UC Berkeley UC Berkeley Electronic Theses and Dissertations

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

UC Berkeley UC Berkeley Electronic Theses and Dissertations UC Berkeley UC Berkeley Electronic Theses and Dissertations Title The Ware Course: Architecture as a Useful, Liberal, and Fine Art Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/5sh8m1pk Author Block, Kevin Publication Date 2019 Peer reviewed|Thesis/dissertation eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California The Ware Course: Architecture as a Useful, Liberal, and Fine Art By Kevin P. Block A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Rhetoric in the Graduate Division of the University of California, Berkeley Committee in charge: Professor Pheng Cheah, Co-Chair Professor Andrew Shanken, Co-Chair Professor David Henkin Associate Professor Winnie Wong Fall 2019 Copyright Page Abstract The Ware Course: Architecture as a Useful, Liberal, and Fine Art by Kevin P. Block Doctor of Philosophy in Rhetoric University of California, Berkeley Professor Pheng Cheah, Co-Chair Professor Andrew Shanken, Co-Chair This dissertation examines the academic career of William Robert Ware (1832-1915), an American architect who became the leading architectural educator in the late nineteenth century. Previous accounts of Ware have focused either on his work as a practicing architect or his role as a department builder at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology and Columbia University, where he imported the Beaux-Arts system of design instruction to the United States. This dissertation, in contrast, interprets archival documents and nineteenth-century architectural theory to situate Ware in relation to a number of core questions and concepts in the broader history of architectural expertise, including the construction of professional authority, the meaning of culture, the use of judgment, and the tension between creative expression and information processing. In addressing these core questions and concepts as a pedagogue, Ware helped to embed architectural education within the institutional setting of the modern research university and—for a brief historicist moment near the turn of the century—transform the discipline from a useful art into a liberal art. Part I covers the first half of Ware’s career at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (M.I.T.) and the relationship of architectural education to drawing reform in the 1860s and 1870s. In the Introduction to Part I, I explain how Ware’s involvement with the 1870 Drawing Act helped to expand the relevancy of architectural expertise from its traditional concerns with the construction and design of buildings to the general problem of producing and coordinating skillful labor. The public supported M.I.T. and M.I.T. supported Ware’s architecture department because they recognized in architectural education a source of technical rather than artisanal or aesthetic competency. Architectural education received institutional support in New England not because of professional lobbying, but because the discipline became associated with economic development and the useful arts tradition. In Chapter One, I consider why the legislators of the 1870 Drawing Act would have sought out Ware’s involvement, or what constituted Ware’s professional persona given his limited experience as an architect. I argue that Ware’s credibility derived from his institutional affiliation with M.I.T. and from his travels in Europe, where he studied 1 different methods of drawing instruction in art academies and polytechnics. In Chapter Two, I argue that art and education reformers like Walter Smith, Charles Eliot, and John Runkle set the groundwork for the incorporation of architecture within the university. This chapter proceeds over four sections. First, I briefly review literature in economic history on the collapse of the American apprenticeship system. In the next section, I describe how skill emerged as an abstract category of economic thought as work shifted from artisanal to industrial production and how abstraction changed the meaning of skill. These two sections constitute what one might call the social problematic that drawing education attempted to address. Then in the third section, I describe the desire for managers and workers with technical drawing skills as part of a system of industrial remote control. Most advocates of the 1870 Drawing Act supported drawing education for this reason, as part of a technological system that was dependent on precise interactions between workers and machines. In the fourth section, I describe drawing education as the subject of a broad institutional critique, one that was supported by new theories of mind that made the university more receptive to visual disciplines like architecture. Part II covers Ware’s move to Columbia and the architecture program that he created there between 1881 and 1902. In the Introduction to Part II, I argue that Ware’s move to Columbia was motivated by his objective to make the discipline of architecture a liberal art and I suggest what “liberality” meant to him in relation to how he understood terms like culture and judgment. Chapter Three focuses on the disciplinary legitimation of architecture within the modern research university. I argue that Ware’s liberal course in architectural education, with its heavy emphasis on the study of architectural history, was meant to demonstrate to administrators and colleagues in other academic disciplines that architecture conformed both to the university’s culture of professionalism, which was based on the study of precedent, and to its culture of classicism, which was defined by the interpretive methods of philology. In conforming the discipline to these two cultures, Ware’s program secured an institutional order that would help American architects avoid the perils of eclecticism. Chapter Four describes the key instrument that Ware and his successor, A.D.F. Hamlin, used to institutionalize his historicist model of architectural education at Columbia: the Avery Architecture Library. In the early 1890s, architecture students in New York could study the history of architecture in museums like the Metropolitan Museum of Art, with its extensive collections of plaster casts, and in universities like Columbia, with its collection of casts and architectural books. By the turn of the century, however, it was clear that the future of architectural education would be in the university and textual, not in the object-oriented environment of the museum. This chapter therefore considers the growth of the Avery Library and its impact on the architecture curriculum at Columbia. I conclude the dissertation with a discussion of Ware’s dismissal from Columbia in 1902 and the growing division of architectural labor around the turn of the century. While celebrated architects like Charles McKim after the turn of the century tried to enclose the collegiate system of architectural education to produce an elite cadre of fine artists, 2 Ware tried to make this system more accessible by collaborating with the International Correspondence School to create a series of rudimentary architecture courses that could be completed through the postal system. Ware’s dismissal was indicative of a cultural hierarchy in modern America that made a university education a barrier rather than a gateway to the pursuit of architecture as a fine art. As a figure who determined much of what constituted expertise for American architects around the turn of the century, Ware’s legacy was ambiguous. While the university grounded the discipline within an institutional order and provided instruments like the Avery Library that were necessary for producing liberal architectural subjects, access to this institutional order and these resources remained severely constrained. 3 Table of Contents Dedication ii List of Figures iii Acknowledgements x Introduction 1 Part I: Architecture as a Useful Art 13 Introduction to Part I: The 1870 Drawing Act Chapter One: 21 Professional Self-Fashioning: Building Credibility, Becoming Expert Chapter Two: 36 After Apprenticeship: Drawing and the Need for Skill in the 1870s Part II: Architecture as a Liberal Art 59 Introduction to Part II: Ware’s Move to Columbia Chapter Three: 86 Architecture in the Age of University Reform: Professionalism, Classicism, and the Study of Architectural History at Columbia Chapter Four: 123 Schooling Design: The Avery Library and the Bibliographic Order of Collegiate Architecture Part III: Architecture as a Fine Art 161 Conclusion: Captains of Erudition and the Collar Line Bibliography 173 Visual Appendix 204 i Dedication I dedicate this dissertation to my whole family, especially my parents, for their constant love and support. ii List of Figures Introduction Figure 1. William Robert Ware circa 1865. M.I.T. Special Collections. Introduction to Part I Figure 2. Walter Smith. From Green (1966), p. 8. Figure 3. Cover-page to Walter Smith’s American Text Books of Art Education: Geometrical Drawing (James R. Osgood & Co., 1873). Figure 4. Learning to draw models, from Smith’s American Text Books of Art Education (1873). Chapter One Figure 5. Ware’s first large project: Harvard’s Memorial Hall, final exterior perspective. The building would not be completed until the late 1870s. Courtesy of Harvard University Archives (Collection #166). Figure 6 The original seal for the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Courtesy of MIT Institute Archives and Special Collections. Figure 7. Rogers Building (1866), Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Courtesy of MIT Institute Archives and Special Collections. Figure 8.
Recommended publications
  • The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: a Critique of Received Explanations
    The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: A Critique of Received Explanations Joseph T. Salerno or roughly the first three quarters of the nineteenth century, the "liberal school" thoroughly dominated economic thinking and teaching in F France.1 Adherents of the school were also to be found in the United States and Italy, and liberal doctrines exercised a profound influence on prominent German and British economists. Although its numbers and au- thority began to dwindle after the 1870s, the school remained active and influential in France well into the 1920s. Even after World War II, there were a few noteworthy French economists who could be considered intellectual descendants of the liberal tradition. Despite its great longevity and wide-ranging influence, the scientific con- tributions of the liberal school and their impact on the development of Eu- ropean and U.S. economic thought—particularly on those economists who are today recognized as the forerunners, founders, and early exponents of marginalist economics—have been belittled or simply ignored by most twen- tieth-century Anglo-American economists and historians of thought. A number of doctrinal scholars, including Joseph Schumpeter, have noted and attempted to explain the curious neglect of the school in the En- glish-language literature. In citing the school's "analytical sterility" or "indif- ference to pure theory" as a main cause of its neglect, however, their expla- nations have overlooked a salient fact: that many prominent contributors to economic analysis throughout the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries expressed strong appreciation of or weighty intellectual debts to the purely theoretical contributions of the liberal school.
    [Show full text]
  • Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative
    [Show full text]
  • Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series
    Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series The Rise and Fall of Economic History at MIT Peter Temin Working Paper 13-11 June 5, 2013 Rev: December 9, 2013 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2274908 The Rise and Fall of Economic History at MIT Peter Temin MIT Abstract This paper recalls the unity of economics and history at MIT before the Second World War, and their divergence thereafter. Economic history at MIT reached its peak in the 1970s with three teachers of the subject to graduates and undergraduates alike. It declined until economic history vanished both from the faculty and the graduate program around 2010. The cost of this decline to current education and scholarship is suggested at the end of the narrative. Key words: economic history, MIT economics, Kindleberger, Domar, Costa, Acemoglu JEL codes: B250, N12 Author contact: [email protected] 1 The Rise and Fall of Economic History at MIT Peter Temin This paper tells the story of economic history at MIT during the twentieth century, even though roughly half the century precedes the formation of the MIT Economics Department. Economic history was central in the development of economics at the start of the century, but it lost its primary position rapidly after the Second World War, disappearing entirely a decade after the end of the twentieth century. I taught economic history to MIT graduate students in economics for 45 years during this long decline, and my account consequently contains an autobiographical bias.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics and Finance: the Evolution of Economic Science
    MIT 150 | Economics and Finance: The Evolution of Economic Science POTERBA: Good morning. As many of you may guess, I am not, as your program suggests, Dean Deborah Fitzgerald. She will be joining us and welcoming all of you this afternoon as we start into the second half of our program today. But as Jim Poterba and one of the organizers of the events that we will be going through in the next day and a half, I want to thank you all for braving the snow this morning. I want to thank David and the members of the MIT 150 committee for selecting the Economics Department in the Sloan School to sponsor this symposium. And I would like to thank both the dean of the Sloan School and the dean of Humanities, Arts, and Social Sciences for agreeing to support this exciting adventure. When MIT was founded in 1861, the field of political economy was already taking shape as a well-defined academic discipline. The leading text was John Stuart Mill's Principles of Political Economy, which had been published in 1848. And although in the very early years, economics was not yet on the radar screen of MIT, it arrived soon in the history of the young institution. In 1880, when Francis Amasa Walker was recruited from Yale to come and serve as the third president of MIT, that was a rather unusual thing for an institution of science and technology because Walker was, actually, one of, along with Irving Fisher at Yale, the most distinguished economists in the United States at that point.
    [Show full text]
  • A Preface to Neoclassical Legal Thought
    University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law 6-28-2011 A Preface to Neoclassical Legal Thought Herbert J. Hovenkamp University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Business Organizations Law Commons, Corporate Finance Commons, Economic Policy Commons, Economic Theory Commons, Finance Commons, Labor and Employment Law Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Law and Race Commons, Legal History Commons, Policy History, Theory, and Methods Commons, Public Law and Legal Theory Commons, and the Tax Law Commons Repository Citation Hovenkamp, Herbert J., "A Preface to Neoclassical Legal Thought" (2011). Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law. 1867. https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/1867 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law by an authorized administrator of Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Hovenkamp, Neoclassical Legal Thought in the United States July 2011, Page 1 A Preface to Neoclassical Legal Thought Herbert Hovenkamp * Introduction This preliminary essay explores the roots of fundamental changes in American legal thought that began to take hold in the United States after Reconstruction. It is written in contemplation of a larger project that is not yet finished. The term “neoclassical legal thought” seems appropriate to describe this set of developments for a number of reasons. First, neoclassical legal thought overlapped with but also succeeded its predecessor, classical legal thought.
    [Show full text]
  • From Bimetallism to Monetarism: the Shifting Political Affiliation of the Quantity Theory*
    From Bimetallism to Monetarism: the Shifting Political Affiliation of the Quantity Theory* by David Laidler Abstract: The quantity theory of money was associated with the politics of the right in the ‘70s and ‘80s, but a century earlier, particularly in America, it had played an important part in the proposals of the Progressive left. These political associations are examined, and it is argued that a crucial factor in the quantity theory’s apparent migration from left to right was its newly-forged links to the case for monetary policy rules in the interwar years. It was also in the 1930s that the endogenous-money Banking School doctrines deployed by anti-quantity theorists during the monetarist controversy first became mainly associated with the case for discretionary policy, rather than with support for the gold- standard rule, as they had been in earlier times. More generally, shifting scientific opinion about the causes of the Great Depression moved the political centre of gravity of monetary economics to the left from the 1930s onwards, and then back towards the right beginning in the ‘60s, creating an illusion of movement on the quantity theory’s part. ___________________________ *The opening lecture delivered at the 2001 conference of the European History of Economic Thought Society, on “The Influence of Politics on Economic Thought”, held at the Technical University of Darmstadt. This lecture had its origins in an email correspondence with Robert Leeson about post-war Chicago economics, and why the quantity theory should be regarded as a right-wing doctrine. I am grateful to him for the intellectual stimulation, and to Perry Mehrling, Bill Robson, Rick Szostak and Michael Trautwein made many useful comments on an earlier draft.
    [Show full text]
  • The Concept of Indexation in the History of Economic Thought
    The Concept of lndexation in the History of Economic Thought Periods of severe monetary disturbance tend to justment of tax brackets, personal exemptions, asset spawn unorthodox and often ingenious stabilization depreciation schedules, and capital gains. schemes. During such episodes, conventional policies Such comprehensive indexing, Friedman claims, often appear inadequate and the situation seems to would have at least two therapeutic effects. First, he call for extraordinary remedies. Thus, for example, says, “it would reduce the revenue the government the Great Depression of the 1930’s inspired a host of acquires from inflation” thus weakening the govern- novel schemes-including stamped money, taxation of ment’s “incentive to inflate.” Second, and more im- idle hoards, 100 percent reserve requirements behind portant, indexation, in his words, “would reduce the demand deposits, security reserve proposals, com- adverse side effects that effective measures to end modity reserve currency, “social credit” remedies, and inflation would have on output and employment.” the like-all designed to promote the recovery that [8 ; 94] Constituting the most serious obstacle to monetary policy was thought incapable of accomplish- the ending of inflation, these harmful side effects ing by itself. Currently the major economic problem stem from institutional and expectational rigidities is inflation, virulent double-digit inflation seemingly built into the structure of commodity and factor unstoppable by orthodox measures alone. Predict- prices. By preventing
    [Show full text]
  • Eugenics and American Economics in the Progressive Era Thomas C
    “More Merciful and Not Less Effective”: Eugenics and American Economics in the Progressive Era Thomas C. Leonard Oliver Wendell Holmes was made a Progressive lion upon his pithy dis- sent to the U.S. Supreme Court’s landmark decision to overturn a New York statute restricting (male) bakers’ working hours. “The 14th Amend- ment,” said Holmes famously, “does not enact the Social Statics of Mr. Herbert Spencer.”1 Twenty-two years later, in another well-known case, Holmes wrote for the majority, which upheld the constitutionality of a Virginia law proposing involuntary sterilization of persons believed to be mentally retarded—the “feebleminded,” in the jargon of the day. “The principle that sustains compulsory vaccination is broad enough to cover cutting the Fallopian tubes,” Holmes wrote in Buck v. Bell (1927). “Three generations of imbeciles,” Holmes volunteered, “is enough.” How does an opponent of Spencerian Social Darwinism come to en- dorse coercive sterilization of the unfit? This essay argues that, as a mat- ter of history, there is no contradiction in the views that underwrite the Correspondence may be address to Thomas C. Leonard, Department of Economics, Fisher Hall, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ 08544; e-mail: [email protected]. I acknowl- edge with gratitude the constructive criticisms of Malcolm Rutherford, Deirdre McCloskey, David Levy, Sandy Peart, Bob Goldfarb, and seminar participants at the annual meetings of the Eastern Economic Association, and of the History of Economics Society. 1. Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45, 76 (1905) (USSC). As popular as his Lochner dissent was with Progressives, Wendell Holmes was no Progressive.
    [Show full text]
  • Eklanche 1.Pdf
    Prediction and Control: Global Population, Population Science, and Population Politics in the Twentieth Century by Emily R. Merchant A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy (History) in the University of Michigan 2015 Doctoral Committee: Associate Professor John Carson, Chair Professor Barbara A. Anderson Professor Howard Brick Professor Paul N. Edwards Acknowledgements In many ways, this dissertation was a joy to write. I found the topic fascinating when I began writing and it continues to fascinate me today. Going to the archives shaped the story in ways that I did not expect when I wrote the prospectus but that only deepened my interest in and commitment to this project. The enthusiasm of my advisors, research subjects, and interlocutors helped keep my own enthusiasm for the project high, even through difficult and frustrating moments in the archives and while writing. I could not have written this dissertation without the assistance and support of many people and organizations. The seeds of this dissertation were sown in Barbara Anderson's demographic theory and methods courses in the Department of Sociology at the University of Michigan, which I attended in 2008-2009 at the urging of Myron Gutmann. Myron Gut- mann and Barbara Anderson encouraged my critical interest in the history of demography, and this encouragement eventually led me back to the Department of History at the Uni- versity of Michigan, which I had left after earning my M.A. in 2005. I am grateful to John Carson for agreeing to be my advisor at our very first meeting, and to Kali Israel, Farina Mir, Nancy Hunt, and Gabrielle Hecht, who helped me successfully petition for re-admission to the Ph.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Francis Amasa Walker
    BIOGKAPHIGAL MEMOIR FRANCIS AM ASA WALKER. 1840-1897. JOHN S. BILLINGS. READ BEFORE THE NATIONAL ACADEMY OF SCIENCES, APRIL 17, 1902. (21) 209 BIOGRAPHICAL MEMOIR OF FRANCIS AMASA WALKER. FRANCIS AMASA WALKER, member and Vice-President of the National Academy of Sciences, was born in Boston, Mass., July 2, 1840, and died in the same city January 5, 1897. He was a son of Amasa Walker, the well-known teacher and writer, whose studies in political economy had great influence in directing his own line of work. He graduated at Amherst in 1860, and studied law in the office of Devens and Hoar, of Worcester, Mass., until the commencement of the civil war, when he en- listed as sergeant major in the Fifteenth Massachusetts, under the command of -Colonel Devens. He soon received a commission as captain and was rapidly promoted through the several grades to that of brigadier general, serving on the staffs of Generals Couch, Humphreys, Warren, and Hancock, being long connected with the latter, and the author of the History of the Second Army Corps and of the Life of General Hancock. He was severely wounded in 1863, and was captured in 1864 and confined for a time in Libby Prison. After the war he was on the editorial staff of the Springfield Re- publican in 1868 ; was Chief of the Bureau of Statistics in Wash- ington from January, 1869, to February, 1870, and then became Superintendent of the Census. In 1872 he accepted the chair of political economy in the Sheffield Scientific School at New Haven; in 1879 he became Superintendent of the Census, and in 1881 he accepted the presidency of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, which he held until his death.
    [Show full text]
  • Professional Economists and Policymaking in the United States, 1880-1929
    ABSTRACT Title of Dissertation: IRRELEVANT GENIUS: PROFESSIONAL ECONOMISTS AND POLICYMAKING IN THE UNITED STATES, 1880-1929 Jonathan S. Franklin, Doctor of Philosophy, 2014 Dissertation Directed By: Professor David B. Sicilia, Department of History The rapid establishment and expansion of economics departments in colleges across the United State in the late nineteenth century indicates a significant shift in the way Americans understood economic science and its importance to federal economic policy. This dissertation addresses that phenomenon by explaining how American economists professionalized; and how that process influenced economic policymaking in the U.S. from the formation of the American Economic Association in 1885 to the Great Depression of the 1930s. Chapters alternate between analyzing the dilemmas economists faced while crafting a distinct academic discipline and investing early professional economists’ role in the federal economic policymaking process. Three emerging themes help explain the consistent failure of early U.S. economists to translate modern economic theory to economic policy in a timely fashion. First, public skepticism and the persistence of folk economics proved to be a powerful deterrent to professionally-trained economists’ authority in debates over policy matters. The combination of democratic idealism, populist politics, and skepticism regarding the motivations of professionally-trained economists undercut much of the social prestige professional economists garnered as educated elites. Second, disagreement among professional economists, often brought on by young economists’ efforts to overturn a century’s worth of received wisdom in classical economic theory, fostered considerable dissent within the field. Dissent, in turn, undermined the authority of professional economists and often led to doubt regarding economists’ abilities among the public and policy compromises that failed to solve economic problems.
    [Show full text]
  • Poverty Measurement
    1''<,' ' .... J I ' .. ··· . ./ i (! \ POVERTY MEASUREMENT A THEORETICAL CONTRIBUTION AND APPLICATION TO PORTUGAL 2007 Celso Luis Pereira Nunes Orienta9ao: Professor Doutor Jose Antonio Correia Pereirinha DOUTORAMENTO EM ECONOMIA Juri: Presidente - Reitor da Universidade Tecnica de Lisboa Vogais - Professor Doutor Jose Antonio Correia Pereirinha Professor Doutor Francisco Jose Nascimento Branco Professor Doutor Luis Manuel Antunes Capucha Professora Doutora Elvira Sofia Leite de Freitas Pereira Professor Doutor Francisco Jose Duarte Nunes Lisboa, Dezembro de 2012 Index List of figures and tables ........................................................................................... 3 Agradecimentos ....................................................................................................... 4 Resumo ........................•.......................................................•................................... 5 Abstract ................................................................................................................... 6 INTRODUCTION ................•.............................................•......................................... 7 CHAPTER 1 - POVERTY MEASUREMENT: HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENTS AND PRESENT CHALLENGES ..................•...........•.•.......................................•................................. 1.2 1.1 The roots of the economic thought on poverty ......................................................... 13 1.2 Rediscovering Poverty in the 1960s .........................................................................
    [Show full text]