Revisiting the Status Quo Bias: Replication of Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Revisiting the Status Quo Bias: Replication of Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) Meta-Psychology, 2021, vol 5, MP.2020.2470, Open data: Yes Edited by: Rickard Carlsson https://doi.org/10.15626/MP.2020.2470 Open materials: Yes Reviewed by: Emil Persson & Nils Kobis Article type: Replication report Open and reproducible analysis: Yes Analysis reproduced by: André Kalmendal Published under the CC-BY4.0 license Open reviews and editorial process: Yes All supplementary files can be accessed at the OSF project Preregistration: Yes page: https://doi.org/10.17605/OSF.IO/WUPF4 Revisiting the status quo bias: Replication of Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) Qinyu Xiao Choi Shan Lam University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong Chinese University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong Muhrajan Piara Gilad Feldman Maastricht University, Netherlands University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong Status quo bias refers to people’s general preference to stick to, or continue with, a pre- viously chosen option. In two pre-registered experiments with U.S. participants re- cruited from the Amazon Mechanical Turk (n1 = 311, n2 = 316), we attempted to replicate four decision scenarios (Question 1, 2, 4, and 6) from Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988), the seminal article that provided the first experimental demonstration of the status quo bias. We found strong empirical support for the status quo bias in three decision scenar- ios out of the four, including budget allocation (Scenario 1/Question 1 in the original ar- ticle), investment portfolios (Scenario 3/Question 2), and college jobs (Scenario 4/Ques- tion 4). However, we failed to find substantial support for the status quo bias in the wagon color choice scenario (Scenario 2/Question 6). We discuss the implications of our results and possible explanations using multiple accounts put forward in the status quo bias lit- erature. Keywords: status quo bias, judgment and decision making, replication People tend to favor things as they are. The sta- replications of the original study, as they differed tus quo bias refers to people’s general tendency to only in terms of physical settings and contextual stick with a previously chosen option in the face of variables (i.e., those that are beyond researchers’ other alternatives. In a seminal paper, Samuelson control; please refer to Figure 2S and Table 12S in the and Zeckhauser (1988) surveyed participants with supplementary for details regarding the criteria and hypothetical decision questions. They found that the classification). Our goal was to revisit these clas- framing an option as the status quo resulted in a sic findings, to examine whether they withstand the higher choice rate of that option, compared with test of time, and to accumulate further evidence to framing it neutrally or as an alternative to the status try and establish more precise effect size estimates quo (or non-status quo). Further supplementing the (Nosek & Lakens, 2014). We begin by introducing the experimental results with field evidence, they literature on the status quo bias and the chosen ar- demonstrated that the status quo bias is pervasive ticle for replication, i.e., Samuelson and Zeckhauser and profound in people’s decision-making. (1988). We then highlight the motivation for the cur- In this article, we report two attempts to repli- rent replication study, present the results, and dis- cate Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988). Based on cuss their implications. LeBel et al.’s (2018) criteria for evaluating replica- tions, we classified our experiments to be very close XIAO, LAM, PIARA, & FELDMAN 2 Status quo bias models, which states that only preference-relevant features matter in choosing among alternatives Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) were the first (Samuelson & Zeckhauser, 1988). Economists once to demonstrate the status quo bias using controlled assumed that decision makers have well-defined experiments. In part of their investigation, they pre- and relatively stable preferences and make decisions sented a series of hypothetical decision-making accordingly (Kahneman et al., 1991). These prefer- scenarios and asked participants to choose among ences are determined by the overall value of options several available options. The scenarios and options for a decision maker (i.e., utility) after the decision came in two versions: in the neutral version, all op- maker evaluated those features of their concern. tions were presented equally as they were, without Once their preferences are set, the decision maker any framing, whereas in the status quo version (SQ), will go for the option with the highest expected util- one option was framed as the status quo and the ity, ignoring those preference-irrelevant variables. other options were reframed either as a change or For instance, the order in which the options are pre- in reference to the status quo option. The options sented or the labels they carry (e.g., a label of being were effectively the same in both versions. the status quo) should not influence the decision. Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) found that op- Conversely, if we know a decision maker’s choice tions were chosen more often when framed as the among several options, we can confidently infer that status quo, compared with when they were framed the chosen option has the highest expected utility as an alternative to the status quo or without any for, and hence preferred the most by, that person. framing. The status quo framing consistently led to We can infallibly predict that the same option will be the highest rate of choice, followed by the neutral chosen regardless of, e.g., how the available options framing and then by the non-status quo framing. are presented, if there is no alternative with a higher Additionally, they showed that preference for status expected utility. quo options became more pronounced as the num- This assumption no longer holds in the case of ber of options increased (see also Tversky & Shafir, the status quo bias. Samuelson and Zeckhauser 1992; Redelmeier & Shafir, 1995). (1988) showed that a status quo can drastically influ- People may sometimes be willing to continue ence decision makers’ choices. An option chosen with the status quo despite its lower utility com- when framed as the status quo may no longer be as pared to available alternatives (e.g., Suri et al., 2013). preferred when framed as a non-status quo, despite For instance, Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988, p. 10) that available options all remained the same. The described a case where a small town in Germany implications of their results are profound, if we con- was to be relocated due to a mining project. The au- sider how often in real life we make decisions where thority offered the townspeople several planning there is a status quo. Arguably, continuing with the options for the new town, which would be estab- current choice or situation is almost always an op- lished at the authority’s expense. Surprisingly, the tion. townspeople opted for a plan quite much like that of Indeed, empirical evidence so far suggests that the old town. The intricate layout of the old town the status quo bias has a great influence in real life that had evolved through centuries was unlikely to judgment and decision-making. Unlike the experi- be efficient in modern times. Nonetheless, people ments by Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988, Part chose it, arguably because of their preference for One), where options became the status quo because the status quo. Apparently, the status quo bias vio- they were so framed, studies on the status quo bias lates one of the foremost assumptions in rational in real life involved actual past choices. For instance, decision-making theory that people aim to maxim- Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) went to the field ize expected utility and minimize loss (Tversky & to examine the choice of health insurance plans by Kahneman, 1991). Should this assumption have held, Harvard employees and the allocation of retirement the townspeople would have been happy to see their contributions to different funds by faculty through- new town be built using modern knowledge of city out the U.S. Again, evidence pointed to a prominent planning but not as a legacy of centuries’ history. status quo bias: Harvard employees tended to stick The status quo bias challenges yet another, more with the insurance plan they initially chose, despite specific assumption in rational decision-making the presence of a more attractive option. Teachers REVISITING THE STATUS QUO BIAS 3 across the States tended to maintain one allocation like a series of revolutions rather than an incremen- ratio towards different retirement funds, though a tal accumulation of small advances (Kuhn, 2012). change was easy and bore almost no cost. Similarly, New policies are hard to establish, and old ones are Hartman et al. (1991) surveyed around 1,500 con- hard to abolish. A well-received scientific paradigm sumers in the U.S. on the reliability and rate of their could dominate researchers’ attention and re- electricity service. The researchers found that sources for years and even decades. In sum, our ev- around 60 percent households, regardless of the ac- idence and theoretical conjectures imply that the tual reliability of the services they received, indi- status quo bias is pervasive in economic, scientific, cated that they preferred the status quo the most (p. social, and cultural decision-making situations. 149). Johnson and colleagues (1993) looked into the automobile insurance industry in New Jersey and Explaining the status quo bias Pennsylvania, where different status quos were pre- sent. They found that when given an option to lower Numerous accounts have been put forward to insurance rates by reducing the right to sue, 75% of explain the status quo bias. They fall roughly into Pennsylvanians chose to retain their full right; in two categories. Some attempted to accommodate contrast, when given an option to obtain the full the bias into a rational decision-making framework, right to sue by paying higher rates, only 20% of arguing that the seemingly irrational preference for those in New Jersey chose that option (p.
Recommended publications
  • The Status Quo Bias and Decisions to Withdraw Life-Sustaining Treatment
    HUMANITIES | MEDICINE AND SOCIETY The status quo bias and decisions to withdraw life-sustaining treatment n Cite as: CMAJ 2018 March 5;190:E265-7. doi: 10.1503/cmaj.171005 t’s not uncommon for physicians and impasse. One factor that hasn’t been host of psychological phenomena that surrogate decision-makers to disagree studied yet is the role that cognitive cause people to make irrational deci- about life-sustaining treatment for biases might play in surrogate decision- sions, referred to as “cognitive biases.” Iincapacitated patients. Several studies making regarding withdrawal of life- One cognitive bias that is particularly show physicians perceive that nonbenefi- sustaining treatment. Understanding the worth exploring in the context of surrogate cial treatment is provided quite frequently role that these biases might play may decisions regarding life-sustaining treat- in their intensive care units. Palda and col- help improve communication between ment is the status quo bias. This bias, a leagues,1 for example, found that 87% of clinicians and surrogates when these con- decision-maker’s preference for the cur- physicians believed that futile treatment flicts arise. rent state of affairs,3 has been shown to had been provided in their ICU within the influence decision-making in a wide array previous year. (The authors in this study Status quo bias of contexts. For example, it has been cited equated “futile” with “nonbeneficial,” The classic model of human decision- as a mechanism to explain patient inertia defined as a treatment “that offers no rea- making is the rational choice or “rational (why patients have difficulty changing sonable hope of recovery or improvement, actor” model, the view that human beings their behaviour to improve their health), or because the patient is permanently will choose the option that has the best low organ-donation rates, low retirement- unable to experience any benefit.”) chance of satisfying their preferences.
    [Show full text]
  • Ambiguity Seeking As a Result of the Status Quo Bias
    Ambiguity Seeking as a Result of the Status Quo Bias Mercè Roca 1, Robin M. Hogarth 2, A. John Maule 3 1ESRC Postgraduate Researcher, Centre for Decision Research, Leeds University Business School, The University of Leeds, Leeds, LS2 9JT, United Kingdom 2ICREA Research Professor, Departament d’Economia i Empresa, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Ramon Trias Fargas, 08005, Barcelona, Spain 3Professor, Centre for Decision Research, Leeds University Business School, The University of Leeds, Leeds, LS2 9JT, United Kingdom Contact details: Mercè Roca, [email protected] , Telephone: (0044)07709557423. Leeds University Business School, Maurice Keyworth Building. The University of Leeds, Leeds, LS2 9JT, United Kingdom * Funds for the experiments were provided by the Centre for Decision Research of Leeds University Business School. The authors are grateful for the comments received from Gaëlle Villejoubert, Albert Satorra and Peter Wakker. This paper was presented at SPUDM20 in Stockholm. 1 Abstract Several factors affect attitudes toward ambiguity. What happens, however, when people are asked to exchange an ambiguous alternative in their possession for an unambiguous one? We present three experiments in which individuals preferred to retain the former. This status quo bias emerged both within- and between-subjects, with and without incentives, with different outcome distributions, and with endowments determined by both the experimenter and the participants themselves. Findings emphasize the need to account for the frames of reference under which evaluations of probabilistic information take place as well as modifications that should be incorporated into descriptive models of decision making. Keywords Ambiguity, risk, status quo bias, decision making, uncertainty. JEL code: C91, D81. 2 The phenomenon of ambiguity aversion – or the preference for gambles with known as opposed to unknown probabilities – has been well documented in the literature on decision making in both psychology and economics (see, e.g., Ellsberg, 1961; Camerer & Weber, 1992; Keren & Gerritsen, 1999).
    [Show full text]
  • Cognitive Bias in Emissions Trading
    sustainability Article Cognitive Bias in Emissions Trading Jae-Do Song 1 and Young-Hwan Ahn 2,* 1 College of Business Administration, Chonnam National University, Gwangju 61186, Korea; [email protected] 2 Korea Energy Economics Institute, 405-11 Jongga-ro, Jung-gu, Ulsan 44543, Korea * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +82-52-714-2175; Fax: +82-52-714-2026 Received: 8 February 2019; Accepted: 27 February 2019; Published: 5 March 2019 Abstract: This study investigates whether cognitive biases such as the endowment effect and status quo bias occur in emissions trading. Such cognitive biases can serve as a barrier to trade. This study’s survey-based experiments, which include hypothetical emissions trading scenarios, show that the endowment effect does occur in emissions trading. The status quo bias occurs in only one of the three experiments. This study also investigates whether accumulation of experience can reduce cognitive bias as discovered preference hypothesis expects. The results indicate that practitioners who are supposed to have more experience show no evidence of having less cognitive bias. Contrary to the conventional expectation, the practitioners show significantly higher level of endowment effect than students and only the practitioners show a significant status quo bias. A consignment auction situation, which is used in California’s cap-and-trade program, is also tested; no significant difference between general permission trading and consignment auctions is found. Keywords: emissions trading; cognitive bias; consignment auction; climate policy 1. Introduction Emissions trading allows entities to achieve emission reduction targets in a cost-effective way through buying and selling emission allowances in emissions trading markets [1,2].
    [Show full text]
  • Cognitive Biases in Software Engineering: a Systematic Mapping Study
    Cognitive Biases in Software Engineering: A Systematic Mapping Study Rahul Mohanani, Iflaah Salman, Burak Turhan, Member, IEEE, Pilar Rodriguez and Paul Ralph Abstract—One source of software project challenges and failures is the systematic errors introduced by human cognitive biases. Although extensively explored in cognitive psychology, investigations concerning cognitive biases have only recently gained popularity in software engineering research. This paper therefore systematically maps, aggregates and synthesizes the literature on cognitive biases in software engineering to generate a comprehensive body of knowledge, understand state of the art research and provide guidelines for future research and practise. Focusing on bias antecedents, effects and mitigation techniques, we identified 65 articles (published between 1990 and 2016), which investigate 37 cognitive biases. Despite strong and increasing interest, the results reveal a scarcity of research on mitigation techniques and poor theoretical foundations in understanding and interpreting cognitive biases. Although bias-related research has generated many new insights in the software engineering community, specific bias mitigation techniques are still needed for software professionals to overcome the deleterious effects of cognitive biases on their work. Index Terms—Antecedents of cognitive bias. cognitive bias. debiasing, effects of cognitive bias. software engineering, systematic mapping. 1 INTRODUCTION OGNITIVE biases are systematic deviations from op- knowledge. No analogous review of SE research exists. The timal reasoning [1], [2]. In other words, they are re- purpose of this study is therefore as follows: curring errors in thinking, or patterns of bad judgment Purpose: to review, summarize and synthesize the current observable in different people and contexts. A well-known state of software engineering research involving cognitive example is confirmation bias—the tendency to pay more at- biases.
    [Show full text]
  • Dynamic Collective Choice with Endogenous Status Quo∗
    Dynamic Collective Choice With Endogenous Status Quo Wioletta Dziuday Antoine Loeperz August 2014 First version: December 2009 Abstract This paper analyzes an ongoing bargaining situation in which preferences evolve over time and the previous agreement becomes the next status quo, determining the payoffs until a new agreement is reached. We show that the endogeneity of the status quo induces perverse incen- tives that exacerbate the players’ conflict of interest: Players disagree more often than they would if the status quo was exogenous. This leads to ineffi ciencies and status quo inertia. When players are suffi ciently patient, the endogenous status quo can lead the negotiations to a com- plete gridlock in which players never reach an agreement even though their preferences agree arbitrarily often. When applied to the legislative setting, our model predicts partisan behavior, and explains why oftentimes legislators fail to react in a timely fashion to economic shocks. JEL Code: D72. Previously circulated under the title “Ongoing Negotiation with an Endogenous Status Quo.”We thank David Austen-Smith, David Baron, Daniel Diermeier, Bard Harstad, and seminar participants at Bonn University, Leuven University, CUNEF, Northwestern University, Nottingham University, Rice University, Simon Fraser University, Universidad de Alicante, Universidad Carlos III, Universidad Complutense, the University of Chicago, and the Paris Game Theory Seminar. Yuta Takahashi profided an excellent research assistance. yCorresponding author. Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, 2001 Sheridan Road, Evanston, 60208, IL. Email: [email protected] zUniversidad Carlos III de Madrid. Email: [email protected] 1 1 Introduction The legislative gridlock that paralyzed the 112th U.S. Congress and led to a fiscal cliff highlighted the inability of legislators to agree on much needed fiscal policy reforms, in particular concerning the various entitlement programs such as medicare and social security.
    [Show full text]
  • Thorsten Hippe Civics Beyond Social Science? a Review Essay on Ian
    Journal of Social Science Education Volume 15, Number 1, Spring 2016 DOI 10.4119/UNIBI/jsse-v15-i1-1502 Thorsten Hippe Civics Beyond Social Science? A Review Essay on Ian Mac Mullen, Civics Beyond Critics. Character Education in a Liberal Democracy. Oxford University Press 2015, 288 pp., £30.00. ISBN: 9780198733614 towards fundamental institutions of a nation`s polity, causing too quick support for radical change (Part III). Overall, he admits that his proposal(s) for (an) alternative(s) is well developed only with regard to alternative goals, but hardly so with regard to con- crete prescriptions of how exactly to achieve these. 1 Part I: Compliance with the law – an individual or a social phenomenon? According to the orthodox view, education should avoid habituating as well as teaching compliance with any law just based on a certain degree of general trust in the democratic legislator and / or the collective legal wisdom of democratic ancestors or today`s public. Instead, the merit of laws should be openly discussed and individually evaluated based on plain facts (reason) and basic universal values (morals). Mac Mullen criticizes that such a strategy puts not This book undertakes a fundamental critique of a only an unrealistic faith in the intellectual ability of theory of civic education which its author calls the children as well as young people to make qualified “orthodox view” of civic education. Ian Mac Mullen, judgments but also puts too much faith in the associate professor at Washington University in St. individual`s capacity of moral self-restraint (actually Louis, defines the “orthodox view” as a theory of civic acting according to one`s theoretical moral conclu- education which argues that normative civic character sion).
    [Show full text]
  • Fixing Biases: Principles of Cognitive De-Biasing
    Fixing biases: Principles of cognitive de-biasing Pat Croskerry MD, PhD Clinical Reasoning in Medical Education National Science Learning Centre, University of York Workshop, November 26, 2019 Case q A 65 year old female presents to the ED with a complaint of shoulder sprain. She said she was gardening this morning and injured her shoulder pushing her lawn mower. q At triage she has normal vital signs and in no distress. The triage nurse notes her complaint and triages her to the fast track area. q She is seen by an emergency physician who notes her complaint and examines her shoulder. He orders an X-ray. q The shoulder X ray shows narrowing of the joint and signs of osteoarthrtritis q He discharges her with a sling and Rx for Arthrotec q She is brought to the ED 4 hours later following an episode of syncope, sweating, and weakness. She is diagnosed with an inferior MI. Biases q A 65 year old female presents to the ED with a complaint of ‘shoulder sprain’. She said she was gardening this morning and sprained her shoulder pushing her lawn mower (Framing). q At triage she has normal vital signs and in no distress. The triage nurse notes her complaint and triages her to the fast track area (Triage cueing). q She is seen by an emergency physician who notes her complaint and examines her shoulder. He orders an X-ray (Ascertainment bias). q The shoulder X ray shows narrowing of the joint and signs of osteoarthrtritis. He explains to the patient the cause of her pain (Confirmation bias).
    [Show full text]
  • Croskerry MD, Phd, FRCP(Edin)
    Clinical Decision Making + Strategies for Cognitive Debiasing Pat Croskerry MD, PhD, FRCP(Edin) International Association of Endodontists Scottsdale, Arizona June 2019 Financial Disclosures or other Conflicts of Interest None It is estimated that an American adult makes 35,000 decisions a day i.e. about 2200 each waking hour Sollisch J: The cure for decision fatigue. Wall Street Journal, 2016 Decision making ‘The most important decision we need to make in Life is how we are going to make decisions’ Professor Gigerenzer Is there a problem with the way we think and make decisions? 3 domains of decision making Patients Healthcare leadership Healthcare providers Patients Leading Medical Causes of Death in the US and their Preventability in 2000 Cause Total Preventability (%) Heart disease 710,760 46 Malignant neoplasms 553,091 66 Cerebrovascular 167,661 43 Chronic respiratory 122,009 76 Accidents 97,900 44 Diabetes mellitus 69,301 33 Acute respiratory 65,313 23 Suicide 29,350 100 Chronic Liver disease 26,552 75 Hypertension/renal 12,228 68 Assault (homicide) 16,765 100 All other 391,904 14 Keeney (2008) Healthcare leadership Campbell et al, 2017 Healthcare providers US deaths in 2013 • 611,105 Heart disease • 584,881 Cancer • 251,454 Medical error Medical error is the 3rd leading cause of death Estimated number of preventable hospital deaths due to diagnostic failure annually in the US 40,000 – 80,000 Leape, Berwick and Bates JAMA 2002 Diagnostic failure is the biggest problem in patient safety Newman-Toker, 2017 Sources of Diagnostic Failure The System 25% The Individual 75% Graber M, Gordon R, Franklin N.
    [Show full text]
  • Influence of Cognitive Biases in Distorting Decision Making and Leading to Critical Unfavorable Incidents
    Safety 2015, 1, 44-58; doi:10.3390/safety1010044 OPEN ACCESS safety ISSN 2313-576X www.mdpi.com/journal/safety Article Influence of Cognitive Biases in Distorting Decision Making and Leading to Critical Unfavorable Incidents Atsuo Murata 1,*, Tomoko Nakamura 1 and Waldemar Karwowski 2 1 Department of Intelligent Mechanical Systems, Graduate School of Natural Science and Technology, Okayama University, Okayama, 700-8530, Japan; E-Mail: [email protected] 2 Department of Industrial Engineering & Management Systems, University of Central Florida, Orlando, 32816-2993, USA; E-Mail: [email protected] * Author to whom correspondence should be addressed; E-Mail: [email protected]; Tel.: +81-86-251-8055; Fax: +81-86-251-8055. Academic Editor: Raphael Grzebieta Received: 4 August 2015 / Accepted: 3 November 2015 / Published: 11 November 2015 Abstract: On the basis of the analyses of past cases, we demonstrate how cognitive biases are ubiquitous in the process of incidents, crashes, collisions or disasters, as well as how they distort decision making and lead to undesirable outcomes. Five case studies were considered: a fire outbreak during cooking using an induction heating (IH) cooker, the KLM Flight 4805 crash, the Challenger space shuttle disaster, the collision between the Japanese Aegis-equipped destroyer “Atago” and a fishing boat and the Three Mile Island nuclear power plant meltdown. We demonstrate that heuristic-based biases, such as confirmation bias, groupthink and social loafing, overconfidence-based biases, such as the illusion of plan and control, and optimistic bias; framing biases majorly contributed to distorted decision making and eventually became the main cause of the incident, crash, collision or disaster.
    [Show full text]
  • Status Quo Or Change? the Influence of Creativity and Openness to Experience on the Status
    Running head: PERSONALITY, INFORMATION SAMPLING, STATUS QUO BIAS 1 Status Quo or Change? The Influence of Creativity and Openness to Experience on the Status Quo Bias and Information Sampling Kyara Smit (551088) Tilburg University Supervised by A.K. Spälti. Department of social psychology, Tilburg School of Social and Behavioral Sciences Date PERSONALITY, INFORMATION SAMPLING, STATUS QUO BIAS 2 Abstract Limited research has been done on the influence of openness to experience and/or creativity in relation to information sampling and the status quo bias. Literature shows that the traits openness to experience and/or creativity might promote status quo rejecting behavior (Jost, Nosek, & Gosling, 2008; McCrae, 1987). Therefore, it was hypothesized that highly open and/or creative people would prefer the alternative policy over the status quo policy and show information sampling behavior focused on the alternative policy. The research consisted of 60 participants who were presented with a survey containing a decision board, a choice between an alternative and status quo, questions concerning the levels of openness and creativity of the participant, and questions testing the decision-making of the participant. The results show that individuals scoring high on creativity read information of the alternative policy longer compared to those scoring low on creativity. The opposite effect was discovered for openness to experience. Furthermore, no effect was identified concerning openness to experience and/or creativity and the participant's interestedness in alternative policy. Lastly, both creativity and openness to experience individually fail to have an effect on policy preference. However, the participants with a high score on both openness to experience and creativity would likely prefer the alternative, while those with low creativity would likely prefer the status quo.
    [Show full text]
  • Retention and Transfer of Cognitive Bias Mitigation Interventions: a Systematic Literature Study
    Retention and Transfer of Cognitive Bias Mitigation Interventions: A Systematic Literature Study J.E. (Hans) Korteling1, Jasmin Y.J. Gerritsma1, and Alexander Toet*1 1 TNO Human Factors, Soesterberg, Netherlands * Correspondence: Alexander Toet E: [email protected] Word count: 6428 1 2 Abstract 3 Cognitive biases can adversely affect human judgement and decision making and should therefore 4 preferably be mitigated, so that we can achieve our goals as effectively as possible. Hence, numerous bias 5 mitigation interventions have been developed and evaluated. However, to be effective in practical 6 situations beyond laboratory conditions, the bias mitigation effects of these interventions should be 7 retained over time and should transfer across contexts. This systematic review provides an overview of the 8 literature on retention and transfer of bias mitigation interventions. A systematic search yielded 41 studies 9 that were eligible for screening. At the end of the selection process, only seven studies remained that 10 adequately studied retention over a period of at least 14 days (six studies) or transfer to different tasks and 11 contexts (two studies). Retention of bias mitigation was found up to 12 months after the interventions. 12 Most of the relevant studies investigated the effects of bias mitigation training with specific serious games. 13 Only two studies (the second one being a replication of the first) found evidence for a transfer effect of bias 14 mitigation training across contexts. Our main conclusion is that there is currently insufficient evidence for 15 the retention and transfer of bias mitigation effects to consider the associated interventions as useful tools 16 that can help people to make better decisions in daily life.
    [Show full text]
  • An Inclusive Taxonomy of Behavioral Biases
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by European Journal of Government and Economics European Journal of Government and Economics 6(1), June 2017, 24-58. European Journal of Government and Economics journal homepage: www.ejge.org ISSN: 2254-7088 An inclusive taxonomy of behavioral biases David Peóna, *, Manel Antelob, Anxo Calvo-Silvosaa a Department of Business Studies, Universidade da Coruña, Spain. b Department of Economics, University of Santiago de Compostela, Spain. * Corresponding author at: Departamento de Empresa. Universidade da Coruña, Campus de Elviña s/n, 15071 A Coruña, Spain. email: [email protected] Article history. Received 25 May 2016; first revision required 9 December 2016; accepted 27 February 2017. Abstract. This paper overviews the theoretical and empirical research on behavioral biases and their influence in the literature. To provide a systematic exposition, we present a unified framework that takes the reader through an original taxonomy, based on the reviews of relevant authors in the field. In particular, we establish three broad categories that may be distinguished: heuristics and biases; choices, values and frames; and social factors. We then describe the main biases within each category, and revise the main theoretical and empirical developments, linking each bias with other biases and anomalies that are related to them, according to the literature. Keywords. Behavioral biases; decision-making; heuristics; framing; prospect theory; social contagion. JEL classification. D03; G02; G11; G14; G30 1. Introduction The standard model of rational choice argues that people choose to follow the option that maximizes expected utility. However, this ignores the presence of behavioral biases, i.e.
    [Show full text]