The Comedy of the Commons: Commerce, Custom, and Inherently

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Comedy of the Commons: Commerce, Custom, and Inherently The University of Chicago Law Review VOLUME 53 NUMBER 3 SUMMER 1986 1986 by The University of Chicago The Comedy of the Commons: Custom, Commerce, and Inherently Public Property Carol Roset I. INTRODUCTION: THE CONUNDRUM OF "PUBLIC PROPERTY" The right to exclude others has often been cited as the most important characteristic of private property.' This right, it is said, makes private property fruitful by enabling owners to capture the full value of their individual investments, thus encouraging every- one to put time and labor into the development of resources. 2 Moreover, exclusive control makes it possible for owners to iden- tify other owners, and for all to exchange the fruits of their labors, until these things arrive in the hands of those who value them tProfessor of Law, Northwestern University. I have foisted earlier versions of this pa- per on numerous patient friends and colleagues. For their helpful comments and criticism, I particularly thank Jonathan Entin, Victor Goldberg, Mark Grady, Hendrik Hartog, Henry Hansmann, Richard Helmholz, William Marshall, Thomas Merrill, Stephen Presser, George Priest, and the indefatigable Cass Sunstein. 1 2 WILLIAM BLACKSTONE, COMMENTARIES *2 (property defined as "that sole and des- potic dominion . over the external things of the world, in total exclusion of the right of any other individual in the universe"); see also Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp., 458 U.S. 419, 435 (1982) (the right to exclude is the most valuable element of property). 1 2 W. BLACKSTONE, supra note 1, at *4 (no one would devise conveniences to make life more "agreeable" unless s/he could keep them permanently); id. at *7 ("who would be at the pains of tilling [the earth] if another might ... seise upon and enjoy the product of his industry, art, and labour?"). HeinOnline -- 53 U. Chi. L. Rev. 711 1986 The University of Chicago Law Review [53:711 most highly-to the great cumulative advantage of all.3 Thus ex- clusive private property is thought to foster the well-being of the community, giving its members a medium in which resources are used, conserved and exchanged to their greatest advantage. There is nothing new about this set of ideas; Richard Posner, a modern- day proponent of neoclassical economics, remarks that the wealth- enhancing value of property rights "has been well known for sev- eral hundred years."'4 Posner cites Blackstone for this proposition, 5 and indeed, since the advent of eighteenth-century classical eco- nomics, it has been widely believed that the whole world is best managed when divided among private owners. ' ' The obverse of this coin is the "tragedy of the commons. 1 When things are left open to the public, they are thought to be wasted by overuse or underuse. No one wishes to invest in some- thing that may be taken from him tomorrow, and no one knows whom to approach to make exchanges. All resort to snatching up what is available for "capture" today, leaving behind a wasteland.' From this perspective, "public property" is an oxymoron: things left open to the public are not property at all, but rather its antithesis. 3 Holderness, A Legal Foundation for Exchange, 14 J. LEGAL STUD. 321, 321-22, 344 (1985) (narrow and specific assignment of rights necessary for exchange). 4 RICHARD POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 28 (2d ed. 1977). Posner is speaking here only of property as an inducement to good management, but points out the importance of transferability a few paragraphs later. See id. at 28-29. 5 Id. at 28 n.3 (citing 2 W. BLACKSTONE, supra note 1, at *4, *7); Blackstone also praises "that wise and orderly maxim, of assigning to every thing capable of ownership a legal and determinate owner." 2 W. BLACKSTONE, supra note 1, at *15. 8 See, e.g., JEREMY BENTHAM, THE THEORY OF LEGISLATION, CIVIL CODE pt. 1, chs. 7-9 (Ogden ed. 1931). The great 18th-century economist Adam Smith also mentioned in passing that it is only where no one has anything worth more than two or three days' labor that there is no need to protect private property. ADAM SMITH, THE WEALTH OF NATIONS 669-70 (Modern Library ed. 1937). See also JOSEPH ANGELL, A TREATISE ON THE RIGHT OF PROPERTY IN TIDE WATERS AND IN THE SOIL AND SHORES THEREOF 17 (1826), where this American jurist follows Blackstone in arguing that all things capable of ownership should be assigned an owner, with those things incapable of exclusive ownership being assigned to the sovereign. For a modern statement of this idea, see Yandle, Resource Economics: A Property Rights Perspective, 5 J. ENERGY L. & POL'Y 1, 1-2 (1983) (natural progression toward individual ownership of scarce resources). For a challenge to the view that private ownership is pre- sumptively the most efficient form of management, see Kennedy & Michelman, Are Prop- erty and Contract Efficient?, 8 HOFSTRA L. REV. 711 (1979-80). The phrase and the classic modern statement of the position come from Hardin, The Tragedy of the Commons, 162 SCIENCE 1243 (1968), reprinted in ECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS OF PROPERTY LAW 2 (B. Ackerman ed. 1975). 8 Id.; see also Holderness, supra note 3, at 344 ("ordinary forms of social interaction, both within and beyond trade and commerce, could not take place if property rights were inconsistent or ill defined"). HeinOnline -- 53 U. Chi. L. Rev. 712 1986 1986] Custom, Commerce, and Public Property Thus it is peculiar to find a longstanding notion of "public property" in the law of the western world. The Romans, whose le- gal thinking greatly influenced later European law, were suffi- ciently interested in "public property" to separate it into at least four categories.9 And despite the power of the classical economic argument for private property, a curious cross-current has continu- ally washed through American law. Our legal doctrine has strongly suggested that some kinds of property should not be held exclu- sively in private hands, but should be open to the public or at least subject to what Roman law called the "jus publicum": the "public 10 right. Moreover, this view is not merely a vestige of premodern thought; there is currently an extensive academic and judicial dis- cussion of the possibility that certain kinds of property ought to be public. In recent years, the most striking version of this "inherent publicness" argument has appeared in a series of cases expanding public access to waterfront property.11 The land between the low and high tides has traditionally been considered "public property," or at least subject to a public easement for navigational and fishing purposes. 12 But some modern courts have stretched this easement to include a new use-recreation-and have expanded its area from the tidelands to the dry sand areas landward of the high-tide I For the Roman law categories of public property, see Coquillette, Mosses from an Old Manse: Another Look at Some Historic Property Cases about the Environment, 64 CORNELL L. REv. 761, 801-03 (1979); MacGrady, The Navigability Concept in the Civil and Common Law, 3 FLA. ST. U.L. REv. 511, 518 (1975). For applications of these classifications, see Deveney, Title, Jus Publicum, and the Public Trust: An Historical Analysis, 1 SEA GRANT L.J. 13, 29-36 (1976); Wiel, Natural Communism: Air, Water, Oil, Sea, and Sea- shore, 47 HARv. L. REV. 425 (1934); Winett, Contemporary Water Pollution Cases and Ro- man Law, III TEMp. ENvTrL. L. & TECH. J. 31 (1984). 10 This has been argued forcefully by Molly Selvin and Harry Scheiber, whose recently published historical studies argue that 19th-century American law was replete with notions of "public rights," some of which were characterized as property rights. Scheiber, Public Rights and the Rule of Law in American Legal History, 72 CAL.L. REv. 217 (1984); Selvin, The Public Trust Doctrine in American Law and Economic Policy, 1789-1920, 1980 Wis. L. REv. 1403. For the "jus publicum" (or "publici juris") language, see Deveney, supra note 9, at 29-31; see also Commonwealth v. Alger, 61 Mass. (7 Cush.) 53, 76 (1851), discussed in Scheiber, supra, at 222. "' See, e.g., City of Berkeley v. Superior Court, 26 Cal. 3d 515, 606 P.2d 362, 162 Cal. Rptr. 327, cert. denied, 449 U.S. 840 (1980); Gion v. Santa Cruz, 2 Cal. 30 29, 465 P.2d 50, 84 Cal. Rptr. 162 (1970); Borough of Neptune City v. Borough of Avon-by-the-Sea, 61 N.J. 296, 294 A.2d 47 (1972); State ex rel. Thornton v. Hay, 254 Or. 584, 462 P.2d 671 (1969); Seaway Co. v. Attorney General, 375 S.W.2d 923 (Tex. Civ. App. 1964). " See, e.g., Martin v. Waddell, 41 U.S. (16 Pet.) 366, 412-14 (1842); cf. MacGrady, supra note 9, at 566-68 (the "public" character of this land is a creation of the 17th and 18th centuries). HeinOnline -- 53 U. Chi. L. Rev. 713 1986 The University of Chicago Law Review [53:711 mark."3 These new cases extrapolate from older precedents in which the public acquired-or allegedly reasserted-claims to certain types of property, most notably roadways and lands under naviga- ble waters. Like the older precedents, the new beach cases usually employ one of three theoretical bases: (1) a "public trust" theory, to the effect that the public has always had rights of access to the property in question, and that any private rights are subordinate to the public's "trust" rights; 4 (2) a prescriptive or dedicatory the- ory, by which a period of public usage gives rise to an implied grant or gift from private owners;' 5 and (3) a theory of "custom," where the public asserts ownership of property under some claim so ancient that it antedates any memory to the contrary."" These theories of increased public access to shores and water- ways have garnered a vocal but decidedly mixed reaction.
Recommended publications
  • International Intellectual Property Law
    ee--RRGG Electronic Resource Guide International Intellectual Property Law * Jonathan Franklin This page was last updated February 8, 2013. his electronic resource guide, often called the ERG, has been published online by the American Society of International Law (ASIL) since 1997. T Since then it has been systematically updated and continuously expanded. The chapter format of the ERG is designed to be used by students, teachers, practitioners and researchers as a self-guided tour of relevant, quality, up-to-date online resources covering important areas of international law. The ERG also serves as a ready-made teaching tool at graduate and undergraduate levels. The narrative format of the ERG is complemented and augmented by EISIL (Electronic Information System for International Law), a free online database that organizes and provides links to, and useful information on, web resources from the full spectrum of international law. EISIL's subject-organized format and expert-provided content also enhances its potential as teaching tool. 2 This page was last updated February 8, 2013. I. Introduction II. Overview III. Research Guides and Bibliographies a. International Intellectual Property Law b. International Patent Law i. Public Health and IP ii. Agriculture, Plant Varieties, and IP c. International Copyright Law i. Art, Cultural Property, and IP d. International Trademark Law e. Trade and IP f. Arbitration, Mediation, and IP g. Traditional Knowledge and IP h. Geographical Indications IV. General Search Strategies V. Primary Sources VI. Primary National Legislation and Decisions VII. Recommended Link sites VIII. Selected Non-Governmental Organizations IX. Electronic Current Awareness 3 This page was last updated February 8, 2013.
    [Show full text]
  • Tragedy of the Commons : Th
    tragedy of the commons : The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_T000193&pr... tragedy of the commons Elinor Ostrom From The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition, 2008 Edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume Abstract ‘The tragedy of the commons’ arises when it is difficult and costly to exclude potential users from common-pool resources that yield finite flows of benefits, as a result of which those resources will be exhausted by rational, utility-maximizing individuals rather than conserved for the benefit of all. Pessimism about the possibility of users voluntarily cooperating to prevent overuse has led to widespread central control of common-pool resources. But such control has itself frequently resulted in resource overuse. In practice, especially where they can communicate, users often develop rules that limit resource use and conserve resources. Keywords collective action; common-pool resources; common property; free rider problem; Hardin, G.; open-access resources; private property; social dilemmas; state property; tragedy of the commons Article The term ‘the tragedy of the commons’ was first introduced by Garrett Hardin (1968) in an important article in Science. Hardin asked us to envision a pasture ‘open to all’ in which each herder received large benefits from selling his or her own animals while facing only small costs of overgrazing. When the number of animals exceeds the capacity of the pasture, each herder is still motivated to add more animals since the herder receives all of the proceeds from the sale of animals and only a partial share of the cost of overgrazing.
    [Show full text]
  • The Realized Benefits from Bioprospecting in the Wake of the Convention on Biological Diversity
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Washington University St. Louis: Open Scholarship Washington University Journal of Law & Policy Volume 47 Intellectual Property: From Biodiversity to Technical Standards 2015 The Realized Benefits from Bioprospecting in the Wake of the Convention on Biological Diversity James S. Miller Missouri Botanical Garden Follow this and additional works at: https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_journal_law_policy Part of the Ecology and Evolutionary Biology Commons, Environmental Law Commons, and the Plant Sciences Commons Recommended Citation James S. Miller, The Realized Benefits from Bioprospecting in the Wake of the Convention on Biological Diversity, 47 WASH. U. J. L. & POL’Y 051 (2015), https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_journal_law_policy/vol47/iss1/10 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law School at Washington University Open Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Washington University Journal of Law & Policy by an authorized administrator of Washington University Open Scholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Realized Benefits from Bioprospecting in the Wake of the Convention on Biological Diversity James S. Miller MISSOURI BOTANICAL GARDEN In the mid-1980s, the convergence of several technological advances led to a serious resurgence of interest in surveying plant species for drug development. The emergence of methods to miniaturize in-vitro bioassays (a test used to quantify the biological effect of a chemical compound or extract against a specific disease target) run the bioassays with robotic equipment, and isolate and identify active compounds with a speed and precision never before possible.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding Bioprospecting: Can Indigenous Populations Benefit from the Search for Pharmaceuticals in Areas of High Biodiversity
    University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Environmental Studies Undergraduate Student Theses Environmental Studies Program Spring 5-2011 Understanding Bioprospecting: Can Indigenous Populations Benefit from the Search for Pharmaceuticals in Areas of High Biodiversity Emily Schwindt University of Nebraska-Lincoln Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.unl.edu/envstudtheses Part of the Agricultural and Resource Economics Commons, Biological and Physical Anthropology Commons, Environmental Health and Protection Commons, Ethnic Studies Commons, Natural Resource Economics Commons, Natural Resources and Conservation Commons, Natural Resources Management and Policy Commons, Other Environmental Sciences Commons, Place and Environment Commons, and the Sustainability Commons Disclaimer: The following thesis was produced in the Environmental Studies Program as a student senior capstone project. Schwindt, Emily, "Understanding Bioprospecting: Can Indigenous Populations Benefit from the Search for Pharmaceuticals in Areas of High Biodiversity" (2011). Environmental Studies Undergraduate Student Theses. 46. https://digitalcommons.unl.edu/envstudtheses/46 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Environmental Studies Program at DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. It has been accepted for inclusion in Environmental Studies Undergraduate Student Theses by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. UNDERSTANDING BIOPROSPECTING:
    [Show full text]
  • Relationships Among Biodiversity Dimensions of Birds in Nebraska Nadejda Mirochnitchenko University of Nebraska - Lincoln, [email protected]
    University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Dissertations & Theses in Natural Resources Natural Resources, School of Fall 12-2018 Relationships Among Biodiversity Dimensions of Birds in Nebraska Nadejda Mirochnitchenko University of Nebraska - Lincoln, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.unl.edu/natresdiss Part of the Biodiversity Commons, Ecology and Evolutionary Biology Commons, Natural Resources and Conservation Commons, Natural Resources Management and Policy Commons, Ornithology Commons, and the Poultry or Avian Science Commons Mirochnitchenko, Nadejda, "Relationships Among Biodiversity Dimensions of Birds in Nebraska" (2018). Dissertations & Theses in Natural Resources. 275. http://digitalcommons.unl.edu/natresdiss/275 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Natural Resources, School of at DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dissertations & Theses in Natural Resources by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. RELATIONSHIPS AMONG BIODIVERSITY DIMENSIONS OF BIRDS IN NEBRASKA by Nadejda Anatolievna Mirochnitchenko A THESIS Presented to the Faculty of The Graduate College at the University of Nebraska In Partial Fulfillment of Requirements For the Degree of Master of Science Major: Natural Resource Sciences Under the Supervision of Professors Erica F. Stuber and Joseph J. Fontaine Lincoln, Nebraska December 2018 RELATIONSHIPS AMONG BIODIVERSITY
    [Show full text]
  • Mill's "Very Simple Principle": Liberty, Utilitarianism And
    MILL'S "VERY SIMPLE PRINCIPLE": LIBERTY, UTILITARIANISM AND SOCIALISM MICHAEL GRENFELL submitted for degree of Ph.D. London School of Economics and Political Science UMI Number: U048607 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Dissertation Publishing UMI U048607 Published by ProQuest LLC 2014. Copyright in the Dissertation held by the Author. Microform Edition © ProQuest LLC. All rights reserved. This work is protected against unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code. ProQuest LLC 789 East Eisenhower Parkway P.O. Box 1346 Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 I H^S £ S F 6SI6 ABSTRACT OF THESIS MILL'S "VERY SIMPLE PRINCIPLE'*: LIBERTY. UTILITARIANISM AND SOCIALISM 1 The thesis aims to examine the political consequences of applying J.S. Mill's "very simple principle" of liberty in practice: whether the result would be free-market liberalism or socialism, and to what extent a society governed in accordance with the principle would be free. 2 Contrary to Mill's claims for the principle, it fails to provide a clear or coherent answer to this "practical question". This is largely because of three essential ambiguities in Mill's formulation of the principle, examined in turn in the three chapters of the thesis. 3 First, Mill is ambivalent about whether liberty is to be promoted for its intrinsic value, or because it is instrumental to the achievement of other objectives, principally the utilitarian objective of "general welfare".
    [Show full text]
  • The Tragedy of the Government Created Commons
    The Tragedy of the Government Created Commons by Robert B. Kauffman, Ph.D. In terms of the tragedy of the commons, the government and those advocating for larger government have an incentive to purposely create commons and collective harm. It furthers their agenda. [Keywords: tragedy of the commons, Garrett Hardin, tragedy of government created commons] In his classic article published in the December 1968 issue of Science, Garrett Hardin linked the lesson of the commons to the need for government management and the supervision of individuals in order to prevent the tragedy that harm comes to all in the tragedy of the commons. Collectively, individual self- interest leads to collective harm. As part of the lesson of the commons, he demonstrated that moral restraint does not work in the commons and that this justified the need for government intervention in individual's lives to temper the pursuit of self-interest by the individual. The basic paradigm where government is the solution and not the problem needs to be reexamined. In the government created commons, government purposely creates commons to unleash its destructive powers of collective harm. Along with the traditional solutions of rationing, the collective harm justifies the government’s solution to increase the size of the commons and to increase its power and control in an effort to solve the problem. Unfortunately, because the underlying tenets of the commons are not addressed, the problem persists and is exacerbated as is the need for even more governmental involvement to solve the problem it created. The story used to illustrate the tragedy of the commons is sometimes affectionately referred to as the story of Bessy the cow.
    [Show full text]
  • Exclusivity and the Construction of Intellectual Property Markets
    The Fable of the Commons: Exclusivity and the Construction of Intellectual Property Markets Shubha Ghosh* TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ................................................................................... 857 I. LOOKING BEYOND THE COMMONS: TURNING HIGH TRAGEDY INTO LOW DRAMA .................................................................... 860 A. The Fable of the Commons................................................. 861 B. Governing the Commons Through the Goals of Distributive Justice ............................................................ 864 II. THE DIMENSIONS OF DISTRIBUTIVE JUSTICE.............................. 870 A. Creators ............................................................................ 871 B. Creators and Users............................................................ 876 C. Intergenerational Justice.................................................... 879 III. DISTRIBUTIVE JUSTICE IN PRACTICE .......................................... 880 A. Fair Use: Allocating Surplus Among Creators and Users .. 881 B. Secondary Liability: Spanning Generational Divides......... 883 C. Antitrust: Natural and Cultural Monopolies and the Limits of Exclusivity in the Marketplace ............................ 886 D. Traditional Knowledge: Expanding Canons and the Global Marketplace ........................................................... 888 CONCLUSION....................................................................................... 889 * Professor of Law, Southern Methodist University, Dedman School
    [Show full text]
  • Plant Genetic Resources As Commons: the Model of Fao’S International Treaty
    PLANT GENETIC RESOURCES AS COMMONS: THE MODEL OF FAO’S INTERNATIONAL TREATY Dr. María Iglesias Introduction After almost 7 years of negotiations, the International Treaty on Plant Genetic Resources for Food and Agriculture (hereinafter ITPGRFA) was adopted in November 20011. The Treaty already recognises in its Preamble that plant genetic resources for food and agriculture are a common concern of all countries, in that all countries depend very largely on plant genetic resources for food and agriculture that originated elsewhere. Thus, the main objectives of the ITPGRFA are the conservation and sustainable use of plant genetic resources for food and agriculture (hereinafter PGRFAs) and the fair and equitable sharing of the benefits arising out of their use, in harmony with the Convention on Biological Diversity, for sustainable agriculture and food security2. Although the Treaty covers all PGRs3, it establishes an international commons pool, the so called multilateral system, only for certain kinds of resources that will guarantee the access to these resources and the sharing of benefits 1 The ITPGRFA entered in to force in June 2004. In December 2008, 119 states had ratified it. 2 Art. 1. The ITPGRFA may be considered in fact as a special application of art. 15 (Access to Genetic Resources) of the Convention on Biological Diversity: “1. Recognizing the sovereign rights of States over their natural resources, the authority to determine access to genetic resources rests with the national governments and is subject to national legislation. 2. Each Contracting Party shall endeavour to create conditions to facilitate access to genetic resources for environmentally sound uses by other Contracting Parties and not to impose restrictions that run counter to the objectives of this Convention.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Commons: Between Cooperation and Competition by Gerald Stang
    17 2013 Photo by NASA / Rex Features (1568628a) Features / Rex NASA by Photo Global commons: Between cooperation and competition by Gerald Stang Rapid economic development and increasing inter- What exactly are the global commons? national trade are leading to a more crowded interna- tional stage and raising new challenges in the ‘global Security analysts generally identify four domains as commons’ – those domains that are not under the global commons: high seas, airspace, outer space control or jurisdiction of any state but are open for use and, now, cyberspace. From a security perspective, by countries, companies and individuals from around the primary concern is safeguarding ‘access’ to these the world. Their management involves increasingly domains for commercial and military reasons. complex processes to accommodate and integrate the interests and responsibilities of states, international It is important to highlight that this language differs organisations and a host of non-state actors. from the discourse on commons developed by envi- ronmental analysts: their arguments focus on dam- Shared rules regarding the usage of - and access to age to the ‘condition’ of the commons from overuse - the global commons encourage their peaceful and by actors who do not have to pay direct costs. They cooperative use. Over the last seven decades, the US worry about the depletion of shared resources such as has led in the creation of a liberal international order ocean fish stocks, or the damage to shared domains which has attempted to define these rules in such a such as Antarctica or the atmosphere. way as to make it easier and more beneficial to join the order and follow the rules than it does to operate A third strand of analysis looks not at the need for outside of (or undermine) it.
    [Show full text]
  • Intergovernmental Fiscal Immunity
    BEST BEST & KRIEGER LLP A CALIFORNIA LIMITED LIABILITY PARTNERSHIP INCLUDING PROFESSIONAL CORPORATIONS RIVERSIDE ONTARIO LAWYERS (909) 686-1450 TH (909) 989-8584 WEST BROADWAY FLOOR ,, 402 , 13 ,, INDIAN WELLS SAN DIEGO, CALIFORNIA 92101-3542 ORANGE COUNTY (760) 568-2611 (619) 525-1300 (949) 263-2600 (619) 233-6118 FAX ,, SACRAMENTO BBKLAW COM . (916) 325-4000 CITY ATTORNEYS DEPARTMENT LEAGUE OF CALIFORNIA CITIES CONTINUING EDUCATION SEMINAR FEBRUARY 2003 WARREN DIVEN OF BEST BEST & KRIEGER LLP INTERGOVERNMENTAL FISCAL IMMUNITY TOPIC OUTLINE TAXES Property Taxes Publicly Owned Property as Generally Exempt from Property Taxation Construction of the Constitutional Exemption Use of Publicly Owned Property Property Owned by a Public Agency Outside its Jurisdictional Boundaries Taxation of Possessory Interest Miscellaneous Statutory Provisions or Decisions Related to Property Taxation Sales and Use Tax Business License Tax Special Taxes Utility Users Tax CAPITAL FACILITIES FEES Capital Facilities Fees - Judicial History Legislative Response to San Marcos USER FEES ASSESSMENTS Pre-Proposition 218 Implied Exemption Public Use Requirement Post Proposition 218 - What Effect Proposition 218? City Attorneys Department League of California Cities Continuing Education Seminar February 2003 Warren Diven Partner INTERGOVERNMENTAL FISCAL IMMUNITY1 The purpose of this paper is to review the concept of intergovernmental fiscal immunity, i.e., the exemption of one governmental entity from liability for the payment of taxes, assessments or fees levied or imposed by another governmental entity: • Where does such immunity exist? • How is such immunity created? • When does it apply? • What is the extent of such immunity? • What are the exceptions to the application of such immunity? This paper shall in turn review the application of intergovernmental fiscal immunity to: • Taxes; • Capital facility fees; • User fees; and • Assessments.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 1 Sustainability of Our Planet the Environment
    Chapter 1 Sustainability of our planet The environment Everything around you; both living and nonliving things Examples: air, water, sunlight, people, plants, animals Environmental Science The study of how humans interact with the environment. Involves many subjects such as: engineering, biology, chemistry, earth science, economics, political science, ethics, moral judgments Goals of Environmental Science There are 3 goals to studying environmental science. 1. Learn how life on Earth has survived and thrived. 2. Understand how humans interact with the environment. 3. Find ways to deal with environmental problems and live more sustainably. What is sustainability? The ability of Earth’s natural systems that support life to adapt to the changing environmental conditions indefinitely. Scientific factors to sustainability Why has life existed on the planet for about 3.8 billion years? 1. Solar energy - photosynthesis 2. Biodiversity – variety of species, genes, ecosystems on the planet to help with adapting to new environmental conditions 3. Nutrient cycling – when an organism dies, it decays, nutrients go back into ground for another organism Social factors to sustainability How have past decisions on environmental problems effected today’s society? 1. Economics –production and consumption of goods and services 2. Political science – government/politics and how it relates to the environment 3. Ethics – study of right and wrong Natural Capital Natural resources and ecosystem services that keep humans and other species alive and
    [Show full text]