<<

Discussion Paper No. 2017-49 | August 08, 2017 | http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2017-49

The displacement and attraction effects in interurban migration: an application of the input-output scheme to the case of large cities in Korea

Cheol-Joo Cho

Abstract In this paper, two migratory impact-assessment schemes are constructed within the framework of Ghoshian and Leontief input-output analysis. These schemes are designed to estimate the rural-to-urban migration-induced and the urban-to-rural migration-induced effects on interurban migration, where the former effect is termed the replacement effect, while the latter the attraction effect. The established input-output schemes are empirically applied to the 2012 data on interregional migration in Korea. The results show that an arrival of migrants to and/or a departure of residents from the 20 largest cities in Korea induce direct and indirect ripples of population flow between those cities. A combination of the displacement and the attraction effects yields a classification of cities by which the 20 largest cities are grouped into four different types. JEL D57 R15 R23 R58 Keywords interregional migration; displacement effect; attraction effect; input-output schemes; classification of cities; largest cities in Korea Authors Cheol-Joo Cho, University, Korea, [email protected]

Citation Cheol-Joo Cho (2017). The displacement and attraction effects in interurban migration: an application of the input-output scheme to the case of large cities in Korea. Economics Discussion Papers, No 2017-49, Kiel Institute for the World Economy. http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2017-49

Received May 19, 2017 Accepted as Economics Discussion Paper July 25, 2017 Published August 8, 2017 © Author(s) 2017. Licensed under the Creative Commons License - Attribution 4.0 International (CC BY 4.0) 1. Introduction

Inequality in regional development has attracted the attention of economists and policy- makers. By the way, it is contended that regional disparities in economic development are closely related with regional adjustment mechanisms. Incidentally, migration flows between different regions adjust the process through which the regional distribution of economic resources can be organized (OECD 2005). Where the balance of net migration is towards a surplus of inflow, migrants bring the benefits such as their skills and contribution to economic growth, or they might place demanding pressures on finite resources such as housing and services. On the other hand, where a surplus is towards a net outflow, different but no less important issues, such as the loss of human capital or the benefits accrued by remittances, may be of concern. In line with the claim of the close relationship between migration and regional disparity, empirical evidence reveals that the persistence of regional disparities is attributed to the role of interregional migration as a regional adjustment mechanism (Kondo and Okubo 2015). Then, this conceivable relationship of migration with lasting regional disparities may constitute a most compelling reason for the pervasive concern of academia and policy analysists about the migration of people. As the majority of intra-country regions throughout the world have undergone unemployment for a long period of time, reducing the intensity of uneven regional development has long been a major policy focus at national or regional governments (OECD 2005). Korea, with rapid economic growth and the consequential high rate of urbanization, is no exception of the countries which place higher policy priority on promoting balanced development between regions. During the past several decades, Korean governments have rigorously pursued a variety of policies to cope with population drain, industrial decline, and degrading quality of life in the lagging regions. Examples include the construction of various new cities, such as the new administrative city, innovative cities, and enterprise cities, and the relocation of public corporations into the underdeveloped regions (Jang 2015). Given the rigorous policy concern about persistent disparities in the levels of economic development between different regions in Korea, the proclaimed relationship between migration and regional disparities justifies investigating the consequences of residential migration between regions in the Korean context. With its significant effect on the economic performance of the receiving as well as leaving regions of migrants, migration has been high on the academic subject for the past

1

several decades. Indeed, the migration-related literature has proliferated such that up to 2014 since 1969, more than 12,000 articles in economics-related journals alone have been published (Cushing and Poot 2003). A number of previous studies on migration have devoted on empirical analysis of the determinants of migration decisions. From the micro-economic perspective, the majority of the empirical literature investigate the migration decision through the interregional difference in wages and employment. Along the framework of Todaro (1969) and Harris and Todaro (1970), for example, several extensive studies identify real wage gaps and employment opportunities as the influential factors of migration. This strand of studies extends the argument into the prospective migrant’s utility to incorporate diverse elements, such as, for example, employment and housing opportunities, environmental quality, cultural amenities, and so on. Meanwhile, another stream of migration research centers on the impact of migration on labor market performance. Some migrants may take jobs or depress wages of existing resident workers, while others invest savings or add entrepreneurial talent to the economy. Whatever effects this stream of literature claims, the debate on labor market performance rarely takes place within a spatial context. The aspatial assessments of migration impact put prime emphasis on employment and wage effects at the migration destinations. In contrast to the aspatial assessment, some migration literature has paid attention to the potential effects that the exogenous arrival or departure of migrants can produce on the internal migration patterns between regions. The main focus of this literature is on assessing the impact of immigration or rural-to-urban migrants on interregional migration (Fernandez-Vazquez et al. 2011; Vinuela and Fernandez-Vazquez 2012). This paper is in line with the stream of literature that assesses the effects that rural-urban or urban-rural migrants cause on internal migration between regions. The aim of this paper is to estimate the ripple effect that the rural-to-urban or urban-to-rural migrants bring on interurban migration in Korea. Specifically, using the Ghoshian and Leontief input-output schemes, estimated are the impacts of rural-urban and urban-rural movements on the interurban migration between the largest cities in Korea. The former is used for estimating the displacement effect, which represents the total number of migration outflows from a particular large city to other large cities as induced by a migrant moving into the relevant large city from non-large city areas. On the contrary, the latter is employed to measure the attraction effect, which represents the direct and indirect migration inducement that a resident

2

departing a particular large city towards non-large city areas brings on the number of migration inflows into the relevant large city from other large cities. Next, based on the estimation of the two opposing effects, the largest cities in Korea are distinguished into different groups of cities. This paper is organized as follows. The next section is devoted to a review of the related literature. The third section derives two contrasting input-output schemes with which the displacement and attraction effects can be estimated. The fourth section applies the established input-output schemes to the 20 largest cities in Korea and then, based on the results of empirical application, classifies the largest cities into four different groups. Finally, summary and conclusions are presented.

2. Literature Review

Research on migration was initially approached from the disequilibrium perspective, which suggests that interregional wage differentials and the probability of finding jobs are the major factors behind migration (Todaro 1969; Harris and Todaro 1970; Stark et al. 1991; Walker et al. 1992; Wright et al. 1997; Hatton and Tani 2005; Lim 2011). According to this view, an equilibrium of migration, at which no one has an incentive to move, is reached when real wages are equal in all regions. Some disequilibrium models depend on the perfect rationality assumption that migration decisions are made based on the risk-free deterministic expectation of income differentials (Todaro 1969; Harris and Todaro 1970), whereas others on the notion of imperfect information that uncertainty in the expectation of real income differentials prevails in migration decisions (Stark et al. 1991; Bonasia and Napolitano 2012). Meanwhile, with Tiebout’s (1956) contribution, the disequilibrium perspective of migration has been overridden by the equilibrium model: it is suggested that migration is possible even though wages are equal in all regions because of different levels of local public services. The idea implicit in the equilibrium perspective is that a migration imbalance between pairs of regions reveals the existence of difference in locational attributes. The locational quality-of-life attributes, which cause equilibrium in migration by offsetting the wage differentials, comprise natural amenities such as climate and scenery, as well as man- made amenities such as infrastructure, healthcare and public safety (Greenwood 1985; Knapp and Graves 1987; Greenwood at al. 1991; Greenwood 1997; Wall 2001; Krupka 2004; Plantinga et al. 2013). Besides the physical and man-made attributes, furthermore, other factors are incorporated as part of the local attributes into the equilibrium model. Examples

3

include crime and pollution (Blomquist et al. 1988; Buch et al. 2014), institutional strength (Gyourko and Tracy 1991), and the activities of local and regional governments such as tax and government policies (Day 1992; Charney 1993). It is noted that the disequilibrium or equilibrium perspective does not account for the spatial dimension in migration. Both perspectives do not consider spatial deterrence as a key determinant of interregional migration (Krugman 1995; Karlsson 2015). In contrast, the gravity model of spatial interaction explicitly employs spatial distances in migration analysis, assuming that the volume of migration interchange between regions is dependent on the mass and the distance deterrence (Plane and Rogerson 1994: 196-211; Molho 2013). As applied to migration analysis, the mass is measured by the population of regions, whereas the distance deterrence is represented by the geographical distances between destinations and origins. In this way, the spatial dimension is explicitly embedded into the model such that a longer distance between regions causes less migration to occur between them. Several variants of the gravity model are applied to migration research. The unconstrained and origin-constrained gravity models, among others, are most often used (Stillwell 1978; Plane 1984; Rogerson 1990; Plane and Rogerson 1994). Also, the attraction-constrained model is used to analyze movement patterns in the former Soviet Union (Mitchneck 1990). In addition, Plane (1981) experiments with a net-constrained version of gravity model. More recently, some extensions of the gravity model, in which the fixed vector decomposition estimator is applied, are used to investigate the main determinants of interregional migration flows (Greenwood 1997; Greenwood and Hunt 2003; Etzo 2011). Besides the gravity model, the new economic geography (NEG) also provides another distance-embedded framework of migration analysis. The NEG literature implicitly address the question of migration between regions, showing how the interactions between transport costs and increasing returns at the firm level shape the location of economic activities and workers (Pfluger 2004; Karlsson 2015). The key aspect of the NEG is that regional differences in not only nominal wages but also the cost of living, by which workers migrate across different regions, are endogenously determined.1 Then, incorporating the real wage difference as the determinant of migration decisions is a salient feature of the NEG models,

1When workers migrate into a location, the increased demand in this location attracts more firms. By reducing the price level, then, the more firms lead to the rise of real wages, which encourages the attraction of more workers. This influx of labor into the destination region again increases demand, prompting a new round of the process of cumulative causation (Krugman 1991; Krugman and Venables 1995; Venables 1996; Fujita et al. 2000; Baldwin 2001).

4

compared with other studies of equilibrium or disequilibrium perspective that take into account only nominal wages (Kondo and Okubo 2015). Although many studies in the NEG address the issue of interregional migration, most of them primarily focus on the development of theoretical models (Krugman 1991; Ottaviano et al. 2002; Camacho 2013). In the meantime, a notable strand of migration research, which is much different from the literature examined so far, comes with the framework of input-output analysis. Developed initially by Leontief (1936, 1986), the economic input-output model has been applied to diverse areas, including energy analysis (Miller and Blair 2009; Su and Ang 2011), emergy analysis (Ukidwe and Bakshi 2007; Cho 2013), ecological footprint analysis (Wackernagel and Rees 1996), and natural disaster analysis (Kerschner and Hubacek 2009). However, it is rather recently that the input-output framework is extended to migration research. Following the framework of Cabrer and Pavia (2003), Fernandez-Vazquez et al. (2011) investigate the impact of immigration on the internal migration pattern in Spain. Using the framework of Ghosh input-output analysis, they estimate the direct and indirect effects that the arrival of foreign immigrants can produce on the allocation of population among other regions. In a similar vein, Vinuela and Fernandez-Vazquez (2012) explore the chain of the effects of migrant flows from the periphery to the core in Spain. Based on the Spanish definition of core and periphery regions, they use the Ghoshian input-output scheme to assess the effects that the arrival of new workers from the periphery causes on the core. In a different context from these studies, Sastry (1992) applies the traditional input-output analysis to estimate the economic impacts of elderly migration in Florida in the U.S. Using the data of the consumption expenditures of elderly inmigrants who move into Florida, the study quantifies the impact of elderly inmigration on the output, earnings, and employment of the Florida economy. As examined above, the migration studies based on the input-output scheme are mainly concerned with assessing the consequences of a migration inflow for the regions of destination. No attention is paid to estimating the impact of a migration outflow on the movement of people between regions. Then, the motivation of this paper is to fill this loophole in the migration-related literature.

3. The Input-Output Schemes of Migration Impact

3.1. The Measure of Displacement Effect To analyze the displacement and attraction effects of migration, a set of geographical units,

5

i.e. regions, provinces, cities, etc., between which interregional movements occur, should be posited. For this purpose, it is assumed that the economic space on which interregional migration takes place is composed of a set of 푁 large cities and the remainder areas, i.e. non- large city areas, which comprise small and medium-sized cities and rural areas. For a system of 푁 large cities and non-large city areas, the following vectors and matrix can be defined: a 푁ⅹ1 column vector 퐱 to represent inflow or outflow totals of population for individual large cities; a 푁ⅹ1 column vector 퐧 of inflow totals into individual large cities migrating from other large cities; a 푁ⅹ1 column vector 퐬 of inflow totals into individual large cities from non-large city areas; and a 푁ⅹ푁 matrix 퐌 of interurban migrations between the large cities. Then, the 푁ⅹ푁 matrix of direct displacement coefficients, 퐁, can be written as:

(1) 퐁 = (퐱̂)−1퐌 where 퐱̂ denotes the 푁ⅹ푁 diagonal matrix with the elements of the vector 퐱 along the main diagonal. Using 퐁, the inflows of population arriving into the 푁 large cities can be expressed as:

(2) 퐱′ = 퐬′(퐈 − 퐁)−1 where 퐈 is the 푁ⅹ푁 identity matrix. The derivation of Eq. (2) is detailed in Appendix A. −1 Let 퐆 = (퐈 − 퐁) with elements 푔푖푗 ’s, then, the matrix 퐆 can be called the displacement inverse. The element 푔푖푗 of 퐆 measures the direct and indirect displacement effects.2 In other words, it represents the number of flows from large city 푖 to large city 푗 as caused by the arrival of one migrant into large city 푖 from non-large city areas. Then, the value of this element depends on how many native residents are displaced from large city 푖 to large city 푗 when a new rural-urban migrant arrive in city 푖. 푁 The quantity 푔푖∙ = ∑푗≠푖 푔푖푗 represents the total number of outmigrants from large city 푖

2As the elements of G measure the outflow ripple effects caused by an inmigrant, the model in Eq. (2) can be considered a Ghoshian input-output scheme. The Ghosh model is designed to estimate the total output impact that a unit change in primary inputs (value-added) for a specific sector causes throughout all sectors of an economy (Oosterhaven, 1988; Dietzenbacher, 1997; Miller and Blair, 2009). Despite the occasional critique of the Ghosh model, strong counterarguments in vindication of the Ghoshian framework appear in the related literature (Gruver, 1989; Dietzenbacher, 1997). Consequently, in case of analyzing the effect of a small shock in exogenously specified input, the Ghosh model can be a useful tool.

6

moving towards the set of (푁 − 1) large cities, which are caused by an arrival of population into large city 푖 from non-large city areas. Then, the large city 푖’s displacement multiplier is defined as the sum of the elements in the 푖-th row of 퐆. Accordingly, the displacement effects for the set of 푁 large cities is expressed with a 푁 × 1 column vector 퐩 as:

(3) 퐩 = 퐆퐢

where 퐢 is a 푁 × 1 column vector of ones. The element 푝푖 of 퐩 presents the total number of migrants displaced from large city 푖 to the rest of (푁 − 1) large cities as a resident arrives into large city 푖 from non-large city areas. Meanwhile, in terms of the changes in 퐬, Eq. (2) can be expressed as:

(4) ∆퐱′ = ∆퐬′퐆

Eq. (4) shows the changes in the gross displacement, ∆퐱′, that the changes in the number of rural-urban migrants, ∆퐬′, trigger. This means that, under the assumption that 퐆 remains fixed, the change in 퐱′ can be realized only by the exogenous change in 퐬′.

3.2. The Measure of Attraction Effect In addition to the matrices and vectors defined before, let define the 푁 × 1 column vector 퐫 to represent the outflow totals from individual large cities to non-large city areas and the 푁 × 1 column vector 퐧퐦 to represent the factors that ensure the equivalence of the outflow and the inflow for the individual large cities. Given the matrices and vectors defined above, the 푁ⅹ푁 matrix of direct-attraction coefficients, 퐀, can be expressed as:

(5) 퐀 = 퐌(퐱̂)−1

Then, using the 퐀 matrix, the number of outflows from the 푁 large cities can be expressed as:

(6) 퐱 = (퐈 − 퐀)−1[퐫 + 퐧퐦]

−1 Appendix B presents the derivation of Eq. (6). Let define 퐋 = (퐈 − 퐀) , the element 푙푖푗

7

measures the direct plus indirect attraction effect, which indicates the number of population migrating from large city 푖 to large city 푗 when a resident relocates from large city 푗 to 푁 non-large city areas. Then, the quantity of 푙∙푗 = ∑푖≠푗 푙푖푗 represents the total number of outflows that a departure from large city 푗 to non-large city areas generates across the set of (푁 − 1) large cities. We define the attraction multiplier for large city 푗 as the sum of inflows to city 푗 from the rest of (푁 − 1) large cities, which are generated by a resident relocating from large city 푗 to non-large city areas. Then, the attraction multipliers for 푁 individual large cities can be represented by the 1 × 푁 row vector 퐪′ as:

(7) 퐪′ = 퐢′퐋

Stated from the standpoint of large city 푖, the element 푞푖 of 퐪 means the attraction multiplier of large city 푖, which indicates the sum of inflows migrating into large city 푖 from other (푁 − 1) large cities, which occurs when one resident moves from large city 푖 to non- large city areas. Thus, it represents the number of migrants that large city 푖 attract from other (푁 − 1) large cities as prompted by a resident relocating from large city 푖 to non-large city areas. Meanwhile, set aside the vector 퐧퐦 whose elements are fixed, the outflow vector 퐱 in Eq. (6) can be expressed in terms of the change in 퐫 as:

(8) ∆퐱 = 퐋∆퐫

Eq. (8) calculates the change in the gross attraction, ∆퐱, as caused by the change in the amount of relocation from large cities to non-large city areas ∆퐫. This means that because the attraction coefficient matrix, 퐋, is considered constant, the change in 퐱 can be realized by the exogenous change in 퐫.

4. Empirical Application

4.1. Interurban Migration in Korea This paper applies the input-output schemes to analyzing migration effects in Korean. The point of departure in the empirical application is to distinguish Korean cities by their sizes. For this, the national territory of Korea is split into two segments: the 20 largest cities with greater than 500,000 inhabitants and the rest of the territory, which comprises cities with less

8

than 500,000 residents and counties. It is noted that the segment of the Korean territory comprising cities with less than 500,000 residents and counties is referred to as non-large city areas in this paper. Based on the 2012 data on population of local governments, which is offered by the Korean Statistical Information Service (KOSIS), all 84 cities are listed in descending order of population size, and then the 20 most populous cities of at least 500,000 inhabitants are selected as the largest cities.3 Figure 1 shows the locations and population sizes of the 20 largest cities in Korean.

[Figure 1 about here]

With the largest cities vs. non-large city areas divide, Figure 2 shows the changes of population concentration for the 20 largest cities, which are contrasted with those for all 88 Korean cities. As shown in the upper panel of Figure 2, the overall rate of urbanization steadily increases from 88.5% to 92.1% for the period 2000-2012. In contrast, when confined to the 20 largest cities, the concentration rate of population varies within a narrow margin substantially below the overall urbanization rate, ranging between 64.9% and 65.8% for the same period (see the lower panel of Figure 2). Obviously, the shares of population concentrated in the 20 largest cities relative to those of the rest of the cities appear to decline throughout the period. This trend suggests that the 20 largest cities have continually lost their population.

[Figure 2 about here]

On the other hand, the mobility of population appears quite different across the 20 largest cities. Figure 3 presents the net migration rates for the 20 largest cities for the years 2004, 2008, and 2012.4 According to Figure 3, the majority of the largest cities in the capital region,

3In Korea, a locale with more than 50,000 inhabitants is incorporated as a city, with the status of municipality granted by the central government. There are 84 cities in Korea as of 2012. This total comprises 20 largest cities with greater than 500,000 residents and 64 small and medium-sized cities. The average population for all 84 cities is 558,767, while the standard deviation is 1,216,216. On the other hand, for the 20 largest cities, the average city size and the standard deviation are 1,675,666 and 2,165,917, respectively, 4The net migration rate is defined as the difference between the inmigration rate and the outmigration rate. It is calculated as [(퐼푀푖푡 − 푂푀푖푡)⁄푃푖푡] × 100 , where 퐼푀푖푡 is the number of incoming populations into city 푖 at time 푡 and 푂푀푖푡 is the number of outgoing populations from city 푖 at time 푡.

9

including , have negative net migration rates, whereas four cities located in the outskirts of the capital region, including , Goyang, , and Youngin, attract substantial migrants over the years. This pattern of net migration for the largest cities within the capital region suggests a strong implication that substantial migration streams from the core cities adjacent to Seoul to the cities in the peripheral areas in the capital region. Figure 3 also reveals an additional salient characteristic of the migration pattern for the largest cities. Specifically, most of the top five populous cities in Korea, i.e. Seoul, , , , and , have lost their population over the period. This pattern implies that as the large cities grow, the agglomeration benefits are weaker than the diseconomies from congestion. This effect, combined with the impact of the geographical dispersion of firms and industries, would stimulate the populations of the top largest cities to migrate to other cities or rural areas.

[Figure 3 about here]

4.2. Data Set As mentioned earlier, this paper applies the input-output schemes established in the previous section to estimating the migratory attraction and displacement effects in Korea. For the empirical application of the schemes, a proper data set should be constructed. Based on the 2012 raw data on migration obtained from the KOSIS, a table in input-output format is constructed that contains the interregional flows of migrants occurring across the largest cities and non-large city areas. Table 1 shows the matrix of interurban migrant flows between the 20 largest cities, on the one hand, and the vectors of total inflows and outflows for the cities, on the other.5 Table 1 demonstrates that, when intra-urban mobility is excluded, Seoul is ranked first in the numbers of inmigrants from and outmigrants to other largest cities and non-large city areas. Seoul is followed, but with a large margin, by two metropolitan cities, Busan and Incheon. These three largest cities appear extraordinarily high in the share of interregional

5The diagonal elements of the portion of interurban migrations, which is equivalent to 퐌 in Eq. (A5) in Appendix A, represent the internal migration within the 20 largest cities. Because the intra-city flows are less to nothing at all to do with increasing or decreasing outmigration, they should not be considered in calculating the migration multiplier results, i.e. the displacement and attraction effects. On the other hand, according to the 2012 KOSIS data, the share of immigration and emigration in total migrations in Korea is extremely low to account for only 0.04% in 2012. Reflecting the insignificance of international mobility, both immigration and emigration are excluded from constructing Table 1.

10

migrations compared to the rest of the largest cities in Korean, including four metropolitan cities, i.e. Daegu, Gwangju, Daejeon and , and 13 non-metropolitan large cities. Thus, the data of interregional migration presents the asymmetrical feature of interregional migration with the distribution of migrants skewed heavily to a few largest metropolitan cities.

[Table 1 about here]

4.3. The Displacement Effect As defined earlier, the displacement effect means a rural-to-urban migration-initiated shock. Empirically, the displacement effect with respect to a particular largest city is calculated by horizontal summation of the elements in the row of 퐆 in Eq. (3) which corresponds to the relevant largest city. Then, the index of displacement effect for the individual 20 largest cities is represented by the 20 × 1 column vector, 퐩, as expressed by Eq. (3). Table 2 shows the results of the estimated displacement effect for the 20 largest cities.6 According to Table 2, has a highest displacement effect, with the value of 2.6124. This means that the arrival of one migrant to Bucheon from non-large city areas generates 2.6124 outmigrants moving from Bucheon to the rest of the 20 largest cities. Bucheon is followed by , which shows the value of 2.4995. Other three largest cities, i.e. Youngin, Seoul, and Anyang, appear to have the displacement effect larger than 2.0. The magnitudes of their displacement effect are 2.3420 for Youngin, 2.3323 for Seoul, and 2.3309 for Anyang, respectively. These large cities with a highest level of displacement effect are located in the capital region. These findings indicate that, if a largest city is within the capital region, more residents would be induced to migrate outside the city’s boundaries. On the other hand, five of the 20 largest cities, including Daegu, Cheongju, , Gwangju, and , constitute a group of large cities at the bottom level of displacement effect. These cities have the magnitudes of displacement effect less than 2.0, say, 1.9832 for Daegu, 1.9445 for Cheongju, 1.8823 for Cheonan, 1.8619 for Gwangju, and 1.8485 for Jeonju, respectively. Regarding the geographical location of these cities, none of these cities are located within the capital region. But it is evident that the magnitudes of displacement effect rise as the cities are located closer to the capital region.

6The numbers in the second column in Table 2 represent the displacement effect in original scale, while those in the third column are the standardized z-scores for the values of displacement effect, which are scaled to the mean of 0.0 and the standard deviation of 1.0.

11

[Table 2 about here]

Overall, the distribution of displacement effect across the 20 largest cities examined above casts a strong implication that, for a specific largest city, the intensity of displacement effect is associated with its physical distance to the capital region. That is, it can be said that the closer a largest city to the capital region, the more intense its displacement effect. As the largest cities adjacent to and within the capital region have a higher level of chain effect as initiated by the arrival of a migrant into them, that is, the intense forward waves of migration rippling across the whole set of the 20 largest cities, a specific interplay between the labor skills or job classes of migrants and those of native residents is implied. Specifically, it seems that, for the largest cities within or close to the capital region, skill or job similarities exist between emigrants and native residents, and consequently, the inflowing migration shock leads to a higher level of direct and indirect displacement (Walker et al. 1992; Hatton and Tani 2005). In the circumstance of the similar skill grade, some policies can be justified if they could reduce the adverse economic effect originating from the replacement relationship between emigrants and native residents. For instance, by adjusting the wage of inmigrants, the largest cities exposed to a higher level of displacement can generate production complementarity with an improvement of profit potential, by which the economic distress of resident’s displacement in the cities could be ameliorated (Walker et al. 1992; Wright et al. 1997).7 On the other hand, there exists no apparent relationship between the population sizes of cities and the intensities of displacement effect. That is, there is no indication that a largest city’s population size is associated with the intensity of its displacement effect, i.e. the number of migrants moving from a largest city to other largest cities, which is spurted when a migrant arrives in the largest city from non-large city areas.8 Then, regarding the 20 largest cities, other relevant variables would be responsible for the varying degrees of displacement effect between them. This issue is not further addressed here because the main purpose of this

7If the inmigrants from non-large city areas are adjusted to receive lower than equilibrium wage, labor is substituted for capital and consequently, profit opportunities at inmigrant destination cities are enhanced. By attracting high-skilled workers into these inmigrant destinations, then, the improved profit potential generates production complementarity between skilled white-collar professionals and low-skilled workers, Thus, the production complementarity with an improvement of profit potential at migrant destination cities can be a condition under which the inflows of skilled migrants into these places are fostered. 8The correlation coefficient between the city size and the displacement effect is 0.1547. This value is too low to claim the substantial relationship between the two variables.

12

study is to measure the aggregated migratory effect rather than to identify plausible factors that account for migration.

4.4. The Attraction Effect In contrast to the rural-to-urban migration shock, the attraction effect for a specific largest city represents the urban-to-rural migrant-triggered effect as measured by the total number of inflows to a specific largest city from other largest cities, which is prompted when a resident in the largest city migrates to non-large city areas. The measure of migratory attraction is conceptually parallel to the vector of output multipliers constructed to capture both direct and indirect backward linkages in ordinary economic input-output analysis (Miller and Blair 2009, 556-558). As defined in Eq. (7), then, the column sums of 퐋, represented by the 20 × 1 row vector 풒′, contain the magnitudes of attraction effect for the individual largest cities. Table 3 shows the results of the estimated attraction effect for the top 20 largest cities in Korea.9 As shown in Table 3, the city with the highest attraction effect is Bucheon. The intensity of attraction effect for the city is 2.6221. This means that, if a resident living in Bucheon migrates into non-large city areas, this outgoing migrant generates a total of 2.6221 additional migrants, who relocate into Bucheon from the rest of the largest cities. Youngin has the next highest value of attraction, 2.6136. Besides these two cities, four other largest cities, including Seongnam, Goyang, Namyangju, and Incheon, appear to have relatively higher attraction effect, with their magnitudes of greater than 2.4. The attraction indices for these cities are 2.5885, 2.5114, 2.4623, and 2.4007, respectively. It is notable that all these six largest cities with a higher value of attraction effect are located in the capital region. This finding implies that, as per a resident relocating to non- large city areas, the largest cities in the capital region tend to attract more migrants from other largest cities across the nation. The tendency of the largest cities in the capital region to have stronger attraction effect is similar to the case of displacement effect examined previously, even though the cities are not exactly identical for the two opposing migratory effect. In the meantime, Jeonju is the lowest in the generation of urban-to-rural migrant-initiated migration, with the amount of 1.7216. Jeonju is one of the five large cities that have lower levels of attraction. In addition to Jeonju, other four cities with weak attraction effect are

9The entries in the second column in Table 3 represent the attraction effect in original scale, while the numbers in the third column are the standardized z-scores for the original scale of attraction effect. For the standardized z-scores, the original values of attraction are scaled to the mean of 0.0 and the standard deviation of 1.0.

13

Busan, Cheongju, Daegu, and Gwangju. These cities constitute the bottom five in the order of attraction effect, all of which have the attraction index less than 2.0. Of these five cities with least attraction, three cities, i.e. Daegu (1.7579), Gwangju (1.7389), and Jeonju (1.7216), are very close in the strength of migratory attraction. Here, excluding Busan, the remaining four cities also represent the ones with the weakest displacement effect, which are readily identified in Table 2. In addition, Table 3 shows that, excluding the large cities with the top highest and bottom lowest levels of attraction, the rest of the largest cities in the middle strata of attraction intensity have the magnitudes of 2.0 to 2.4.

[Table 3 about here]

Incidentally, regarding the geographic locations of the largest cities with the weakest attraction, none of them are located within the capital region. This implies that the physical distances that the largest cities are away from the capital region affect the intensity of attraction effect. All told, the findings that the largest cities in the capital region have the relatively strong effect of attraction, whereas the cities with lower attraction effect are distant from the capital region, indicate that the locations of the largest cities with respect to the capital region would influence the intensity of attraction effect. The crucial role of the capital region is also claimed in the previous analysis of the displacement effect. Like the case of the displacement effect, the tendency that the largest cities located near to or inside the capital region have a stronger effect on attraction implies a certain labor-skill relationship between migrants and native inhabitants. As far as the largest cities within or near to the capital region are concerned, there exist similarities in labor or job skill between the migrants departing these cities and the native residents. Given this property of labor markets, the migrants who leave these cities for non-large city areas would induce high volumes of migration originating from other largest cities (Hatton and Tani 2005; Giulietti 2009; Docquier et al. 2014). The differences in the condition of labor markets between the cities suggest that, if urban- to-rural migration is left alone to thrive in the largest cities near to or within the capital region, it renders the cities remote from the capital region at higher risk of population drain. In this respect, some policies can be recommended to ameliorate the adverse effect afflicting the largest cities distant from the capital region. For example, various forms of welfare and wage subsidies, which are provided to the would-be outmigrants from the largest cities near to or within the capital region, would contribute to preventing the likelihood of population drain in

14

the largest cities distant from the capital region. On the other hand, just like the case of displacement effect examined earlier, the results of the analysis of attraction effect suggest no identifiable relationship between the city size and the attraction effect.10 That is, the there is no indication that a bigger city is more likely to have a stronger attraction effect. Then, other variables except for the city size may account for the difference in the attraction effect between the largest cities. Again, because this paper aims to assess the aggregate impacts of a unit migration, the issue of identifying the determinants of attraction effect is not addressed.

4.5. The Classification of Korean Largest Cities So far in this section, two forms of migration effect, namely, the displacement effect and the attraction effect, are estimated within the input-output framework. Given the intercity variances in the two types of migration effect, then, the 20 largest cities can be classified according to their intensities. By combining the z-scores for both types of migration effect, which are shown in Tables 2 and 3, respectively, the 20 largest cities can be distinguished into four different groups of cities. To construct the migration effect-dependent classification of cities, each pair of z-scores for the two types of migration effect is plotted on two axes: z-scores for the displacement effect are plotted on the horizontal axis, while z-scores for the attraction effect are plotted on the vertical axis. Figure 4 shows the resultant scattered plots, which represent the 20 sets of z- scores corresponding to the 20 pairs of migration effect for the 20 largest cities.

[Figure 4 about here]

By combining the relative strength of the displacement effect and that of the attraction effect, the scattergram in Figure 4 identifies four groups of large cities in Korea. First, the type 1 group of cities, which are plotted in the northeast quadrant of the graph, comprises the largest cities with a positive z-score in both types of effect. Put differently, the type 1 cities are those in which the values of both displacement and attraction effects are greater than their mean values. Of the 20 largest cities, eight cities, i.e. Seoul, Bucheon, Seongnam, Youngin, Goyang, Namyangju, Anyang, and , are included in the group of type 1 cities.

10The correlation coefficient between the city size and the attraction effect is -0.0458. With such tiny magnitude of correlation, a claim of the relationship between the two variables is not justified.

15

It is noticed that all the cities of type 1 are located within the capital region. Then, it is argued that the largest cities in the region are quite intense not only in pushing out more residents to other largest cities when the arrival of residents from non-large city areas to them occurs, but also in pulling population from other largest cities into them when the residents depart from them to non-large city areas. This means that the migration impact imposed on or originating from the largest cities in the capital region is highly probable to provoke reallocations of residence between the largest cities across Korea. Next, the type 2 group of cities in the northwest quadrant are formed with combination of the negative displacement effect and the positive attraction effect. The cities in this quadrant are relatively extensive in the displacement effect, whereas weak in the attraction effect. The former effect is above its average value, while the latter effect falls short of its average. Figure 4 shows that, of the 20 largest cities, only two cities, i.e. Incheon and , are included in this category. Third, the southwest quadrant in Figure 4 represents the type 3 group of cities, which are shown to be weak in the intensities of both types of migration effect. The cities included in this category fall below the average values in the strength of both migration effects. Then, it can be argued that the cities in this quadrant are in the opposite direction to the type 1 group of cities in the northeast quadrant, which are relatively strong in both displacement and attraction effects. In contrast to the cities of type 1, therefore, the cities of this category are least in pushing out residents to other largest cities when residents arrive from non-large city areas, and also in pulling population from other largest cities when their residents move migrate to non-large city areas. Then, it is argued that, when the migration impact takes place, these cities might cause a weak level of reallocations of residence between the largest cities across Korea. Of the 20 largest cities, eight cities are classified as the group of type 3 cities. They include four metropolitan cities, i.e. Daejeon, Ulsan, Daegu, and Gwangju, and four non-metropolitan large cities, i.e. , Cheongju, Cheonan, and Jeonju. Finally, the southeast quadrant presents the group of type 4 cities, which is established by the combination of a higher displacement effect and a lower attraction effect. As combined with these two odd values of effect, the cities in this category are placed diagonal to type 2 cities. In contrast to type 2 cities, therefore, the cities in this group are represented by a positive z-score of attraction effect and a negative score of displacement effect. This means that the cities in the southeast quadrant are relatively strong in the attraction effect, whereas weak in the displacement effect. Like the case of the group of type 2 cities, two cities, one of

16

which is metropolitan city (Busan) and the other is non-metropolitan large city (), are included in this group. So far, the four different types of cities into which the 20 largest cities are classified are explained. A glance at the four-quadrant diagram in Figure 4 suggests that the two types of migration effect are correlated. That is, the plots of the 20 largest cities indicate that the effect of migratory attraction varies with the intensity of displacement effect. The strength of association between the two opposing effects can be measured by a correlation coefficient, which represents whether the two types of migration effect tend to move in the same or opposite directions when they change. In this case, the magnitude of correlation coefficient is 0.7886, reflecting a substantial level of positive relationship between the two effects. Then, it is apparent that, as far as the 20 largest cities in Korea are concerned, the more intense their attraction effect, the stronger the level of displacement effect, and vice versa.

5. Conclusions

This paper aims to extend the input-output model framework for the assessment of migratory effects. Within the Ghoshian and Leontief input-output schemes, two contrasting versions of migratory impact-assessment model are constructed: one is for estimating the inmigration- initiated displacement effect and the other for calculating the outmigration-triggered attraction effect. For a given large city, the former effect represents the number of residents displaced from that largest city, which is invoked by an arrival of inmigrant from non-large city areas to that large city, while the latter effect means the chain effect of migrant attraction that a migrant outflowing from the large city in question to non-large city areas brings about. The two input-output schemes are applied to a set of 2012 data that contains interregional migration in Kore. The results of empirical application show that an arrival of migrant to and a departure of resident from the 20 largest cities generate the substantial ripples of direct and indirect interurban migration between them. However, the intensities of migration effect, whether the displacement or attraction effect, are various between the largest cities. The physical distances that the cities are away from the capital region impinge on the intercity variations in the strengths of migration effect. The results of the estimation of migration effect reveal that the largest cities near to or within the capital region are more likely to have the stronger displacement and attraction effects. This finding suggests a plausible policy recommendation that would contribute to curtailing consistent population drain in the largest cities located remote from the capital

17

region. Policies of adjusting the wages of inmigrants moving to these peripheral cities and/or providing welfare and wage subsidies to outmigrants from the largest cities near to or within the capital region would slow down the decline of population in the largest cities in the peripheral regions, most of which experience significant economic decline and consequently a diminished quality of their residents' lives. On the other hand, combining the displacement and attraction effects produces a classification of cities, in which the 20 largest cities can be distinguished into four different groups of cities. The classification reveals the existence of a substantial level of positive relationship between the displacement and attraction effects, which implies that a large city with higher attraction is more likely to have a higher level of displacement effect, or vice versa.

18

References

Baldwin, R.E. (2001). Core-periphery model with forward-looking expectations. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 31: 21-49. Blomquist, G.C., Berger, M.C., and Hoehn, J.P. (1988). New estimates of quality of life in urban areas. The American Economic Review, 78: 89-107. Bonasia M. and Napolitano, O. (2012). Determinants of interregional migration flows: the role of environmental factors in the Italian case. The Manchester School, 80: 525-44. Buch, T., Hamann, S., Niebuhr, A., and Rossen, A. (2014). What makes cities attractive? The determinants of urban labor migration in Germany. Urban Studies, 51: 1960–1978. Cabrer, B. and Pavia, J.M. (2003). Flujos demograficos regionals: an analisis input-output, Estadistica Espanola, 45: 407-429. Camacho, C. (2013). Migration modelling in the new economic geography. Mathematical Social Sciences, 66: 233-244. Charney, A.H. (1993). Migration and the public sector: a survey. Regional Studies, 27: 313- 26. Cho, C.-J. (2013). An exploration of reliable methods of estimating emergy requirements at the regional scale: traditional emergy analysis, regional thermodynamic input-output analysis, or the conservation rule-implicit method. Ecological Modelling, 251: 288-96. Cushing, B. and Poot, J. (2003). Crossing boundaries and borders: regional science advances in migration modelling. Papers in Regional Science, 83: 317-338. Day, K.M. (1992). Interprovincial migration and local public goods. Canadian Journal of Economics, 25: 123-44. Dietzenbacher, E. (1997). In vindication of the Ghosh model: a reinterpretation as a price model. Journal of Regional Science, 37: 629-651. Docquier, F., Ozden, C., and Peri, G. (2014). The labor market effects of immigration and emigration in OECD countries. The Economic Journal, 124: 1106-1145. Etzo, I. (2011). The determinants of the recent interregional migration flows in Italy: a panel data analysis. Journal of Regional Science, 51: 948-966. Fernandez-Vazquez, E., Garcia-Muuiz, A.S., and Ramos-Carvajal, C. (2011). The impact of immigration on interregional migrations: an input-output analysis with an application for Spain. Annals of Regional Science, 46: 189-204. Fujita, M., Krugman, P., and Venables, A.J. (2000). The Spatial Economy: Cities, Regions, and International Trade. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Giulietti, C. (2009). Immigration and displacement across local labor markets. ESRC Centre for Population Change Working Paper Series 2. Greenwood, M.J. (1985). Human migration: theory, models, and empirical studies. Journal of Regional Science, 25: 521-44. Greenwood, M.J. (1997). Internal migration in developed countries. In M.R. Rosenzweig and O. Stark (eds). Handbook of Population and Family Economics 1B. Elsevier, Amsterdam.

19

Greenwood, M.J. and Hunt, G.L. (2003). The early history of migration research. International Regional Science Review, 26: 3-37. Greenwood, M.J., Hunt, G.L., Rickman, D.S., and Treyz, G.I. (1991). Migration, regional equilibrium, and the estimation of compensating differentials. The American Economic Review, 81: 1382-90. Gruver, G.W. (1989). On the plausibility of the supply-driven input-output model: a theoretical basis for input-coefficient change. Journal of Regional Science, 29: 441-450. Gyourko, J. and Tracy, J. (1991). The structure of local public finance and the quality of life. The Journal of Political Economy, 99: 774-806. Harris, J.R. and Todaro, M.P. (1970). Migration, unemployment and development: a two- sector analysis. The American Economic Review, 60: 126-42. Hatton, T.J. and Tani, M. (2005). Immigration and inter-regional mobility in the UK 1982- 2000. The Economic Journal, 115: 342-358. Jang, Y-H. (2015). The policy implications and characteristics of regional disparities and urban area gaps: the case of 31 counties in . The Korean Local Administration Review, 29: 99~125 (in Korean). Karlsson, V. (2015). Interregional migration and transportation improvements in Iceland. International Regional Science Review, 38: 292-315. Kerschner, C. and Hubacek, K. (2009). Assessing the sustainability of input-output analysis for enhancing our understanding of potential economic effects of peak oil. Energy, 34: 284- 90. Kondo, K. and Okubo, T. (2015). Interregional labor migration and real wage disparities: evidence from Japan. Papers in Regional Science, 94: 67-87. Knapp, T.A. and Graves, E. (1987). On the roles of amenities in models of migration and regional development. Journal of Regional Science, 29: 71-87. Krugman, P. (1991). Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of Political Economy, 99: 483-99. Krugman, P. and Venables, A.J. (1995). Globalization and the inequality of nations. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110: 857-80. Krugman, P. (1995). Development, Geography and Economic Theory. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Krupka, D.J. (2004). Location-specific human capital, migration and amenities. School of Policy Studies Working Paper 04-06. Georgia State University. Leontief, W. (1936). Quantitative input-output relations in the economic system of the United States. Review of Economics and Statistics, 18: 105-125. Leontief, W. (1986). Input-Output Economics [2nd ed]. Oxford University Press, New York. Lim, J. (2011). Does wage differential driven migration continue to exist? Test on the role of regional economic structure in wage differential driven migration. Annals of Regional Science, 47: 217-33. Mitchneck, B.A. (1990). Geographical and Economic Determinants of Interregional Migration in the USSR, 1965-1986. The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC.

20

Miller, R.E. and Blair, P.D. (2009). Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions [2nd ed]. Cambridge University Press, New York. Molho, I. (2013). Theories of migration: a review. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 60: 526-56. OECD. (2005). How persistent are regional disparities in employment? The role of geographic mobility. In OECD (eds.) OECD Employment Outlook 2005, OECD, Paris. Oosterhaven, J. (1988). On the plausibility of the supply-driven input-output model. Journal of Regional Science, 28: 203-217. Ottaviano, G., Tabuchi, T., and Thisse, J.F. (2002). Agglomeration and trade revisited. International Economic Review, 43: 409-435. Pfluger, M. (2004). A simple, analytically solvable, Chamberlinian agglomeration model. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 34: 565-73. Plane, D.A. (1981). The geography of urban commuting field: some empirical evidence from New England. Professional Geographer, 33: 182-88. Plane, D.A. (1984). Migration space: doubly constrained gravity model mapping of relative interstate separation. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 74: 244-56. Plane, D.A. and Rogerson, P.A. (1994). The Geographical Analysis of Population: With Applications to Planning and Business. John Wiley & Sons, New York. Plantinga, A.J., Detang-Dessendre, C., Hunt, G.L., and Piguet, V. (2013). Housing prices and inter-urban migration. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 43: 296-306. Rogerson, P.A. (1990). Migration analysis using data with time intervals of differing widths. Papers of the Regional Science Association, 68: 97-106. Sastry, M.L. (1992). Estimating the economic impacts of elderly migration: an input‐output analysis. Growth and Change, 23: 54-79. Stark, O., Ranjan, G.M., and Levhari, D. (1991). Equilibrium urban unemployment in developing countries: Is migration the culprit? Economics Letters, 37: 477-82. Stillwell, J.C.H. (1978). Interzonal migration: some historical tests of spatial interaction models. Environment and Planning A, 10: 1187-1200.

Su, B. and Ang, B.W. (2011). Input-output analysis of CO2 emissions embodied in trade: the feedback effects. Ecological Economics, 71: 42-53. Tiebout, C.M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. The Journal of Political Economy, 64: 416-24. Todaro, M.P. (1969). A model of labor migration and urban unemployment in less developed countries. The American Economic Review, 59: 138-48. Ukidwe, N.U. and Bakshi, B.R. (2007). Industrial and ecological cumulative exergy consumption of the United States via the 1997 input-out benchmark model. Energy, 32: 1560- 92. Venables, A.J. (1996). Equilibrium locations of vertically linked industries. International Economic Review, 37: 341-59. Vinuela, A. and Fernandez-Vazquez, E. (2012). From the periphery to the core: direct and

21

indirect effects of the migration of labor. Jahrbuch fur Regionalwissenshaft, 32: 1-18. Wackernagel, M. and Rees, W. (1996). Our Ecological Footprint: Reducing Human Impact on the Earth. New Society Publishers, Philadelphia, PA. Walker, R., Ellis, M., and Barf, M. (1992). Linked migration systems: immigration and internal labor flows in the United States. Economic Geography, 68: 234-48. Wall, H.J. (2001). Voting with your feet in the United Kingdom: using cross-migration rates to estimate relative living standards. Papers in Regional Science, 80: 1-23. Wright, R.A., Ellis, M., and Reibel, M. (1997). The linkage between immigration and internal migration in large metropolitan areas in the United States. Economic Geography, 73: 234-254.

22

Appendices

Appendix A: Derivation of Eq. (2)

Suppose the economic space that is composed of a set of 푁 large cities and non-large city areas. For the system of 푁 large cities and non-large city areas, the following vectors and matrix can be defined: A 푁ⅹ1 column vector 퐱 to represent the inflow or outflow totals of population for the individual large cities; a 푁ⅹ1 column vector 퐧 of inflow totals into the individual large cities originating from other large cities; a 푁ⅹ1 column vector 퐬 of inflow totals into the individual large cities originating from non-large city areas; and a 푁ⅹ푁 matrix 퐌 of interurban migrations between the 푁 large cities. To specify the migration input-output scheme in the above-defined economic space, some notations for a specific large city 푖 are defined as follows: oi the total number of outmigration from large city 푖 to other large cities; 푛푖 the inflow total to large city 푖 migrating from other large cities; 푟푖 the number of residents relocating from large city 푖 to non-large city areas; 푠푖 the number of inmigrants into large city 푖 from non-large city areas; and 푛푚푖 the balancing factor for large city 푖 that ensures the inflow total and the outflow total of large city 푖 to be identical.

In fact, the balancing factor 푛푚푖 means the net flow of migrants for large city 푖. Using the balancing factor 푛푚푖, we can establish a simple equation that accounts for the outflow 표푢푡 total of population from large city 푖, 푥푖 , which can be written as:

표푢푡 (A1) 푥푖 = 표푖 + 푟푖 + 푛푚푖

푖푛 On the other hand, the inflow total of population into large city 푖, 푥푖 is expressed as the following equation:

푖푛 (A2) 푥푖 = 푛푖 + 푠푖

For the large city 푖 in question, then, the outflow total from and the inflow total into that city, respectively, should be equivalent. Therefore, the demographic identity for large city 푖 can be written as follows:

(A3) 표푖 + 푟푖 + 푛푚푖 = 푛푖 + 푠푖

23

Eq. (A3) represents the equivalence of the outflow from and the inflow into large city 푖. Then, from Eq. (A3), the balancing factor 푛푚푖 is derived as:

(A4) 푛푚푖 = [푛푖 + 푠푖] − [표푖 + 푟푖]

As mentioned earlier, the balancing factor in Eq. (A4) is set to ensure that the raw sum of the migration input-output table is equal to the inflow total for the relevant large city 푖. To construct the measure of displacement effect, define the following vectors and matrix for the system of 푁 large cities and non-large city areas:

푥1 푛1 푠1 푚11 ⋯ 푚1푁 (A5) 퐱 = [ ⋮ ] 퐧 = [ ⋮ ] 퐬 = [ ⋮ ] and 퐌 = [ ⋮ ⋱ ⋮ ] 푥푁 푛푁 푠푁 푚푁1 ⋯ 푚푁푁 where x represent the vector of inflow or outflow totals of population for individual large cities; n the vector of inflow totals into individual large cities migrating from other large cities; and s the vector of inflow totals into individual large cities from non-large city areas.

In addition, M represents the matrix of interurban migrations whose element mij denotes the number of population migrating from large city i to large city j . With these vectors and matrix, the vector that shows the inflows arriving to each of N large cities can be expressed as:

′ (A6) 퐱 = [푥1 … 푥푁] = 퐧′ + 퐬′ = 퐢′퐌 + 퐬′ where 퐢 is the 푁 × 1 summation column vector whose elements are 1’s. When 퐱̂ denotes the 푁 × 푁 diagonal matrix with the elements of the vector 퐱 along the main diagonal, the 푁 × 푁 matrix of direct-displacement coefficients, 퐁, can be represented as:

(A7) 퐁 = (퐱̂)−1퐌

Using the direct-displacement matrix in Eq. (A7), the inflows of population arriving into the 푁 large cities shown in Eq. (A6) can be rewritten as:

(A8) 퐱′ = 퐢′퐌 + 퐬′

24

= 퐢′퐱̂퐁 + 퐬′ = 퐱′퐁 + 퐬′ since 퐢′퐱̂ = 퐱′. Let 퐈 be the 푁 × 푁 identity matrix, then the inflow total in Eq. (A8) can be expressed just as:

(A9) 퐱′ = 퐬′(퐈 − 퐁)−ퟏ which is equal to Eq. (2) in Section 3.

Appendix B: Derivation of Eq. (6)

In addition to the vectors and matrices used for constructing the measure of displacement effect in Appendix A, we can define the following three column vectors:

표1 푟1 푛푚1 (B1) 퐨 = [ ⋮ ] 퐫 = [ ⋮ ] and 퐧퐦 = [ ⋮ ] 표푁 푟푁 푛푚푁 where 퐨 represents the vector of outflow totals for individual large cities moving to other large cities; 퐫 the vector of outflow totals for the 푁 individual large cities moving toward non-large city areas; and 퐧퐦 the vector of balancing factors that ensure the balance equation in Eq. (A3) to hold for the 푁 individual large cities. With these definitions, the matrix form of Eq. (A1), in which the elements of the 푁 × 1 column vector 퐱 show the outflows originating from the 푁 large cities, is expressed as:

(B2) 퐱 = 퐨 + 퐫 + 퐧퐦 = 퐌퐢 + 퐫 + 퐧퐦

As before, let 퐱̂ denotes the 푁 × 푁 diagonal matrix with the elements of the vector 퐱 along the main diagonal. Then, the 푁 × 푁 matrix of direct-attraction coefficients, 퐀, can be calculated by the following equation:

(B3) 퐀 = 퐌(퐱̂)−1

Substituting Eq. (B3) into Eq. (B2) yields the following equation that shows the number of

25

people outflowing from the 푁 large cities:

(B4) 퐱 = 퐀퐱̂퐢 + [퐫 + 퐧퐦] = 퐀퐱 + [퐫 + 퐧퐦] since 퐱̂퐢 = 퐱. Then, solving Eq. (B4) in terms of 퐱 gives the flowing expression as shown in Eq. (B5):

(B5) 퐱 = (퐈 − 퐀)−1[퐫 + 퐧퐦] which is correspond to Eq. (6) in Section 3.

26

Table 1. Matrix of interregional migration among the largest cities and non-large city areas

Seoul Busan Daegu Incheon Gwangju Daejeon Ulsan Suwon Seongnam Anyang Bucheon Seoul 0 12,766 7,938 32,504 8,071 10,375 4,564 13,008 21,087 9,408 15,104 Busan 17,965 0 3,939 2,391 1,072 1,755 8,815 1,706 1,207 539 696 Daegu 11,495 3,897 0 1,490 512 1,476 3,017 1,454 854 417 432 Incheon 23,732 1,985 1,253 0 1,416 2,042 839 2,544 1,697 1,228 8,771 Gwangju 9,824 1,069 464 1,639 0 1,107 467 1,145 768 384 541 Daejeon 11,460 1,430 1,188 2,073 838 0 669 1,357 910 458 584 Ulsan 5,624 7,052 2,276 795 296 642 0 591 356 165 174 Suwon 10,326 1,147 904 2,319 927 1,246 497 0 1,517 1,342 729 Seongnam 16,286 942 678 1,949 696 912 296 2,246 0 774 598 Anyang 7,918 427 327 1,676 412 562 162 2,023 820 0 560 Bucheon 12,305 555 391 11,437 523 652 253 985 654 491 0 Ansan 6,622 609 459 2,790 563 687 258 2,296 637 1,314 778 Goyang 17,825 894 532 2,975 557 761 279 987 936 426 909 Namyangju 12,875 415 268 1,195 308 377 168 554 680 269 327 Youngin 12,593 1,037 820 1,991 759 911 451 6,626 5,541 772 609 Cheongju 4,134 403 436 801 251 2,160 219 683 378 208 234 Cheonan 4,741 595 439 1,170 350 1,849 270 948 481 301 386 Jeonju 4,913 304 223 795 1,129 1,017 176 624 404 201 258 Pohang 3,003 1,733 2,412 744 99 418 970 362 222 111 152 Changwon 5,258 7,333 1,542 866 327 588 1,395 582 343 152 231 nm jij i  198,899 44,953 26,489 71,600 19,106 29,537 23,765 40,721 39,492 18,960 32,703 Non-large city areas 166,625 51,795 49,316 44,793 38,208 32,127 24,581 29,354 16,794 13,376 12,737 Inflow Total 365,524 96,388 75,805 166,393 57,314 61,644 48,346 70,075 56,286 32,336 44,810 (continued) 27

Table 1 (continued) Outflow omiij  Ansan Goyang Namyangju Youngin Cheongju Cheonan Jeonju Pohang Changwon   j  nmi total Seoul 7,121 23,943 18,744 16,778 3,673 5,106 3,995 2,253 3,750 220,188 145,336 365,524 Busan 737 1,123 446 1,325 460 963 339 1,751 8,322 55,551 40,837 96,388 Daegu 506 754 289 1,028 558 790 194 2,632 1,728 33,523 42,282 75,805 Incheon 2,213 2,638 959 1,854 788 1,449 658 758 734 57,558 58,835 116,393 Gwangju 633 620 297 857 269 538 1,047 134 317 22,120 35,194 57,314 Daejeon 593 711 338 1,074 2,056 2,037 843 335 509 29,463 32,201 61,664 Ulsan 261 277 171 493 202 326 135 941 1,225 22,002 26,344 48,346 Suwon 1,625 811 428 5,045 567 941 434 268 405 31,478 38,597 70,075 Seongnam 648 944 790 7,947 348 535 361 157 248 37,355 18,931 56,286 Anyang 1,575 524 294 975 212 347 222 94 127 19,257 13,079 32,336 Bucheon 813 1,144 393 695 281 485 265 138 184 32,644 12,166 44,810 Ansan 0 546 302 809 273 519 286 142 200 20,090 16,751 36,841 Goyang 522 0 641 1,073 250 338 298 162 248 30,613 24,083 54,696 Namyangju 331 658 0 693 148 214 156 109 148 19,893 19,050 38,943 Youngin 701 946 656 0 424 560 381 239 334 36,351 24,233 60,584 Cheongju 271 284 111 491 0 835 162 126 164 12,351 16,256 28,607 Cheonan 359 279 166 590 723 0 225 111 190 14,173 21,212 35,385 Jeonju 298 304 127 410 192 339 0 66 141 11,921 19,051 30,972 Pohang 141 173 103 297 172 197 51 0 423 11,783 7,929 19,712 Changwon 215 283 126 422 180 250 135 470 0 20,698 19,224 39,992 nm 19,563 36,962 25,381 42,856 11,776 16,769 10,187 10,886 19,397 j i ij  Non-large city areas 17,278 17,734 13,562 17,728 16,831 18,616 20,785 8,826 20,525 Inflow total 36,841 54,696 38,943 60,584 28,607 35,385 30,972 19,712 39,992

28

Table 2. Displacement effects and z-scores Table 3. Attraction effects and z-scores Displacement Standardized Attraction Standardized effect z-score effect z-score Seoul 2.3323 0.8160 Seoul 2.2260 0.1585 Busan 2.2566 0.4588 Busan 1.9836 -0.6692 Daegu 1.9832 -0.8315 Daegu 1.7579 -1.4399 Incheon 2.1345 -0.1175 Incheon 2.4007 0.7550 Gwangju 1.8619 -1.4040 Gwangju 1.7389 -1.5047 Daejeon 2.0486 -0.5229 Daejeon 2.0374 -0.4855 Ulsan 2.0095 -0.7074 Ulsan 2.0156 -0.5599 Suwon 2.0111 -0.6998 Suwon 2.3197 0.4785 Seongnam 2.4995 1.6051 Seongnam 2.5885 1.3963 Anyang 2.3309 0.8094 Anyang 2.3162 0.4665 Bucheon 2.6124 2.1379 Bucheon 2.6221 1.5110 Ansan 2.2091 0.2346 Ansan 2.1950 0.0527 Goyang 2.2702 0.5229 Goyang 2.5114 1.1330 Namyangju 2.1663 0.0326 Namyangju 2.4623 0.9654 Youngin 2.3420 0.8618 Youngin 2.6136 1.4820 Cheongju 1.9445 -1.0141 Cheongju 1.8984 -0.9601 Cheonan 1.8823 -1.3077 Cheonan 2.0344 -0.4957 Jeonju 1.8485 -1.4672 Jeonju 1.7216 -1.5638 Pohang 2.2960 0.6447 Pohang 2.1409 -0.1321 Changwon 2.1484 -0.0519 Changwon 2.0074 -0.5879 Total 43.1878 0.0000 Total 43.5916 0.0000

Average 2.1594 0.0000 Average 2.1796 0.0000 Standard 0.2119 1.0000 Standard 0.2929 1.0000 deviation deviation

29

Figure 1. Locations of the 20 largest cities in Korea

Note: Numbers in parenthesis are population sizes of the cities. 30

Figure 2. Urbanization Rates

31

Figure 3. Net Migration Rates for 20 Largest Cities

32

Figure 4. Scattergram of displacement and attraction effects

33

Please note:

You are most sincerely encouraged to participate in the open assessment of this discussion paper. You can do so by either recommending the paper or by posting your comments.

Please go to: http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2017-49

The Editor

© Author(s) 2017. Licensed under the Creative Commons License - Attribution 4.0 International (CC BY 4.0).