Regional Trade Agreements: a Tool for Development?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Regional Trade Agreements: a Tool for Development? An Evaluation of Trade Capacity Building Programs Regional Trade Agreements: A Tool for Development? Bureau for Policy and Program Coordination October 2004 PPC EVALUATION WORKING PAPER NO. PAPER WORKING 15 PPC EVALUATION PN-ACT-170 RELATED PUBLICATIONS The analysis in this paper is based on the following documents: An Evaluation of Trade Capacity Building: Overview (PN-ACT-167) USAID Support for WTO/FTA Accession and Implementation (PN-ACT-168) USAID Behind-the-Border Trade Capacity Building (PN-ACT-169) Other relevant documents include Building Trade Capacity in the Developing World (PD-ABX-241) U.S. Contributions to Trade Capacity Building: Improving Lives through Aid and Trade (PD-ABY-500) An Evaluation of Trade Capacity Building Programs Regional Trade Agreements: A Tool for Development? James W. Fox The Louis Berger Group, Inc. October 2004 Abstract Caribbean Community and Common Market (CARICOM) and the Organization of East n the past, regional trade arrangements (RTAs) Caribbean States (OECS). Several large African among developing countries have not lived up groupings emerged: the Common Market for East Ito the hopes of proponents as vehicles for pro- and Southern Africa (COMESA), the Southern moting efficient industrialization. Newer approach- Africa Development Community (SADC), and the es, notably including low tariffs for countries out- Economic Community of West African States side the RTA, have more promise. RTAs with devel- (ECOWAS). Most sought to achieve an “open oped countries also are more likely to produce regionalism,” with lower external tariffs than the favorable results. Therefore, USAID should earlier efforts.1 approach supporting RTAs among developing countries with care. There are at least four ways to evaluate the impact of RTAs. First, there are the traditional static eco- There are advantages to assisting small countries nomic concepts of trade diversion and trade cre- through regional service centers or hubs so that ation that economists use. Second are dynamic USAID assistance does not have to rely on the “infant industry” effects that may come from narrower technical capabilities of small bilateral RTAs providing an initially protected environment missions. Such regional hubs may be efficient for firms that may eventually achieve competitive- tools for providing bilateral assistance. However, ness in world markets. Third is to determine in the absence of clear benefits to regionalism, whether RTAs provide a reliable platform for firms a hub is not a reason to promote regional to make investment decisions that would bring integration or RTAs. infant industry as well as other dynamic effects into play. Fourth, is to examine the potential of RTAs to promote peace and stability. The evidence Introduction on each of these four factors is discussed below. A Free trade with the world has always been viewed final section considers the implications for USAID with suspicion by all but economists. The contrary of the analysis. tends to be true of free trade among neighboring countries. Economists have usually been skeptical, while others—including political leaders—have Trade Diversion and Trade often been enthusiastic supporters. Support for Creation regional free trade has waxed and waned. There was considerable enthusiasm in the 1960s. The Central The Concepts American Common Market (CACM), the Latin The traditional analysis of the impact of regional American Free Trade Area, the East African groupings by economists is based on the concepts Community (EAC), and the association of fran- of trade diversion and trade creation. Trade diver- cophone West African countries (UOEMA) were sion occurs when a country ceases to import a established in that period. After some disappoint- product from the low-cost source on the world ment with results, and political changes that dis- market in favor of buying a product from a coun- solved some efforts, RTAs generated little interest try within the free trade area at a price higher than in the 1980s. world market but lower than the world market price plus the external tariff imposed by the RTA. In recent years, there has been renewed interest in RTAs. The Southern Cone Common Market— Mercosur—was established in South America. 1 See the appended brief summary of the experience of the current Other efforts were reenergized through the regional groupings of developing countries. An Evaluation of Trade Capacity Building Programs 3 A simplified numerical example illustrates the modity and begins importing it from another. point. Suppose that country A has a 50 percent Welfare is increased by reduced production of some import duty on refrigerators, which are not pro- goods, with the attendant adjustments required duced locally. A small refrigerator costing $100 (such as bankruptcies and layoffs of workers). internationally will sell for $150, with the govern- Because the country may be able to export other ment collecting $50 for each refrigerator imported. products to partner countries total employment Prior to the RTA, neighboring country B produced may increase, but the benefit comes from move- refrigerators that sold for $130 in its protected ment of workers and capital from some industries domestic market. When RTA refrigerators cost to others. Second, the potential for trade creation $130 in country A, there is an apparent benefit to and trade diversion depends on the level of the consumers because refrigerator prices have gone RTA’s external tariff: the higher the external tariff, down. Nevertheless, the $20 savings for the con- the greater the trade diversion that is likely to sumer has cost country A’s government $50 in occur. Had the external tariff in the case described revenues. In effect, the government spent $50 to above been only 20 percent, no trade diversion provide $20 in benefits to its citizens. The other would have occurred. $30 has gone to subsidize inefficient refrigerator production in country B. Country A did not Consider the following hypothetical example of an pursue the most beneficial alternative for its RTA between Nigeria and Benin. Nigeria’s manu- consumers: eliminating the tariff on refrigerators facturing sector is far larger than Benin’s, but the imported from all countries. In this case, govern- sector exports almost nothing to world markets. ment revenues would have fallen by the same That suggests that it is inefficient by world stan- amount ($50) for each refrigerator imported, but dards. Benin has a far smaller industrial sector, country A’s consumers would have received exactly so the potential for trade creation is small. Again, that reduction in costs. trade creation for Benin will occur only when its production is replaced by lower-cost production in Trade creation, in contrast, occurs when production Nigeria.2 On the other hand, Benin exporting to shifts from the domestic economy to that of another Nigeria presents a larger opportunity for trade member of the RTA. Suppose now that country A’s creation. Entrepreneurs in Benin would have a domestic refrigerator industry produces refrigerators far larger potential market for their products. at $140 per unit. As before, a 50 percent tariff means that consumers will buy the domestically Unfortunately, in practice there has been a produced item. Now the formation of the FTA with marked tendency for the industrialization from country B will produce trade creation. Country A such a regional agreement to concentrate in the will begin to import refrigerators at $130 each from country (and city) that already has the most country B, and will stop producing the high-cost industry. This “agglomeration” effect results from domestic refrigerators. In this case, consumers are the lower costs that firms encounter in such loca- better off, because their refrigerators are now $10 tions because of better infrastructure and better cheaper. The shift in production thus results in access to inputs and human resources. Less greater efficiency. Since the government collected advanced countries—such as Tanzania and no import duties in either case, its situation is Uganda in the East African Community, unchanged. Nevertheless, eliminating the 50 Honduras in the CACM—have found they incur percent tariff on refrigerator imports from other countries would have produced even cheaper refrigerators at no cost in government revenues. 2 Even where there is potential for trade creation in this way, it is often resisted within RTAs. For example, Trinidad and Tobago feared that its apparel sector would be harmed by imports from other CARI- Two points should be made. First, trade creation COM countries, so it prohibited imports of such products from part- ner countries. RTAs among developing countries seldom have occurs when one country stops producing a com- enforcement mechanisms to penalize such unilateral action. 4 PPC Evaluation Working Paper No. 15 the costs of higher prices and lower tariff revenues tition is prevented by high tariffs, but they make but do not obtain the benefits of increased invest- exporting to world markets impossible. The tradi- ment and industrial employment. The most likely tional economist’s model, based on greed as the prospect for Benin, then, is a diversion of manu- incentive to efficiency and productivity, is surely factured imports from low-cost producers in the wrong. Rather, it is the fear that one’s position in rest of the world to Nigerian producers. Benin the marketplace will be displaced by a more efficient will then import higher cost (and probably lower competitor that has shown itself to spur efficiency. quality) products from Nigeria that are exempt from import duties. Thus, Benin’s duty-paying The net benefits of Mercosur in its initial years imports and tax collections fall. were subject to debate. Leipziger (1997) concludes that the benefits were “small but positive,” while The Empirical Evidence others suggest that it was probably negative For developing countries, the experience with RTAs (Sanguinetti, Pantano, and Posadas 2001; Yeats has been that little trade creation occurs. Instead, 1998). Yeats concluded that the expansion of trade imports that previously came from world markets was largest in products—notably capital goods— now come from other RTA members.
Recommended publications
  • Economic Integration, Trade Diversion, and Welfare Change
    Economic Integration, Trade Diversion, and Welfare Change Juyoung Cheong and Kar-yiu Wong University of Washington November 30, 2007 (Version 1.1. Comments Most Welcome) Abstract This paper examines how the volume of trade diverted from a non-member country to a member country during the formation of a new free trade area may be related to the welfare of a member country. The relation is ana- lyzed in the presence of two types of trade: inter-industry trade with perfect competition and intra-industry trade with oligopoly. We found that in the presence of inter-industry trade, a bigger trade volume diverted is generally associated with a smaller change in welfare while in the presence of intra- industry trade with oligopoly, the relation is not so straighforward. We did find that the result in Krishna (1998) that a bigger trade volume diverted implies a higher likelihood of an FTA may not be true. 1 Introduction The welfare impacts of a new preferential trade agreement (PTA) such as a customs union (CU) or a free trade agreement/area (FTA) on the member countries and non-member countries has long been an interesting issue for economists and policy makers. In particular, they want to know how a country may be affected if it chooses to form a new FTA with other countries. For some time, economists had held the position that anything can hap- pen as an PTA represents a movement of a second-best equilibrium to an- other second-best equilibrium, while it is argued that the first-best position of the world is free trade by all countries.1 Viner, in his pioneering work (Viner, 1950), suggested an approach to identifying welfare-improving PTAs and welfare-deteriorating PTAs.
    [Show full text]
  • Sustainable Growth Based on Export-Oriented Economic Strategy : the Bulgarian Case in an International Comparison
    ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSES Sustainable Growth Based on Export-Oriented Economic Strategy The Bulgarian Case in an International Comparison Prof. András Inotai This paper aims at identifying the strengths and weaknesses of the Bulgarian economy’s transformation to a more dynamic and export-oriented growth model. By referring to two groups of countries – Central European EU member states as well as the Western Balkans, the study puts an emphasis on the impact the EU membership and the 2009 crisis year have on the Bulgarian foreign trade and export performance in particular. The first chapter gathers arguments in favour of the export-oriented growth model but also addresses potential risk factors of such long-term policy. Despite some drawbacks as increasing vulnerability and de- pendence on external factors, this development path is justified as the better way for achieving sustainable economic growth of small economies like Bulgaria. The second chapter deals with the global financial crisis and its influence on the exports and foreign trade in general. Then, the author focuses on Bulgaria’s export performance in the EU and on a regional compari- son by stressing on the role of foreign direct investments in the export orientation of the country. Finally, the paper concludes by summarizing measures and instruments for catching-up export-driven economic development and by formulating policy recommendations supporting the successful implementa- tion of such an export-led growth model. April 2013 Imprint Orders All texts are available online Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung Economic www.fes.bg Office Bulgaria Policy Institute 97, Knjaz Boris I St. Yasen Georgiev The views expressed in this publication 1000 Sofia, Bulgaria are not necessarily those of the Responsible: e-mail: [email protected] Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung or of the Regine Schubert, Director Fax: (+359 2) 9522693 organization for which the author works.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Political Economy Theory and Practice Seventh Edition THEODORE H. COM IM R Routledge Taylor & Francis Grou P NEW YORK
    Global Political Economy Theory and Practice Seventh Edition THEODORE H. COM IM Routledge R Taylor & Francis Grou p NEW YORK AND LONDON DETAILED CONTENTS Preface xiii Acknowledgments xvii Acronyms and Abbreviations xix PART I Introduction and Overview 1 CHARTER 1 Introduction 2 What is International Political Economy? 3 The IPE Theoretical Perspectives 4 Purposes and Themes ofThis Book 6 Globalization 6 • North-North Relations 8 • North-South Relations 10 Focus of this Book 12 Questions 13 * Key Terms 14 • Further Reading 14 • Notes 14 CHARTER 2 Managing the Global Economy Since World War II: The Institutional Framework 17 Global Economic Relations Before World War II 18 The Mercantilist Period 18 • The Industrial Revolution and British Hegemony 29 • The Decline of British Hegemony and World War I 20 • The Interwar Period 20 • The Institutional Framework Before World War II 21 The Functions of the IM F, World Bank, and GATT 21 The KIEOs and the United Nations 22 The Postwar Economic Institutions and Changing North-South Relations 23 The IMF, World Bank, and WTO 26 • The OECD 28 •The G5, G7, G8, andG20 29 The Postwar Economic Institutions and International Development 31 The KIEOs and the Centrally Planned Economies 39 IMonstate Actors 42 The 2008 Global Financial Crisis: A Turning Point? 43 Questions 44 • Key Terms 45 • Further Reading 45 • Notes 46 vi DETAILED CONTENTS VÜ PART II Theoretical Perspectives 51 CHARTERS Neomercantilism 55 BasicTenets of Neomercantilism 55 The Role of the Individual, the State, and Societal Groups 55 • The Nature and Purpose of International Economic Relations 56 • The Relationship Between Politics and Economics 56 • The Causes and Effects of Globalization 57 The Mercantilists 57 Neomercantilism and the Industrial Revolution 58 Neomercantilism in the Interwar Period 59 Neomercantilism After World War II 60 The Revival of Neomercantilist IRE 60 Hegemonie Stability Theory and U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • The European Union's Trade Policies and Their Economics Effects
    Summary Already the Treaty Forty years ago, external protection was high in most of Rome called for countries and Europe was comprised of many “trade for- internal and tresses”. The founders of the Community shared a coherent external economic policy view, with the Treaty of Rome calling for an liberalisation internal market with no obstacles to trade and strong com- petition, as well as for multilateral liberalisation. This publi- cation retraces the external liberalisation efforts, discusses the current trade regime in international comparison, and sets out the Community’s future trade agenda. A key aim of the study will be to clarify and, where feasible, to quantify the economic effects of the European Union’s (EU) trade policies. Decision-making Partly by necessity, partly by design, the EU’s trade policy on foreign trade has been “walking on two legs” since its early days: multilateral policy is largely liberalisation and regional integration. The long-standing centralised at the pursuit of deeper integration and enlargement, and the EU level involvement in regional preferential agreements makes the EU’s experience unique. Another unique feature is the insti- tutional set-up. While largely prepared by the Commission, major decisions are taken by the Council (for trade in goods and part of services). Some competencies are shared between the Union and the Member States. However, the negotiation and decision making process is not different between the areas of mixed or exclusive competence. Cen- tralisation of most decisions on foreign trade policy at the EU level is necessary to ensure the functioning of the inter- nal market.
    [Show full text]
  • In Lieu of MIL (Political Science) Politics of Globalization Study Material : Unit I-V
    B.Com. (Prog.) Semester-III/IV In Lieu of MIL (Political Science) Politics of Globalization Study Material : Unit I-V SCHOOL OF OPEN LEARNING UNIVERSITY OF DELHI Department of Political Science Editor : Prof. Tapal Biswal Dr. Mangal Deo Graduate Course In Lieu of MIL B.Com Semester III/IV POLITICS OF GLOBALIZATION CONTENTS Unit-I : The Concept of Globalization and its Debate Dr. Rukmani Unit-II : Approaches to Understanding Globalization Lesson-1 : Liberal Approach Anwita Lesson-2 : Radical Approach Anwita Unit-III : Issues in Globalization : Alternative Perspectives on Globalization: Nature and Character Inder Sekhar Yadav Unit-IV : Globalization and Politics in Developing Countries Lesson-1 : Globalization and the Social Movements Dr. Abhishek Nath Lesson-2 : Globalization and the Demise of Nation-State Nishant Yadav Lesson-3 : Globalization and Human Migration Nishant Yadav Unit-V : The Inevitability of Globalization: Domestic and Deepika Global Responses Edited by: Prof. Tapan Biswal Dr. Mangal Deo SCHOOL OF OPEN LEARNING UNIVERSITY OF DELHI 5, Cavalry Lane, Delhi-110007 Unit-I The Concept of Globalization and its Debate Outline Student Learning Outcomes Introduction Understanding of Globalization- Globalists, Sceptics, and Transformationalists Dimensions of Globalization – Economic, Political, Cultural The Globalization Debate – Argument in Favor and Against Conclusion Summary Probable Questions Suggested Readings Student Learning Outcomes Student will be able to define the Concept of Globalization Student will be able
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of US Tariffs Against China on US
    Discussion Paper Deutsche Bundesbank No 46/2019 The impact of US tariffs against China on US imports: Evidence for trade diversion? Philipp Meinen Patrick Schulte (Deutsche Bundesbank and (Deutsche Bundesbank) European Central Bank) Simone Cigna Nils Steinhoff (European Central Bank) (École polytechnique) Discussion Papers represent the authors‘ personal opinions and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Deutsche Bundesbank or the Eurosystem. Editorial Board: Daniel Foos Thomas Kick Malte Knüppel Vivien Lewis Christoph Memmel Panagiota Tzamourani Deutsche Bundesbank, Wilhelm-Epstein-Straße 14, 60431 Frankfurt am Main, Postfach 10 06 02, 60006 Frankfurt am Main Tel +49 69 9566-0 Please address all orders in writing to: Deutsche Bundesbank, Press and Public Relations Division, at the above address or via fax +49 69 9566-3077 Internet http://www.bundesbank.de Reproduction permitted only if source is stated. ISBN 97 8–3–95729–652–8 (Printversion) ISBN 97 8–3–95729–653–5 (Internetversion) Non-technical summary Research Question In light of the recent increase of protectionist policies, such as those in the context of the trade dispute between China and the US, interest in quantifying their effects has risen. Besides assessing the direct implications for the trading partners involved in the trade conflict, both researchers and policymakers are also interested in the effects on third countries and the question of whether other countries might even benefit from such actions due to trade diversion effects, replacing the targeted country's exports with own exports. While simulation results suggest that such effects may materialise even within the first year, less is known empirically about the importance of trade diversion effects in the short run.
    [Show full text]
  • Trading Arrangements and Industrial Development*
    Trading Arrangements and Industrial Development* Diego Puga CEP, London School of Economics; and CEPR Anthony J. Venables London School of Economics; and CEPR CENTRE for ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Discussion Paper No. 319, December 1996 ABSTRACT: This paper outlines a new approach for analysing the role of trade in promoting industrial development. It offers an explanation as to why firms are reluctant to move to economies with lower labour costs, and shows how trade liberalisation can change the incentives for firms to locate in developing countries. Unilaterally liberalising imports of manufactures can promote industrialisation, but membership of a preferential trading arrangement is likely to create larger gains. South-South PTAs will be sensitive to the market size of member states, while North-South PTAs seem to offer better prospects for participating Southern economies, if not for excluded countries. * Thanks to Maurice Schiff, Alan Winters and referees for valuable comments on an earlier version. This paper was prepared for the Research Project on Regional Integration of the International Trade Division of the World Bank. The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank or its affiliated organizations. KEY WORDS: preferential arrangements, industrialisation, development, linkages. JEL CLASSIFICATION: F12, R12. Addresses: Diego Puga Anthony J. Venables Centre for Economic Performance Department of Economics London School of Economics London School of Economics Houghton Street Houghton
    [Show full text]
  • Topic 9: Preferential Trade Agreements (Ptas)
    Topic 9: Preferential trade agreements (PTAs) Introduction One of the most important elements of trade policy in the world is the rapid growth of various forms of Free Trade Agreements (FTAs), more generally referred to as PTAs or Regional Trade Agreements (RTAs). They have been in existence for many centuries in various forms, such as the Hanseatic League among northern German principalities and parts of Scandinavia in the 13th to 17th centuries and various trade agreements among Italian republics during the Renaissance. The first major FTA after World War II was the European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC), which eventually became the European Community and now the European Union. The first major agreement involving the United States was the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) with Canada and Mexico in 1994, which succeeded the Canada-US FTA. PTAs really began to grow in number and scope after NAFTA and as of January 2018 there were 455 such agreements in place involving nearly all countries in the WTO (Chart). US PTAs In recent decades PTAs have become the primary way that the US and the EU try to manage their trade relations with specific countries or groups of countries. In addition to NAFTA the US has the following agreements (20 countries in total): • Central America (CAFTA); • Several nations in the Caribbean (CARICOM); • Agreements in South America (Chile, Peru, Colombia); • Australia; • South Korea; • Israel, Jordan, and numerous other small countries. Other PTAs The EU itself is a massive FTA with 28 current members (actually a Customs Union; see below). The EU also has an FTA with the members of the European Free Trade Agreement (EFTA; Switzerland, Norway and Iceland) and a customs union with Turkey and some smaller states.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade Implications of the Trans-Pacific Partnership for ASEAN and Other Asian Countries
    Trade Implications of the Trans-Pacific Partnership for ASEAN and Other Asian Countries ∗ ALAN V. D EARDORFF Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/adev/article-pdf/31/2/1/1641915/adev_a_00035.pdf by guest on 25 September 2021 The Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) aspires to become a state-of-the-art trade agreement linking 12 countries on both sides of the Pacific. In addition to establishing a free trade agreement (FTA) among these countries, negotiators are pursuing a long list of other issues, both trade-related and non-trade related. This paper examines the likely effects of the TPP on trade alone, taking into account the fact that all of the potential members of the TPP are already participants in other FTAs. Using information from the World Trade Organization (WTO) on the existence of these FTAs plus data on the identities of countries’ major trading partners for both exports and imports, I discuss the likely effects on a list of countries in terms of trade creation, trade diversion, preference erosion, and “trade reversion”—the reversal of trade diversion that has already occurred due to existing FTAs. The list of countries includes all of the members of the TPP as well as of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN). In addition it includes 10 additional Asian economies that are not part of either. Keywords: Trans-Pacific Partnership, free trade agreements JEL codes: F13 I. Introduction Negotiations have been underway for several years towards the formation of the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), which aims to be a “next generation” or “21st century” trade agreement linking countries on both sides of the Pacific.
    [Show full text]
  • How Different Are Safeguards from Antidumping? Evidence from US Trade Policies Toward Steel
    How Different are Safeguards from Antidumping? Evidence from US Trade Policies Toward Steel Chad P. Bown†,‡ Department of Economics and International Business School Brandeis University July 2004 Abstract How do the trade impacts of a safeguard measure - which is statutorily designed to follow the most-favored-nation (MFN) principle of equal treatment - compare to explicitly discriminatory measures such as antidumping? We address this question empirically by ex- amining the trade effects of the 2002 US safeguard on steel imports and comparing this with the impact of other US trade remedies on steel imports in the 1990s. We first estimate a fixed-effects model on a dynamic panel of product-level US steel imports over 1989-2003 and examine the potential discriminatory impact on foreign-produced steel of the 2002 “MFN” safeguard that used relatively new tools from the policymakers’ arsenal: country and prod- uct exclusions. A unique data set on the excluded products allows us to document the sizable impact on trade of both forms of preferential treatment. We also exploit higher- frequency (i.e., quarterly) data to examine potential differences in the timing of the foreign export response to policies of differential treatment. With respect to safeguard exclusions, we find that while developed country exporters have a quicker response to an exclusion, the developing-country export response is more persistent. Finally, relative to antidumping measures, country and product exclusions from a safeguard allow the protection-imposing country to target preferential treatment more effectively toward specific foreign countries, much like a preferential trade agreement, or even more narrowly toward a specific foreign firm.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade Diversion and Trade Deficits: the Case of the Korea-U.S
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TRADE DIVERSION AND TRADE DEFICITS: THE CASE OF THE KOREA-U.S. FREE TRADE AGREEMENT Katheryn N. Russ Deborah L. Swenson Working Paper 25613 http://www.nber.org/papers/w25613 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 February 2019 We thank Kelly Stangl for excellent research assistance. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2019 by Katheryn N. Russ and Deborah L. Swenson. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Trade Diversion and Trade Deficits: The case of the Korea-U.S. Free Trade Agreement Katheryn N. Russ and Deborah L. Swenson NBER Working Paper No. 25613 February 2019 JEL No. F10,F40 ABSTRACT We study whether tariff preferences conferred on South Korean goods through the implementation of the Korea-U.S. Free Trade Agreement (KORUS) drew U.S. import demand away from other U.S. trading partners through the phenomenon known as trade diversion. In the two years following the implementation of KORUS, trade diversion was particularly strong for U.S. imports of consumption goods and for trade partners who already had free trade agreements with the U.S. Our estimates of trade diversion sum to $13.1 billion in 2013 and $13.8 billion in 2014.
    [Show full text]
  • Appendix a Notes on Trade Creation, Diversion, and Economic Efficiency
    Appendix A Notes on Trade Creation, Diversion, and Economic Efficiency The mere fact that an FTA between two countries would increase bilateral trade flows does not necessarily mean that it would yield an economic efficiency gain. The increase in bilateral trade is achieved at the expense of domestically produced goods, in a process known as ‘‘trade creation,’’ at the expense of imports from other countries outside the FTA bloc, known as ‘‘trade diversion,’’ or both. As Jacob Viner pointed out in his classic analysis (Viner 1950), trade creation improves economic efficiency because the FTA partner country turns out to be a lower-cost producer, compared with producers at home, of the product that is imported more as a result of an FTA. However, trade diversion might be detrimental not only to the welfare of the world as a whole but also to the importing country because the increased imports may not be the best choice due to the price discrimination against the third-country product. In other words, the increase in imports from the FTA partner country might not have occurred if there had been no price discrimination applied to the third party, which actually may have been a cheaper source of supply but was not able to compete with the FTA countries because of tariff discrimina- tion. In reality, an FTA is likely to have both trade creation and trade diver- sion effects. Thus the question of the economic efficiency impact of an FTA would depend on which effect dominates. In practice, however, it is extremely difficult to accurately measure the magnitude of trade-creat- ing and trade-diverting effects.
    [Show full text]