Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware Working Paper No. 2004-07 The Constitutional Creation of a Common Currency in the U.S. 1748-1811: Monetary Stabilization Versus Merchant Rent Seeking. Farley Grubb FARLEY GRUBB THE CONSTITUTIONAL CREATION OF A COMMON CURRENCY IN THE U.S., 1748-1811: MONETARY STABILIZATION VERSUS MERCHANT RENT SEEKING The value of having a single currency, the optimal size of currency unions, and the cost of forming such unions, is an unresolved debate1. An important aspect of this debate is the empirical success claimed for currency unions such as the United States. The fact that otherwise-sovereign states within the United States are not legally allowed to issue their own currency, thus creating a single cur- rency zone for the whole United States based on the U.S. dollar, is commonly used as an example for emulation and as justification for policy choices, such as the current move toward a European currency union based on the Euro2. The benefits of this constitutionally created U.S. currency union and, by analogy, the benefits for other politically manufactured currency unions are as- sumed to be obvious, namely a reduction in monetary instability and exchange- rate transactions costs within the union thereby stimulating long-run economic growth. These alleged benefits for the U.S., however, are not derived from market evidence, but from simple theoretical assertions and from a historical literature that has taken as fact the rhetoric of the winning side at the U.S. Con- stitutional Convention. Independent of theory and rhetoric, little is known about how and why the U.S. currency union was created, and about how this 1 See Barry EICHENGREEN, European Monetary Unification, in: Journal of Economic Literature 31, Sept. 1993, pp. 1321-1357; Mathew FORSTATER, et al., Symposium: The European Economic and Monetary Union, in: Eastern Economic Journal 25, Winter 1999, pp. 31-115; Peter B. KENEN, et al., Common Currencies Versus Currency Areas, in: American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 87, May 1997, pp. 211-229; Pablo Andres NEUMEYER, Currencies and the Allocation of Risk: The Welfare Effects of a Monetary Union, in: American Economic Review 88, Mar. 1998, pp. 246-259; Hugh ROCKOFF, How Long Did It Take the United States to Become an Optimal Currency Area?, in: NBER Historical Paper #124, April 2000, and the sources cited therein. The classic treatment is by Robert A. MUNDELL, A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas, in: American Economic Review 51, Sept. 1961, pp. 657-665; Robert A. MUNDELL, Uncommon Arguments for Common Currencies, in: Harry JOHNSON / Alexander SWOBODA (eds.), The Economics of Common Currencies, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press 1973, pp. 114-132. 2 Recently some scholars have challenged the notion that the United States really achieved an optimal currency zone with its Constitutionally mandated currency union. See ROCKOFF, How Long Did It Take. 1 union performed in relation to the next best alternative. Even exactly when the U.S. dollar was adopted by market participants for private transactions is not known. These deficiencies are addressed here. Market-generated quantitative data on the choice of currency for spot transactions, the choice of currency for for- ward transactions, exchange rates by currency, and price indices by currency from 1748 through 1811 are used to determine when the transition from state- issued currency to the U.S. dollar occurred and to assess the non-wartime per- formance of prices, exchange rates, and purchasing power parity before versus after this transition. This evidence indicates that the formation of the U.S. cur- rency union had more to do with usurpation of state sovereignty for the per- sonal gain of merchant-bankers than with solutions to monetary instability and transaction costs within the union. A concise history of 18th-century American monetary regimes is provided first. Setting the Stage: 18th-Century American Monetary Regimes The British Crown did not permit its colonies to mint coins or establish banks, nor did it permit its coins to be exported from England3. The North American 3 The summary in this section is derived from Ben BAACK, Forging a Nation State: The Continental Congress and the Financing of the War of American Independence, in: Economic History Review 54, Nov. 2001, pp. 639-656; Thomas Senior BERRY, Western Prices Before 1861, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press 1943, pp. 357-405; Hillman Metcalf BISHOP, Why Rhode Island Opposed the Federal Constitution, in: Rhode Island History 8, Jan. 1949, pp. 1-10; Apr. 1949, pp. 33-44; July 1949, pp. 85-95; Oct. 1949, pp. 115-126; Terry BOUTON, Tying Up the Revolution: Money, Power, and the Regulation in Pennsylvania, 1765-1800, unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, Duke Univ., 1996; Leslie V. BROCK, The Currency of the American Colonies, 1700-1764, New York: Arno Press 1975; Charles W. CALOMIRIS, Institutional Failure, Monetary Scarcity, and the Depreciation of the Continental, in: Journal of Economic History 48, Mar. 1988, pp. 47- 68; David Jack COWEN, The Origins and Economic Impact of the First Bank of the United States, 1791-1797, New York: Garland 2000; Joseph Albert ERNST, Money and Politics in America, 1755-1775, Chapel Hill, NC: Univ. of North Carolina Press 1973; James E. FERGUSON, The Power of the Purse, Chapel Hill, NC: Univ. of North Carolina Press 1961; Farley GRUBB, The Circulating Medium of Exchange in Colonial Pennsylvania, 1729-1775: New Estimates of Monetary Composition, Performance, and Economic Growth, in: Explorations in Economic History, 2004, forthcoming; Farley GRUBB, Two Theories of Money Reconciled: The Colonial Puzzle Revisited with New Evidence, unpublished working paper, Economics Dept., Univ. of Delaware, 2002; Bray HAMMOND, Banks and Politics in America, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1957, pp. 3-226; A. Barton HEPBURN, A History of Currency in the United States, New 2 colonies imported foreign coins through their trade surplus with the Caribbean and Southern Europe. Much of this specie, however, was re-exported, largely as a result of the mercantile policies that held the colonies in a chronic current- accounts trade deficit with the mother country. Colonists constantly com- plained that they lacked a sufficient circulating medium of exchange, especially with which to pay taxes, since taxes could not be paid through merchant-store book credit or with barter goods. Initially, some colonies allowed non-specie York: Augustus M. Kelly, Revised and Enlarged Edn. 1967, pp. 1-87; Merrill JENSEN (ed.), The Documentary History of the Ratification of the Constitution, Volumes 1-3, Madison, WI: State Historical Society of Wisconsin 1976-1978; Edward S. KAPLAN, The Bank of the United States and the American Economy, Westport, CT: Greenwood Press 1999; Donald L. KEMMERER, The Colonial Loan-Office System in New Jersey, in: Journal of Political Economy 47, Dec. 1939, pp. 867-874; Richard LESTER, Currency Issues to Overcome Depression in Pennsylvania, 1723 and 1729, in: Journal of Political Economy 46, June 1938, pp. 324-375; Richard LESTER, Currency Issues to Overcome Depressions in Delaware, New Jersey, New York, and Maryland, 1715-37, in: Journal of Political Economy 47, Apr. 1939, pp. 182-217; John J. MCCUSKER, Money and Exchange in Europe and America, 1600-1775, Chapel Hill, NC: Univ. of North Carolina Press 1978; Samuel MCKEE JR. (ed.), Papers on Public Credit, Commerce and Finance by Alexander Hamilton, New York: Columbia Univ. Press 1934; Margaret Ellen NEWELL, From Dependency to Independence, Ithaca, NY: Cornell Univ. Press 1998; Eric P. NEWMAN, The Early Paper Money of America, Iola, WI: Krause Publications, 4th edn., 1997; Arthur NUSSBAUM, A History of the Dollar, New York: Columbia Univ. Press 1957; Lawrence H. OFFICER, Between the Dollar-Sterling Gold Points, New York: Cambridge Univ. Press 1996; Edwin J. PERKINS, Conflicting Views on Fiat Currency: Britain and its North American Colonies in the Eighteenth Century, in: Business History 33, July 1991, pp. 8-30; Edwin J. PERKINS, American Public Finance and Financial Services, 1700-1815, Columbus, Ohio: Ohio State Univ. Press 1994; B. U. RATCHFORD, American State Debts, Durham, NC: Duke University Press 1941, pp. 9- 72; Sidney RATNER / James H. SOLTOW / Richard SYLLA, The Evolution of the American Economy, New York: Basic Books 1979, pp. 82-99; Anna Jacobson SCHWARTZ, The Beginning of Competitive Banking in Philadelphia, 1782-1809, in: Journal of Political Economy 55, Oct. 1947, pp. 417-431; Bruce SMITH, American Colonial Monetary Regimes: The Failure of the Quantity Theory and Some Evidence in Favor of an Alternative View, in: Canadian Journal of Economics 18, Aug. 1985, pp. 531- 565; Bruce SMITH, Some Colonial Evidence on Two Theories of Money: Maryland and the Carolinas, in: Journal of Political Economy 93, Dec. 1985, pp. 1178-1211; Clarence L. VER STEEG, Robert Morris, Revolutionary Financier, New York: Octagon Books 1976; Gary M. WALTON / Hugh ROCKOFF, History of the American Economy, New York: Dryden Press, Eighth Edn. 1998, pp. 79-89; Elmus WICKER, Colonial Monetary Standards Contrasted: Evidence from the Seven Years’ War, in: Journal of Economic History 45, Dec. 1985, pp. 869-884; Janet WILSON, The Bank of North America and Pennsylvania Politics: 1781-1787, in: Pennsylvania Magazine of History and Biography 66, Jan. 1942, pp. 3-28, and the sources cited therein. 3 commodity monies, such as paper tobacco contracts or tobacco leaf, to fill this void. In 1690 Massachusetts issued small-denomination bills of credit (paper money) to its soldiers participating in King William’s War. These bills could be used to pay taxes levied by Massachusetts and began to circulate as a medium of exchange within the colony. Soon thereafter other colonies adopted this in- novation, e.g., South Carolina in 1703, New York and New Jersey in 1709, Rhode Island in 1710, North Carolina in 1712, Pennsylvania in 1723, Maryland in 1733, Georgia in 1735, and the last being Virginia in 1755.
Recommended publications
  • Monetary Policy and the Dollar Peter L. Rousseaua 1. Introduction Twenty
    Monetary Policy and the Dollar Peter L. Rousseaua 1. Introduction Twenty-first century Americans take for granted that a dollar is worth a dollar, meaning that a given Federal Reserve note at a point in time carries a fixed purchasing power regardless of who tenders it or where it is tendered. And though one may rightfully say that prices of goods with identical physical characteristics can and do differ across localities and that a dollar may therefore not purchase the same quantities of goods everywhere, an apple in New York is a distinct economic good from an apple in Cleveland. This again just means that a dollar is worth a dollar with no questions asked of its holder. When the United States adopted the dollar as a common currency shortly after the ratification of the Federal Constitution in 1788, it represented the birth of the monetary system that for the most part continues to the present day―a system that eventually led to the dollar’s universal acceptance and rise to its position as the world’s leading currency. With it came a central bank, a mint, the start of modern banking operations and securities markets, and a newly- found confidence among investors in the ability of the young nation to service its financial obligations. The new system and its specie standard represented a marked improvement over the fiat paper money systems that had operated in the British North American colonies prior to their independence in 1776, and an enormous improvement over the rapidly-deteriorating monetary conditions that existed during the during the Revolutionary War (1776-1781) and under the Articles of Confederation (1781-1788).
    [Show full text]
  • The Circulating Medium of Exchange in Colonial Pennsylvania, 1729-1775
    The Circulating Medium of Exchange in Colonial Pennsylvania, 1729-1775: * New Estimates of Monetary Composition and Economic Growth Farley Grubb Economics Dept. Univ. of Delaware Newark, DE 19716 USA July 3, 2001 Preliminary Draft Comments Welcome * The author is Professor of Economics, University of Delaware, Newark, DE 19716 USA. E-mail: [email protected]. The author thanks Peter Coclanis, Joseph Mason, Ronald Michener, and Richard Sylla for helpful suggestions. Anne Pfaelzer de Ortiz provided research and editorial assistance. The Circulating Medium of Exchange in Colonial Pennsylvania, 1729-1775: * New Estimates of Monetary Composition and Economic Growth Market transaction data are used to estimate the composition and quantity of specie in circulation. This estimate is used to provide the first comprehensive measure of the colony's money supply. This estimate, along with data on population and prices, is used to measure the growth in output using the quantity theory of money. Output growth is found to depend on periodization and the extent to which rising commercialization increased the velocity of circulation. Specie was scarce but becoming less so as the Revolution approached, and specie and paper currency were both substitutes and complements depending on the period of analysis. Nobody knows the amount of specie in circulation in colonial America. The absence of this one piece of information has left unanswered a number of important questions about how colonial economies worked. One such question is whether specie was scarce in colonial America. Some writers believe it was scarce (Brock 1975, pp. 86, 267, 386; Bouton 1996; Lester 1938; Walton and Shepard 1979, pp.
    [Show full text]
  • The Financial Services Roundtable Insurance Information Institute
    05Fs.cover 12/21/04 1:06 PM Page 1 (2,1) 110 WFilliam StreetINANCIAL New York, NY 10038 (212) 669-9200 http//wwwS.iii.org ERVICES Insurance Information FACT Institute The Financial BOOK Services Roundtable 2 0 0 5 05.fm.fs. 12/20/04 1:58 PM Page i T h e FINAN C IAL SERVI C E S FACT B O O K 2 0 0 5 Insurance Information Institute The Financial Services Roundtable 05.fm.fs. 12/20/04 1:58 PM Page ii TO THE READER The Financial Services Fact Book, a partnership of the Insurance Information Institute and The Financial Services Roundtable, has become an indispensable resource for executives, public officials, researchers and others seeking a better understanding of financial services. In this, our fourth edition, we also identify important trends emerging post Gramm- Leach-Bliley that affect financial services as a whole. We have put these together in a sepa- rate chapter. We now see, for example, that more than 50 percent of bank holding companies a re re p o rting income from sales of insurance, mutual funds and annuities, and from invest- ment banking activities. And the number of financial holding companies involved in insur- ance underwriting more than doubled from 2000 to 2003. Early data for 2004 suggest these t rends will continue upward. In addition to these trends, other features that have been added to this edition include: • Percentage of workers with retirement benefits • Remittances (money transfers from immigrants to their families in other countries) • Information technology spending in the insurance industry • New charts on finance companies and e-commerce and more details on bank loans.
    [Show full text]
  • Lessons for Eu Integration from Us History
    LESSONS FOR EU INTEGRATION FROM US HISTORY Jacob Funk Kirkegaard and Adam S. Posen, editors Report to the European Commission under Tender Reference 2016: ECFIN 004/A Washington, DC January 2018 © 2018 European Commission. All rights reserved. The Peterson Institute for International Economics is a private nonpartisan, nonprofit institution for rigorous, intellectually open, and indepth study and discussion of international economic policy. Its purpose is to identify and analyze important issues to make globalization beneficial and sustainable for the people of the United States and the world, and then to develop and communicate practical new approaches for dealing with them. Its work is funded by a highly diverse group of philanthropic foundations, private corporations, and interested individuals, as well as income on its capital fund. About 35 percent of the Institute’s resources in its latest fiscal year were provided by contributors from outside the United States. Funders are not given the right to final review of a publication prior to its release. A list of all financial supporters is posted at https://piie.com/sites/default/files/supporters.pdf. Table of Contents 1 Realistic European Integration in Light of US Economic History 2 Jacob Funk Kirkegaard and Adam S. Posen 2 A More Perfect (Fiscal) Union: US Experience in Establishing a 16 Continent‐Sized Fiscal Union and Its Key Elements Most Relevant to the Euro Area Jacob Funk Kirkegaard 3 Federalizing a Central Bank: A Comparative Study of the Early 108 Years of the Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank Jérémie Cohen‐Setton and Shahin Vallée 4 The Long Road to a US Banking Union: Lessons for Europe 143 Anna Gelpern and Nicolas Véron 5 The Synchronization of US Regional Business Cycles: Evidence 185 from Retail Sales, 1919–62 Jérémie Cohen‐Setton and Egor Gornostay 1 Realistic European Integration in Light of US Economic History Jacob Funk Kirkegaard and Adam S.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Bank Activism Duke Law Journal, Vol
    Central Bank Activism Duke Law Journal, Vol. 71: __ (forthcoming) Christina Parajon Skinner † ABSTRACT—Today, the Federal Reserve is at a critical juncture in its evolution. Unlike any prior period in U.S. history, the Fed now faces increasing demands to expand its policy objectives to tackle a wide range of social and political problems—including climate change, income and racial inequality, and foreign and small business aid. This Article develops a framework for recognizing, and identifying the problems with, “central bank activism.” It refers to central bank activism as situations in which immediate public policy problems push central banks to aggrandize their power beyond the text and purpose of their legal mandates, which Congress has established. To illustrate, the Article provides in-depth exploration of both contemporary and historic episodes of central bank activism, thus clarifying the indicia of central bank activism and drawing out the lessons that past episodes should teach us going forward. The Article urges that, while activism may be expedient in the near term, there are long-term social costs. Activism undermines the legitimacy of central bank authority, erodes its political independence, and ultimately renders a weaker central bank. In the end, the Article issues an urgent call to resist the allure of activism. And it places front and center the need for vibrant public discourse on the role of a central bank in American political and economic life today. © 2021 Christina Parajon Skinner. Draft 2021-05-27 20:46. † Assistant Professor, The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania. This article benefited from feedback provided by workshop or conference participants at The Wharton School, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York .
    [Show full text]
  • The Preservation and Adaptation of a Financial Architectural Heritage
    University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Theses (Historic Preservation) Graduate Program in Historic Preservation 1998 The Preservation and Adaptation of a Financial Architectural Heritage William Brenner University of Pennsylvania Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.upenn.edu/hp_theses Part of the Historic Preservation and Conservation Commons Brenner, William, "The Preservation and Adaptation of a Financial Architectural Heritage" (1998). Theses (Historic Preservation). 488. https://repository.upenn.edu/hp_theses/488 Copyright note: Penn School of Design permits distribution and display of this student work by University of Pennsylvania Libraries. Suggested Citation: Brenner, William (1998). The Preservation and Adaptation of a Financial Architectural Heritage. (Masters Thesis). University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA. This paper is posted at ScholarlyCommons. https://repository.upenn.edu/hp_theses/488 For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Preservation and Adaptation of a Financial Architectural Heritage Disciplines Historic Preservation and Conservation Comments Copyright note: Penn School of Design permits distribution and display of this student work by University of Pennsylvania Libraries. Suggested Citation: Brenner, William (1998). The Preservation and Adaptation of a Financial Architectural Heritage. (Masters Thesis). University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA. This thesis or dissertation is available at ScholarlyCommons: https://repository.upenn.edu/hp_theses/488 UNIVERSITY^ PENN5YLV^NIA. UBKARIE5 The Preservation and Adaptation of a Financial Architectural Heritage William Brenner A THESIS in Historic Preservation Presented to the Faculties of the University of Pennsylvania in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of MASTER OF SCIENCE 1998 George E. 'Thomas, Advisor Eric Wm. Allison, Reader Lecturer in Historic Preservation President, Historic District ouncil University of Pennsylvania New York City iuatg) Group Chair Frank G.
    [Show full text]
  • I. Introduction This Work Aims to Show That the Present Banking Regulations
    2009-2010 BANKING REGULATION: COMPARING U.S. & ITALY 405 TOWARD AN EVOLUTIONARY THEORY OF BANKING REGULATION: THE UNITED STATES AND ITALY IN COMPARISON LEONARDO GIANI♦ & RICCARDO VANNINI♥ I. Introduction∗ This work aims to show that the present banking regulations of two very different countries—the United States and Italy—can be viewed as two outcomes of the same evolutionary path. Let us start by quoting a leading American scholar of banking law: ♦ Leonardo Giani currently works as an Attorney at Law in Italy and he is a Fellow in Business Law (Cultore della materia in diritto commerciale) at the University of Florence School of Law. In 2004, he earned an L.L.B. at the Bocconi University of Milan School of Law; in 2008, an M.Sc. in Law and Economics at the University of Siena School of Economics; and, in January 2010, a Ph.D. in Law and Economics at the University of Siena School of Economics. In the past he was a Visiting Scholar at the Boston University School of Law during the spring semester of 2007 and he worked in the capacity of Financial Supervision Expert at the European Central Bank. ♥ Riccardo Vannini is currently a Research Fellow at I-Com (www.i-com.it) and a Ph.D. candidate in Law and Economics at the University of Siena School of Economics. He earned an M.A. in Economics in 2004 and an M.Sc. in Law and Economics in 2008, both at the University of Siena School of Economics. ∗ The authors wish to thank Leandro Conte, Luca Fiorito, Tamar Frankel, Antonio Nicita, Lorenzo Stanghellini and Marco Ventoruzzo for their helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • A History of Merchant, Central and Investment Banking Learning
    Chapter 2: A History of Merchant, Central and Investment Banking Learning Objectives: To apply the history and evolution of money and banking to comprehension of existing systems To diagnose and calculate seniorage and debasement To recount how conditions drawn from history led to today's instruments and institutions To examine how economic problems lead to banking and capital market innovations To describe how money and banking integrated into the many economies over thousands of years To summarize the many artistic, literary, technological and scientific achievements that were funded or otherwise facilitated by banking To recognize the problems associated with usury in religious, social and economic contexts To express how academic, exploration, technological, trading, religious and other cultural developments contributed to the practice of banking A. Early History of Money In Chapter 1, we briefly discussed the economic roles of a number of types of financial institutions along with their origins. In this chapter, we discuss in greater detail the history of money and banking, beginning with the early history of money and extending through the advent of modern banking in the early 20th century. In later chapters, we will discuss the repeated occurrence and consequences of banking crises and development of banking regulation from a historical perspective. Commodity and Representative Money The earliest forms of money tended to have alternative intrinsic value as commodities. For example, grain-money has been used since the dawn of agriculture. Neolithic peoples in what is now China are believed to have used cowrie (sea snail) shells as money perhaps as long ago as 4,500 years.
    [Show full text]
  • Robert Morris: America’S First Financier from Forbes Greatest Business Stories of All Time by Daniel Gross, Et Al
    Robert Morris: America’s First Financier from Forbes Greatest Business Stories of All Time by Daniel Gross, et al. As the richest person in America during the Revolutionary War, Robert Morris was commonly known by the single name that encompassed his profession, his accomplishment, and his genius: he was referred to simply as “the Financier.” In the 1770s, when the United States was in its first throes of independence, Morris served as a statesman in the company of Adams, Franklin, and Jefferson. But by 1781, with the nation on the verge of forfeiting that independence to bankruptcy, he was the only choice for the newly created government post of Super- intendent of Finance, a position equivalent in the desperate days of 1781-82 to the head of the emerging executive branch. Before resigning in 1784, Morris had formulated a workable plan to restore the solvency of the United States. Though hindered from instituting his strategy completely, Morris at least staved off panic and managed to maintain the army—an estimable accomplishment. He also replaced the uncomfortable standoff between government and commerce that remained from the colonial era, establishing a closer yet freer relationship between government and business. “To do any good, [we] must infuse into traders of America a spirit of enterprise and direct their attention to such objects as will most benefit the pub- lick,” Morris insisted. “. Their own interest and the publick good goes hand in hand and they need no other prompter or tu- tor.” Robert Morris was the country’s first real businessman, and in many ways his life is a model for the mil- lions of people who have found success in the American economy he helped to create.
    [Show full text]
  • Causes of the Panic of 1907 and Its Implications for the Future (Under the Direction of Dr
    Abstract Samantha Stewart Causes of the Panic of 1907 and Its Implications for the Future (Under the Direction of Dr. Fred Bateman) There is significant knowledge that one can glean from the Panic of 1907, as it was the recession that led to the creation of the Federal Reserve and the passage of the Clayton Act. This paper will explore the causes of the Panic of 1907 by expanding upon previous research. A significant portion of this research will explore the international economy in 1907, as the Panic of 1907 began abroad and spread to the U.S. The U.S. moved completely to the gold standard in 1900, the economy became more dependent on international markets. While economists know that there was some disturbance in the European market prior to autumn 1907, the extent to which international interdependency caused the Panic in the U.S. to spread is less certain. Additionally, there are some similarities between the 1907 recession and today’s recession. The market in the early 1900s was greatly impacted by an influx of new financial instruments that encouraged people to invest. Similarly, the credit default swaps market grew significantly in the past few years. While the U.S. lacked a central bank in 1907, there is still much to be learned about the solutions employed to end the Panic. For instance, one of the early attempts to end the Panic involved giving money to banks—the same solution utilized by the Federal Reserve today. In determining the causes of the Panic of 1907 and evaluating the attempted solutions to end the Panic, I research hope to shed some light on today’s recession.
    [Show full text]
  • The Bank of North America Was Chartered in 1781 to Fund the Continental Army by Financing the Supplies Needed for It
    When and Why Was the Bank Started? • Before the Revolutionary War the American Colonies were governed by Great Britain. • The Bank of North America was chartered in 1781 to fund the Continental Army by financing the supplies needed for it. ___________________________________________________________________________ Charter: a written agreement that says how an organization will be run. Colonies: a group of people who settle in a new place but are often still governed by their homeland. Continental Army: the army George Washington led during the American Revolution. Finance: to give money for a project. Fund: to provide money for something. Revolutionary War: the war we fought against Great Britain to form our own country. Who Started the Bank? • Two main founders of the bank were: Alexander Robert Morris: Hamilton: From Philadelphia. First Secretary A key figure in of the Treasury. raising money for the Continental Army. • Both were also Founding Fathers of the United States. ______________________________________________________________________ Founder: a person who invests their time or money to start something new. Founding Father: a man who played an important role in the creation of our U.S. government. How do You Start a Bank? • To start a bank a group of people called investors decide to put their money together to use as the bank’s money. Another founding father Benjamin Franklin invested in the Bank of North America. • Once the bank has money it can make loans. For example, The Bank of North America loaned money to the Continental Army. List of some original investors _______________________________________________________________________ Benjamin Franklin: a major figure in the founding of our nation.
    [Show full text]
  • Colonial Currency
    Created by Julie Miller, May 2020 Historian and curator of manuscripts Library of Congress Colonial Currency As former British subjects, American colonists and others living in America usually expressed the value of items they bought and sold in pounds (£), shillings (s), and pence (d). One pound was worth 20 shillings, and one shilling equaled twelve pence. Prices, such as the ones in George Washington’s Revolutionary War receipts, are usually written like this: pounds.shillings.pence. For example: Lloyd Danbury sold Washington: Two bottles of “Sallad Oyl” for .7.0 (7 shillings) “3 doz & 10 Bottles Porter” for 3.16.8 (3 pounds, 16 shillings, 8 pence) There are plenty of individual variations. For example: James Sequin, who sold Washington three items, including a “long box” for 5/2 (5 shillings, 2 pence), wrote the total for all three as “£0=15=1” (no pounds, 15 shillings, 1penny). Note the unusual way he writes his pound symbol. Pennsylvania tavern keeper Isaac Servill billed Washington “30:19:9” (30 pounds, 19 shillings, 9 pence) for dinners, wine, “tody” (toddy), “Musickennons” (musicians), and more. Thomas Marston spelled out his bill for “Thirty Nine pounds Twelve Shillings” for “Eleven dozen of Old Madeira Wine,” then expressed the amount as £39.12 – . A straight or wavy line resembling an em dash sometimes substituted for a period in the eighteenth century. Dorothy Shewcraft, who sold Washington a pair of andirons and a “Scoch Carpett” [Scotch carpet] used a wavy line: Andirons 5 10 ~ (5 pounds, 10 shillings) Scotch carpet 3 ~ ~ (3 pounds) Her total was: £18 10 ~ (18 pounds, ten shillings) The value of American pounds, shillings, and pence was local.
    [Show full text]