The Roman Market Economy Peter Temin

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Roman Market Economy Peter Temin The Roman Market Economy Peter Temin Princeton University Press Princeton & Oxford PUP_Temin_The Roman Market Economy_FM_v1.indd iii Achorn International 06/05/2012 07:22AM Copyright © 2013 by Princeton University Press Published by Princeton University Press, 41 William Street, Princeton, New Jersey 08540 In the United Kingdom: Princeton University Press, 6 Oxford Street, Woodstock, Oxfordshire OX20 1TW press.princeton.edu All Rights Reserved ISBN 978-­0-­691-­14768-­0 <~?~FULL CIP TO COME> British Library Cataloging-­in-­Publication Data is available This book has been composed in <~?~DES: Please add typeface(s)> Printed on acid-­free paper. ∞ Printed in the United States of America 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 PUP_Temin_The Roman Market Economy_FM_v1.indd iv Achorn International 06/05/2012 07:22AM 1 2 3 4 5 Contents 6 7 8 9 10 Preface and Acknowledgments vii 11 12 1. Economics and Ancient History 1 13 14 Part I: Prices 15 Introduction: Data and Hypothesis Tests 27 16 2. Wheat Prices and Trade in the Early Roman Empire 29 17 3. Price Behavior in Hellenistic Babylon 53 18 Appendix to Chapter 3 66 19 4. Price Behavior in the Roman Empire 70 20 21 Part II: Markets in the Roman Empire 22 Introduction: Roman Microeconomics 95 23 5. The Grain Trade 97 24 6. The Labor Market 114 25 7. Land Ownership 139 26 8. Financial Intermediation 157 27 28 Part III: The Roman Economy 29 Introduction: Roman Macroeconomics 193 30 9. Growth Theory for Ancient Economies 195 31 10. Economic Growth in a Malthusian Empire 220 32 Appendix to Chapter 10 240 33 11. Per Capita GDP in the Early Roman Empire 243 34 35 References 263 36 Index 287 37 38 39 40 41 v PUP_Temin_The Roman Market Economy_FM_v1.indd v Achorn International 06/05/2012 07:22AM 1 2 3 4 5 Chapter 5 6 7 8 The Grain Trade 9 10 11 12 13 ong-­distance trade in the many centuries before the telegraph was beset by 14 information problems. There was the uncertainty present to all when ships 15 Lset out and people awaited their return with little or no news in the interim. 16 There also was the need to transact business at a distance when information 17 traveled slowly, often by using an imperfectly controlled agent. The problem of 18 finding good agents and providing proper incentives for them has been studied 19 for the early modern world and even occasionally for the medieval world. I 20 extend this exploration back into the ancient world in this chapter, analyzing 21 how Roman merchants dealt with asymmetric information in the centuries 22 surrounding the beginning of the Christian Era. 23 Rome was the largest city before London at the time of the Industrial 24 Revolution as noted earlier. The multitudinous Romans ate a great deal of 25 grain, much of it wheat. This simple fact becomes more surprising when one 26 considers how easily and conveniently Romans could buy that grain. Shipped 27 from distant provinces, the grain changed hands many times before it reached 28 Rome. This trade was organized by the state and private merchants who did 29 not have the benefit of modern means of transportation or communication, 30 and merchants faced high transaction costs from several sources. At times, 31 merchants had to wait weeks to find out if their ships had sunk or if a harvest 32 had wiped out the grain supply in a particular location. The Roman govern- 33 ment cleared the Mediterranean of pirates in 67 BCE, completing a process 34 reducing greatly one major source of risk for merchants. 35 In addition to these problems resulting from incomplete information, 36 merchants in Rome had to rely on potentially corrupt agents—­whom they 37 could not monitor—operating­ in faraway provinces for months at a time. This 38 arrangement created adverse selection and moral hazard problems from the 39 asymmetric information available to merchants and their agents. I reconcile 40 in this chapter the success of the Roman grain market described in chapter 2 41 97 PUP_Temin_The Roman Market Economy_Ch05.indd 97 Achorn International 06/02/2012 02:37AM 98 Chapter 5 1 with the apparent barriers to that success, arguing that grain merchants used a 2 sophisticated set of institutions to mitigate their information problems. 3 Roman grain merchants contended with the consequences of highly lim- 4 ited information and of adverse selection and moral hazard, called collectively, 5 principal-­agent problems. There were large barriers of distance and time be- 6 tween merchants and their agents, making the coordination of buying and sell- 7 ing difficult to manage. Merchants could not ascertain quickly when the price 8 of grain in Egypt, Africa, or Rome might be high or low, or even if their ship 9 had sunk in a storm. The advent of the telegraph and then the wireless would 10 reduce some of those problems in the nineteenth century, but merchants had 11 dealt with these problems for several millennia before then. 12 Adverse selection comes about when people have choices whether to par- 13 ticipate in an activity. If the nature of the activity attracts undesirable people, 14 then we say there is adverse selection. For example, Adam Smith argued for 15 usury limitations on interest rates on the grounds that only crooks and scoun- 16 drels would borrow money at high interest rates. Once people have decided 17 to participate in an activity, they have choices in their actions. If the incen- 18 tives promote choices injurious to other people, we say there is moral hazard. 19 For example, insurance may cause people to take excessive risks because they 20 know they are insured. Asymmetric information is shorthand for one party to 21 a transaction knowing more than the other. An agent on the spot may know 22 more than the merchant who sent him on a voyage, and this gives him an 23 advantage in making choices we identify as asymmetric information. All of 24 these concepts arise when we discuss the relations of principals who furnish 25 resources or make rules and agents who are asked to act for the principal. They 26 are the ordinary settings for the questions of the New Institutional Economics. 27 Roman grain merchants, like merchants in other times and places, had 28 to find capable, trustworthy agents under conditions of adverse selection. As 29 Akerlof (1970) explained in his famous “lemons” paper, when the buyer of a 30 good or a service (the merchant in our case) has no clear way of discerning 31 the quality of the good or service itself (the agent), the buyer typically faces an 32 adverse selection of goods. The provider of goods and services (the agent) has 33 an incentive to provide only lower-quality­ goods, and so the market for that 34 product may even disappear entirely. Stiglitz and Spence, who shared a Nobel 35 Prize in economics for analyzing the effects of adverse selection, both outline 36 modern examples of the screening problems that have become particularly 37 pertinent recently in areas such as the management of American health main- 38 tenance organizations (Altman, Cutler, and Zeckhauser 1998). 39 The merchant-­agent relationship also established conditions for moral haz- 40 ard, a problem closely related to adverse selection. Agents working in distant 41 and therefore unobservable settings could skim profits or steal cargos from PUP_Temin_The Roman Market Economy_Ch05.indd 98 Achorn International 06/02/2012 02:37AM The Grain Trade 99 owners with little fear of reprisal. The moral hazard was exacerbated by adverse 1 selection, since the merchants might hire agents with an inclination to cheat. 2 This problem has been mitigated from time immemorial by using family and 3 friends as agents whenever possible. This proclivity to use known agents is 4 pervasive in all societies; only the details change. The Rothschilds succeeded in 5 part because Mayer Amschel had five trustworthy sons, and president of the 6 United States George W. Bush was helped in business by family connections 7 (Ashton 1948; Mathias 1999; Ferguson 1998; Phillips 2004). 8 Many papers have demonstrated that institutions play a critical role in re- 9 ducing the costs of these asymmetric and incomplete information problems 10 when family or household connections are not enough. Akerlof (2002) sug- 11 gested that business institutions such as warranties, brand names, and reputa- 12 tion provide means to reduce the problem of adverse selection because those 13 types of “signaling”—proactive­ identification of quality or ability—increase­ the 14 available information. Sixteenth-­ and seventeenth-­century North American 15 merchant groups hired people from within specific families or communities 16 that were already considered trustworthy and promoted people from entry-­ 17 level positions once their level of ability was clear (Carlos and Nicholas 1990; 18 Jones and Ville 1996). Similarly, Greif argues that the Maghribi Muslim trad- 19 ers in early medieval times depended on a different kind of social signaling—­ 20 membership in a common religious group—­to mark the reputable agents. 21 Genoese traders, on the other hand, relied on the enforcement mechanism 22 inherent in their legal framework to ensure a selection of honest agents (Greif 23 1994). In general, common ways to reduce moral hazard include paying high 24 wages to raise the costs of being fired for cheating and implementing peer-­ 25 monitoring institutions (Shapiro and Stiglitz 1984; Arnott and Stiglitz 1991). 26 Early trading companies relied on those monitoring systems and also required 27 agents to take oaths to work solely in the best interests of the company (Carlos 28 1992).
Recommended publications
  • Symbolic Universe, Metaphor and Conviction
    SYMBOLIC UNIVERSE,METAPHOR AND CONVICTION: A STUDY OF THE SLAVE METAPHOR IN PAUL'S LETTER TO THE GALATIANS A Dissertation Submitted to the Faculty of Arts Biblical Studies Department University of Sheffield In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirementsfor the Degree Doctor of Philosophy by Sam Tsang August 2001 Accepted on CONTENTS Abstract Introduction ChapterI ISSUESIN RESEARCHINGGRECO-ROMAN SLAVE IDENTITY AND PAUL'S RHETORIC: PRELIMINARY REMARKS 28 1.1. The State of the Scholarly Questions in Greco-Roman Slave Identity 28 1.2. Scholarship on First-Century Greco-Roman Slave Identity and Paul 35 1.3 Scholarship on the Metaphors of Paul: Symbolic Universe, Metaphors and Rhetoric 39 1.4. Conclusion 48 Chapter 2 IDENTITY SHIFTS OF THE SLAVE IN THE PROCESS OF GRECO-ROMAN SLAVERY: FROM BONDAGE TO FREEDOM AND OBLIGATION - THE SYMBOLIC UNIVERSE OF PAUL'S SOCIETY ON SLAVERY 52 2.1. Greco-Roman Slavery 52 2.2. Greco-Roman Manumission 69 2.3 Greco-Roman Re-enslavement 85 2.4. The Identity and Power Shifts in Greco-Roman Processof Slavery 87 Chapter3 THE APOLOGETICUSAGE OF THE SERVILE METAPHOR IN GALATIANS 90 3.1. Paul's Self Descriptionin Gal. 1.1,10 90 3.2. Paul's Self Descriptionin Gal. 6.17 105 Chapter4 THE POLEMICAL USAGE OF THE SERVILE METAPHOR IN GALATIANS 113 4.1. Paul's Attack on the Agitators in Gal. 2.4 113 4.2. Paul's Attack on the Agitators in Gal. 4.30 121 Chapter5 THE DIDACTIC USAGE OF THE SERVILE METAPHOR IN GALATIANS 147 5.1. Paul's Teachingof the Galatiansin Gal.
    [Show full text]
  • Slavery in Ancient Rome and the United States of America: Natural Rights and Their Role in the Brutality of Slavery in America and Its Abolition
    Crossings (Number 3) 197 Slavery in Ancient Rome and the United States of America: Natural Rights and their Role in the Brutality of Slavery in America and its Abolition David J. Wiebe Inception This paper was written for Dr. Jason Brown’s Roman Law and Legacy course in the winter term of the 2017-18 academic year. Students where asked to choose a topic that related to Roman law and its relation to legal history. Abstract This essay looks at the legal framework of slavery in ancient Rome and America, leading up to the Civil War and emancipation. By taking account of legal documents from these two time periods and placing them in relation to each other, the philosophic underpinnings of the law emerge more clearly. Where American perceptions of justice revolve around natural law and natural justice, Roman ones take a more practical approach to justice. This leads to three positions: American pro-slavery, American abolitionist, and Roman pro-slavery. The American pro-slavery arguments posit slavery as a positive good, some texts going so far as to say that anti-slavery arguments are against God. The abolitionist position roots in the same natural justice and natural law philosophic position as their pro-slavery opponents, only the abolitionist position views all humans regardless of race as equal under the law. The Roman position, on the other hand, views slavery as a necessary evil, and as such, has more protections, and a more humane legal position than the American legal system allows for slaves. These three legal positions and their philosophic underpinnings are discussed.
    [Show full text]
  • Slavery in Ancient Rome Was Not Necessarily for Life
    Slavery and Manumission in Ancient Rome Presented at An Tir Collegium, AS LI, November 11, 2017 Slavery played a huge role socially and politically in the ancient Roman world. We will examine daily life for both slaves and their masters, how slavery was affected by the growth of the Empire, the laws and rituals surrounding manumission (freeing of slaves), and subsequent changes in social status. Please note that I DO NOT condone slavery or any other nonconsensual control of human lives. Domina Tullia Saturnina, JdL, GdS Email: [email protected] Website: RomanaSum.com Why study it Jewish perspective: Actively teaching to retain tribal memory, good and bad, instead of whitewashing history Understanding Roman mindset Applying knowledge to modern world Where slaves came from Spoils of war (income for soldiers), debtors, sold by family, born to a slave Percentage of population: 10-40% (changes over time, difficult to find good numbers, underreporting to save taxes) Most were owned by the elite 1%: Rich families had hundreds of slaves. Pliny the Younger owned 4,116 (farm owner)! Middle class families had 1-3. Slave markets Slave traders had sleazy reps (used car salesman) Slaves marked with signs listing geographic origin (stereotypes), age, skills, etc. Newly imported: Chalked one foot Daily life Average life span 17.5, vs. 40 for citizens. Clothing reveals status (very important in Roman culture) Imagery - slaves are smaller City vs. farms Status levels – continuum from mines up to trusted assistant. Educated Greeks – tutors, doctors Gladiators (mostly slaves): weird mix of low status and fame/wealth for the best Higher status slaves could earn money, buy their freedom (Peculium), or their own slaves.
    [Show full text]
  • The “Happy Slave” Narrative and Classics Pedagogy: a Verbal and Visual Analysis of Beginning Greek and Latin Textbooks
    New England Classical Journal Volume 46 Issue 1 Pages 62-87 2019 The “Happy Slave” Narrative and Classics Pedagogy: A Verbal and Visual Analysis of Beginning Greek and Latin Textbooks Kelly P. Dugan University of Georgia Follow this and additional works at: https://crossworks.holycross.edu/necj Part of the Classics Commons Recommended Citation Dugan, Kelly P. (2019) "The “Happy Slave” Narrative and Classics Pedagogy: A Verbal and Visual Analysis of Beginning Greek and Latin Textbooks," New England Classical Journal: Vol. 46 : Iss. 1 , 62-87. Available at: https://crossworks.holycross.edu/necj/vol46/iss1/5 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by CrossWorks. It has been accepted for inclusion in New England Classical Journal by an authorized editor of CrossWorks. Abstract: In Greek and Latin textbooks, verbal and visual discourses function together to construe Greco-Roman systems of enslavement. This article is a survey of the words and images of enslavement in five popular Greek and Latin textbooks and includes sample lessons for educators to apply in their own classroom. Based on the theories and methodologies of multicultural education and systemic functional linguistics, the findings illustrate how the linguistic resources of appraisal (feelings and character) and transitivity (agency and action) function to sanitize and normalize enslavement. The accompanying comparative analysis to 19th-century American discourses on enslavement to demonstrate how the use of these linguistic resources are consistent across time and context. Therefore, although systems of enslavement in the Greco-Roman world were not race-based, the presentation of enslavement in Greek and Latin textbooks today engages in racist discourses that permeate the American education system.
    [Show full text]
  • Beard's SPQR. a History of Ancient
    Beard’s SPQR. A History of Ancient Rome as Background Reading in Classical Latin Courses. A Teaching Proposal by Tamara Lobato Beneyto The Cambridge scholar provides an formulated by the present author and Introduction. Rationale, scope, analysis and discussion of primary aimed at furthering a reflection on and a and structure sources, and re-examines the significance discussion of the book’s contents among and consequences of the main historical students. This document was originally Contextual or background knowledge events and processes during such elaborated for undergraduates completing performs an important function in centuries. She starts by focusing on the ab initio and intermediate courses in second language learning and reading events of 63 BCE (first chapter), and then Classical Latin as part of degree comprehension, as a number of proceeds to discuss previous periods in programmes other than Classics (mainly theoretical and empirical studies have Roman History. In the sixth chapter, History), but it may be likewise useful for shown (see, for instance, P. L. Carrell, Beard resumes the account of events of students in other educational settings, 1983, 1982).1 To the extent that the already mentioned year, and continues such as the pre-university stage and Ancient Greek and Latin are verbal thereon with the rest of the historical continuous education. codes too, they constitute no exception account in linear chronological order. The headings in the first section, to the aforementioned principle. With a most engaging narrative style,she entitled On the chapter contents, are phrased Indeed, contextual knowledge is implicitly introduces non-specialist in a similar way as essay questions.
    [Show full text]
  • The Roman Market Economy
    The Roman Market Economy PUP_Temin_The Roman Market Economy_FM_v1.indd i Achorn International 06/05/2012 07:22AM The Princeton Economic History of the Western World Joel Mokyr, Series Editor A list of titles in this series appears at the back of the book. PUP_Temin_The Roman Market Economy_FM_v1.indd ii Achorn International 06/05/2012 07:22AM The Roman Market Economy Peter Temin Princeton University Press Princeton & Oxford PUP_Temin_The Roman Market Economy_FM_v1.indd iii Achorn International 06/05/2012 07:22AM Copyright © 2013 by Princeton University Press Published by Princeton University Press, 41 William Street, Princeton, New Jersey 08540 In the United Kingdom: Princeton University Press, 6 Oxford Street, Woodstock, Oxfordshire OX20 1TW press.princeton.edu All Rights Reserved ISBN 978-­0-­691-­14768-­0 <~?~FULL CIP TO COME> British Library Cataloging-­in-­Publication Data is available This book has been composed in <~?~DES: Please add typeface(s)> Printed on acid-­free paper. ∞ Printed in the United States of America 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 PUP_Temin_The Roman Market Economy_FM_v1.indd iv Achorn International 06/05/2012 07:22AM 1 2 3 4 5 Contents 6 7 8 9 10 Preface and Acknowledgments vii 11 12 1. Economics and Ancient History 1 13 14 Part I: Prices 15 Introduction: Data and Hypothesis Tests 27 16 2. Wheat Prices and Trade in the Early Roman Empire 29 17 3. Price Behavior in Hellenistic Babylon 53 18 Appendix to Chapter 3 66 19 4. Price Behavior in the Roman Empire 70 20 21 Part II: Markets in the Roman Empire 22 Introduction: Roman Microeconomics 95 23 5.
    [Show full text]
  • Finding Onesimus: Recovering the Story of a First-Century Fugitive Slave
    University of Denver Digital Commons @ DU Electronic Theses and Dissertations Graduate Studies 1-1-2015 Finding Onesimus: Recovering the Story of a First-Century Fugitive Slave Ryan Lokkesmoe University of Denver Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.du.edu/etd Part of the Biblical Studies Commons, and the Religious Thought, Theology and Philosophy of Religion Commons Recommended Citation Lokkesmoe, Ryan, "Finding Onesimus: Recovering the Story of a First-Century Fugitive Slave" (2015). Electronic Theses and Dissertations. 1039. https://digitalcommons.du.edu/etd/1039 This Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate Studies at Digital Commons @ DU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Electronic Theses and Dissertations by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons @ DU. For more information, please contact [email protected],[email protected]. FINDING ONESIMUS RECOVERING THE STORY OF A FIRST-CENTURY FUGITIVE SLAVE ____________________________ A Dissertation Presented to the Faculty of the University of Denver and the Iliff School of Theology Joint PhD Program University of Denver ____________________________ In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Doctor of Philosophy ____________________________ by Ryan Lokkesmoe August 2015 Advisor: Pamela Eisenbaum © Copyright by Ryan Lokkesmoe 2015 All Rights Reserved Author: Ryan Lokkesmoe Title: Finding Onesimus: Recovering the Story of a First-Century Fugitive Slave Advisor: Pamela Eisenbaum Degree Date: August 2015 ABSTRACT This dissertation is an investigation into the experience of a first-century fugitive slave named Onesimus, who is known to us primarily through Paul’s letter to Philemon (Phlm) in the New Testament. Within this broader purpose, this project challenges a popular historical theory for Onesimus’ flight, the so-called Amicus Domini theory.
    [Show full text]
  • 500 CE Closeup Teaching Unit 4.5.2 Roman Slavery 100
    Big Era Four Expanding etworks of Exchange and Encounter 1200 BCE - 500 CE Closeup Teaching Unit 4.5.2 Roman Slavery 100 BCE – 450 CE PowerPoint Presentation Roman Slavery Table of Contents Why this unit? 2 Unit objectives 2 Time and materials 2 Author 2 The historical context 2 This unit in the Big Era timeline 5 Introductory activity 6 Lesson 1: Becoming a Slave in Rome 8 Lesson 2: The Life of a Slave 17 Lesson 3: Manumission 25 Lesson 4: Abuse and Resistance 33 Assessment 47 This unit and the Three Essential Questions 48 This unit and the Seven Key Themes 48 This unit and the Standards in Historical Thinking 48 Resources 49 Correlations to National and State Standards 51 Conceptual links to other lessons 52 World History for Us All A project of San Diego State University In collaboration with the National Center for History in the Schools (UCLA) http://worldhistoryforusall.sdsu.edu/ World History for Us All Big Era 4 Closeup 4.5.2 Why this unit? Slaves made up a substantial part of the population in ancient Rome. According to some estimates, during the first century CE, they may have comprised one third of the population of the empire. Wealthy Romans owned hundreds or thousands of slaves, but even the average person could own a few. Some slaves even had their own slaves (vicarii). Slaves performed a wide variety of jobs in Rome. Although some tasks, such as domestic service, did not generate revenue for the master, there were many others, such as farming and mining, that did.
    [Show full text]
  • This Thesis Has Been Submitted in Fulfilment of the Requirements for a Postgraduate Degree (E.G
    This thesis has been submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for a postgraduate degree (e.g. PhD, MPhil, DClinPsychol) at the University of Edinburgh. Please note the following terms and conditions of use: This work is protected by copyright and other intellectual property rights, which are retained by the thesis author, unless otherwise stated. A copy can be downloaded for personal non-commercial research or study, without prior permission or charge. This thesis cannot be reproduced or quoted extensively from without first obtaining permission in writing from the author. The content must not be changed in any way or sold commercially in any format or medium without the formal permission of the author. When referring to this work, full bibliographic details including the author, title, awarding institution and date of the thesis must be given. Pro-slavery and the Classics in Antebellum America, 1840 – 1860: Thomas Cobb, Louisa McCord, George Frederick Holmes, George Fitzhugh, and James Henry Hammond under Scrutiny. Jared Jodoin Doctorate of Philosophy The University of Edinburgh March 2019 Signed Declaration I hereby declare that that this thesis is entirely my own composition and work. It contains no material previously submitted for the award of any other degree or professional degree. Jared A. Jodoin 2 Table of Contents Abstract / 4 Acknowledgments / 6 1 / Two Worlds Collided: Greco-Roman Antiquity and the Antebellum United States / 7 2 / The Pro-Slavery Argument / 36 3 / As the Greeks and Romans “Did”: Thomas R. Cobb’s Black Slaves
    [Show full text]
  • HIST7104: Slavery in the Classical World: Dr Simon Corcoran | University College London
    09/28/21 HIST7104: Slavery in the Classical World: Dr Simon Corcoran | University College London HIST7104: Slavery in the Classical World: View Online Dr Simon Corcoran Akrigg B, ‘The Nature and Implications of Athens’ Changed Social Structure and Economy’, Debating the Athenian cultural revolution: art, literature, philosophy, and politics 430-380 BC (Cambridge University Press 2007) ——, ‘Demography and Classical Athens’, Demography and the Graeco-Roman world: new insights and approaches (Cambridge University Press 2011) Alcock SE, ‘A Simple Case of Exploitation? The Helots of Messenia’, Money, labour and land: approaches to the economies of ancient Greece (Routledge 2002) ——, ‘Researching the Helots: Details, Methodologies, Agencies’, Helots and their masters in Laconia and Messenia: histories, ideologies, structures (Center for Hellenic Studies, Trustees for Harvard University 2003) Anastasiadēs, V. I., Colloque du GIREA and Groupe international de recherches sur l’esclavage dans l'antiquité, Esclavage Antique et Discriminations Socio-Culturelles: Actes Du XXVIIIe Colloque International Du Groupement International de Recherche Sur L’esclavage Antique (Mytilène, 5-7 Décembre 2003) (Peter Lang 2005) Andreau J, ‘The Freedman’, The Romans (University of Chicago Press 1993) ——, ‘Twenty Years after Moses I. Finley’s The Ancient Economy’, The ancient economy, vol Edinburgh readings on the ancient world (Edinburgh University Press 2002) Andreau, Jean, Banking and Business in the Roman World, vol Key themes in ancient history (Cambridge University
    [Show full text]
  • Servus Publicus and Servus Privatus in Ancient Rome: Legal Status and Social Status
    Pobrane z czasopisma Studia Iuridica Lublinensia http://studiaiuridica.umcs.pl Data: 27/09/2021 17:16:17 Articles Studia Iuridica Lublinensia vol. XXX, 1, 2021 DOI: 10.17951/sil.2021.30.1.251-264 Bronisław Sitek SWPS University in Warsaw, Poland ORCID: 0000-0002-7365-6954 [email protected] Servus publicus and servus privatus in Ancient Rome: Legal Status and Social Status Servus publicus a servus privatus w antycznym Rzymie. Status prawny a status społeczny ABSTRACT Public slaves were a special group of slaves. As a rule, their legal situation was analogous to private slaves. Hence, there are relatively few preserved sources of law regarding this slave group. There are relatively few Romanist studies regarding the legal situation of public slaves. A larger number of these studies appeared only in the second half of the 20th century. The subject of this study is to compare the legal and social status of both groups of slaves. The purpose is to show a different application of legal provisions depending on their suitability for public matters and the education of public slaves. UMCS Keywords: legal status; social status; private slaves; public slaves INTRODUCTION The issue of slavery in ancient Rome was relatively well developed in historical literature, especially in the legal and historical, i.e. in the Romanist literature. The Romanists’ greatest interest was related to the legal situation of slaves owned by private persons. These slaves were used as a labor force to work in the fields (familia rustica) or in cities (familia urbana) to perform various physical, mental and even business CORRESPONDENCE ADDRESS: Bronisław Sitek, PhD, dr.
    [Show full text]
  • Part II Paper 9. Slavery in the Greek and Roman Worlds
    Slavery in the Greek and Roman World History Part II: Paper 9 = Classics Part II Paper C3 [2021–2] Course Director: Professor Robin Osborne ([email protected]) Course description: Aims and objectives 1. To introduce students to ubiquitous importance of slaves in all aspects of life, political, social, economic and cultural, across Greek and Roman history. 2. To explore a wide range of literary, documentary and visual sources relevant to slaves in Greek and Roman society. 3. To encourage students to reflect on the particular methodological problems in accessing the culture or experience of those outside the elite. 4. To reflect more widely on the range of ways in which human beings were enslaved and the range of justifications given for slavery in antiquity. Nothing signals the gap between the modern world and the world of ancient Greece and Rome more starkly than the more or less universal ancient acceptance of slavery. Slavery was not simply an institution which the ancient world had and the modern does not, it grounded Greek and Roman thought as well as Greek and Roman life in the systematic subjection of a substantial section of the human population. Understanding the effects of slavery is vital for our understanding of all aspects of the Greek and Roman world. But if slavery is something that unites Greece and Rome in opposition to us, slavery in the ancient world was not a single thing. Slavery profoundly affected social, political, economic and cultural relations, but it did not determine them. Indeed, slavery offers us one of the best lenses through which to do comparative history both within the Greek and Roman worlds and between them.
    [Show full text]