The Victorian World and the Underworld of Economics

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Victorian World and the Underworld of Economics THE VICTORIAN WORLD 171 right, as we have seen. But if he meant that their physical misery would worsen, he was wrong. Indeed, a Royal Commission convened to look into the slump of 1886 expressed particular satisfaction with the condition of the working classes. And this was not just the pa- The Victorian World tronizing cant of class apologists. Conditions were better- and the Underworld perceptibly and significantly better. Looking back on the situation from the i88os, Sir Robert Giffen wrote: 'What we of Economics have to consider is that fifty years ago, the working man with wages on the average about half, or not much more than half what they are now, had at times to contend with a fluctu- ation in the price of bread which implied sheer starvation. Periodic starvation was, in fact, the condition of the masses of - working men throughout the kingdom fifty years ago." But by the time Giffen wrote, although prices had risen, wages had risen faster. For the first time, the English working- Karl Marx pronounced his sentence of doom on capitalism in man was making enough to keep body and soul together-a the Manqesto of 1848; the system was diagnosed as the vic- . sorry commentary on the past, but a hopeful augury for the tim of an incurable disease, and although no timetable was .future. given, it was presumed to be close enough to its final death And not only had wages gone up, but the very source of struggle for the next of kin-the Communists-to listen surplus value had diminished: hours were far shorter. At the avidly for the last gasp that would signal their inheritance of Jarrow Shipyards and the New Castle Chemical Works, for power. Even before the appearance of Capital in 1867, the example, the work week had fallen from sixty-one to fifty- deathwatch had begun, and with each bout of speculative four hours, while even in the sweated textile mills, the stint fever or each siege of industrial depression, the hopeful drew was reduced to only fifty-seven hours. Indeed the mill own- nearer to the deathbed and told each other that the moment ers complained that their wage costs had risen by better than of Final Revolution would now be soon at hand. 20 percent. But while progress was expensive, it paid intangi- But the system did not die. True, many of the Marxist ble dividends. For as conditions ameliorated, the muttering laws of motion were verified by the march of events: big of 1848 died down. "You cannot get them to talk of politics so business did grow bigger and recurrent depressions and un- long as they are well employed," testified a Staffordshire employment did plague society. But along with these confir- manufacturer on the attitude of his working force. mations of the prognosis of doom, another highly important Even Marx and Engels had to recognize the trend. "The and portentously phrased Marxist symptom was remarkable English proletariat is actually becoming more and more by its absence: the "increasing misery" of the proletariat bourgeois," mourned Engels in a letter to"~arx,"so that the failed to increase. ultimate aim of this most bourgeois of all nations would ap- Actually, there has been a long debate among Marxists as pear to be the possession, alongside the bourgeois, of a bour- to what Marx meant by that phrase. If he meant only that geois aristocracy and a bourgeois proletariat." more and more of the working class would experience the Clearly, Marx was premature in his expectation of im- "misery" of becoming proletarians-wage workers-he was pending doom. For the faithful, of course, the disconcerting 172 THE WORLDLY PHILOSOPHERS THE VICTORIAN WORLD 173 turn of events could be swallowed in the comforting knowl- written by the greatest of academicians, but perhaps by the edge that "inevitable" still meant inevitable, and that a matter most revealing of them-a strange, shy professor named of a generation or two came to little in the grand march Francis Ysidro Edgeworth, a nephew of that Maria Edge- of history. But for the non-Marxist surveyors of the scene, worth who had once played charades with Ricardo. the great Victorian boom meant something else. The world Edgeworth was undoubtedly a brilliant scholar. In his more and more appeared full of hope and promise, and the final examinations at Oxford, when he was asked a particu- forebodings of a dissenter like Karl Marx seemed merely the larly abstruse question, he inquired of his examiners, "Shall I ravings of a discontented radical. Hence the intellectual answer briefly, or at length? and then proceeded to hold bombshell that Marx had prepared went off in almost total si- forth for half an hour, punctuating his reply with excursions lence; instead of a storm of abuse, Marx met the far more into Greek while his examiners gaped. crushing ignominy of indifference. But Edgeworth was not fascinated with economics be- For economics had ceased to be the proliferation of cause it justified or explained or condemned the world, or world views that, in the hands of now a philosopher, now a because it opened new vistas, bright or gloomy, into the fu- financial trader, now a revolutionary, seemed to illuminate ture. This odd soul was fascinated because economics dealt the whole avenue down which society was marching. It with quantities and because anything that dealt with quanti- became instead the special province of professors, whose in- ties could be translated into mathematics! The process of vestigations threw out pinpoint beams rather than the wide- translation required the abandonment of that tension-fraught searching beacons of the earlier economists. world of the earlier economists, but it yielded in return a There was a reason for this: as we have seen, Victorian world of such neat precision and lovely exactness that the loss England had caught the steady trade winds of late- seemed amply compensated. nineteenth-century progress and optimism. Improvement To build up such a mathematical mirror of reality, the was in the air, and so quite naturally there seemed less world obviously had to be simplified. Edgeworth's simplifica- cause to ask disturbing questions about the nature of the tion was this assumption: evey man is a pleasure machine. voyage. Hence the Victorian boom gave rise to a roster of Jeremy Bentham had originated the conception in the early elucidators, men who would examine the workings of the nineteenth century under the beguiling title of the Felicific system in great detail, but not men who would express Calculus, a philosophical view of humanity as so many living doubt as to its basic merits or make troublesome prognosti- profit-and-loss calculators, each busily arranging his life to cations as to its eventual fate. A new professordom took over maximize the pleasure of his psychic adding machine. To this the main life of economic thought. Its contributions were general philosophy Edgeworth now added the precision of often important, yet not vital. For in the minds of men like mathematics to produce a kind of Panglossian Best of All Alfred Marshall, Stanley Jevons, John Bates Clark, and the Possible Worlds. proliferating faculties that surrounded them, there were no Of all men to have adopted such a view of society, Edge- wolves in the economic world anymore, and therefore no worth seems a most unlikely choice. He himself was as ill- life-and-death activities for economic theory to elucidate. constructed a pleasure machine as can be imagined. The world was peopled entirely with agreeable, if imaginary, Neurotically shy, he tended to flee from the pleasures of sheep. human company to the privacy of his club; unhappy about The sheep were never more clearly delineated than in a the burden of material things, he received few of the plea- little volume entitled Mathematical Psychics, which ap- sures that for most people flow from possessions. His rooms peared in 1881, just two years before Marx died. It was not were bare, his library was the public one, and his stock of ma- 174 THE WORLDLY PHILOSOPHERS THE VICTORIAN WORLD 175 terial wealth did not include crockery, or stationery, or even tenets of conservatism. Edgeworth actually believed that his - stamps. Perhaps his greatest source of pleasure was in the algebraic insight into human activity might yield helpful re- construction of his lovely imaginary economic Xanadu. suits in the world of flesh and blood. His analysis involved ~utregardless of his motives, Edgeworth's pleasure- such terms as these: machine assumption bore wonderful intellectual fruit. For if economics was defined to be the study of human pleasure- mechanisms competing for shares of society's stock of plea- sure, then it could be shown-with all the irrefutability of the differential calculus-that in a world of perfect competition "Considerations so abstract," wrote ~dgiworth,"it would each machine would achieve the highest amount of of course be ridiculous to fling upon the floodtide of practical pleasure that could be meted out by society. politics. But they are not perhaps out of place when we re- In other words, if this was not yet quite the best of all mount to the little rills of sentiment and secret springs of mo- possible worlds, it could be. Unfortunately, the world was not tive where every course of action must be originated." organized as a game of perfect competition; men did have "The little rills of sentiment," indeed! Whit would Adam the lamentable habit of sticking together in foolish disregard Smith have thought of this conversion of his pushy mer- of the beneficent consequences of stubbornly following their chants, his greedy journeymen, and his multiplying laboring ' self-interest; trade unions, for example, were in direct con- classes into SO many categories of delicate pleasure-seekers? troversion to the principle of each for himself, and the uncle- In fact, Henry Sid~ck,a contemporary of Edgeworth's md niable fact of inequalitiesof wealth and position did make the a disciple of J.
Recommended publications
  • F:\RSS\Me\Society's Mathemarica
    School of Social Sciences Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK Discussion Papers in Economics and Econometrics Mathematics in the Statistical Society 1883-1933 John Aldrich No. 0919 This paper is available on our website http://www.southampton.ac.uk/socsci/economics/research/papers ISSN 0966-4246 Mathematics in the Statistical Society 1883-1933* John Aldrich Economics Division School of Social Sciences University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ UK e-mail: [email protected] Abstract This paper considers the place of mathematical methods based on probability in the work of the London (later Royal) Statistical Society in the half-century 1883-1933. The end-points are chosen because mathematical work started to appear regularly in 1883 and 1933 saw the formation of the Industrial and Agricultural Research Section– to promote these particular applications was to encourage mathematical methods. In the period three movements are distinguished, associated with major figures in the history of mathematical statistics–F. Y. Edgeworth, Karl Pearson and R. A. Fisher. The first two movements were based on the conviction that the use of mathematical methods could transform the way the Society did its traditional work in economic/social statistics while the third movement was associated with an enlargement in the scope of statistics. The study tries to synthesise research based on the Society’s archives with research on the wider history of statistics. Key names : Arthur Bowley, F. Y. Edgeworth, R. A. Fisher, Egon Pearson, Karl Pearson, Ernest Snow, John Wishart, G. Udny Yule. Keywords : History of Statistics, Royal Statistical Society, mathematical methods.
    [Show full text]
  • MODES for Windows Print
    Marshall Library of Economics Marshall Papers Section 9 Autobiography and personal honours Identity code Marshall 9 Description level 3 Content Summary This diverse section contains the few remaining biographical notes by Alfred, longer notes on Alfred by Mary Marshall, lists of recipients of complimentary copies of Marshall's books and subscribers to his portrait fund, his academic honours, a large scrapbook of newspaper cuttings about Alfred's career kept by Mary and her album of watercolour paintings of places visited on European travels Identity code Marshall 9/1 Previous number Marshall LBB 34 (part) [uncertain attribution] Description level 4 Record creation Person Role writer Name Marshall, Alfred Date undated Document form Record type notes Specific type autobiographical Acquisition Summary Possibly a late accession as formerly in Large Brown Box Content Summary Single page annotated 'Reminiscences' down left side by Marshall. Recounts how when at school was told not to take account of accents in pronouncing Greek words and therefore decided to save time by not learning them or using them in written work. The result was he received the only very heavy punishment of his life. 'This suggested to me that classical studies do not induce an appreciation of the value of time; and I turned away from them as far as I could towards mathematics'. Summary In later years he has observed that fine students of science are greedy of time, whereas many classical men value it lightly. Is most grateful to his headmaster [Revd James Augustus Hessey] for making him think out essays in Latin. Person Name Hessey, James Augustus, Revd Subject keywords Physical descript Summary 1 p.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 1: What Is Statistics? Christopher J
    Chapter 1: What is Statistics? Christopher J. Wild, Jessica M. Utts, and Nicholas J. Horton Christopher J. Wild University of Auckland, New Zealand President, American Statistical Association Jessica M. Utts University of California, Irvine, United States Chair, Statistical Education Section, ASA Nicholas J. Horton Amherst College, United States e-mail: [email protected], [email protected], [email protected] Abstract What is Statistics? We attempt to answer this question as it relates to grounding research in statistics education. We discuss the nature of statistics (the science of learning from data), its history and traditions, what characterises statistical thinking and how it differs from mathematics, connections with computing and data science, why learning statistics is essential, and what is most important. Finally, we attempt to gaze into the future, drawing upon what is known about the fast-growing demand for statistical skills and the portents of where the discipline is heading, especially those arising from data science and the promises and problems of big data. Key Words Discipline of statistics; Statistical thinking; Value of statistics; Statistical fundamentals; Decision making; Trends in statistical practice; Data science; Computational thinking 1.1 Introduction In this, the opening chapter of the International Handbook of Research in Statistics Education, we ask the question, “What is statistics?” This question is not considered in isolation, however, but in the context of grounding research in statistics education. Educational endeavour in statistics can be divided very broadly into “What?” and “How?” The “What?” deals with the nature and extent of the discipline to be conveyed, whereas any consideration of “How?” (including “When?”) brings into play a host of additional factors, such as cognition and learning theories, audience and readiness, attitudes, social interactions with teachers and other students, and learning and assessment strategies and systems.
    [Show full text]
  • A Complete Bibliography of Publications in Biometrika for the Decade 1960–1969
    A Complete Bibliography of Publications in Biometrika for the decade 1960{1969 Nelson H. F. Beebe University of Utah Department of Mathematics, 110 LCB 155 S 1400 E RM 233 Salt Lake City, UT 84112-0090 USA Tel: +1 801 581 5254 FAX: +1 801 581 4148 E-mail: [email protected], [email protected], [email protected] (Internet) WWW URL: http://www.math.utah.edu/~beebe/ 19 May 2021 Version 1.02 Title word cross-reference #4315 [Har79]. 0 · 1 [dVW66]. 2 × 2 [BH60a, BH61a, OI61a, OI61b, Pla64]. 50 [Bar66d]. k [Bur60b]. A [Hol66, Mar63]. A + B [Mar63]. b2 [Pea65b]. β [Mos62]. β2 [JNAP63, JNAP65]. χ [JP69, JP70]. χ2 2 [Hit62, MA65, Put64, Tik65b, Wis63a, Wis63b, You62]. χr [Sen67]. d [dVW66]. Ek=M=1 [Bur60c]. [RK69a]. exp(−a)+ka = 1 [BDM60]. exp(b) − b=(1 − p) = 1 [BDM63]. F [Ati62, BDO60, CB63, CB66, GS62b, PB61, Pri64a, SZ60, Tik65b, Tik66]. GI=G=1 [Kin62]. GI=M=1 [Fin60a]. k [DG68a, Kor69, Maa66]. M [Har69a, Pea69, Cro61, Lin60]. M=M=1 [GS65]. X2 [Wis63a, Wis63b]. N [Gil65, Hai65b, ST66, Arc62, Arc64, Hof63]. p [Rao68b, Rao69]. Q [Gow66a]. 3 2 2 R [Mil65a]. ρ [Sno63]. S [Bur60a, Bar66d].p s = 1 [Bar66d].p smax=s0 2 2 [Cha67a]. SU [Joh65b]. σB/σ [Sis68]. b1 [Pea65b]. β1 [JNAP63]. 1 2 P m p 0 f(Yt) [Con65]. β1 [JNAP65]. t [Amo64, FKM67, GJ68, Haj61, HPW61, Joh61, MSA66, Owe65, SA62a, Sis64]. 2 2 2 2 T0 [IS64]. U [Maa66]. UM;N [Ste65b]. UN [PS62b, Ste63a, Ste64, Tik65a]. (s) 2 2 V1 [Bar66d]. VN [Ste65a].
    [Show full text]
  • 1 the MAKING of INDEX NUMBERS in the EARLY 1920S
    THE MAKING OF INDEX NUMBERS IN THE EARLY 1920s: A CLOSER LOOK AT THE FISHER–MITCHELL DEBATE Felipe Almeida Victor Cruz e Silva Universidade Federal do Paraná Universidade Estadual de Ponta Grossa Área 1 - História do Pensamento Econômico e Metodologia RESUMO O surgimento sistemático da abordagem axiomática dos números de índice ocorreu no início dos anos 1920, um período marcado pelo pluralismo na academia econômic estadunidense. Promovida por Irving Fisher, a abordagem axiomática dos números de índice teve como objetivo selecionar uma fórmula ideal universalmente válida para números de índice, empregando uma série de testes estatísticos. No entanto, desde a primeira apresentação da abordagem de Fisher, no Encontro Anual da Associação Estadunidense de Estatística em 1920, até a publicação de seu livro “The Making of Index Numbers” em 1922, Fisher enfrentou uma série de críticas, não endereçadas à sua fórmula ideal propriamente dita, mas à própria idéia de uma fórmula universal para números de índice. Os principais indivíduos envolvidos nesse debate foram Wesley Mitchell, Warren Persons, Correa Walsh (que foi o único que apoiou a proposta de Fisher) e Allyn Young. Entre eles, o principal representante dos antagonistas de Fisher era Mitchell. Este estudo argumenta que as divergências entre Fisher e Mitchell resultam de seus distintos entendimentos da economia como uma "ciência". Portanto, o objetivo deste estudo é ilustrar como Fisher, como economista matemático, privilegiou a universalidade das teorias econômicas, enquanto Mitchell, como institucionalista, entendeu a economia como uma disciplina contextual e histórica e como essas preconcepções estão presentes no debate sobre números de índice. Para ilustrar suas posições, este estudo explora evidências baseadas em arquivo.
    [Show full text]
  • AN INVESTIGATION INTO the FORMATION of CONSENSUS AROUND NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICS in the 1950S
    THE ECLIPSE OF INSTITUTIONALISM? AN INVESTIGATION INTO THE FORMATION OF CONSENSUS AROUND NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICS IN THE 1950s A Dissertation Submitted to the Temple University Graduate Board In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy By Julie Ragatz May, 2019 Committee Members: Dr. Miriam Solomon, Department of Philosophy Dr. David Wolfsdorf, Department of Philosophy Dr. Dimitrios Diamantaras, Department of Economics Dr. Matthew Lund, Department of Philosophy, Rowan University, External Reader © Copyright 2019 by Julie Ragatz Norton All Rights Reserved ii ABSTRACT The Eclipse of Institutionalism? An Investigation into the Formation of Consensus Around Neoclassical Economics in the 1950s Julie Ragatz Norton Temple University, 2019 Doctoral Advisory Committee Chair: Dr. Miriam Solomon As the discipline of economics professionalized during the interwar period, two schools of thought emerged: institutionalism and neoclassical economics. By 1954, after the publication of Arrow and Debreu’s landmark article on general equilibrium theory, consensus formed around neoclassical economics. This outcome was significantly influenced by trends in the philosophy of science, notably the transformation from the logical empiricism of the Vienna Circle to an ‘Americanized’ version of logical empiricism that was dominant through the 1950s. This version of logical empiricism provided a powerful ally to neoclassical economics by affirming its philosophical and methodological commitments as examples of “good science”. This dissertation explores this process of consensus formation by considering whether consensus would be judged normatively appropriate from the perspective of three distinct approaches to the philosophy of science; Carl Hempel’s logical empiricism, Thomas Kuhn’s account of theory change and Helen Longino’s critical contextual empiricism.
    [Show full text]
  • Francis Ysidro Edgeworth
    Francis Ysidro Edgeworth Previous (Francis Xavier) (/entry/Francis_Xavier) Next (Francis of Assisi) (/entry/Francis_of_Assisi) Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (February 8, 1845 – February 13, 1926) was an Irish (/entry/Ireland) polymath, a highly influential figure in the development of neo­ classical economics, and contributor to the development of statistical theory. He was the first to apply certain formal mathematical techniques to individual decision making in economics. Edgeworth developed utility theory, introducing the indifference curve and the famous "Edgeworth box," which have become standards in economic theory. He is also known for the "Edgeworth conjecture" which states that the core of an economy shrinks to the set of competitive equilibria as the number of agents in the economy gets large. The high degree of originality demonstrated in his most important book on economics, Mathematical Psychics, was matched only by the difficulty in reading it. A deep thinker, his contributions were far ahead of his time and continue to inform the fields of (/entry/File:Edgeworth.jpeg) microeconomics (/entry/Microeconomics) and areas such as welfare economics. Francis Y. Edgeworth Thus, Edgeworth's work has advanced our understanding of economic relationships among traders, and thus contributes to the establishment of a better society for all. Life Contents Ysidro Francis Edgeworth (the order of his given names was later reversed) 1 Life was born on February 8, 1845 in Edgeworthstown, Ireland (/entry/Ireland), into 2 Work a large and wealthy landowning family. His aunt was the famous novelist Maria 2.1 Edgeworth conjecture Edgeworth, who wrote the Castle Rackrent. He was educated by private tutors 2.2 Edgeworth Box until 1862, when he went on to study classics and languages at Trinity College, 2.3 Edgeworth limit theorem Dublin.
    [Show full text]
  • INFORMATION to USERS the Most Advanced Technology Has Been Used to Photo­ Graph and Reproduce This Manuscript from the Microfilm Master
    INFORMATION TO USERS The most advanced technology has been used to photo­ graph and reproduce this manuscript from the microfilm master. UMI films the text directly from the original or copy submitted. Thus, some thesis and dissertation copies are in typewriter face, while others may be from any type of computer printer. The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations and photographs, print bleedthrough, substandard margins, and improper alignment can adversely affect reproduction. In the unlikely event that the author did not send UMI a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized copyright material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Oversize materials (e.g., maps, drawings, charts) are re­ produced by sectioning the original, beginning at the upper left-hand comer and continuing from left to right in equal sections with small overlaps. Each original is also photographed in one exposure and is included in reduced form at the back of the book. These are also available as one exposure on a standard 35mm slide or as a 17" x 23" black and white photographic print for an additional charge. Photographs included in the original manuscript have been reproduced xerographically in this copy. Higher quality 6" x 9" black and white photographic prints are available for any photographs or illustrations appearing in this copy for an additional charge. Contact UMI directly to order. UMI University Microfilms International A Bell & Howell Information Company 3 00 Nortfi Z eeb Road, Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 USA 313/761-4700 800/521-0600 Order Number 9011133 Sudden leaps: The young Alfred Marshall Butler, Robert William, Ph.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Power, Organization, Markets, Money and the Allocation of Resources
    Yale University EliScholar – A Digital Platform for Scholarly Publishing at Yale Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers Cowles Foundation 1-1-2018 Who Gets What, When, How? Power, Organization, Markets, Money and the Allocation of Resources Martin Shubik Follow this and additional works at: https://elischolar.library.yale.edu/cowles-discussion-paper-series Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Shubik, Martin, "Who Gets What, When, How? Power, Organization, Markets, Money and the Allocation of Resources" (2018). Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers. 158. https://elischolar.library.yale.edu/cowles-discussion-paper-series/158 This Discussion Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the Cowles Foundation at EliScholar – A Digital Platform for Scholarly Publishing at Yale. It has been accepted for inclusion in Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers by an authorized administrator of EliScholar – A Digital Platform for Scholarly Publishing at Yale. For more information, please contact [email protected]. WHO GETS WHAT, WHEN, HOW? POWER, ORGANIZATION, MARKETS, MONEY AND THE ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES By Martin Shubik January 2018 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 2118 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY Box 208281 New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8281 http://cowles.yale.edu/ WHO GETS WHAT, WHEN, HOW? Power, Organization, Markets, Money and the Allocation of Resources Martin Shubik © Copyright Martin Shubik, 2015 1 Contents Preface Acknowledgments 1 The Emergence of Civilization with Money and Financial Institutions
    [Show full text]
  • School of Social Sciences Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK
    School of Social Sciences Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK Discussion Papers in Economics and Econometrics Professor A L Bowley’s Theory of the Representative Method John Aldrich No. 0801 This paper is available on our website http://www.socsci.soton.ac.uk/economics/Research/Discussion_Papers ISSN 0966-4246 Key names: Arthur L. Bowley, F. Y. Edgeworth, , R. A. Fisher, Adolph Jensen, J. M. Keynes, Jerzy Neyman, Karl Pearson, G. U. Yule. Keywords: History of Statistics, Sampling theory, Bayesian inference. Professor A. L. Bowley’s Theory of the Representative Method * John Aldrich Economics Division School of Social Sciences University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ UK e-mail: [email protected] Abstract Arthur. L. Bowley (1869-1957) first advocated the use of surveys–the “representative method”–in 1906 and started to conduct surveys of economic and social conditions in 1912. Bowley’s 1926 memorandum for the International Statistical Institute on the “Measurement of the precision attained in sampling” was the first large-scale theoretical treatment of sample surveys as he conducted them. This paper examines Bowley’s arguments in the context of the statistical inference theory of the time. The great influence on Bowley’s conception of statistical inference was F. Y. Edgeworth but by 1926 R. A. Fisher was on the scene and was attacking Bayesian methods and promoting a replacement of his own. Bowley defended his Bayesian method against Fisher and against Jerzy Neyman when the latter put forward his concept of a confidence interval and applied it to the representative method. * Based on a talk given at the Sample Surveys and Bayesian Statistics Conference, Southampton, August 2008.
    [Show full text]
  • The Enigma of Karl Pearson and Bayesian Inference
    The Enigma of Karl Pearson and Bayesian Inference John Aldrich 1 Introduction “An enigmatic position in the history of the theory of probability is occupied by Karl Pearson” wrote Harold Jeffreys (1939, p. 313). The enigma was that Pearson based his philosophy of science on Bayesian principles but violated them when he used the method of moments and probability-values in statistics. It is not uncommon to see a divorce of practice from principles but Pearson also used Bayesian methods in some of his statistical work. The more one looks at his writings the more puzzling they seem. In 1939 Jeffreys was probably alone in regretting that Pearson had not been a bottom to top Bayesian. Bayesian methods had been in retreat in English statistics since Fisher began attacking them in the 1920s and only Jeffreys ever looked for a synthesis of logic, statistical methods and everything in between. In the 1890s, when Pearson started, everything was looser: statisticians used inverse arguments based on Bayesian principles and direct arguments based on sampling theory and a philosopher-physicist-statistician did not have to tie everything together. Pearson did less than his early guide Edgeworth or his students Yule and Gosset (Student) to tie up inverse and direct arguments and I will be look- ing to their work for clues to his position and for points of comparison. Of Pearson’s first course on the theory of statistics Yule (1938, p. 199) wrote, “A straightforward, organized, logically developed course could hardly then [in 1894] exist when the very elements of the subject were being developed.” But Pearson never produced such a course or published an exposition as integrated as Yule’s Introduction, not to mention the nonpareil Probability of Jeffreys.
    [Show full text]
  • Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (1889) "The Mathematical Theory of Political Economy: Review of Léon Walras, Éléments D'économie Politique Pure", Nature, Vol
    Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (1889) "The Mathematical Theory of Political Economy: Review of Léon Walras, Éléments d'économie politique pure", Nature, Vol. 40, September 5, p.434-6. [Note on electronic version: Page and column numbers in bold square brackets, e.g. [p.434, Col. 2], denote the beginning of the respective page and/or column in the original 1889 Nature version. All errors are left intact. Both this Nature article and a related address by Edgeworth to the British Association for the Advancement which was jointly published in Nature, 12 Sept., 1889, p.496-509 and in the Journal of the Statistical Society of London, Dec. 1889 and reprinted in his Papers Relating to Political Economy (1925, Vol. 2, Sec. VI , Essay α), were severely criticized by Ladislaus von Bortkiewicz (1890, Revue d'économie politique). This, in turn, led to a rejoinder by Edgeworth (1891, Revue d'économie politique) expanding on the themes laid out here. As far as we know, this essay is in the public domain. You are free to make use of this electronic version in any way you wish, except for commercial purposes, without asking permission. All comments and corrections of this text are encouraged and can be addressed to [email protected]. The Editors, History of Economic Thought Website, http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/] ________________________________________________________ [p.434, Col. 2] THE MATHEMATICAL THEORY OF POLITICAL ECONOMY Éléments d'Économie Politique Pure. Par Léon Walras (Lausanne: F. Rouge, 1889) The appearance of a new and enlarged edition affords us a wished-for opportunity of calling attention to this original work.
    [Show full text]