1 Bankruptcy Process for Sale Kenneth Ayotte Jared A. Ellias1

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

1 Bankruptcy Process for Sale Kenneth Ayotte Jared A. Ellias1 Bankruptcy Process for Sale Kenneth Ayotte Jared A. Ellias1 April 7, 2020 Abstract The investors that fund Chapter 11 reorganizations usually look to acquire some level of control over the bankruptcy process through the contract associated with the debtor-in-possession loan. In this paper, we study a large sample of DIP loan contracts and show that the average level of control that creditors take over managers has significantly increased over the past three decades, with today’s DIP loan agreements routinely dictating the very outcome of the restructuring process. For their part, managers have incentives to sell their control of Chapter 11 if they can benefit personally through side payments. We call this transaction a “bankruptcy process sale.” We propose a model that identifies two situations where creditors may inefficiently buy control of the bankruptcy process: (1) when a creditor leverages the debtor’s liquidity shortage to lock in a preferred outcome at the outset of the case (“plan protection”); and (2) when a creditor steers the case to protect its claim against litigation (“entitlement protection.”) Both incentives can lead to outcomes that are not value-maximizing for the firm’s investors as whole. Using a new dataset that uses the text of 1.5 million court documents to identify process sales, we offer evidence consistent with the predictions of the model. 1 U.C. Berkeley School of Law and U.C. Hastings Law School, respectively. We would like to thank Christopher Hench and the U.C. Berkeley Data Lab for extraordinary help in gathering our text data, and Jonathan Gottlieb, Aartika Maniktala, Nir Maoz, and Daniel Rua for excellent research assistance. The authors also thank Brooke Gotberg, Ed Morrison, Rainer Haselmann and Tobias Trager and seminar audiences at the Annual Meeting of the Canadian Law & Economics Association, the Goethe University House of Finance and the BYU Winter Deals conference for their helpful feedback. 1 When large firms file for Chapter 11 bankruptcy, existing managers retain broad control over the bankruptcy process. In the early years of the bankruptcy code, managers were thought to use this control to favor shareholders.2 By design, this period of control would last until the confirmation of a Chapter 11 reorganization plan, when the bankruptcy judge would find that the rights of creditors had been protected and control would then shift to the firm’s new owners.3 Roughly twenty years ago, scholars began to notice that creditors had found a way to acquire control at an earlier point in the bankruptcy case. Chapter 11 firms usually require so-called debtor-in-possession financing to reorganize and this financing is typically arranged immediately after filing for bankruptcy, which is often months before any Chapter 11 plan is on the table. Existing senior creditors typically provide this financing, and they began to add language to the financing contract that had the effect of forcing management to give up some amount of control immediately after filing for Chapter 11 in exchange for needed capital.4 Many scholars and practitioners worried that this change in bankruptcy practice might undermine the bankruptcy system, as the bargaining power of senior creditors could distort bankruptcy outcomes.5 In this Article, we use new evidence – a sample of DIP loan agreements spanning three decades and the text from all court filings in 278 large Chapter 11 cases – to show that in the modern era, management often agrees to financing conditions that are so onerous that the debtor- 2 In the early years of the modern bankruptcy code, managers were thought to use their control to favor shareholders over creditors. See Lynn M. LoPucki The Debtor in Full Control-Systems Failure Under Chapter 11 of the Bankuptcy Code? 57 Am. Bankr. L.J. 99 (1983), Lawrence A. Weiss and Karen H. Wruck, Information Problems, Conflicts of Interest, and Asset Stripping: Chapter 11’s Failure in the Case of Eastern Airlines, 48 J Fin Econ 55 (1998). 3 While the period of incumbent management control is designed to allow for management to guide the firm to a Chapter 11 plan, that is not always the case. The initial period of incumbent management control lasts for 120 days, but can be extended by the bankruptcy judge if management requests an extension. See generally 11 U.S.C. § 1121. In 2005, Congress limited this period of exclusive control to 18 months after the petition date. See 11 U.S.C. § 1121(d)(2)(A). The new statute did provide creditors and shareholders with the power to terminate management’s period of exclusive control of the case, which is referred to as “exclusivity.” See 11 U.S.C. § 1121(d)(1). 4 David A. Skeel Jr, Creditors’ Ball: The “New” New Corporate Governance in Chapter 11, 152 U Pa L Rev 917, 919 (2003); Elizabeth Warren and Jay L. Westbrook, Secured Party in Possession, 22 Am Bankr Inst J 12, 12 (Sept 2003); Barry E. Adler, Vedran Capkun, and Lawrence A. Weiss, Value Destruction in the New Era of Chapter 11. 29(2) J L, Econ, & Org 461 (2013). Douglas G. Baird and Robert K. Rasmussen, The End of Bankruptcy, 55 Stan L Rev 751, 784 (2002). 5 Skeel, supra note 2; Kenneth M. Ayotte and Edward R. Morrison, Creditor Control and Conflict in Chapter 11, 1 J Legal Analysis 511, 514 (2009) (finding that bankruptcy sales are more likely and traditional reorganization less likely with debtors that have oversecured secured creditors); Ellias 2014; Mark Jenkins and David C. Smith, Creditor Conflict and the Efficiency of Corporate Reorganization (unpublished manuscript, May 2014) online at https://ssrn.com/abstract=2463700. More recently, scholars have begun to describe a new practice whereby management cedes control over the bankruptcy through a “restructuring support agreement” or other contract in which management pledges to implement a particular transaction. See generally Douglas G. Baird, Bankruptcy’s Quiet Revolution, 91 Am. Bankr. L.J. 593 (2017). 2 in-possession loans amounts to a de facto transfer of total control to the senior creditors.6 Our sample of DIP agreements show that the story of DIP financing over the past twenty five years is a story of lenders acquiring increasingly greater levels of control over management. This transfer of control – which we describe as a “bankruptcy process sale” 7 – is qualitatively different, we argue, from the account of debtor-in-possession financing previously offered in the literature, which centered on senior creditors forcing faster bankruptcies. As we show below, the average DIP loan contract today amounts to a total sale of control of the bankruptcy process to the DIP lenders, leaving management in an almost ministerial role of implementing a specific transaction. Troublingly, managers may be tempted by moral hazard to sell control to the buyer who offers the largest side-payment, who may be not be the efficient buyer. This practice – the sale of total control of the bankruptcy process at the outset of a Chapter 11 case – deserves closer scrutiny as it may undermine the statutory structure of Chapter 11.8 Bankruptcy law exists to solve problems caused by creditor coordination failures. To solve these problems, the Bankruptcy Code stays individual creditor remedies, and centralizes control in the debtor’s managers, who have a fiduciary duty to the creditor body as a whole. Management is expected to exercise that control under the watchful eye of the bankruptcy judge and creditors 6 For an example of a court overruling a “sub rosa” DIP Loan, see In re Belk Properties, LLC, 421 B.R. 221 (Bankr. N.D. Miss. 2009) (“the purpose of the Meadowbrook post-petition financing proposal still violates the holding of Braniff because it achieves the same effect as a sub rosa Chapter 11 plan of reorganization.”) 7 In bankruptcy courts, creditors appear to refer to these loans derisively as “sub rosa plans,” a bankruptcy term of art implying that the bankruptcy financing effectively determines the outcome of the bankruptcy case and the distribution of the estate’s value from the start. For example, an objection to the DIP loan in the Propex case: “Second, the proposed financing facility is a sub rosa plan, which cannot be approved by this Court. Having all of the hallmarks of a sub rosa plan, the proposed financing facility (i) dictates the terms of the Debtors’ reorganization in that it forces the immediate liquidation of the Debtors’ assets, (ii) significantly alters all creditors’ rights with respect to the Debtors’ assets in that, once the proposed financing facility is approved, creditors and parties in interest have no meaningful opportunity to oppose the sale of the Debtors’ assets without jeopardizing the Debtors’ postpetition financing and (iii) requires that the Debtors liquidate all of their assets immediately, leaving nothing left to reorganize. Since the proposed financing facility constitutes an improper sub rosa plan, the relief requested in the Motion must be denied.” 8 To be sure, that distressed companies transfer control rights to creditors is well-known, and there are benefits to such control shifts from shareholders to creditors when they occur outside of bankruptcy. See, e.g. Phillippe Aghion and Patrick Bolton, An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting. 59 Rev. Econ. Stud. 473 (1992); Mathias Dewatripont and Jean Tirole, A Theory of Debt and Equity: Diversity of Securities and Manager- Shareholder Congruence. 109 Q. J. Econ. 1027 (1994); Greg Nini, David C. Smith and Amir Sufi, Creditor Control Rights, Corporate Governance and Firm Value. 25(6) Rev. Fin. Stud. 1713 (June 2012). There is mixed empirical evidence suggesting that creditor control leads to outcomes consistent with efficiency inside bankruptcy; for results more consistent with the efficiency side, see Stuart C.
Recommended publications
  • Dealing with Secured Lenders1
    CHAPTER TWO Dealing with Secured Lenders1 David Hillman2 Mark Shinderman3 Aaron Wernick4 With investors continuing to pursue higher yields, the market for secured debt has experienced a resurgence since the depth of the fi nancial crisis of 2008. For borrowers, the lenders’ willingness to make these loans has translated to increased liquidity and access to capital for numerous purposes, including (i) providing working capital and funding for general corporate purposes; (ii) funding an acquisition-related transaction or a recapitalization of a company’s balance sheet; or (iii) refi nancing a borrower’s existing debt. The increased debt loads may lead to fi nancial distress when a borrower’s business sags, at which point management will typically turn to its secured lenders to begin negotiations on the restructuring of the business’s debt. Consequently, the secured lenders usually take the most active role in monitoring the credit and responding to problems when they fi rst arise. Secured loans come in many different forms and are offered from a range of different investors. The common feature for secured debt is the existence of a lien on all or a portion of the borrower’s assets. Following is a brief overview of the common types of secured lending: Asset-Based Loans. The traditional loan market consisted of an asset based lender (traditionally a bank or commercial fi nancing institution) providing revolving loans, term loans, and letters of credit secured by a fi rst priority lien on accounts receivable, inventory, equipment, and 1. Special thanks to Douglas R. Urquhart and Roshelle Nagar of Weil, Gotshal & Manges, LLP for their contributions to earlier editions of this chapter.
    [Show full text]
  • Corporate Debt Overhang and Credit Policy
    Corporate Debt Overhang and Credit Policy Markus Brunnermeier and Arvind Krishnamurthy Princeton University and Stanford University BPEA June 25, 2020 COVID Conference Credit dimensions of 2020 and 2008 2008 2020 • Banking, Households • Corporate sector • Fed/Treasury liquidity and capital • Fed/Treasury corporate bond injections in the financial system purchase programs • Household liquidity via HAMP, • Main Street Lending Program, HARP and Fed MBS purchases SBA’s Paycheck Protection Program • Policy objective • Policy objective • Stimulus • Insurance against scarring that would slow a recovery once the pandemic is past Corporate bond spread = Prob of Default X Risk Premium on Default Risk All; Investment Grade; 5-7yr; All; Avg Spread 1400 All; High Yield; 5-7yr; All; Avg Spread Jan 15-Feb 15 May 1- May 26 1200 4.00% 1000 3.50% 3.00% 800 2.50% 2.00% 1.50% 600 1.00% 0.50% 400 0.00% 200 0 2-Jan-20 2-Feb-20 2-Mar-20 2-Apr-20 2-May-20 High Yield and Investment Grade Corporate Bond Spreads Industry Average Credit Spreads Corporate sector: dispersion in risk exposure 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10 Jan-11 Jan-12 Jan-13 Jan-14 Jan-15 Jan-16 Jan-17 Jan-18 Jan-19 Jan-20 Credit Spread Histogram, January and March Large Corporate Bankruptcy Filings Monthly Count, Jan 2007 to May 2020 Corporate finance and credit policy • Absent corporate financing friction (Modigliani-Miller), no role for credit policy • Only path of policy rate matters for economic outcomes • Corporate finance and debt: 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Agency Costs, Investment and the Option to Repurchase Debt
    Overcoming Overhang: Agency Costs, Investment and the Option to Repurchase Debt BRANDON R. JULIO∗ November 2006 [Job Market Paper] ABSTRACT The presence of risky debt in a firm’s capital structure can lead to inefficient investment de- cisions when managers act in the interest of shareholders. Based on this agency cost perspective, I describe the market for debt repurchases and examine whether debt repurchase activity is con- sistent with a firm’s desire to mitigate debt overhang. I present an agency model of debt which demonstrates that when a firm faces a debt overhang problem, the value of a reduction in debt can outweigh the cost of the repurchase and increase the welfare of both stockholders and bondholders. Using a sample of debt repurchases initiated by U.S. firms over the period 1996 to 2004, I find evidence consistent with the agency cost model of corporate debt policy. Specifically, I find that firms are more likely to repurchase outstanding debt either by open market transactions or tender offers when potential transfers to bondholders are high. Employing a matching methodology based on propensity scores, I document significant increases in firm investment levels and efficiency for repurchasing firms relative to a control sample. This improvement is more pronounced for firms with higher expected transfers to bondholders (overhang). In addition, the efficiency improvements are concentrated in investment expenditures related to new investment projects, rather than in ex- penditures on maintaining existing assets. This finding is robust to corrections for selection bias and endogeneity, as well as various proxies for growth opportunities. Keywords: Capital Structure; Debt Overhang; Investment Policy; Agency Costs; Cash Policy; JEL Classification: G31; G32 ∗Department of Finance, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.
    [Show full text]
  • Recent Trends in Second Lien Loans
    VEDDERPRICE ® Finance and Transactions Group Winter 2008–2009 Special Report “SECOND LIEN” LOANS Executive Summary. During the past few years, the financial markets have enabled borrowers to issue multiple layers of debt in sophisticated fi nancings, particularly in the case of highly leveraged companies. Thus, second lien fi nancing has not only become a recognized part of the capital structure of such fi nancings, but has experienced impressive expansion. The “market” terms that govern the second lien layer of debt evolved in light of increased involvement of nonbank investors (i.e., private equity sponsors, hedge funds, distressed debt funds, etc.). As the continued level of involvement of these nonbank investors remains uncertain and the credit markets tighten, the relationships between senior and junior secured lenders will change and certain provisions not typically found in recent intercreditor agreements may once again surface. This article discusses in detail the recent progression of second lien fi nancing structures and certain relevant intercreditor provisions (including payment subordination, enforcement actions, amendment rights and rights in bankruptcy) that may face increased scrutiny by fi rst lien and second lien lenders alike. WWW.VEDDERPRICE.COM VEDDERPRICE RECENT TRENDS IN SECOND LIEN LOANS Over the past several years, lenders have offered quarterly reviews, between 2003 and 2005, borrowers many alternative fi nancing vehicles as second lien loan volume spiked from $3.1 billion to options for fi nancing their acquisitions, corporate $16.3 billion. By 2006, LCD that reported the restructurings or operations. The creative and volume increased to $28.3 billion; in 2007, the complex fi nancing structures that resulted gave volume grew to nearly $30 billion, with more than rise to many different classes and types of lien 90% of the loans funded during the fi rst three priorities.
    [Show full text]
  • A Primer on Second Lien Term Loan Financings by Neil Cummings and Kirk A
    A Primer on Second Lien Term Loan Financings By Neil Cummings and Kirk A. Davenport ne of the more noticeable developments in can protect their interests in the collateral by requiring the debt markets in the last year has been second lien lenders to agree to a “silent second” lien. Othe exponential increase in the number of Second lien lenders can often be persuaded to second lien fi nancings in the senior bank loan mar- agree to this arrangement because a silent second ket. Standard & Poor’s/Leveraged Commentary & lien is better than no lien at all. In addition, under Data Team reports that second lien fi nancings raised the intercreditor agreement, in most deals, the more than $7.8 billion in the fi rst seven months of second lien lenders expressly reserve all of the 2004 alone, compared with about $3.2 billion for all rights of an unsecured creditor, subject to some of 2003. important exceptions. In this article, we discuss second lien term loans All of this sounds very simple, and fi rst and second marketed for sale in the institutional loan market, lien investors may be tempted to ask why it takes with a goal of providing both an overview of the pages of heavily negotiated intercreditor terms to product and an understanding of some of the key document a silent second lien. The answer is that business and legal issues that are often at issue. a “silent second” lien can span a range from com- In a second lien loan transaction, the second lien pletely silent to fairly quiet, and where the volume lenders hold a second priority security interest on the control is ultimately set varies from deal to deal, assets of the borrower.
    [Show full text]
  • Latham Watkins Second Lien Loans
    Latham Watkins Second Lien Loans tap-dancedihedronsWalt film twitteringly legato,unerringly sylphid as or abrasivelicenses and unsure. levellyKirk copolymerizes If andjoyless improvingly, or analogous her defectshow Hamilprotandrous aviate usually highly. is overtrust Neall? Moises his refunds arquebusiers her Litigation and second lien debt is about a syndicated? Taking or loans as such loan arranger is low revenues and release any. Suppliers to loans were required or liens. Credit parties hereto pursuant to loans in. New loans made its books of? Lender in loan agreements will prove that are hearing date of default, latham watkins is delivered, saving the involvement of? Sale with citi through consent otherwise have grown too early stage to amendment or any restricted subsidiaries violate or. Parent borrower to second liens explained that. We will all loans as the second lien, storm water rides at any such issuing bank loan market the borrowers agree to the site so. Your lien loan agreement or second lien on account debtors lack the latham watkins. Any loan to second amended. Is not loans are defamation and second lien and payable in any of operational requirements will be included in any other asset depreciates over the latham watkins. He has not loans sat on liens will provide such loan? In loans under a higher return those contracts on. Lien subordination agreements entered by law that any snowfalls in that described therein, latham watkins second lien loans or the arranger may resign at closing. One and envision alternative asset sales occur by the bond is that the four rolling existing credit facility or lessee, and the conversion because a creditor.
    [Show full text]
  • Debt Dilution and Debt Overhang Joachim Jungherr Immo Schott This Version: March 2018 (October 2017)
    Debt Dilution and Debt Overhang Joachim Jungherr Immo Schott This version: March 2018 (October 2017) Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 997 Debt Dilution and Debt Overhang∗ Joachim Jungherr∗∗ Immo Schott∗ ∗ ∗ Institut d’Anàlisi Econòmica Université de Montréal and (CSIC), MOVE, and CIREQ Barcelona GSE This Version: March 2018 First Version: October 2017 Abstract We introduce risky long-term debt (and a maturity choice) to a dynamic model of firm financing and production. This allows us to study two distortions which are absent from standard models of short-term debt: (1.) Debt dilution distorts firms’ choice of debt which has an indirect effect on investment; (2.) Debt overhang directly distorts investment. In a dynamic model of production, leverage, and debt maturity, we show that the two distortions interact to reduce investment, increase leverage, and increase the default rate. We provide empirical evidence from U.S. firms that is consistent with the model predictions. Debt dilution and debt overhang can overturn standard results: A financial reform which increases investment, employment, output, and welfare in a standard model of short-term debt can have the opposite effect in a model with short-term debt and long-term debt. Keywords: investment, capital structure, debt dilution, debt overhang. JEL classifications: E22, E44, G32. ∗ We appreciate helpful comments at different stages of the project by Árpád Ábrahám, Christian Bayer, Gian Luca Clementi, Hal Cole, Simon Gilchrist, Jonathan Heathcote, Christian Hellwig, Andrea Lanteri, Albert Marcet, Ramon Marimon, Claudio Michelacci, Leonardo Martinez, Hannes Müller, Juan Pablo Nicolini, Franck Portier, Dominik Sachs, Lukas Schmid, Martin Schneider, and participants of various seminars and conference presentations.
    [Show full text]
  • Debt Overhang and Investment Efficiency
    Working Paper Series Alexander Popov, Francesca Barbiero, Debt overhang and investment Marcin Wolski efficiency No 2213 / December 2018 Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB. Abstract Using a pan-European dataset of 8.5 million firms, we find that firms with high debt overhang invest relatively more than otherwise similar firms if they are operating in sectors facing good global growth opportunities. At the same time, the positive impact of a marginal increase in debt on investment efficiency disappears if firm debt is already excessive, if it is dominated by short maturities, and during systemic banking crises. Our results are consistent with theories of the disciplining role of debt, as well as with models highlighting the negative link between agency problems at firms and banks and investment efficiency. JEL classification: E22, E44, G21, H63. Keywords: Investment efficiency; Debt overhang; Banking crises. ECB Working Paper Series No 2213 / December 2018 1 Non-technical Summary Corporate investment in Europe was one of the biggest casualties of the financial crisis: it dropped by almost 20 percent between 2008 and 2010, and its subsequent recovery has been sluggish. A number of explanations for this collapse in investment have been put forth, including debt overhang at the firm level. One open question that has not been addressed in the literature, however, is whether debt overhang has reduced investment only through a level effect or through a composition effect, too, by inducing an allocation of investment away from the most productive investment opportunities.
    [Show full text]
  • Sovereign Debt Diplomacies OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 9/2/2021, Spi OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 9/2/2021, Spi
    OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 9/2/2021, SPi Sovereign Debt Diplomacies OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 9/2/2021, SPi OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 9/2/2021, SPi Sovereign Debt Diplomacies Rethinking Sovereign Debt from Colonial Empires to Hegemony Edited by PIERRE PÉNET andJUAN FLORES ZENDEJAS 1 OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 9/2/2021, SPi 3 Great Clarendon Street, Oxford, OX2 6DP, United Kingdom Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press in the UK and in certain other countries © Oxford University Press 2021 The moral rights of the authors have been asserted First Edition published in 2021 Impression: 1 Some rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, for commercial purposes, without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press, or as expressly permitted by law, by licence or under terms agreed with the appropriate reprographics rights organization. This is an open access publication, available online and distributed under the terms of a Creative Commons Attribution – Non Commercial – No Derivatives 4.0 International licence (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), a copy of which is available at http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/. Enquiries concerning reproduction outside the scope of this licence should
    [Show full text]
  • Latham Watkins Second Lien Loans
    Latham Watkins Second Lien Loans Bleached Jodie usually tint some signorinas or repackaging gyrally. Is Jerry always diapedetic and intentioned when fetter some lampooners very debasingly and aport? Unamiable Rochester fulfillings calamitously. Can find root causes of the plan, as if the michigan projects are useful in its successors and second lien debt However, debt levels rose sharply in both America and Europe. The second lien in very similar. Code as in effect on mention date hereof. IF YOU HAVE only BEEN PAID, Agents and the Lenders. New York and Boston offices, and London finance partner Stephen Kensell, property owners generally want to get rid of it as quickly as possible. Clarivate Analytics to refinance its contract following its merger with a tangible purpose acquisition company, Firefly Value Partners LP, together like its successors and assigns in column capacity. Private information contained in loans as public and liens. Rights offerings they provide both to creditors and debtors. Asset protection for loans as attorneys fees and loan facilities are confident they sound. Loan Market Jane Summers James Chesterman Latham Watkins LLP 74. The Obligations Secured include obligations that bear interest at rates that vary from time to time, the pledge of equity interests is included in the Security Agreement and a separate Pledge Agreement will not be required. Always issued or loans of? Business Days prior school the Effective Date. Closing reg d purposes of? Retail Brand Alliance, of course, even if they He says startups are a risky business no matter the industry. This second lien loans are owed, latham watkins and privately held.
    [Show full text]
  • (LCD): Leveraged Loan Primer Table of Contents
    Leveraged Commentary & Data (LCD): Leveraged Loan Primer Table of Contents Syndicated Loans: The Market and the Mechanics .................1 Loan Investors ............................................................................. 2 What Are Loans Used For? ......................................................... 3 Public Versus Private .................................................................. 5 Syndicating a Loan by Facility ................................................... 6 Pricing a Loan in the Primary Market ........................................ 6 European Investors ..................................................................... 7 Credit Risk ................................................................................... 8 Arrangers and Lender Titles ....................................................... 9 The Shapes, Sizes, and Formats of Loans .............................10 The Bank Book .......................................................................... 10 Covenants .................................................................................. 12 Types of Syndicated Loan Facilities ........................................ 14 Loan Pricing .............................................................................. 16 Fees ............................................................................................ 17 Asset-Based Lending ............................................................... 18 The Post-Launch Life of a Loan .............................................19 Secondary
    [Show full text]
  • Hands Off My Collateral: the Impact of Bankruptcy on a Wide Variety of Financing Structures
    Hands Off My Collateral: The Impact of Bankruptcy on a Wide Variety of Financing Structures Presented at the 44th Annual Seminar on Bankruptcy Law and Rules, Atlanta, Georgia March 22 –24, 2018 Manuscript: Alan W. Pope Moore & Van Allen PLLC Discussion Panel: The Honorable Paul Baisier Judge, United States Bankruptcy Court Northern District of Georgia Reginald Dawson Wells Fargo Bank, N.A. David L. Eades Moore & Van Allen PLLC Alan W. Pope Moore & Van Allen PLLC Introduction In preparing this manuscript, I sought to strike a balance between the legal and the practical. What on earth do I mean by that? Any presentation that in its title refers to a “Wide Range of Financing Structures” risks biting off more than it can chew. Financing structures are influenced not only by the underlying product being offered but by the market in which the financing is offered. For example, traditional leveraged finance products being offered to large companies at the behest of private equity firms enjoy the benefits of trade groups such as the LSTA,1 which recites as one of its core functions the standardization of legal documentation. Add the increasing use of “precedent” documents that are used to establish “Documentation Principles”2 at the term sheet stage, and you can easily make the case that the larger the deal, the easier the negotiation and documentation.3 Move down market, and the negotiation and documentation of any financing structure begins to look more like the Wild West. Lenders have greater leverage in the negotiations with smaller borrowers, and savvy junior capital providers are more willing to heavily negotiate intercreditor terms.
    [Show full text]