World Trade Organization Trade Policy Substitution: Theory and Evidence from Specific Trade Concerns

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

World Trade Organization Trade Policy Substitution: Theory and Evidence from Specific Trade Concerns Staff Working Paper ERSD-2014-18 Date: 29 October 2014 World Trade Organization Economic Research and Statistics Division Trade Policy Substitution: Theory and Evidence from Specific Trade Concerns Cosimo Beverelli (Economic Research Division, WTO) Mauro Boffa (GSEM, University of Geneva) Alexander Keck (Economic Research Division, WTO) Manuscript date: 29 October 2014 Disclaimer: This is a working paper, and hence it represents research in progress. The opinions expressed in this paper should be attributed to its authors. They are not meant to represent the positions or opinions of the WTO and its Members and are without prejudice to Members' rights and obligations under the WTO. Any errors are attributable to the authors. Trade Policy Substitution: Theory and Evidence from Specific Trade Concerns* Cosimo Beverelli Mauro Boffa Alexander Keck Abstract We investigate to what extent the probability that a Specific Trade Concern (STC) is raised in the WTO against a Member in a given sector is affected by past reductions in applied tariffs. Employing an identification strategy based on `new measures', we find evidence of a substitution of non-tariff measures for tariffs both in the sample of TBT and in the sample of SPS concerns. While in the SPS sample this result holds both among developed and developing economies, in the TBT sample such `trade policy substitution' only occurs when the country maintaining the measure at issue is economically developed. These results are consistent with our theoretical model, which predicts policy substitution between tariffs and standards in economies where meeting such standards is relatively less costly and in sectors where meeting such standards is relatively more important from the perspective of producers. Keywords: Import, International Trade Agreements, Non Tariff, Tariff, WTO JEL Classification: F13, F14, F15 *This is a working paper, and hence it represents research in progress. The opinions expressed in this paper should be attributed to its authors. They are not meant to represent the positions or opinions of the WTO and its Members and are without prejudice to Members' rights and obligations under the WTO. Any errors are attributable to the authors. Without implicating them, we thank Marc Bacchetta, Marcelo Olarreaga, Lorenzo Rotunno and participants at the Fifth Research Workshop on International Trade (Villars, 6-7 February 2014) and at the Trade Agreements Workshop (KU Leuven, 14-15 March 2014) for valuable comments and suggestions. Economic Research Division, World Trade Organization. Rue de Lausanne 154, CH-1211, Geneva, Switzerland. E-mail: [email protected] (corresponding author); [email protected]. GSEM, University of Geneva. Bd. du Pont d'Arve 40, CH-1211 Geneva, Switzerland. E-mail: mauro.boff[email protected]. 1 Introduction Through successive waves of liberalization, tariffs have steadily dropped over the years both in industrial and developing countries (WTO, 2007; Milner, 2013; Bown, 2014). Having constrained this traditional instrument of import protection, countries may be inclined to pursue trade policy objectives through non-tariff measures (NTMs). Unlike tariffs, such measures may have a dual purpose: NTMs may be designed or administered in ways that intentionally restrict trade even if their declared purpose is to serve a public policy goal (WTO, 2012). For example, a technical product requirement may be introduced to prevent the importation and marketing of products considered unsafe for consumption, but it may also be targeted at undoing some of the impact of opening up to trade on the domestic industry. The use of NTMs to replace, at least in part, former levels of tariff protection can be defined as `trade policy substitution'. We develop a model that can explain the occurrence of policy substitution when tariffs come down, but also allows for the possibility of policy complementarity, whereby NTMs would be positively correlated with tariffs. In the baseline version of the model, NTMs such as product standards unambiguously increase the firm’s marginal production costs. Whether a domestic firm prefers standards to be tightened or loosened after tariff reductions depends on the cost advantage in meeting the standard vis-`a-vis foreign producers. Policy substitution, i.e. the tightening of standards, is likely to occur when domestic firms find it relatively less costly to meet the standard than foreign firms, and vice versa for the case of policy complementarity. At the aggregate level, therefore, policy substitution is expected to occur in more advanced economies (where meeting product standards is relatively less costly) and policy complementarity in less advanced economies (where meeting product standards is relatively more costly). When we relax the assumption that product standards only represent a cost for the firms adopting them, and allow for the possibility that firms’ productivity may increase with the standard, results depend on the net cost advantage, i.e. the relative cost-benefit of domestic versus foreign firms in meeting the standard. Under this scenario, policy substitution can result in all cases in which the benefits related to adopting the standard are high enough to warrant the costs. At the aggregate level, therefore, policy substitution is expected to occur in sectors where product standards are relatively more important. In the empirical application of our model, we seek to determine to what extent the probability of applying 1 NTMs is related to tariff reductions. To measure NTMs, we use the information embedded in Specific Trade Concerns (STCs) raised in two WTO committees { the Committee on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT) and the Committee on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (SPS).1 STCs may be brought by any WTO member considering to be negatively affected by an SPS/TBT measure imposed by a WTO trading partner. They are `soft law' mechanisms to deal with NTMs, as they are based on diplomatic relations, rather than adjudication. Unlike other data on NTMs that has been used to address the question of trade policy substitution and that may include trade-enhancing policies { such as frequency counts of product standards { STCs identify actual trade restrictions in specific sectors. Moreover, they refer to measures of general application { as opposed to bilateral measures such as anti-dumping investigations. To address the issue of causality, we employ an identification strategy based on pre-determined (lagged) cuts in sectoral applied tariffs and on the exclusive use of STCs relating to `new measures'. The intuition is that if a new TBT or SPS measure is introduced after a tariff is liberalized, it is less likely (indeed, quite unlikely) to affect tariff liberalization itself compared to a pre-existing measure. To address the issues of confounding biases and of nuisance parameters, we control for a multitude of factors that are likely to affect the use of NTMs and add country-sector fixed effects with year dummies in a conditional logit specification. Our contribution to the literature is fourfold. First, we build a simple model of trade policy substitution that lends itself to empirical testing with existing data. Second, we examine the empirical evidence of trade policy substitution at a fairly disaggregated sectoral level (HS four digit headings), using more suitable information on NTMs than previous studies. Third, we exploit the fact that TBT and SPS measures are subject to different WTO disciplines and affect a different range of sectors to show that TBT and SPS measures are subject to different policy dynamics. Finally, we demonstrate that the likelihood of trade policy substitution differs between groups of countries, in function of their level of development and { to a lesser extent { the degree of sectoral tariff commitments (as measured by the so-called `water' in the tariffs, i.e. the difference between applied and bound rates). 1The TBT Committee deals with technical regulations, standards and conformity assessment procedures, for instance in relation to testing and certification requirements. The SPS Committee focuses on measures regarding food safety and animal and plant health. Both committees normally meet three times per year at the WTO headquarters in Geneva. 2 The paper is structured as follows. In Section 2 we give an overview of the existing theoretical and empirical literature on trade policy substitution, identify shortcomings in the methodologies and data employed and explain how we intend to address these concerns. Section 3 presents the theoretical model from which we derive testable hypotheses regarding policy substitution between applied tariffs and product standards. Section 4 describes in detail the information contained in the TBT and SPS databases on STCs. In Section 5 we explain our empirical strategy. Section 6 discusses descriptive statistics for the variables used in the regression analysis. Our econometric findings (in terms of both statistical and economic significance) are discussed in Section 7. Section 8 concludes and discusses some implications of our results for multilateral trade co-operation. 2 Literature Trade liberalization lowers tariff protection afforded to import-competing sectors and increases their incentive to lobby the government for the restoration of previous levels of protection through other means (Copeland, 1990; Yu, 2000; Bagwell and Staiger, 2001; Ederington, 2001; Anderson and Schmitt, 2003; Bajona and Ederington, 2012). In this context, it has been claimed that there is a `Law of Constant Protection', applying more
Recommended publications
  • Economic Integration, Trade Diversion, and Welfare Change
    Economic Integration, Trade Diversion, and Welfare Change Juyoung Cheong and Kar-yiu Wong University of Washington November 30, 2007 (Version 1.1. Comments Most Welcome) Abstract This paper examines how the volume of trade diverted from a non-member country to a member country during the formation of a new free trade area may be related to the welfare of a member country. The relation is ana- lyzed in the presence of two types of trade: inter-industry trade with perfect competition and intra-industry trade with oligopoly. We found that in the presence of inter-industry trade, a bigger trade volume diverted is generally associated with a smaller change in welfare while in the presence of intra- industry trade with oligopoly, the relation is not so straighforward. We did find that the result in Krishna (1998) that a bigger trade volume diverted implies a higher likelihood of an FTA may not be true. 1 Introduction The welfare impacts of a new preferential trade agreement (PTA) such as a customs union (CU) or a free trade agreement/area (FTA) on the member countries and non-member countries has long been an interesting issue for economists and policy makers. In particular, they want to know how a country may be affected if it chooses to form a new FTA with other countries. For some time, economists had held the position that anything can hap- pen as an PTA represents a movement of a second-best equilibrium to an- other second-best equilibrium, while it is argued that the first-best position of the world is free trade by all countries.1 Viner, in his pioneering work (Viner, 1950), suggested an approach to identifying welfare-improving PTAs and welfare-deteriorating PTAs.
    [Show full text]
  • The Trade and Investment Effects of Preferential Trading Arrangements
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: International Trade in East Asia, NBER-East Asia Seminar on Economics, Volume 14 Volume Author/Editor: Takatoshi Ito and Andrew K. Rose, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-37896-9 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/ito_05-1 Conference Date: September 5-7, 2003 Publication Date: August 2005 Title: The Trade and Investment Effects of Preferential Trading Arrangements Author: Philippa Dee, Jyothi Gali URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c0193 5 The Trade and Investment Effects of Preferential Trading Arrangements Philippa Dee and Jyothi Gali The number of preferential trading arrangements (PTAs) has grown dra- matically over the last decade or so. By the end of March 2002, there were 250 agreements in force that had been notified to the World Trade Organi- zation (WTO), compared with 40 in 1990 (WTO 2002). The coverage of preferential trading arrangements has also tended to expand over time. The preferential liberalization of tariffs and other mea- sures governing merchandise trade remains important in many agreements. But they increasingly cover a range of other issues—services, investment, competition policy, government procurement, e-commerce, labor, and en- vironmental standards. This paper examines, both theoretically and empirically, the effects of the trade and nontrade provisions of PTAs on the trade and foreign direct investment (FDI) flows of member and nonmember countries. 5.1 Theoretical Review The first wave of PTAs in the 1950s to 1970s were generally limited in scope, with preferential liberalization of merchandise trade playing a cen- tral role (the European Union [EU] was an important early exception).
    [Show full text]
  • The Dynamic Gravity Dataset: Technical Documentation Update
    The Dynamic Gravity Dataset: Technical Documentation Update Note Version 2.00 Abstract This document provides an update to the technical documentation for the Dynamic Gravity dataset, describing changes from Version 1.00 to Version 2.00. For full descrip- tion of the contents and construction of the dataset, see full technical documentation for Version 1.00 on the dataset page at https://www.usitc.gov/data/gravity/dgd.htm. This documentation is the result of ongoing professional research of USITC Staff and is solely meant to represent the opinions and professional research of individual authors. It is not meant to represent in any way the views of the U.S. International Trade Commission or any of its individual Commissioners. It is circulated to promote the active exchange of ideas between USITC Staff and recognized experts outside the USITC, professional development of Office Staff and increase data transparency by encouraging outside professional critique of staff research. Please address all correspondence to [email protected]. 1 1 Introduction The Dynamic Gravity dataset contains a collection of variables describing aspects of countries and territories as well as the ways in which they relate to one-another. Each record in the dataset is defined by a pair of countries or territories and a year. The records themselves are composed of three basic types of variables: identifiers, unilateral character- istics, and bilateral characteristics. The updated dataset spans the years 1948{2019 and reflects the dynamic nature of the globe by following the ways in which countries have changed during that period. The resulting dataset covers 285 countries and territories, some of which exist in the dataset for only a subset of covered years.1 1.1 Contents of the Documentation The updated note begins with a description of main changes to the dataset from Version 1.00 to Version 2.00 in section 1.2 and a table of variables available in Version 1.00 and Version 2.00 of the dataset in section 1.3.
    [Show full text]
  • 10Chapter Trade Policy in Developing Countries
    M10_KRUG3040_08_SE_C10.qxd 1/10/08 7:26 PM Page 250 10Chapter Trade Policy in Developing Countries o far we have analyzed the instruments of trade policy and its objectives without specifying the context—that is, without saying much about the Scountry undertaking these policies. Each country has its own distinctive history and issues, but in discussing economic policy one difference between countries becomes obvious: their income levels. As Table 10-1 suggests, nations differ greatly in their per-capita incomes. At one end of the spectrum are the developed or advanced nations, a club whose members include Western Europe, several countries largely settled by Europeans (including the United States), and Japan; these countries have per-capita incomes that in many cases exceed $30,000 per year. Most of the world’s population, however, live in nations that are substantially poorer. The income range among these developing countries1 is itself very wide. Some of these countries, such as Singapore, are in fact on the verge of being “graduated” to advanced country status, both in terms of official statistics and in the way they think about themselves. Others, such as Bangladesh, remain desperately poor. Nonetheless, for virtually all developing countries the attempt to close the income gap with more advanced nations has been a central concern of economic policy. Why are some countries so much poorer than others? Why have some coun- tries that were poor a generation ago succeeded in making dramatic progress, while others have not? These are deeply disputed questions, and to try to answer them—or even to describe at length the answers that economists have proposed over the years—would take us outside the scope of this book.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Political Economy Theory and Practice Seventh Edition THEODORE H. COM IM R Routledge Taylor & Francis Grou P NEW YORK
    Global Political Economy Theory and Practice Seventh Edition THEODORE H. COM IM Routledge R Taylor & Francis Grou p NEW YORK AND LONDON DETAILED CONTENTS Preface xiii Acknowledgments xvii Acronyms and Abbreviations xix PART I Introduction and Overview 1 CHARTER 1 Introduction 2 What is International Political Economy? 3 The IPE Theoretical Perspectives 4 Purposes and Themes ofThis Book 6 Globalization 6 • North-North Relations 8 • North-South Relations 10 Focus of this Book 12 Questions 13 * Key Terms 14 • Further Reading 14 • Notes 14 CHARTER 2 Managing the Global Economy Since World War II: The Institutional Framework 17 Global Economic Relations Before World War II 18 The Mercantilist Period 18 • The Industrial Revolution and British Hegemony 29 • The Decline of British Hegemony and World War I 20 • The Interwar Period 20 • The Institutional Framework Before World War II 21 The Functions of the IM F, World Bank, and GATT 21 The KIEOs and the United Nations 22 The Postwar Economic Institutions and Changing North-South Relations 23 The IMF, World Bank, and WTO 26 • The OECD 28 •The G5, G7, G8, andG20 29 The Postwar Economic Institutions and International Development 31 The KIEOs and the Centrally Planned Economies 39 IMonstate Actors 42 The 2008 Global Financial Crisis: A Turning Point? 43 Questions 44 • Key Terms 45 • Further Reading 45 • Notes 46 vi DETAILED CONTENTS VÜ PART II Theoretical Perspectives 51 CHARTERS Neomercantilism 55 BasicTenets of Neomercantilism 55 The Role of the Individual, the State, and Societal Groups 55 • The Nature and Purpose of International Economic Relations 56 • The Relationship Between Politics and Economics 56 • The Causes and Effects of Globalization 57 The Mercantilists 57 Neomercantilism and the Industrial Revolution 58 Neomercantilism in the Interwar Period 59 Neomercantilism After World War II 60 The Revival of Neomercantilist IRE 60 Hegemonie Stability Theory and U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • FTA Tariff Tool New Online Tool Highlights Tariff Benefits of Free Trade Agreements for American Businesses
    U.S. Department of Commerce International Trade Administration FTA Tariff Tool New Online Tool Highlights Tariff Benefits of Free Trade Agreements for American Businesses http://www.export.gov/FTA/FTATariffTool/ • Are you an exporter seeking a market where the United States The FTA Tariff Tool: has an existing competitive advantage? • Are you spending time looking through pages of legal texts • consolidates and distills tariff to figure out the tariff under a trade agreement for your schedules down to a simple products? search function • Would you like to perform instant and at-a-glance searches • allows users to see how for trade and tariff trends in one easily accessed location particular sectors are treated online? under the agreements or recent trends in exports to the trade The Free Trade Agreement (FTA) Tariff Tool will ease your exporting agreement partner markets process and could help you increase your exports to U.S. trade agreement partner markets. It will streamline your industrial and • helps reduce costs and consumer product tariff searches by making information on tariff uncertainty for U.S. businesses benefits companies receive under U.S. trade agreements more accessible. The FTA Tariff Tool consolidates and condenses trade, tariff and sectoral information into a user-friendly public interface. The tool is provided free of charge by the U.S. Department of Commerce. Businesses are able to see the current and future tariffs applied to their products, as well as the date on which those products become duty free. By combining sector and product groups, trade data, and the tariff elimination schedules, users can also analyze how various sectors are treated across multiple trade agreements.
    [Show full text]
  • Handbook on Preferential Market Access for Asean Least Developed Countries
    UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT HANDBOOK ON PREFERENTIAL MARKET ACCESS FOR ASEAN LEAST DEVELOPED COUNTRIES Part III: ASEAN-FTA Agreements Layout and Printing at United Nations, Geneva – 2017833 (E) – March 2021 – 730 – UNCTAD/ALDC/2019/5 “Mazzarello - geometrie del dare, nuovo futuro” is the work of Maurizio Cancelli. Its architectural perspective emphasizes the interactions of governments, societies and economies from around the globe under the United Nations Framework. This collaboration highlights the earth, its resources and potentials, and fosters a recognition of local communities and their right to exist in their places of origin, with their own distinction and diversity. Maurizio Cancelli started his artistic research on the right to live in one’s place of birth more than thirty years ago. His work is inspired by the mountainous terrain surrounding the village of Cancelli in the heart of Umbria, Italy. UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT HANDBOOK ON PREFERENTIAL MARKET ACCESS FOR ASEAN LEAST DEVELOPED COUNTRIES Part III: ASEAN-FTA Agreements Geneva, 2021 © 2021, United Nations This work is available through open access, by complying with the Creative Commons licence created for intergovernmental organizations, at http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo/. The findings, interpretations and conclusions expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the United Nations or its officials or Member States. The designations employed and the presentation of material on any map in this work do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the United Nations concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries.
    [Show full text]
  • Free Trade Agreement with Serbia
    FREE TRADE AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE EURASIAN ECONOMIC UNION AND ITS MEMBER STATES, OF THE ONE PART, AND THE REPUBLIC OF SERBIA, OF THE OTHER PART The Eurasian Economic Union (hereinafter referred to as “the EAEU”) and the Republic of Armenia, the Republic of Belarus, the Republic of Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, the Russian Federation (hereinafter referred to as “the EAEU Member States”), of the one part, and the Republic of Serbia (hereinafter referred to as “Serbia”), of the other part: BUILDING UPON free trade relations previously established between the Republic of Serbia, the Republic of Belarus, the Republic of Kazakhstan and the Russian Federation; SEEKING to promote and deepen mutual trade and economic cooperation between the EAEU Member States and Serbia in the areas of mutual interest; CONFIRMING their commitment to the principles of market economy, as the basis for trade and economic relations, and their intention to participate actively and to encourage expansion of mutually beneficial trade and economic relations between the EAEU Member States and Serbia; CREATING the necessary conditions for the free movement of goods and capital in accordance with the Law of the EAEU, laws and regulations of the EAEU Member States and Serbia, as well as the rules of the World Trade Organization (hereinafter referred to as “the WTO”); EXPRESSING their readiness and full support to the successful accession to the WTO and recognizing that the WTO membership of the EAEU and the Republic of Belarus and of Serbia will create favourable conditions
    [Show full text]
  • Itc) for the Meeting of the Ministers of Foreign Affairs of Lldcs
    STATEMENT OF THE INTERNATIONAL TRADE CENTRE (ITC) FOR THE MEETING OF THE MINISTERS OF FOREIGN AFFAIRS OF LLDCS PARTNERING FOR ACCELERATED IMPLEMENTATION OF THE VIENNA PROGRAMME OF ACTION FOR LLDCS AND ACHIEVING SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT IN LLDCS IN THE ERA OF COVID-19 TUESDAY, 23 SEPT 2020 DOROTHY TEMBO ACTING EXECUTIVE DORECTOR Your Excellency Minister Tileuberdi, Chair of the Group of LLDCs, Ministers of Foreign Affairs, Excellencies, During this period of continued uncertainty, it is important to recall the most essential ingredients of resilience: partnership, technical collaboration, and the stability of the multilateral system. The Vienna Programme of Action for LLDCs (VPoA) remains a central actionable component of helping LLDCs to meet the SDGs and building back better for the ‘new normal’. As the joint agency of the United Nations and the World Trade Organization, the International Trade Centre is fully committed to supporting the implementation of the VPoA through enhancing trade in LLDCs and their transit countries. Our approach is focused on assisting micro, small and medium-sized enterprises (MSMEs) to connect to global markets, and for that we work closely with private sector institutions. ITC contributes to two of the six priority areas of the VPoA: 1) International trade and trade facilitation, and 2) Regional integration and cooperation. Since 2014, ITC has implemented more than 40 projects for almost all LLDCs including our global projects such as of public goods on data and intelligence. Still, in this period of COVID-19, we have seen demand for trade related assistance increasing as LLDCs and their MSMEs seek help in coping with the pandemic.
    [Show full text]
  • In Lieu of MIL (Political Science) Politics of Globalization Study Material : Unit I-V
    B.Com. (Prog.) Semester-III/IV In Lieu of MIL (Political Science) Politics of Globalization Study Material : Unit I-V SCHOOL OF OPEN LEARNING UNIVERSITY OF DELHI Department of Political Science Editor : Prof. Tapal Biswal Dr. Mangal Deo Graduate Course In Lieu of MIL B.Com Semester III/IV POLITICS OF GLOBALIZATION CONTENTS Unit-I : The Concept of Globalization and its Debate Dr. Rukmani Unit-II : Approaches to Understanding Globalization Lesson-1 : Liberal Approach Anwita Lesson-2 : Radical Approach Anwita Unit-III : Issues in Globalization : Alternative Perspectives on Globalization: Nature and Character Inder Sekhar Yadav Unit-IV : Globalization and Politics in Developing Countries Lesson-1 : Globalization and the Social Movements Dr. Abhishek Nath Lesson-2 : Globalization and the Demise of Nation-State Nishant Yadav Lesson-3 : Globalization and Human Migration Nishant Yadav Unit-V : The Inevitability of Globalization: Domestic and Deepika Global Responses Edited by: Prof. Tapan Biswal Dr. Mangal Deo SCHOOL OF OPEN LEARNING UNIVERSITY OF DELHI 5, Cavalry Lane, Delhi-110007 Unit-I The Concept of Globalization and its Debate Outline Student Learning Outcomes Introduction Understanding of Globalization- Globalists, Sceptics, and Transformationalists Dimensions of Globalization – Economic, Political, Cultural The Globalization Debate – Argument in Favor and Against Conclusion Summary Probable Questions Suggested Readings Student Learning Outcomes Student will be able to define the Concept of Globalization Student will be able
    [Show full text]
  • United States-Southern African Customs Union (SACU) Free Trade Agreement Negotiations: Background and Potential Issues
    Order Code RS21387 Updated May 27, 2008 United States-Southern African Customs Union (SACU) Free Trade Agreement Negotiations: Background and Potential Issues Danielle Langton Analyst in International Trade and Finance Foreign Affairs, Defense, and Trade Division Summary Negotiations to launch a free trade agreement (FTA) between the United States and the five members of the Southern African Customs Union (SACU) (Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia, South Africa, and Swaziland) began on June 3, 2003. In April 2006, negotiators suspended FTA negotiations, launching a new work program on intensifying the trade and investment relationship with an FTA as a long term goal. A potential FTA would eliminate tariffs over time, reduce or eliminate non-tariff barriers, liberalize service trade, protect intellectual property rights, and provide technical assistance to help SACU nations achieve the goals of the agreement. This potential agreement would be subject to congressional approval. This report will be updated as negotiations progress. On November 4, 2002, United States Trade Representative (USTR) Robert B. Zoellick notified Congress of the Administration’s intention to launch negotiations for a free trade agreement (FTA) with the Southern African Customs Union (SACU), comprised of Botswana, Namibia, Lesotho, South Africa, and Swaziland. This agreement would be the first U.S. FTA with a Sub-Saharan African country. The first round of negotiations for the SACU FTA began on June 3, 2003, in Johannesburg, South Africa. The negotiations were initially scheduled to conclude by December 2004, but the deadline was pushed to the end of 2006 after negotiations stalled in late 2004 and resumed in late 2005. The talks continued to move at a slow pace until April 2006, when U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of US Tariffs Against China on US
    Discussion Paper Deutsche Bundesbank No 46/2019 The impact of US tariffs against China on US imports: Evidence for trade diversion? Philipp Meinen Patrick Schulte (Deutsche Bundesbank and (Deutsche Bundesbank) European Central Bank) Simone Cigna Nils Steinhoff (European Central Bank) (École polytechnique) Discussion Papers represent the authors‘ personal opinions and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Deutsche Bundesbank or the Eurosystem. Editorial Board: Daniel Foos Thomas Kick Malte Knüppel Vivien Lewis Christoph Memmel Panagiota Tzamourani Deutsche Bundesbank, Wilhelm-Epstein-Straße 14, 60431 Frankfurt am Main, Postfach 10 06 02, 60006 Frankfurt am Main Tel +49 69 9566-0 Please address all orders in writing to: Deutsche Bundesbank, Press and Public Relations Division, at the above address or via fax +49 69 9566-3077 Internet http://www.bundesbank.de Reproduction permitted only if source is stated. ISBN 97 8–3–95729–652–8 (Printversion) ISBN 97 8–3–95729–653–5 (Internetversion) Non-technical summary Research Question In light of the recent increase of protectionist policies, such as those in the context of the trade dispute between China and the US, interest in quantifying their effects has risen. Besides assessing the direct implications for the trading partners involved in the trade conflict, both researchers and policymakers are also interested in the effects on third countries and the question of whether other countries might even benefit from such actions due to trade diversion effects, replacing the targeted country's exports with own exports. While simulation results suggest that such effects may materialise even within the first year, less is known empirically about the importance of trade diversion effects in the short run.
    [Show full text]