Mandatory Central Clearing: Clearinghouse Failure and Systemic Risk

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Mandatory Central Clearing: Clearinghouse Failure and Systemic Risk Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP www.cadwalader.com Mandatory Central Clearing: Clearinghouse Failure and Systemic Risk Presented By: Robert Zwirb ACI’s Swaps & Derivatives Transaction Conference December 1, 2016 Introduction • Clearing of certain OTC derivatives through central counterparties (“CCPs”) or clearinghouses is touted as a way to reduce both counterparty and systemic risk and greatly lower the likelihood of a repeat of the 2007–2009 financial crisis. • Following the financial crisis of 2007-2009, leaders of the G-20 nations agreed that “[a]ll standardized OTC derivative contracts should be traded on exchanges or electronic trading, where appropriate, and cleared through central counterparties by end- 2012 at the latest.” • To reduce systemic risk in the derivatives markets, the Dodd Frank Act mandated trading of certain OTC derivatives be subject to central clearing. Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 2 Introduction • “The push for mandatory clearing of OTC traded derivatives is as much a result of the long history of success of exchange traded derivative markets in minimizing counterparty risk and promoting transparency as the presumed failure of certain OTC traded derivative markets to handle counterparty risk during the recent financial crisis. Simply stated, exchange traded derivative markets worked well during the crisis while some OTC derivatives markets either did not or appeared not to work well.” • Joseph K. W. Fung; Robert I. Webb, Clearing and OTC Traded Derivatives: A Survey, Review of Futures Markets; 2012 Special Edition, Vol. 20, p. 9, July 2012. Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 3 Introduction • More recently, however, concerns have been raised that CCPs themselves may be a source of systemic risk. • For example, while acknowledging that requiring most bilateral swaps to be cleared through a CCP “minimizes counterparty risk and represents a significant step towards ensuring a safe and stable financial system,” some members of Congress have expressed concerns that such an arrangement “engenders the risk that a DCO might fail because of an increased concentration of risk at the clearinghouse, causing significant threats to the financial system.” Letters from Sen. Elizabeth Warren, Sen. Mark Warner and Rep. Elijah E. Cummings (D-MD and Rep. Cummings to CME Group, Inc. and Ice Clear Credit LLC regarding recovery and resolution plans of those clearing organizations (July 5, 2016) . Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 4 Central counterparty clearing • “Central counterparty clearing” refers to an arrangement by which a central counterparty (or CCP) is substituted as a principal to all cleared trades, becoming the buyer to all sellers and the seller to all buyers.” Ivan Ruffini & Robert Steigerwald, OTC Derivatives — A Primer on Market Infrastructure and Regulatory Policy (Nov. 25, 2014). Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 5 Bilateral vs Cleared Transactions Bilateral Central Clearing A B 100 A B CCP Chart derived from presentation slides by Darrell Duffie, Failure Resolution of Central Counterparties, Banque de France-ACPR Conference, Paris (September 28, 2015). Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 6 Benefits of central counterparty clearing • Clearing facilitates three important benefits: (1) multilateral netting of exposures and payments by the clearinghouse, (2) improved counterparty risk management, and (3) increased transparency for regulators and the public through increased availability of information on market activity and exposures. – Clearing also permits customers to take positions without concern for the financial integrity of persons on the other side of the trade, because it is the clearinghouse, not the customer, that deals with counterparty risk. Thus, clearing members do not need to make a credit assessment of the other clearing members or their clients. – Clearing also allows large losses to be mutualized, or spread among a CCP’s broad membership. If one member cannot honor its obligations in a trade, the member's losses are first borne by its margin. If the margin is insufficient, then the DCO can tap a default fund, which all members pay into as a condition of membership. Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 7 Benefits of central counterparty clearing • Under clearing, the tangled and highly opaque picture of a purely bilateral market is replaced by a neater and simpler hub-and-spoke network in which the CCP is buyer to every seller, and seller to every buyer, allowing netting and greater transparency for participants and regulators alike, as illustrated by the chart below: Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 8 Benefits of central counterparty clearing • It is also claimed that a clearinghouse is much less likely than its members to fail during a crisis. • “When a member fails, the clearinghouse engages in netting, meaning that it uses short-term debts owed to the member to immediately repay short-term debts owed by the member. • As a result, the surviving clearinghouse members are paid much more quickly than they would be in bankruptcy. Meanwhile, the bankrupt member's outside (non-clearinghouse) creditors are not paid any less quickly: they still are paid at the end of the bankruptcy proceeding, which the clearinghouse does nothing to prolong. • By accelerating cash payouts to some creditors without slowing down payouts to others, the clearinghouse decreases total illiquidity risk in the financial sector.” • Richard Squire, Clearinghouses as Liquidity Partitioning, 99 Cornell L. Rev., 857, 859 (May 2014). Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 9 Risks of Central Counterparty Clearing • In general, the risks associated with clearing are: a) a default by a large clearing member or more than one clearing member, which could put at risk the financial integrity of the clearing organization; b) contagion, whereby the failure of a clearing member could cause the CCP to fail to meet its obligations to other clearing members; c) fire sales of collateral or derivatives contracts, and disorderly unwind of CCPs exacerbating broad market volatility; and d) loss of continuity of critical clearing services on which the financial system has come to depend. Darrell Duffie, "Resolution of Failing Central Counterparties," in Making Failure Feasible: How Bankruptcy Reform Can End 'Too Big To Fail', edited by Thomas Jackson, Kenneth Scott and John E. Taylor, Hoover Institution Press, p. 88, (2015). Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 10 The Case For Mandatory Central Clearing • Advocates of mandatory central clearing argue that it reduces both 1) interconnectedness that leads to financial contagion in times of stress, and 2) systemic risk. • “Advocates have repeatedly stated that the interconnected nature of the financial system makes it vulnerable to contagion, in which the failure of one large financial institution brings down others with which it has traded. They state further that clearing ‘greatly reduces’ these interconnections. Advocates have also claimed that CCPs eliminate counterparty risk and guarantee all payments owed under derivatives contracts.” Craig Pirrong, The Inefficiency of Clearing Mandates, p. 24 (CATO Inst., Policy Analysis No. 665, 2010). • Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 11 Mandatory Central Clearing—CFTC View • “The Commission believes that a clearing requirement will reduce counterparty credit risk and provide an organized mechanism for collateralizing the risk exposures posed by swaps.” • “‘With appropriate collateral and margin requirements, a central clearing organization can substantially reduce counterparty risk and provide an organized mechanism for clearing transactions. * * * While large losses are to be expected in derivatives trading, if those positions are fully margined there will be no loss to counterparties and the overall financial system and none of the uncertainty about potential exposures that contributed to the panic in 2008.’” • Clearing Requirement Determination Under Section 2(h) of the CEA, 77 Fed. Reg. 74284, 74285 (Dec. 13, 2012) (Final Rule), quoting Senate Report 111–176, at 32 (April 30, 2010). Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 12 Mandatory Central Clearing—CFTC View • “The Commission notes that CME or its predecessors have cleared futures since 1898 and is the largest futures clearinghouse in the world. CME has not defaulted during that time.” • “[T]he Commission believes that the central clearing of the interest rate swaps that are the subject of this determination and final rule would serve to mitigate counterparty credit risk thereby having a positive effect on reducing systemic risk.” • “Clearinghouses have demonstrated resilience in the face of past market stress. Most recently, they remained financially sound and effectively settled positions in the midst of turbulent events in 2007–2008 that threatened the financial health and stability of many other types of entities.” Clearing Requirement Determination Under Section 2(h) of the CEA, 77 Fed. Reg. 74284, 74312, 74322 (Dec. 13, 2012). Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 13 Mandatory Central Clearing—Views of Critics • Critics argue that mandatory central clearing: 1) transforms credit risk into liquidity risk, and that liquidity risk is more systemically threatening than credit risk; 2) does not make default risks disappear, but instead distributes them among the other members of the clearinghouse; and 3) does not reduce systemic risk, but rather concentrates it in the clearinghouse. • For example, Federal Reserve Governor Jerome H. Powell points out that central clearing has its own set of risks including
Recommended publications
  • New Monetarist Economics: Methods∗
    Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 442 April 2010 New Monetarist Economics: Methods∗ Stephen Williamson Washington University in St. Louis and Federal Reserve Banks of Richmond and St. Louis Randall Wright University of Wisconsin — Madison and Federal Reserve Banks of Minneapolis and Philadelphia ABSTRACT This essay articulates the principles and practices of New Monetarism, our label for a recent body of work on money, banking, payments, and asset markets. We first discuss methodological issues distinguishing our approach from others: New Monetarism has something in common with Old Monetarism, but there are also important differences; it has little in common with Keynesianism. We describe the principles of these schools and contrast them with our approach. To show how it works, in practice, we build a benchmark New Monetarist model, and use it to study several issues, including the cost of inflation, liquidity and asset trading. We also develop a new model of banking. ∗We thank many friends and colleagues for useful discussions and comments, including Neil Wallace, Fernando Alvarez, Robert Lucas, Guillaume Rocheteau, and Lucy Liu. We thank the NSF for financial support. Wright also thanks for support the Ray Zemon Chair in Liquid Assets at the Wisconsin Business School. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Banks of Richmond, St. Louis, Philadelphia, and Minneapolis, or the Federal Reserve System. 1Introduction The purpose of this essay is to articulate the principles and practices of a school of thought we call New Monetarist Economics. It is a companion piece to Williamson and Wright (2010), which provides more of a survey of the models used in this literature, and focuses on technical issues to the neglect of methodology or history of thought.
    [Show full text]
  • TORC3: Token-Ring Clearing Heuristic for Currency Circulation
    TORC3: Token-Ring Clearing Heuristic for Currency Circulation Carlos Humes Jr.∗, Marcelo S. Lauretto†, Fábio Nakano†, Carlos A.B. Pereira∗, Guilherme F.G. Rafare∗∗ and Julio M. Stern∗,‡ ∗Institute of Mathematics and Statistics of the University of São Paulo, Brazil †School of Arts, Sciences and Humanities of the University of São Paulo, Brazil ∗∗FinanTech Ltda. ‡[email protected] Abstract. Clearing algorithms are at the core of modern payment systems, facilitating the settling of multilateral credit messages with (near) minimum transfers of currency. Traditional clearing procedures use batch processing based on MILP - mixed-integer linear programming algorithms. The MILP approach demands intensive computational resources; moreover, it is also vulnerable to operational risks generated by possible defaults during the inter-batch period. This paper presents TORC3 - the Token-Ring Clearing Algorithm for Currency Circulation. In contrast to the MILP approach, TORC3 is a real time heuristic procedure, demanding modest computational resources, and able to completely shield the clearing operation against the participating agents’ risk of default. Keywords: Bayesian calibration; Clearing algorithms; Heuristic optimization; Multilateral netting; Operational risk; Payment systems; Real-time heuristic procedures. 1. INTRODUCTION Clearing algorithms are at the core of modern payment systems, facilitating multilat- eral netting, that is, the settling of multilateral credit messages with (near) minimum transfers of currency. Traditional clearing procedures use batch processing based on mixed-integer linear programming algorithms. Large scale mixed-integer programming demands intensive computational resources; most of the traditional clearing algorithms require large mainframe computers. Furthermore, this approach delays all payments to after the batch processing (usually overnight). Moreover, batch processing introduces an operational risk originated from the possibility of a participant’s default in the iter-batch processing period.
    [Show full text]
  • International Barter
    WORKING PAPER ALFRED P. SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT INTERNATIONAL BARTER Adrian E. Tschoegl Sloan School of Management M.I.T. Working Paper #996-78 May 1978 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 INTERNATIONAL BARTER* Adrian E. Tschoegl Sloan School of Management M.I.T. Working Paper #996-78 May 1978 *I would like to thank Edward M, Graham, Donald R, Lessard, N.G. Tschoegl, and N.W. Tschoegl for their comments, criticism, and assistance. -1- I. Introduction Barter is the oldest form of trade. The payment for goods with goods predates the invention of money and is still with us today. This paper has two purposes: first, to expose the student of international business to this form of trade between nations; and second, to contradict the sentiments ex- pressed in this quotation: "It is difficult for Americans, so committed to free trade, to understand the logic behind trade without money. Per- haps there is no 'logic,' at least in terms of traditional Western economic theory. Maybe the-re are only reasons that few Americans can understand and even fewer can accept. "' In this section we summarily review the nature of 'trade without money' and its recent history. Section II examines the various modes of barter in some detail, focusing on the common provisions and pitfalls of such transactions. Section III discusses two proximate causes for barter, price distortions and the need for liquidity, and two benefits, improvement in the terms of trade and the creation of long-term contracts and trading relationships. Section IV concerns itself with the political-economy of barter, that is, the reasons behind the proximate causes.
    [Show full text]
  • Ben S Bernanke: Clearinghouses, Financial Stability, and Financial Reform
    Ben S Bernanke: Clearinghouses, financial stability, and financial reform Speech by Mr Ben S Bernanke, Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, at the 2011 Financial Markets Conference, Stone Mountain, Georgia, 4 April 2011. The original speech, which contains various links to the documents mentioned, can be found on the US Federal Reserve System’s website. * * * I am pleased to speak once again at the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta’s Financial Markets Conference. This year’s conference covers an interesting mix of topics bearing on the vital ongoing global debate on how best to prevent and respond to financial crises. Tonight I would like to discuss post-crisis reform as it relates to a prominent part of our financial market infrastructure – namely, clearinghouses for payments, securities, and derivatives transactions. This audience, I know, recognizes the importance of what is often called the “plumbing” of the financial system – a set of institutions that very safely and efficiently handles, under most circumstances, enormous volumes of financial transactions each day. Because clearinghouses and other parts of the financial infrastructure fared relatively well during the crisis – despite moments of significant stress – the public debate on financial reform has understandably focused on the risks posed by so-called too-big-to-fail financial firms, whose dramatic failures or near failures put our financial system and economy in dire jeopardy. Nevertheless, the smooth operation and financial soundness of clearinghouses and related institutions are essential for financial stability, and we must not take them for granted. Importantly, title 8 of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (Dodd-Frank Act) contains provisions aimed at improving the transparency, resilience, and financial strength of clearinghouses, which the act calls financial market utilities.
    [Show full text]
  • Nber Working Paper Series David Laidler On
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DAVID LAIDLER ON MONETARISM Michael Bordo Anna J. Schwartz Working Paper 12593 http://www.nber.org/papers/w12593 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 October 2006 This paper has been prepared for the Festschrift in Honor of David Laidler, University of Western Ontario, August 18-20, 2006. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2006 by Michael Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. David Laidler on Monetarism Michael Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz NBER Working Paper No. 12593 October 2006 JEL No. E00,E50 ABSTRACT David Laidler has been a major player in the development of the monetarist tradition. As the monetarist approach lost influence on policy makers he kept defending the importance of many of its principles. In this paper we survey and assess the impact on monetary economics of Laidler's work on the demand for money and the quantity theory of money; the transmission mechanism on the link between money and nominal income; the Phillips Curve; the monetary approach to the balance of payments; and monetary policy. Michael Bordo Faculty of Economics Cambridge University Austin Robinson Building Siegwick Avenue Cambridge ENGLAND CD3, 9DD and NBER [email protected] Anna J. Schwartz NBER 365 Fifth Ave, 5th Floor New York, NY 10016-4309 and NBER [email protected] 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Exchange Clearing of Financial Transmission Rights (Eftrs)
    APRIL 22, 2021 Exchange Clearing of Financial Transmission Rights (EFTRs) NEPOOL Budget & Finance Subcommittee Meeting Cheryl Arnold DIRECTOR, FINANCE & ACCOUNTING ISO NEW ENGLAND Sylvie Jobes SENIOR MANAGER, RISK & STRATEGIC ANALYSIS NODAL EXCHANGE, LLC ISO-NE PUBLIC Contents of Presentation Page(s) • Project Objectives 3 • Introduction: Current Financial Transmission Rights (FTR) Mechanisms 4-7 • Overview of Design Concept 8-9 • Proposed Design 10-33 – Participating Entities – Background on Clearing House Model – Sequence for Exchanging FTR Awards to Futures Contracts – Billing, Collections and Settlement Process – Benefits of Proposed Design/Risk Management • Legal and Regulatory Considerations 34 • Tentative Project Schedule 35-36 ISO-NE PUBLIC 2 Project Objectives • Replace ISO-NE Financial Assurance requirements for holding Financial Transmission Rights (FTRs) with clearing of equivalent futures contracts by a CFTC jurisdictional exchange / clearing house – A clearing house is better positioned to handle valuation (margin) on an ongoing basis – Default risk is shifted from ISO-NE’s market participants to clearing house • Facilitate secondary market trading ISO-NE PUBLIC 3 Introduction: Current FTR Mechanisms (1) • An FTR is a financial instrument − acquired in an ISO-NE auction − that entitles the holder to receive compensation for congestion costs. It can be used to hedge the Day-Ahead LMP congestion component difference on a specific path between receipt and delivery points in the New England energy market. • Revenues from the
    [Show full text]
  • Clearing and Settlement
    Clearing and Settlement OmniPay is First Data’s™ cost effective, industry-leading payment processing platform. Flexible data capture, batch handling and posting options At-a-Glance First Data’s goal is to provide the data that you need, when you need The OmniPay platform enables efficient and cost effective it. The OmniPay platform receives, consolidates, formats and posts Clearing and Settlement services transaction data at a designated frequency and according to a client’s and outstanding responsiveness required processing calendar. And because it’s designed for domestic to acquiring customers and their and international schemes, processing can occur in alignment with banks’ customer’s needs. different time zones, different bank holidays, and varying volumes across varying countries, etc. Even sub-groups of activity within an institution can each be processed distinctly. Clearing and Settlement Extensive business, transaction and Settlement product support Settlement data is instantly visible through First Data’s The OmniPay platform supports acquiring for a broad Remote Access Module (RAM). One click lets you locate range of merchant segments: scheme reports or utilise a suite of production reconciliation reporting tools. • The volume of contract deliverables puts a strain on resources to keep up with timely review and approval The OmniPay platform predicts when settlement will occur—even before the transactions are cleared—by assessing • Retail the characteristics of individual transactions to determine the • eCommerce service under which they will be settled. : • Aggregator merchants Interchange management • Airline acquiring Interchange fees are estimated before settlement occurs, • Car hire ensuring clients can bill at least what they will pay in interchange.
    [Show full text]
  • Required Clearing Balances by E.J
    Required Clearing Balances by E.J. Stevens E.J. Stevens is an assistant vice president and economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleve- land. The author thanks Cheryl L. Edwards for helpful comments on an earlier draft of this article and Ann Dombrosky for invaluable re- search assistance. Introduction Bank to comply with the combined require- ments. For each of these institutions, the conse- Few people realize that in addition to complying quences of modest account deficiencies or with a Federal Reserve System regulation for surpluses are reckoned on the basis of re- holding a required reserve balance, many banks quired clearing balance rules. Only if a bank simultaneously meet an additional requirement fails to meet any of its clearing balance require- to hold a clearing balance in their account at a ment does it face the familiar "discount rate Federal Reserve Bank. This clearing balance re- plus 2 percent" penalty for a required reserve quirement differs from the familiar reserve re- deficiency. Likewise, such a bank wastes sur- quirement in three significant ways. First, a bank's plus balances by earning no rate of return only agreement to meet the requirement is typically a if its actual balance exceeds its required bal- business decision, not a legal necessity. Second, ance by more than a preestablished margin. the amount of the requirement is mostly discre- Almost all analyses of bank reserve manage- tionary, not a fixed percentage of the bank's de- ment behavior focus entirely on reserve require- posit liabilities. And third, the rate of return on a ments, ignoring clearing balances because they clearing balance is about equal to the federal are a relatively recent innovation.2 Clearly, how- funds rate, not zero, although a bank can use the ever, an important set of banks now maintains earnings only to pay for services it buys from a balances at the Fed following a somewhat differ- Federal Reserve Bank.
    [Show full text]
  • By:Bill Medley
    By: Bill Medley Highways of Commerce Central Banking and The U.S. Payments System By: Bill Medley Highways of Commerce Central Banking and The U.S. Payments System Published by the Public Affairs Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City 1 Memorial Drive • Kansas City, MO 64198 Diane M. Raley, publisher Lowell C. Jones, executive editor Bill Medley, author Casey McKinley, designer Cindy Edwards, archivist All rights reserved, Copyright © 2014 Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City No part of this book may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior consent of the publisher. First Edition, July 2014 The Highways of Commerce • III �ontents Foreword VII Chapter One A Calculus of Chaos: Commerce in Early America 1 Chapter Two “Order out of Confusion:” The Suffolk Bank 7 Chapter Three “A New Era:” The Clearinghouse 19 Chapter Four “A Famine of Currency:” The Panic of 1907 27 Chapter Five “The Highways of Commerce:” The Road to a Central Bank 35 Chapter Six “A problem…of great novelty:” Building a New Clearing System 45 Chapter Seven Bank Robbers and Bolsheviks: The Par Clearance Controversy 55 Chapter Eight “A Plump Automatic Bookkeeper:” The Rise of Banking Automation 71 Chapter Nine Control and Competition: The Monetary Control Act 83 Chapter Ten The Fed’s Air Force: A Plan for the Future 95 Chapter Eleven Disruption and Evolution: The Development of Check 21 105 Chapter Twelve Banks vs. Merchants: The Durbin Amendment 113 Afterword The Path Ahead 125 Endnotes 128 Sources and Selected Bibliography 146 Photo Credits 154 Index 160 Contents • V ForewordAs Congress undertook the task of designing a central bank for the United States in 1913, it was clear that lawmakers intended for the new institution to play a key role in improving the performance of the nation’s payments system.
    [Show full text]
  • CLEARING and SETTLING MONEY MARKET INSTRUMENTS David L
    Page 173 The information in this chapter was last updated in 1993. Since the money market evolves very rapidly, recent developments may have superseded some of the content of this chapter. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Richmond, Virginia 1998 Chapter 13 BEHIND THE MONEY MARKET: CLEARING AND SETTLING MONEY MARKET INSTRUMENTS David L. Mengle Whenever a money market instrument is traded, some means must exist for transferring the instrument and for making payment. In other words, there is a necessity for clearing and settling the trade, tasks that are usually referred to as operational, or back-office, functions. Clearing refers to processing a trade and establishing what the parties to the trade owe each other. Settlement refers to the transfer of value between the parties so the trade is completed (Group of Thirty 1989, p. 35). The first step in the clearing and settlement process involves conveying the details of the trade from traders to the back office. Second, the details must be compared and matched between the buyer and seller to ensure that both buyer and seller agree on what is to be traded and on what terms. Failure to do so might lead to delivery problems. This chapter will focus on what happens next: determination of the obligations between the parties and settlement of the trade. Clearing and settlement systems link the participants in the money market. This chapter uses examples to describe how clearing and settlement take place for various types of money market instruments.1 In addition, it discusses risks inherent in clearing and settlement, and the steps being considered to reduce such risks.
    [Show full text]
  • The Options Clearing Corporation Disclosure Framework for Financial Market Infrastructures
    THE OPTIONS CLEARING CORPORATION DISCLOSURE FRAMEWORK FOR FINANCIAL MARKET INFRASTRUCTURES © 2021 The Options Clearing Corporation Page 1 of 123 Responding Institution: The Options Clearing Corporation Jurisdiction in which the FMI Operates: United States Authority regulating, supervising or U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission overseeing the FMI: U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve The date of this disclosure is June 10, 2021. This disclosure can also be found at: https://www.theocc.com/Risk-Management/PFMI- Disclosures. For further information, please contact [email protected]. © 2021 The Options Clearing Corporation Page 2 of 123 TABLE OF CONTENTS I. Executive Summary .....................................................................................................................4 II. Summary of Major Change Since Last Update .............................................................................4 III. General Background on OCC .......................................................................................................4 IV. Glossary of Terms and Abbreviations ...........................................................................................7 V. Principle-By-Principle Narrative Disclosure ..................................................................................9 Principle 1: Legal Basis; SEC Rule 17Ad-22(e)(1) .......................................................................10 Principle 2: Goverance; SEC Rule 17Ad-22(e)(2) ........................................................................15
    [Show full text]
  • Modernisation of Cheque Clearing
    Modernisation of cheque clearing The Bank of Mauritius in collaboration with the Mauritius Bankers Association introduced a modern system for clearing cheques in September 2011. From this date, banks send only the digital image of cheques to the Bank of Mauritius for clearing. This process, called ‘Truncation’, is the most secure and fastest mode of cheques clearing and is already in use in several countries amongst which Singapore, Hong Kong and India. What are the benefits of the system? Cheque truncation will bring speed, efficiency and security to the whole chain of processes related to payment by cheques. The system will: • speed up the process of collection of cheques and reduce the time required for payment, • reduce the delay in processing and associated cost of transit; and • identify high value cheques which will undergo a fast track clearing (High value cheques are those with value above Rs 1 million). What changes for me as a cheque user or cheque receiver? The new system impacts mainly the processes of banks and the clearing house. For cheque users, the new system will imply: • no change if the cheque is in order and it is honoured. • that if the cheque is dishonoured, an authenticated copy of the image of the cheque is returned instead of the original cheque. Depending on the reason for return, the image can be used for re-presentment. How does the system work? • Cheques will be deposited at the collecting bank in the same manner as it is currently done. • Cheques are scanned by collecting bank and the images are sent, as in the current process, to the Clearing House at the Bank of Mauritius where exchange of cheque images is carried out.
    [Show full text]