The Origins and Consequences of Compulsory Voting in Latin America

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Origins and Consequences of Compulsory Voting in Latin America THE ORIGINS AND CONSEQUENCES OF COMPULSORY VOTING IN LATIN AMERICA By Arturo Maldonado Dissertation Submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Vanderbilt University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY in Political Science December, 2015 Nashville, Tennessee Approved: Date: _______________________________________________ __________________ Elizabeth J. Zechmeister, Ph.D. _______________________________________________ __________________ Mitchell A. Seligson, Ph.D. _______________________________________________ __________________ Cindy D. Kam, Ph.D. _______________________________________________ __________________ Jonathan Hiskey, Ph.D. _______________________________________________ __________________ André Blais, Ph.D. Copyright © 2015 by Arturo Maldonado All Rights Reserved Para Gioco, mi elección voluntaria iii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Six years of graduate education have transformed me from a person interested in Political Science to a political scientist. This journey would not have been possible without the support of my lovely and supportive wife Gioco. Te amo!! Together, we moved to a new country and began our new life in Nashville. During this time, she has been in charge of the needs of our growing family while I was busy struggling with this dissertation and finishing the Ph.D. She is the light in this journey. In the meantime, our two kids were born: Arturo and Florencia, who bring more happiness to our life. My family is the main motivation to grow still further as scholar and professional. When I arrived to Nashville, I met a fantastic group of people. I first met Charo Basay and her family who courteously welcomed to her home in our first days in Nashville. I also met awesome professors and fellow graduate students in the Department of Political Science. I would specially like to thank Mitch Seligson and Liz Zechmeister, who have been mentors and advisors in my years in graduate school and have co-chaired this dissertation project. Mitch has inspired me to be a rigorous and meticulous scholar. I learned about the political economy of inequality in his seminar and the intricacies of public opinion research in Latin America in the LAPOP project. This dissertation owes a great deal of its content to the thoughts and feedback of Liz Zechmeister. She provided invaluable comments and was a critical reader of every chapter of this dissertation. I really appreciate the time and commitment that she dedicated to this dissertation in the middle of her innumerable activities as a remarkable professor at Vanderbilt University and as a LAPOP Director. I am also indebted to many professors, colleagues, and friends, who have helped me at different stages in this project. At Vanderbilt University, I would like to thank Jonathan Hiskey iv and Cindy Kam, who were also part of my dissertation committee. Josh Clinton, Zeynep Somer- Topcu, Suzanne Globetti, Alan Wiseman, Monique Lyle, and Larry Bartels, all were terrific instructors in substantive and methodological topics. My research included fieldwork in Colombia. This part of my research was generously sponsored by the RIPS Small Grant for Experimental Research at the Research on Individuals, Politics & Society Lab at Vanderbilt University. In Colombia, Fredy Barrero and Nicolás Liendo graciously granted me access to the Universidad Sergio Arboleda, Ivonne León to the Universidad Nacional de Colombia, Miguel García to the Universidad de Los Andes, and Fabián Acuña to the Pontificia Universidad Javeriana, where I applied a survey experiment with their students. I was also able to spend time in Peru for doing fieldwork. This research was made possible due to a research grant from the National Science Foundation (0851136 and 0850824), which supported the implementation of a survey-based experiment in Lima, Peru. I was the Peru- based coordinator of that study, administered by Jennifer Merolla and Liz Zechmeister, and had their approval to embed the experiment into that data collection effort. The broader study was approved by the Vanderbilt IRB (IRB# 081383) and the experiment presented here was also reviewed and approved by the Vanderbilt IRB office. In my country, Aldo Panfichi kindly reserved a space in the Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú. In this carrel, I wrote much of this dissertation. In my alma mater, I would like to thank Eduardo Dargent, Martín Tanaka and David Sulmont for their generous support during these years. Among my Peruvian colleagues and friend, Carlos Meléndez, José Carlos Requena and Paula Muñoz deserve a special note of gratitude. v Among my “Nashvillian” colleagues and friend, I would like to thank: Rubí Arana, José Miguel Cruz, Margarita Corral, Justin Pickering, Alejandro Diaz-Dominguez, Diana Orcés, Daniel Montalvo, María Fernanda Boidi, Dominique Zephyr, Abby Córdova, Mason Moseley, Mariana Rodriguez, Matt Leyton, Trevor Lyons, Scott Revey, Steve Utych, Becca McBride, Anna Carella, Ted Enamorado, Fabiola Pineda, Camilo Plata, Fred Batista, Gui Russo, Mollie Cohen, Rafael Piñeiro, Amy Erica Smith, Ana María Montoya, Nicole Hinton, and Georgina Pizzolitto. Among the administrative staff at Vanderbilt, I want to than Tonya Mills, Darlene Davidson, Tina Bembry and Natasha Duncan for their significant help during these years. In particular, I would like to thank Daniel Zizumbo-Colunga, my friend and colleague, with whom I spent endless hours discussing our dissertation projects. Some ideas in this dissertation were born in these stimulating talks. Last but definitely not least, I would like to thanks my parents and my large family. I remembered my parents at every stage and they were the inspiration for this journey: Arturo and Reneé, tarea cumplida!! In these six years, my family experienced profound losses: my father-in- law Manuel, my mother-in-law Irma, and my sister Charo. The culmination of this project is a tribute to their memories. vi TABLE OF CONTENTS Page DEDICATION ............................................................................................................................... iii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ............................................................................................................ v LIST OF TABLES ......................................................................................................................... vi LIST OF FIGURES ...................................................................................................................... vii CHAPTER I. INTRODUCTION: COMPULSORY VOTING IN LATIN AMERICA .......................... 1 The Debate about the Implementation of Compulsory Voting ................................................... 4 Turnout in Latin America ........................................................................................................... 9 Variation in the Implementation of Compulsory Voting in Latin America .............................. 13 The Dissertation in Brief ........................................................................................................... 19 II. THE STRATEGIC IMPLEMENTATION OF COMPULSORY VOTING AND FRANCHISE EXPANSIONS IN LATIN AMERICA ............................................................. 22 Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 22 The Implementation of Electoral Rules as a Struggle of Power ............................................... 26 Compulsory voting and Enfranchisement as Strategic Decisions ........................................ 26 Pressures for Social and Political Transformation in Latin America ....................................... 35 Argentina and Uruguay: Still Powerful Elite and Rising Disenfranchised Groups .............. 36 Bolivia and Peru: Divided Elites and Weak Disenfranchised Groups .................................. 38 Institutional Outcome ................................................................................................................ 41 Scenario A: Franchise Expansion and Compulsory Voting ................................................. 42 vii Uruguay as a Middle Path Between Scenario A and B ........................................................ 45 Scenario C: Compulsory Voting and Later Franchise Expansion ........................................ 47 Further Consequences After Critical Junctures ........................................................................ 53 Expanding the Model to Other Countries ................................................................................. 58 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................ 64 III. SHIFTING RATIONALES: DETERMINANTS OF VOTER TURNOUT IN COMPULSORY VERSUS VOLUNTARY VOTING COUNTRIES IN LATIN AMERICA ................................................................................................................................... 67 Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 67 Theoretical Framework ............................................................................................................. 70 The Calculus of Voting Under Voluntary and Compulsory Voting Systems ....................... 71 Methods and Data ..................................................................................................................... 76 Results ......................................................................................................................................
Recommended publications
  • AC Compulsory Voting
    Cy-Fair HS Novice Affirmative Case Sept.-Oct 2013- Compulsory Voting “The vote is the most powerful instrument ever devised by man for breaking down injustice and destroying the terrible walls which imprison men because they are different from other men.” Because I agree with these words of former President Lyndon B. Johnson, I stand firmly Resolved: In a democracy, voting ought to be compulsory. According to the Merriam-Webster Dictionary, ought is defined as implying obligation or advisability. Compulsory voting is defined as a system in which electors are obliged to vote in elections or attend a polling place on voting day. If an eligible voter does not attend a polling place, he or she may be subJect to punitive measures.. The value that the affirmative defends is governmental legitimacy. Since a legitimate government must fulfill its obligations to it’s people, a legitimate democracy must strive to be consistent with its core ideals. Thus, the criteria is being consistent with the fundamental characteristics of democracy. As defined in his book Democracy and It’s Critics, Robert Dahl explains that in addition to the concept of “one-person-one-vote”, democracies have four distinguishing characteristics: 1. Effective participation 2. Enlightened understanding of issues 3. Control of the political agenda 4. Inclusiveness Whichever debater’s position is most consistent with these characteristics is being most consistent with democratic legitimacy and should win the debate. 1 Cy-Fair HS Novice Affirmative Case Sept.-Oct 2013- Compulsory Voting My single contention is that compulsory voting is most consistent with the fundamental characteristics of democracy.
    [Show full text]
  • ¿Quién Vota? Compulsory Voting and the Persistence of Class Bias In
    ¿Quien´ Vota? Compulsory Voting and the Persistence of Class Bias in Latin America Yanilda Gonzalez´ Steven A. Snell Harvard Kennedy School Duke University yanilda [email protected] [email protected] August 31, 2015 Abstract Universal suffrage does not guarantee universal participation. Scholars diagnose the dis- parity in turnout between rich and poor as an important democratic deficit and propose com- pulsory voting as a key institutional remedy. While countries with compulsory have higher turnout rates, it is unclear whether compulsory voting meaningfully alleviates inequality in turnout. The present work examines the extent to which compulsory voting mitigates the class bias common to voter turnout. We draw on evidence from Latin America, a region character- ized by widespread compulsory voting laws and high economic inequality. We demonstrate that compulsory voting results in higher turnout only when enforced and that the gains in turnout are primarily among the poor. We also find, however, that unequal turnout persists even under strict compulsory voting systems. We further demonstrate that disadvantaged cit- izens are less likely to vote in countries with strict enforcement of compulsory voting rules due to structural barriers that disproportionately affect the poor, such as a voter identification requirement, as opposed to political disinterest. 1 Universal suffrage does not guarantee universal participation. For almost a century, political observers have shown that enfranchised citizens occasionally or even routinely abstain from voting. The earliest explorations of abstention (e.g., Arneson 1925; Merriam & Gosnell 1924) highlight that certain groups of citizens are more likely than others to abstain, thereby rendering election outcomes potentially unrepresentative of the citizenry.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Knowledge and the Paradox of Voting
    Political Knowledge and the Paradox of Voting Edited by Sofia Magdalena Olofsson We have long known that Americans pay local elections less attention than they do elections for the Presidency and Congress. A recent Portland State University study showed that voter turnout in ten of America’s 30 largest cities sits on average at less than 15% of eligible voters. Just pause and think about this. The 55% of voting age citizens who cast a ballot in last year’s presidential election – already a two-decade low and a significant drop from the longer-term average of 65-80% – still eclipses by far the voter turnout at recent mayoral elections in Dallas (6%), Fort Worth (6%), and Las Vegas (9%). What is more, data tells us that local voter turnout is only getting worse. Look at America’s largest city: New York. Since the 1953 New York election, when 93% of residents voted, the city’s mayoral contests saw a steady decline, with a mere 14% of the city’s residents voting in the last election. Though few might want to admit it, these trends suggest that an unspoken hierarchy exists when it comes to elections. Atop this electoral hierarchy are national elections, elections that are widely considered the most politically, economically, and culturally significant. Extensively covered by the media, they are viewed as high-stakes moral contests that naturally attract the greatest public interest. Next, come state elections: though still important compared to national elections, their political prominence, media coverage, and voter turnout is already waning. At the bottom of this electoral hierarchy are local elections that, as data tells us, a vast majority of Americans now choose not to vote in.
    [Show full text]
  • "I Voted": Examining the Impact of Compulsory Voting on Voter Turnout Nina A
    Claremont Colleges Scholarship @ Claremont CMC Senior Theses CMC Student Scholarship 2016 "I Voted": Examining the Impact of Compulsory Voting on Voter Turnout Nina A. Kamath Claremont McKenna College Recommended Citation Kamath, Nina A., ""I Voted": Examining the Impact of Compulsory Voting on Voter Turnout" (2016). CMC Senior Theses. Paper 1286. http://scholarship.claremont.edu/cmc_theses/1286 This Open Access Senior Thesis is brought to you by Scholarship@Claremont. It has been accepted for inclusion in this collection by an authorized administrator. For more information, please contact [email protected]. CLAREMONT MCKENNA COLLEGE “I VOTED”: EXAMINING THE IMPACT OF COMPULSORY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT SUBMITTED TO Professor Manfred Keil AND Professor Eric Helland AND Dean Peter Uvin By Nina Kamath For Senior Thesis Fall 2015 November 30, 2015 Department of Economics ii iii Abstract Over the past few decades, falling voter turnout rates have induced governments to adopt compulsory voting laws, in order to mitigate issues such as the socioeconomic voter gap and to bring a broader spectrum of voters into the fold. This paper presents evidence that the introduction of mandatory voting laws increases voter turnout rates by 13 points within a particular country through an entity- and time-fixed effect panel model. Moreover, it includes a discussion of the implications of adopting mandatory voting policies within the United States, finding that compelling citizens to vote would have increased participation rates to over 90 percent in the past four presidential elections. iv Acknowledgements First, I want to thank my parents for their unconditional love, support, and encouragement. I would also like to thank Professor Manfred Keil, Associate Professor of Economics at Claremont McKenna College, for his valuable guidance and support in completing this senior thesis.
    [Show full text]
  • Compulsory Voting and Political Participation: Empirical Evidence from Austria
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Gaebler, Stefanie; Potrafke, Niklas; Rösel, Felix Working Paper Compulsory voting and political participation: Empirical evidence from Austria ifo Working Paper, No. 315 Provided in Cooperation with: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Suggested Citation: Gaebler, Stefanie; Potrafke, Niklas; Rösel, Felix (2019) : Compulsory voting and political participation: Empirical evidence from Austria, ifo Working Paper, No. 315, ifo Institute - Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich, Munich This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/213592 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have
    [Show full text]
  • Voter Turnout Trends Around the World
    Voter Turnout Trends around the World Voter Turnout Trends around the World Voter Turnout Trends around the World Abdurashid Solijonov © 2016 International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance International IDEA Strömsborg SE-103 34 Stockholm Sweden Tel: +46 8 698 37 00, fax: +46 8 20 24 22 Email: [email protected], website: www.idea.int The electronic version of this publication is available under a Creative Commons Attribute-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0 licence. You are free to copy, distribute and transmit the publication as well as to remix and adapt it provided it is only for non-commercial purposes, that you appropriately attribute the publication, and that you distribute it under an identical licence. For more information on this licence see: <http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/3.0/>. International IDEA publications are independent of specific national or political interests. Views expressed in this publication do not necessarily represent the views of International IDEA, or those of its Boards or Council members. Cover photograph: ‘Voting queue in Addis Ababa’ (© BBC World Service/Uduak Amimo) made available on Flickr under the terms of a Creative Commons licence (CC-BY-NC 2.0) Graphic design by Turbo Design, Ramallah ISBN: 978-91-7671-083-8 Contents Acronyms and abbreviations ............................................................................................................ 7 Preface ..........................................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Should Voting Be Mandatory?
    Should Voting Be Mandatory? By Stephanie Kraus, Lisa Hill, JASON BRENNAN A voter casts a vote at a ballot box. In the United States, about 40% of eligible voters do not vote in presidential elections. More than 30 countries, including Belgium, Brazil and Australia, have some form of mandatory voting. In 1924, Australia started issuing fines to citizens who didn’t show up to vote. Turnout increased from 47% of eligible voters to over 95%. On top of that, perhaps because more people are involved in choosing their representatives, Australians report high levels of trust in government and satisfaction with the way democracy works. By comparison, a recent poll by the Pew Research Center found that just 24 percent of Americans trust the federal government. Supporters of mandatory voting say a true democracy needs to hear from all citizens. Democracy doesn’t work if a large portion of the population doesn’t participate. Mandatory voting is the best way to encourage politicians to focus their attention on all Americans, not just the middle and upper classes. A study by Pew Research Center found that the eligible voters most likely to avoid the polls are younger, poorer, less educated, and more racially diverse. This means those groups are less likely to have their voices heard. Because wealthier Americans are more likely to vote, government policies are disproportionately geared toward their interests. If voting were mandatory in the U.S., people would he inspired to pay more attention to campaigns—and current events. Compulsory voting would also allow candidates to spend less time and money on getting voters to the polls, and more on explaining where they stand on key issues.
    [Show full text]
  • A New Local Government Electoral Act: Review of the Local Government Electoral System (Excluding BCC)
    LEGISLATIVE ASSEMBLY OF QUEENSLAND LAW, JUSTICE AND SAFETY COMMITTEE A new Local Government Electoral Act: Review of the local government electoral system (excluding BCC) NOVEMBER 2010 REPORT NO. 78 LAW, JUSTICE AND SAFETY COMMITTEE 53RD PARLIAMENT COMMITTEE Chair Ms Barbara Stone MP, Member for Springwood Deputy Chair Mr Andrew Cripps MP, Member for Hinchinbrook Members Mr Jarrod Bleijie MP, Member for Kawana Mr Steve Kilburn MP, Member for Chatsworth Mr Ray Stevens MP, Member for Mermaid Beach Mr Murray Watt MP, Member for Everton Hon. Dean Wells MP, Member for Murrumba SECRETARIAT Acting Research Director Ms Renee Easten Principal Research Officer1 Ms Amanda Honeyman Executive Assistant Mrs Gail Easton Copies of this report and other Committee publications are available on the Committee’s website at www.parliament.qld.gov.au/jjsc Law, Justice and Safety Committee Parliament House George Street Brisbane Qld 4000 Telephone: (07) 3406 7307 Facsimile: (07) 3406 7070 Email: [email protected] 1 The Committee thanks Ms Simone Gregory for her research assistance with this report. CHAIR’S FOREWORD Local Government is often described as the level of government that is closest to the people. With this closeness comes an expectation from communities that their elected representatives will be responsive to their needs, will strive in their best interests, and will be accountable to them. The most consistent message the Committee heard across Queensland is that people want representation. They want to know who their local representatives are and to be able to contact their councillors when they need them. They want their local councillors to understand the needs of their particular area, to provide effective representation of the community’s needs and to be held accountable in fulfilling their duties as an elected representative.
    [Show full text]
  • The Case for Compulsory Voting in the United States
    NOTES THE CASE FOR COMPULSORY VOTING IN THE UNITED STATES Voter turnout in the United States is much lower than in other de- mocracies.1 In European nations, voter turnout regularly tops 80%,2 while turnout in American elections has not approached this number for at least the past century.3 Even in the U.S. presidential election of 2004, with the nation bogged down in an unpopular war and with a very tight campaign that left no front-runner, voter turnout was only about 60%.4 Although many may disparage the American electorate for being forgetful or lazy,5 low voter turnout does not necessarily mean that something is drastically wrong with American voters. The decision not to vote can be a rational one. Democratic government is a classic public good, and like any public good it is subject to a free-rider prob- lem.6 One can enjoy the benefits of living in a free, democratic society whether one incurs the costs of voting — time spent traveling to polls and waiting in line, information costs of choosing whom to vote for — or not. Even potential voters who have a strong preference for one candidate over another are likely to have a rational basis for not vot- ing since the likelihood of any single vote influencing the outcome of an election is negligible. This gives rise to what scholars call the “paradox of voting”7: the fact that some people do vote even though a ––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––– 1 DEREK BOK, THE STATE OF THE NATION 325 (1996). 2 Id. 3 Less is known about earlier American history, in part because of problems with the avail- able data.
    [Show full text]
  • House of Asembly Elections.Pub
    ELECTORAL SYSTEM HOUSE OF ASSEMBLY Tasmania has had compulsory voting ELECTIONS since the 1930s, and since 1978 this has applied to everyone over 18 years of The Tasmanian House of Assembly is age. Each voter is required to indicate a elected under a form of proportional minimum of five candidate preferences representation (PR) in five multi-member in order to cast a formal or valid vote. electorates using the single-transferable To stop before five or make an error vote (STV). This is known locally as the (e.g. two No 4 votes) renders the vote Hare-Clark system partly because it informal. Should voters express choices stems from the ideas of the Englishman beyond five this is also valid but if they Thomas Hare (1806-91). The other half stop at No. 15 or make an error with, of the hyphenated name refers to the say, two No. 21s, their vote becomes Tasmanian Attorney-General, Andrew 'exhausted' at either No. 15 or No. 20. Inglis Clark (1848-1907) who changed Once exhausted a ballot paper is of no and added to Hare's method. Clark's use even if a higher number exists, i.e. and other changes make the Hare-Clark Nos 22, 23, or 24 cannot be correct if system unique, not, as is often thought, No. 21 is repeated. an exact match with the Irish or the Maltese PR systems. From 1907 to 1941 candidates' names were listed ungrouped in alphabetical Tasmania adopted Hare-Clark on a trial order on the ballot paper. After 1941 basis in 1896 for Hobart and candidates were grouped by party or Launceston, but it was abolished in other group but the party was not named 1901.
    [Show full text]
  • Compulsory Voting Around the World
    EC Voting cover 7/6/06 20:22 Page 1 Research report, June 2006 Compulsory voting around the world We are an independent body that was set The Electoral Commission Trevelyan House up by the UK Parliament. Our mission is to Great Peter Street foster public confidence and participation London SW1P 2HW by promoting integrity, involvement and Tel 020 7271 0500 Fax 020 7271 0505 effectiveness in the democratic process. [email protected] www.electoralcommission.org.uk © The Electoral Commission 2006 Democracy matters ISBN: 1-904363-81-4 EC Voting cover 7/6/06 20:22 Page 2 Translations and other formats For information on obtaining this publication in another language or in a large-print or Braille version please contact the Electoral Commission: Tel: 020 7271 0500 Email: [email protected] The Electoral Commission We are an independent body that was set up by the UK Parliament. Our mission is to foster public confidence and participation by promoting integrity, involvement and effectiveness in the democratic process. Compulsory voting around the world Research report Copyright © The Electoral Commission 2006 ISBN: 1-904363-81-4 EC Voting text.qxp 7/6/06 20:24 Page 1 Contents Foreword 3 Executive summary 5 1 Background 9 2 Introducing compulsory voting 13 3 Compulsory voting systems 17 4 The impact of compulsory voting 27 5 Sources 37 Appendix 39 EC Voting text.qxp 7/6/06 20:24 Page 2 2 EC Voting text.qxp 7/6/06 20:24 Page 3 3 Foreword The Electoral Commission is As part of this process, we believe there is merit committed to increasing in opening up the question of compulsory voting for wider debate in the UK, as one of a participation in the democratic series of options which may facilitate higher process in the UK.
    [Show full text]
  • Notes Compulsory Voting in America
    NOTES COMPULSORY VOTING IN AMERICA SEAN MATSLER* I. INTRODUCTION “This . is dedicated . to the American voter. In the future, may there be more of them . .” –Ruy A. Teixeira1 Persistently low voter turnout in the United States continues to disappoint lovers of democracy. When scarcely half of the population of eligible voters turns out for a presidential election once every four years—to say nothing of midterm congressional elections or local elections—it becomes difficult to defend American democracy as truly representative.2 Instead, the will of the active voters, who constitute a stark minority of the eligible voting population, ultimately determines the electoral outcome. This regrettable situation is not the essence of a participatory democracy. Although low turnout might easily be blamed on an American ele ctoral lethargy, it could also be understood as a failure of the American electoral structure to motivate voter turnout. Accepting that premise as fact, it becomes possible to treat declining voter turnout as an opportunity * Class of 2003, University of Southern California Law School; B.A. 1999, University of California at Berkeley. The author would like to thank his parents, Mike and Lou, for their constant love and encouragement. He would also like to thank Glen and Abbe Rabenn for their guidance, Kate Dilligan for all she has done, and his grandmother, Mildred Kim, for her invaluable support. 1. See Dedication to RUY A. TEIXEIRA, W HY A MERICANS D ON’T VOTE (1987). 2. See FED. ELECTION COMM’N, VOTER REGISTRATION AND TURNOUT IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS BY YEAR: 1960–1992, at http://www.fec.gov/pages/tonote.htm (last visited Jan.
    [Show full text]