 Chamberlain, Edward, 22, 75n12, 76 Coase, Ronald, 8, 242–3, 333, 341–2 Chicago Board of Trade v.United Coke, Edward, 36 States, 104–7, 108, 109, 109n37, collusion, 68–9, 222 111–12, 116, 117, 119, 126–8, avoidance of per-se rule in, 117 129, 153, 172, 174, 183, 184, brand loyalty and, 73 267n41, 365n24 cartels and, 69–73 Chicago School, 280–1, 308 cheating on agreement of, 145, City of Columbia v.Omni Outdoor 153–4 Advertising, 367, 369, 377 circumstantial evidence for, 73, 133 Clayton Act, 30, 39–40 concentration and, 156, 312 amendments to, 318, 335, 338 enforcement of, 70–1, 87–8 against attempt of monopolization, evidence and, 135 287, 304, 307 explicit versus tacit, 145 commodities affected by, 290, lying by buyers in, 72 290n29, 293, 294 monitoring of, 72–3, 153 consumer protection with, 320, one-shot versus repeat-player, 349–50 70–1, 96 exclusive dealing and, 303, 304 retail price maintenance, 253 fine/punishment of, 47, 48–9, 52 stable versus instability of, 69–70, horizontal mergers and, 318, 320 71n3, 135 injunctions under, 55, 55n24, 56 tacit, 73–4, 75, 76–7, 85, 86–8, injury requirement of, 218 88n39, 140, 145, 149, 153, 219 private actions, treble damages and trigger strategy, 77 and, 58, 60 tying facilitating of, 283 protection of small businesses vertical mergers facilitation of, with, 320 337–8, 337n12, 340 © Cambridge University Press www.cambridge.org Cambridge University Press 052179031X - Antitrust Law: Economic Theory and Common Law Evolution Keith N.
Recommended publications
  • Building a Conceptual Theory of Anti-Competition Laws in Public-Private Partnerships
    Building a conceptual theory of anti-competition laws in public-private partnerships By Joshua Edgar B.A., Kansas State University, 2017 A THESIS Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree MASTER OF ARTS Department of Political Science College of Arts and Sciences KANSAS STATE UNIVERSITY Manhattan, Kansas 2021 Approved by: Major Professor Dr. Brianne Heidbreder COPYRIGHT ©Joshua Edgar 2021 Abstract The growing economic presence of public-private partnerships in the market has led to an increased monopolization and subsequent reduction in competition in sectors such as infrastructure, utilities, and health services. Much of this can be contributed to the principal- agent problems that arise between the government and its constituents. Previous research has demonstrated the strain that anti-competitive practices place on the market, but little research on competition has been directed towards understanding how the active participation of public sector actors affect competition when in league with their private sector counterparts. Using data from public-private infrastructure projects in the United States, a monte carlo test on public-private infrastructure expenditures, the data of which is then set into a cooperative game-theory to determine changes in the public actor’s preferential outcome in the presence of increased risk. This quantitative analysis is then placed within a conceptual framework which demonstrates that many of the principal-agent problems can be overcome by the inclusion of anti-completion regulations.
    [Show full text]
  • Public-Private Divide in Parker State-Action Immunity Sina Safvati
    Public-Private Divide in Parker State-Action Immunity EVIEW R Sina Safvati ABSTRACT LA LAW LA LAW C The U.S. Supreme Court’s jurisprudence on Parker state-action immunity from federal U antitrust laws has remained largely muddled since its inception. The Court recently attempted to bring clarity to the doctrine in North Carolina Board of Dental Examiners v. FTC, holding that state occupational licensing boards with a controlling number of active market participants are subject to the same active supervision requirement as private actors performing state governmental functions. Given that most state licensing boards are comprised of active market participants in the industry they are charged with regulating, state licensing boards can no longer assume they are immune from antitrust suits. In response, states have been scrambling to reassess the composition and oversight of their regulatory bodies in order to reduce antitrust liability for board members. In addition, litigants are bringing more claims against these boards for alleged antitrust violations. Lower courts are left with the task of determining whether these boards are closer to private actors or to prototypical state agencies. For those boards classified as private, lower courts are left with the task of determining whether the regulatory regimes overseeing the boards’ anticompetitive conduct satisfy the active supervision requirement. In light of these rapid developments, however, doctrinal confusion about Parker immunity persists. This confusion largely stems from the Court’s failure to formally adopt a rule of decision incorporating the two bedrock principles that have explained Parker immunity doctrine since its inception: financial disinterest and political accountability.
    [Show full text]
  • Plain Ambiguities in the Clear Articulation Requirement for State Action Antitrust Immunity: the Ac Se of State Agencies C Douglas Floyd
    Boston College Law Review Volume 41 Article 2 Issue 5 Number 5 9-1-2000 Plain Ambiguities in the Clear Articulation Requirement for State Action Antitrust Immunity: The aC se of State Agencies C Douglas Floyd Follow this and additional works at: http://lawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/bclr Part of the Administrative Law Commons, and the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons Recommended Citation C D. Floyd, Plain Ambiguities in the Clear Articulation Requirement for State Action Antitrust Immunity: The Case of State Agencies, 41 B.C.L. Rev. 1059 (2000), http://lawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/bclr/vol41/iss5/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at Digital Commons @ Boston College Law School. It has been accepted for inclusion in Boston College Law Review by an authorized editor of Digital Commons @ Boston College Law School. For more information, please contact [email protected]. PLAIN AMBIGUITIES IN THE CLEAR ARTICULATION REQUIREMENT FOR STATE. ACTION ANTITRUST IMMUNITY: THE CASE OF STATE AGENCIES C. DOUGLAS FLOYD* Abstract: This Article focuses on the application of the state action antitrust inimunity doctrine of Parker v. Brown to the regulatory programs of state administrative agencies having statewide jurisdiction. It concludes that state agencies should be subject to significantly different requirements for antitrust immunity than are local governmental units. This Article also addresses unresolved issues that frequently recur in the context of state administrative action, such as the effect of retroactive intetpretations of state policy by a state agency, whether the clear articulation and active supervision requirements for antitrust immunity play any separate role in the context of administrative policy making, and whether any distinctions should be drawn among the processes of rulemaking, adjudication, and tariff approval in applying the Parker doctrine.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Act Report Full
    Appendix A. Antitrust Timeline [00.16.3] [08.14] [01.1] [01.3] [02.1] [02.1] [01.6] [02.2] [02.1] [01.7] [01.8] [01.9] [08.8] [01.10] [08.3] [01.15] [01.11] [08.9] [01.12] [08.11] [01.13] [02.1] [02.1] [08.20] [01.14] [02.1] [08.15] [08.20] [02.1] [08.17] [08.21] [08.1] [02.1] [08.21] [08.1] [08.21] [08.5] [08.7] [08.16] [08.4] [08.10] [08.13] [08.19] [08.12] [08.18] Appendix B. Case Annotations For more comprehensive summaries and additional case summaries, please visit the research database accompanying this report at: https://drive.google.com/drive/u/1/folders/0B- Sc0KR7f1Flflpub09BUmtoNWJzTzhrbGV0YlFJSVJzdkE3RmNWNmFiSm5MVV9tOFFiT2s In chronological order: United States v E.C. Knight Co (1895), 156 US 1 The United States claimed that, in order for the American Sugar Refining Company to obtain complete control of the price of sugar in the United States, that the company, and John E. Searles, Jr., acting for it, entered into an unlawful and fraudulent scheme to purchase the stock, machinery, and real estate of the other four corporations defendant for the purpose of restraining interstate trade. It was found that on or about March 4, 1892, Searles entered into contracts with the defendant Knight Company, the Spreckels Company, the Franklin Company and with the Delaware Sugar House [p3]. The argument is that the power to control the manufacturing of refined sugar is a monopoly over a necessary of life, to the enjoyment of which by a large part of the population of the United States interstate commerce is indispensable, and that, therefore, the general government, in the exercise of the power to regulate commerce, may repress such monopoly directly, and set aside the instruments which have created it [p12].
    [Show full text]
  • State Action Antitrust Exemption Collides with Deregulation: Rehabilitating the Foreseeability Doctrine
    Texas A&M University School of Law Texas A&M Law Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 1-2006 State Action Antitrust Exemption Collides with Deregulation: Rehabilitating the Foreseeability Doctrine Elizabeth Trujillo Texas A&M University School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/facscholar Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Energy and Utilities Law Commons, and the Law and Economics Commons Recommended Citation Elizabeth Trujillo, State Action Antitrust Exemption Collides with Deregulation: Rehabilitating the Foreseeability Doctrine, 11 Fordham J. Corp. & Fin. L. 349 (2006). Available at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/facscholar/796 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Texas A&M Law Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Texas A&M Law Scholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. STATE ACTION ANTITRUST EXEMPTION COLLIDES WITH DEREGULATION: REHABILITATING THE FORESEEABILITY DOCTRINE Elizabeth Trujillo* INTRODUCTION A capitalist society with policies established to "regulate" the promotion of competition in traditionally regulated industries such as the electrical market seems counterintuitive. Yet, it is a reality in the United States. In particular, traditionally rate-regulated industries, such as electricity, have been "deregulated." In this context, deregulation means opening up certain components of the industry to competition. However, regulatory mechanisms in place to prevent abuses of the competitive process are also driving this competition, resulting in a "regulated deregulation." 1 Specifically, recent initiatives to "deregulate" the electricity markets have highlighted that free markets thrive where competitive * Visiting Professor, Florida State University College of Law, 2005-2006; Assistant Professor of Law, University of Detroit Mercy School of Law.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust and Democracy: a Case Study from German Fascism
    University of Michigan Law School University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository Law & Economics Working Papers 4-17-2018 Antitrust and Democracy: A Case Study from German Fascism Daniel A. Crane University of Michigan - Ann Arbor, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/law_econ_current Part of the Law and Economics Commons Working Paper Citation Crane, Daniel A., "Antitrust and Democracy: A Case Study from German Fascism" (2018). Law & Economics Working Papers. 155. https://repository.law.umich.edu/law_econ_current/155 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Law & Economics Working Papers by an authorized administrator of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Crane: ANTITRUST AND DEMOCRACY: A CASE STUDY FROM GERMAN FASCISM Daniel A. Crane† Nearly forty years ago, Bob Pitofsky wrote, in his classic article The Political Content of Antitrust, that it is “bad history, bad policy, and bad law to exclude certain political values in interpreting the antitrust laws.”1 Pitofsky argued that pervasive monopoly threatened democratic values in three ways: “[F]irst, . excessive concentration of economic power will breed antidemocratic political pressures . [S]econd, . individual and business freedom [can be enhanced] by reducing the range within which private discretion by a few in the economic
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Act Report Full
    The Sherman Antitrust Act and the Profession of Architecture Peggy Deamer May, 2016 Index I. Introduction II. Antitrust Laws: Histories A. General B. The Professions C. Architecture III. Antitrust Laws: Concepts Consent Decrees, Codes of Ethics, and the Learned Profession IV. Probes A. The Learned Profession Exemption B. The State Exemption C. The Differing Professions D. The Political Nature of Antitrust Rulings V. Legal Forms of Moderating Fees and Wages and Modifying Competition A. 3rd Party Surveys B. Legislation C. Unions VI. Conclusion VII. Appendix A. Antitrust Timeline B. Case Annotations C. AIA Consent Decree 1972 (with letter) D. AIA Consent Decree 1990 E. AIA Statement of Services & Charges of the Architect (1960) F. 2002 AIA Antitrust Compliance Guidelines G. Glossary of Antitrust Terms H. Bibliography I. Introduction This is a report on how antitrust laws have affected the architectural profession. This research was motivated by the thought that the American Institute of Architects (AIA) and the profession of architecture in general have been more negatively affected by antitrust law than the other professions. It seemed that large law firms, for example, agree on a certain salary for associates, ostensibly wage collusion under antitrust law; and realtors seemed to have an “understood” 6% fee structure, ostensibly fee collusion.1 Was it the case that the two antitrust proceedings against the AIA in 1972 and 1990 - which penalized the AIA for inhibiting competition among member architects - had made the profession more conservative with regard to discussion of fees and wages than had other proceedings affecting other professions? Having learned from Robert Ivy, CEO of AIA National, that these consent decrees were the reason that the AIA could not be more aggressive in advocating for higher architectural fees, this was a pertinent question.
    [Show full text]
  • Does Competition Ordinance Result in Consumer Protection
    Does Competition Ordinance Result In Consumer Protection By Qaiser Javed Mian (Director Research/Faculty member Punjab Judicial Academy) There can be “prohibited” anti-competitive behaviour and there can be “permitted” anti-competitive behaviour. In U.SA, what is called Anti-Trust Law, in other Countries, it is called Competition Law and/or Anti-Monopoly Law 1 and/or Consumer Protection Law. According to Philip Areeda, U.S. Anti-Trust Law, “…contains a basic distinction between concerted and “independent” 2 action” , which in other words refers to distinction between “single – firm” and “multi-firm” conduct in the context of “encouraging competition”, and save the “businesses” and/or “consumers”. Antitrust law seeks fair competition on the belief that “free trade” benefits not only the consumer, but also the economy and business. The restraints imposed by this law can be divided into four categories: (i) agreements between competitors (ii) contractual arrangements between sellers and buyers (iii) creating and maintaining of monopoly power, and (iv) mergers. While U.S.A has “The Sherman Antitrust Act” (1890)” named for Senator Johan Sherman as a first measure passed by the U.S. Congress to “regulate interstate commerce” as well, Clayton Act, 1914) and “Robinson Patman Act (1936)”, Pakistan had “Monopolies And Restrictive Trade Practices (Control And Prevention) Ordinance, (V of 1970)”, Competition Ordinance (LII of 2007)” as amended from time to time and “The Punjab Consumer Protection Act (Pb. Act II of 2005)” while the other Provinces have not yet started applying Consumer Protection Law. India promulgated “The Consumer Protection Act, 1986” and Rules 1987 which includes “goods” as well as “services”.
    [Show full text]
  • Cartels & Leniency 2019
    ICLG The International Comparative Legal Guide to: Cartels & Leniency 2019 12th Edition A practical cross-border insight into cartels and leniency Published by Global Legal Group, with contributions from: AGON PARTNERS King & Wood Mallesons AKD Mamo TCV Advocates Aramis MinterEllisonRuddWatts Arnold & Porter Kaye Scholer LLP ML Abogados Bán, S. Szabó & Partners Morais Leitão, Galvão Teles, Soares da Silva & Borenius Attorneys Ltd Associados, R. L. Cassels Brock & Blackwell LLP Nagashima Ohno & Tsunematsu Crowell & Moring Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP Cyril Amarchand Mangaldas Preslmayr Rechtsanwälte OG Debarliev Dameski & Kelesoska, Attorneys at Law Rahmat Lim & Partners Drew & Napier LLC Shearman & Sterling LLP ELIG Gürkaynak Attorneys-at-Law Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom LLP Hannes Snellman Wilmer Cutler Pickering Hale and Dorr LLP The International Comparative Legal Guide to: Cartels & Leniency 2019 General Chapters: 1 Cartel Updates: Recent Trends in Fine Calculations and Cartel Liability – Elvira Aliende Rodriguez & Geert Goeteyn, Shearman & Sterling LLP 1 2 The Proposed Whistleblowers Directive – Ingrid Vandenborre & Thorsten Goetz, Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom LLP 6 Contributing Editors 3 Navigating the Tensions Between Leniency Cooperation and the Risk of Private Follow-On Geert Goeteyn, Matthew Damage Claims in Cartel Cases – Niels Ersbøll & Jane Wessel, Arnold & Porter Kaye Scholer LLP 12 Readings & Elvira Aliende Rodriguez, Shearman & 4 Disincentives to Leniency: Expect Fewer Golden Eggs if You Harass the Goose – Frédéric Louis, Sterling LLP Wilmer Cutler Pickering Hale and Dorr LLP 18 Sales Director Florjan Osmani Country Question and Answer Chapters: Account Director 5 Australia King & Wood Mallesons: Sharon Henrick & Wayne Leach 23 Oliver Smith Sales Support Manager 6 Austria Preslmayr Rechtsanwälte OG: Dieter Hauck 33 Toni Hayward 7 Belgium Crowell & Moring: Thomas De Meese 40 Sub Editor Oliver Chang 8 Canada Cassels Brock & Blackwell LLP: W.
    [Show full text]
  • Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards up Close Rebecca Haw Allensworth
    Vanderbilt University Law School Scholarship@Vanderbilt Law Vanderbilt Law School Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship 2017 Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards Up Close Rebecca Haw Allensworth Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.vanderbilt.edu/faculty-publications Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, and the Commercial Law Commons Recommended Citation Rebecca Haw Allensworth, Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards Up Close, 105 California Law Review. 1567 (2017) Available at: https://scholarship.law.vanderbilt.edu/faculty-publications/11 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Scholarship@Vanderbilt Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Vanderbilt Law School Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of Scholarship@Vanderbilt Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. +(,1 2 1/,1( Citation: Rebecca Haw Allensworth, Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards up Close, 105 Cal. L. Rev. 1567 (2017) Provided by: Vanderbilt University Law School Content downloaded/printed from HeinOnline Mon Feb 5 15:44:56 2018 -- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and Conditions of the license agreement available at http://heinonline.org/HOL/License -- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text. -- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your HeinOnline license, please use: Copyright Information
    [Show full text]
  • 1-Allensworth-34.Pdf
    California Law Review VOL. 105 DECEMBER 2017 NO. 6 Copyright © 2017 by California Law Review, Inc., a California Nonprofit Corporation Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards Up Close Rebecca Haw Allensworth* The dark side of occupational licensing—its tendency to raise prices to consumers with dubious effects on service quality, its enormous payout to licensees, and its ability to shut many willing workers out of the workforce—has begun to receive significant attention. But little has been said about the legal institutions that create and administer this web of professional entry and practice rules. State-level licensing boards regulate nearly one-third of American workers, yet, until now, there has been no systematic attempt to understand who serves on these boards and how they operate. This Article undertakes an ambitious and comprehensive study of all 1,790 licensing boards in the U.S. and identifies their statutory membership. The results are clear: nearly all of them are controlled by professionals holding a license issued by the board itself. DOI: https://dx.doi.org/10.15779/Z38CJ87K75 Copyright © 2017 California Law Review, Inc. California Law Review, Inc. (CLR) is a California nonprofit corporation. CLR and the authors are solely responsible for the content of their publications. * Professor of Law, Vanderbilt Law School; J.D., Harvard Law School; M.Phil, University of Cambridge; B.A., Yale University. Thank you to Lora Chowdhury, Laura Dolbow, Demetrios Festa, Francesco Forin, Janelle Grigaitis, Michael Moore, Stephanie Onyekwere, Jason Palmer, and Carolyn Webb for excellent research assistance. Thank you to Andrea Alexander for managing the empirical project, and to Francesco Forin for extensive help with citations and editing.
    [Show full text]
  • Judicial Review As Midcal Active Supervision: Immunizing Private Parties from Antitrust Liability
    Fordham Law Review Volume 57 Issue 3 Article 3 1988 Judicial Review as Midcal Active Supervision: Immunizing Private Parties from Antitrust Liability Michal Dlouhy Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/flr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Michal Dlouhy, Judicial Review as Midcal Active Supervision: Immunizing Private Parties from Antitrust Liability, 57 Fordham L. Rev. 403 (1988). Available at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/flr/vol57/iss3/3 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. It has been accepted for inclusion in Fordham Law Review by an authorized editor of FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. For more information, please contact [email protected]. NOTES JUDICIAL REVIEW AS MIDCAL ACTIVE SUPERVISION: IMMUNIZING PRIVATE PARTIES FROM ANTITRUST LIABILITY INTRODUCTION The Parker v. Brown' state action doctrine2 may immunize3 a private party4 from liability under federal antitrust laws.5 Private conduct is im- mune, however, only when it satisfies the two-pronged test developed in CaliforniaRetail Liquor Dealers Ass'n v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc.6 The challenged conduct must be pursuant to a "clearly articulated and affirm- atively expressed" state policy, and it must be " 'actively supervised' by 1. 317 U.S. 341 (1943) (immunizing actions of a raisin cartel from liability under the Sherman Act, 26 Stat. 209 (1890) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7 (1982 & Supp. IV 1986))). 2. The Parker state action doctrine provides that the Sherman Act was not intended to restrain state action or official action directed by a state.
    [Show full text]