Germany in an Interconnected World Economy

EDITOR Ashoka Mody

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution © 2013 International Monetary Fund

Cataloging-in-Publication Data Joint Bank-Fund Library

Germany in an interconnected world economy / editor, Ashoka Mody. – Washington, D.C. : International Monetary Fund, 2013. p. : ill. ; cm.

Includes bibliographical references.

1. Germany – Economic conditions. 2. Economic development – Germany. 3. Germany – Foreign economic relations. 4. Financial crises – Germany. 5. Labor market – Germany. I.Mody, Ashoka. II. International Monetary Fund.

HC286.G47 2013

Disclaimer: The views in this book are those of the authors and should not be reported as or attributed to the International Monetary Fund, its Executive Board, or the governments of any of its members.

ISBN: 978-1-61635-424-4 (paper) ISBN: 978-1-47558-239-0 (ePub) ISBN: 978-1-47552-249-5 (Mobipocket) ISBN: 978-1-47551-671-5 (Web PDF)

Please send orders to: International Monetary Fund, Publication Services P.O. Box 92780, Washington, D.C. 20090, U.S.A. Tel: (202) 623-7430 Fax: (202) 623-7201 E-mail: [email protected] Internet: www.imfbookstore.org

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Contents

Foreword v Christian Kastrop Preface ix Ashoka Mody

1 Tests of German Resilience ...... 1 Fabian Bornhorst and Ashoka Mody The Postwar Catch-Up ...... 3 The Slowdown ...... 5 Reemergence ...... 9 The Great Recession...... 19 References ...... 32 2 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters ...... 35 Martin Schindler Introduction ...... 35 Background: Concepts and Related Literature ...... 38 Methodology and Results ...... 41 Germany’s Growth Sources through a Growth Accounting Lens...... 47 Conclusion ...... 50 References ...... 51 Appendix ...... 52 3 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective ...... 55 Hélène Poirson Introduction ...... 55 German and United States Productivity: Stylized Facts ...... 60 An Industry Perspective ...... 64 Conclusion ...... 72 References ...... 73 Appendix ...... 76 4 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market? ..... 77 Martin Schindler Introduction ...... 77 Background ...... 78 Recent Developments ...... 80 Understanding German Labor Market Dynamics ...... 85 Conclusion ...... 92 References ...... 94 Appendix ...... 96

iii

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution iv Contents

5 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery ...... 97 Hélène Poirson and Sebastian Weber Introduction ...... 97 Growth Linkages and Spillovers: Related Literature ...... 100 Empirical Approach ...... 105 Results ...... 109 Channels of Growth Spillover Transmission ...... 123 Conclusion ...... 130 References ...... 131 Appendix ...... 133

6 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter? ...... 149 Anna Ivanova and Sebastian Weber Introduction ...... 149 Literature ...... 151 Framework...... 155 Results ...... 158 Conclusion ...... 186 References ...... 187 Appendix ...... 189

7 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Difference? ...... 199 Anna Ivanova Introduction ...... 199 Literature Review ...... 202 Baseline Model...... 205 Structural Policies and the Current Account ...... 208 Long-Standing Structural Differences and the Current Account ...... 212 Interaction of Structural Factors and Fundamentals ...... 215 Implications for Germany ...... 217 Conclusion ...... 220 References ...... 221 Appendix ...... 223

8 Discussion ...... 239 Comment on Chapters 2 and 3 ...... 239 Malte Hübner Comment on Chapter 4 ...... 242 Werner Eichhorst Comment on Chapter 5 ...... 247 Felix Hüfner Comment on Chapter 7 ...... 252 Carsten-Patrick Meier References ...... 256

About the Contributors ...... 257

Index ...... 261

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Foreword

Germany in its postwar history has a remarkable economic story to tell, not just about success but also about failure, about ground won and lost. The successful post-war recovery, although driven by a clear free-market confession, has also been part of the German policy approach of Ordnungspolitik, which includes a clear commitment to economic fairness, social safety nets, independent wage negotiations between employers and employees, and strong regulations prevent- ing the misuse of economic power in the most economically relevant areas. Then we saw a first slump, starting in the mid-1960s, due to global develop- ments, such as the crises in the coal and steel industries and the loss of the Bretton Woods currency regime at the end of the decade. The slump was prolonged by home-made problems, not least when trying to keep non-competitive sectors alive with high subsidies. Today coal is still active in Germany despite high production costs, and nobody knows if all plants really will be shut down as planned at the end of this decade. Renewables, also heavily subsidized, might not do the trick alone after the closing of all nuclear power plants soon after the Fukushima event. The 1970s brought more trouble with the oil and wage shocks, and they saw the failure of an anti-cyclic macro policy that was also (mis-)used as a tool for goodies of all kind; the cyclical deficits were never paid back in the good times. Last but not least, the decade saw the huge build-up of an over-generous social safety net, at first supported by high growth and stable population figures but soon becoming fragile as birth rates and potential growth rates began shrinking— something that has continued to this day. And the issue hasn’t left us to this day: the question of how to push potential growth is still the most relevant. The 1970s also, as a result, had to manage a level of deficit never seen until the late 1960s, driven by following the new gross investment “(‘golden’) fiscal deficit rule”: that is, the Keynesian-motivated new debt rule, which replaced the old conservative rule that required any deficit to be repaid by revenues created through investment. The new, weakened focus of indirect repayment through growth and taxes, while it may not be completely wrong in economic terms, proved to be a seed of failure. It too could easily be misused, not only as an instru- ment of political compromise of any incoming new term of legislation but also during economic downturns, when cyclically short-term-communicated deficits “surprisingly” turned out to be structural—the classic TTT (timely, temporary, targeted) mistake mentioned in every economic textbook. The 1980s started with stagflation and debt that had already accumulated quite high and grew further in spite of the changing tide of economic thinking in the direction of neoclassical/monetarist concepts (Phillips-Curve and rational expectations) which—at least in communication—were reflected in the political economy, where non-Keynesian/Ricardian effects were heralded, culminating in statements like, “The economics driven by rational behavior needs no macro.”

v

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution vi Foreword

Nevertheless, despite the strong wording, Germany did not really take up the supply-side economy concept and almost completely missed the structural/social reform period of the 1980s that many other European countries entered, such as the Netherlands and Scandinavia. One cushion Germany had at that time was the relatively favorable export side of its economy, even though the deutsche mark slowly but steadily appreciated, taxing away part of gained competitiveness and making structural reforms even more pressing. Before the situation grew too serious, unification brought a big boom. It was construction-driven, and while it did not lead to a general bubble it led to huge overcapacities, which lowered growth in the second half of the decade. The boom wiped the structural reform agenda off the political Top Ten list. Because of its complex and sophisticated system of (federal) checks and balances, therefore politically somewhat “slow,” Germany’s federal government had to spend its lim- ited available political capital on unification, leaving no room for other issues. Seen from outside, it might have been possible to use unification as a catalyst for reform, but the political economy could never deliver. Political capacity was bound by and led to short-term solutions based on already endangered social systems and even higher debt, instead of fundamental reforms and a tax-based financing of unification. The mid-1990s saw Germany taking over Europe’s “red lantern” on economic indicators. The “German Disease” was on the front pages of tabloids and The Economist. The late 1990s brought changes: wage developments were continuously mod- erated, both specialized SMEs and big industries cleared their books, and profits went up. The supply side won, the demand side lost. The nucleus of the next export boom was born, as German SMEs became the little champions offering emerging markets the technology they needed. Adding to that were Social Security and labor market reforms, tax relief for corporates, and a whole program for renovating Germany, even if, as measured against the bold proposals of economists, the program didn’t look so convincing and was heavily blurred by political compromise at the time of design. But time would show that it was not just the German overperformance but also the underperformance of competing countries (and therefore a no-longer- appreciating currency) that did the trick for the new German economic (export) miracle. For the average German, the crisis of 2008 and the years following—the worst world crisis since the 1930s—was and still is something he would watch with some surprise on television, but it never came closer. And this time Germany was lucky, with a well designed macro-strategy that also delivered on the psycho- logical side and was firmly anchored by the new fiscal rule, the so-called “debt brake.” It was quite a new experience, too, one never seen in the decades before, when the typically pessimistic but now optimistic (over-optimistic?) Germans kick-started lagging internal demand and consumption at the height of the crisis. This book on Germany by Ashoka Mody and current and former IMF and internationally regarded experts is one of the most detailed reviews of recent German economic history. It not only offers an excellent empirical analysis based

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Foreword vii on long-term developments but frames that analysis in the context of our actual post-crisis, globalized world. It points clearly at Germany’s successes, but it also points out the remaining weaknesses as well as those upcoming if the reform momentum is lost. Germany has a role to play, not just in Europe but in the interconnected global economy. This should not be forgotten. And that role is not only for its national economy but for the whole region, its trading partners, and its export/ import markets. Germany’s macro- and microeconomic policy does matter, even if measurable spillovers are small. So there is a point in sustaining its reform momentum and not getting lost again on the macro-, structural, supply-and- demand, and all underlying (micro-) factors. Germany indeed should push the structural reform agenda, for example through public investment, reforming the health and service sectors, removing existing market barriers, speeding up research and development, and bridging the existing market gap in founding new-tech companies. It should also adopt family- and birth-friendly policies together with better approaches to migration. Last but not least, Germany should engage in a full renovation of its education system, while keeping its already well working instruments (“dual education”) that pre- vent youth unemployment. And, of course, there is the issue of debt and deficit. The new German debt brake, which now is also enshrined in the European fiscal compact, might move the countries concerned to an adequate soundness of public finance and foster long-term sustainability and the quality and efficiency of public finance as neces- sary complements. The reader might use this book to build up his own picture of Germany. The description and analysis are valuable for rethinking different policy approaches, and for reaching the best solutions (or perhaps the second- or third-best, as poli- ticians of all stripes will most naturally and legitimately ensure) to current and upcoming problems, including the next “black swan” problems, in a world that is interconnected and leveraged. It is my hope that the authors of this book keep an open-minded eye on Germany and continue to offer analyses and advice, since in Germany as with other medium and large sized countries a more inward look sometimes tends to become dominant. This is no longer affordable in a globalized, interconnected world. Nobody can do better alone, not with the real and monetary market world and not with the public sector. Maybe this is one of the main crisis lessons. All the more, then, do we have to strive for credible, convincing, and communica- ble—but most of all problem-solving—economic concepts and strategies, not just on a national but on an international scale . Christian Kastrop Deputy Director-General, Economics Department, and Director of Public Finance, Macroeconomics and Research Directorate German Federal Ministry of Finance

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution This page intentionally left blank

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Preface

The papers in this volume were written by IMF staff. But at all stages, this was a collaborative enterprise with the German authorities. Early versions of the papers were discussed at the Bundesbank, where critical comments and alterna- tive viewpoints were offered. That consultative process culminated in a major— and unprecedented—conference at the Federal Ministry of Finance during the 2011 Article IV Consultation with Germany. Christian Kastrop made that event possible. For that initiative and for the many vigorous conversations, even on controversial issues, I am most grateful to the German authorities. At the conference, a number of senior German scholars joined the discussions as commentators and session chairs. Their comments are included as part of this book. Thanks are due in particular to the session chairs, Christoph Schmidt, Klaus Eckhardt, Ansgar Belke, and Beatrice Weder di Mauro, who kindly took time to moderate the exchange following the papers. The conference closed with a lively panel discussion. Juha Kähkönen, then Deputy Director in the IMF’s European Department, moderated that discussion. The distinguished participants included Markus Kerber, then Head of Department of Fiscal and Economic Policy at the Federal Ministry of Finance (now CEO and Director General of Federation of German Industry, BDI), Thomas Mayer, Deutsche Bank Research, and André Sapir, University of Brussels and Bruegel. Finally, I must acknowledge with much gratitude the contributions of Fabian Bornhorst in making this volume possible. He was legitimately a co-editor but his modesty has prevented him from agreeing to share that credit with me. I also recall with great affection my many colleagues who joined this venture and many other such intellectual and operational adventures. Ashoka Mody

ix

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution This page intentionally left blank

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CHAPTER 1 Tests of German Resilience

FABIAN BORNHORST AND ASHOKA MODY

In the nearly 70 years since World War II ended, the German—earlier the West German—economy has enjoyed dynamic phases, interspersed with periods of slow, even anemic, growth. Germany’s continuing ability to maintain competitive manufactured exports has been crucial to its resilience and dynamism, but it has not always been sufficient. This dependence on exports as the economic driver of the German economy helps in understanding its postwar evolution, including its recovery following the post-Lehman collapse. It also points to the challenges that Germany faces: the calls to do more for the European and global economy and the risk that the rise of manufacturing capabilities in emerging markets will even- tually wear down Germany’s stronghold. In this introductory essay, we review Germany’s growth record over four phases and sneak a look into the future. • For about a decade and a half after World War II, until the early 1960s, the economy responded spectacularly by making up lost ground. German com- panies exploited their traditional advantage in capital and durable goods production for sale to a growing world economy and also to meet pent-up domestic demand. • In the next four decades—until about 2003—economic performance gradually became less impressive. The catch-up potential necessarily waned and the oil shocks of the 1970s raised costs and reduced global demand. By the mid-1980s, with rising wages, West Germany was losing its competitive edge. The unification of West and East Germany in 1990 provided a short boost, but then the German economy again went into a swoon. • Starting around 2004, a strong global economy, combined with reforms that helped Germany regain competitiveness, provided a new opportunity to German exporters. With success came a historically large current account surplus, which was criticized for contributing to global imbalances. But the growth dynamic was summarily interrupted in early 2008 by the onset of the “Great Recession,” when the collapse in global trade also swept Germany.

Fabian Bornhorst is an economist in the IMF’s European Department. Ashoka Mody was deputy director in the European Department and then the Research Department of the IMF when this chapter was written. 1

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 2 Tests of German Resilience

• The recovery from the collapse has once again demonstrated German resil- ience. German companies deepened their export links to the growing economies of Asia, and policymakers have supported stabilization and growth through measures to maintain employment and a sizeable fiscal stimulus. New challenges have to be faced. Some are not unique to Germany. With its reliance on exports, a high savings rate, and a current account surplus, Germany shares similarities with Japan, to the extent that one country can be like another. Looking ahead, like their Japanese counterparts, German exporters face height- ened competition, especially from Asia but also from Emerging Europe. And as in Japan, a rapidly aging population will imply a smaller workforce and changes in savings and investment patterns with far-reaching consequences. But Germany’s challenges arise also from its unique role in Europe: in particular, Germany’s expected contribution to the European recovery and a resolution of the euro area crisis remain controversial. As this preview suggests, throughout the postwar era, (West) Germany has benefited greatly from its relationship with the global economy, but there have been lingering questions whether the German contributions to global and European growth have been commensurate. From its early catch-up phase, Germany’s formidable export engine has been its consistent driver of growth. But with almost equal consistency, Germany has run current account surpluses, with imports lagging exports. As a consequence, despite the size of its economy, Germany’s ability to act as global locomotive has been limited. Germany has contributed to global well-being in important ways—notably through its foreign direct investment and, in particular, the production linkages its companies have built throughout Europe. Nevertheless, the calls on Germany to do more remain vigorous, especially as the European crisis has persisted. The argument in this book is that the German economy has evolved along a particular historical trajectory that tends to reinforce its growth patterns. The innovative manufacturing sector has remained a consistent source of growth, but it has been heavily dependent on external demand. The volatility of external demand, in turn, has caused German GDP growth to be relatively volatile by the standards of advanced countries. Such volatility has likely been a factor in keeping domestic demand growth—especially consumption growth—at surprisingly low levels. As a consequence, the domestically oriented segment of Germany’s econo- my has lagged. This has been so especially in the production and delivery of ser- vices. In turn, this has reinforced the drive for foreign markets. Looking ahead, a more domestically driven growth dynamic will be good for Germany and for the global economy. The key challenge for Germany, then, is to generate new domestic sources of growth. One recent episode—reunification—raised domestic demand, but that boom proved unsustainable as the economic problems associated with unification surfaced. Labor market reforms in response to the ensuing period of stagnation were a bold response, and have proven largely successful. But much of the gain in competitiveness translated into further growth in manufactured exports and

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 3 current account surpluses. Therefore, despite the notable service sector advances achieved since the mid-1990s, a further broad-based impetus to services growth is required. Absent such an effort, German growth will remain constrained, and Germany will tend to run current account surpluses while playing only a modest role in spurring growth elsewhere. Just as the German economy is similar to that of Japan—dependent on exports, running current account surpluses, and generating limited international growth spillovers—the contrast with the United States is marked. The United States is characterized by more reliance on domestic consumption and, as a con- sequence, persistent current account deficits but high international growth spill- overs. Despite popular characterization of the U.S. financial sector’s casino capi- talism, both the U.S. GDP and its stock market have been less volatile than in either Germany or Japan. In part, this reflects the greater reliance on domestic consumption, which tends to be more stable than exports. But the United States has also been diversified, with innovations in globally leading technologies giving it an edge in productivity growth, especially in the services sector. In the future, Germany will perhaps draw on approaches to fostering innovation practiced in the United States, while also maintaining its greater emphasis on social safety nets, where lessons may be available from the Nordic countries. In this introductory chapter, we step back from the themes of immediate policy focus to provide a broad overview of German economic growth and inter- national connections over the past half century. The intent is to describe the historical trajectory that has brought Germany to its present balance of strengths and weaknesses, and to use that analysis to explore the best way forward. Much of the work underlying this book and its principal policy conclusions was devel- oped for the IMF’s Article IV consultation with Germany in 2011 (IMF 2011). The book serves to present the more extensive background analysis in an inte- grated form. This chapter is presented in four main parts, reflecting the four relatively dis- tinct phases of German growth. First, the immediate postwar period witnessed a rapid catch-up with the United States and, importantly, reestablished its export prowess, which has remained Germany’s wellspring ever since. Second, growth slowed starting in the early 1960s, and the oil shocks of the 1970s and unification in 1990 proved to be particularly onerous. Third, the reemergence from this setback on the back of extended global prosperity was aided by wage moderation and broad-based domestic reform. And fourth, the collapse triggered by the Great Recession and the subsequent recovery have brought Germany to a new phase with new challenges to tackle.

THE POSTWAR CATCH-UP Emerging from World War II, West Germany set the pace for much of Western Europe as it embarked on a remarkable catch-up. A massive reconstruction effort was mounted and the depleted capital stock was rebuilt. Growth in those imme- diate postwar years was in the double digits (Figure 1.1).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 4 Tests of German Resilience

Annual growth 5-year average 12 1973 1991 2004 10

8

6

4

2

0

−2

−4

−6 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Figure 1.1 Germany’s Growth Performance since 1950 (Percent) Source: German Statistical Office. Note: From 1950–1991 data for West Germany. Data prior to 1970 based on different National Accounts methodology and thus not fully comparable.

Aid flowing to Europe through the European Recovery Program (also known as the Marshall Plan) was an important catalyst in addressing infrastructure bot- tlenecks and reviving trade. Germany also reclaimed its historic advantages as an exporter of capital and durable goods. Between 1948 and 1950, the pent-up demand for consumption and investment drew in substantial imports, but exports started growing rapidly right from the start, with exceptionally high annual growth rates (Table 1.1). By 1950, exports had exceeded imports, and the German trade surplus established then has persisted, with some ups and downs, ever since. By 1960, West Germany’s shares of world exports and imports exceed- ed those of the German Reich before World War II (Giersch, Paque, and Schmieding, 1992). Eichengreen (2006) describes this as a period of extensive European growth, with Germany in the vanguard. He defines extensive growth as that which deploys relatively well established technologies: “It is the process of raising output by putting more people to work at familiar tasks and raising labor productivity by building more factories along the lines of existing factories” (Eichengreen, 2006, p. 6). Millions of refugees arrived in Germany and, in the immediate postwar

TABLE 1.1 West Germany’s Foreign Trade (Average annual percentage change) 1948–1950 1950–1960 Import volume 26.8 15.0 Export volume 84.4 16.1

Source: Giersch, Paque, and Schmieding, 1992.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 5 period, internal labor mobility was also high. Nearly full employment conditions were achieved, with the unemployment rate down to below 1 percent in 1960. In reorganizing production and rebuilding the capital stock, efficiency gains were significant and quickly realized. Several factors facilitated this outcome. Not only was plentiful labor available, the workers were also industrially literate—or were readily trainable through the traditional vocational training systems. Such systems met the need of the moment precisely because the challenge at hand was not to build new widgets but to build known widgets in larger quantities with incremental technical improvements in a learning-by-doing process. At the same time, an extensive network of relationship- based banking systems provided the needed patient capital to finance the invest- ments. This confluence led to modest wage demands, which allowed profitable firms the resources and the confidence to invest in their workforce and in growth. Germany was particularly well suited to take advantage of these conditions. Giersch, Paque, and Schmieding (1992, p. 89) write: “Germany’s traditional strength in the production of capital goods paid off handsomely in the 1950s, when these goods were in particularly high demand on the world market. In addition, the change in relative prices testifies to the improving quality and sophistication of these exports goods.” In a similar vein, Eichengreen (2006, pp. 93–94) elaborates: The country already possessed the relevant range of industries, from coal and steel to transport equipment and electrical machinery…. Small and medium-sized firms competed with legions of other small and medium-sized firms, requiring them to price aggressively and reduce costs in order to survive. In turn this rendered German firms highly competitive on international markets. Exports rose from 9 percent of national income in 1950 to 19 percent in 1960. External conditions were also propitious for German recovery. Investment demand was high throughout Europe, aiding German firms specializing in the production of capital goods. The Korean crisis stimulated demand for capital goods worldwide. And just when Germany’s expanding industrial sector began diversifying into the production of consumer goods, private consumption surged across Europe, reflecting rising incomes and in turn helping to sustain the growth of German exports….Investment and exports were the fast-growing components of aggregate demand, and government and pri- vate consumption the slow-growing ones. Thus, while all of Europe did well during this period, Germany did particu- larly well. Other countries that grew about as rapidly included Austria, which had close economic ties to Germany, and Italy. While Germany was leveraging off an established industrial capability, Italian growth was due to the shift of resources from agriculture to industry.

THE SLOWDOWN The precise timing of the shift is difficult to pin down, but the growth benefits of the German miracle leveled off in the 1960s. The indicators are clear. From an average growth of about 9 percent in the early 1950s, GDP growth fell to about 4.5 percent by the mid-1960s (Figure 1.1). German growth, which had set the

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 6 Tests of German Resilience

pace for Europe in the immediate postwar years, now fell below the European average growth rate (Figure 1.2). The rapid process of German catch-up with the United States stalled, and even began a modest reversal in the 1980s (Figure 1.3). The slowdown was to be expected. Growth could not persist at the early giddy levels and, as Germany became richer, the convergence possibilities diminished, while the latecomers started their own catch-up process.

8 10th–90th percentile of OECD economies 7 Germany 6 European economies (excluding Germany) 5

4

3

2

1

0

−1 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Figure 1.2 Growth in a Comparative Perspective, 1970–2010 (Five year average, percent) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.

Euro area rangea Ireland 110 Spain, Greece, Portugal France Germany Italy 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Figure 1.3 Per Capita GDP Relative to the U.S., 1960–2010 (Real per capita GDP to U.S. per capita GDP, in percent, PPP constant prices) Sources: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and IMF, World Economic Outlook. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity. aMaximum excludes Luxembourg.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 7

The significance of this phase, therefore, lies in two developments, both of which contributed to the slowdown but had longer-term implications lasting into the present. First, the gains possible from extensive growth tapered off and a new phase of intensive growth created new demands on German firms. Eichengreen (2006, p. 6) defines intensive growth as “…growth through innovation. A larger share of the increase in output is accounted for by technical change, and less by the growth of factor inputs.” Thus, it was not merely a matter of narrowing growth opportunities but also a change in the character of those further possi- bilities and, hence, the resources needed to exploit them. Second, important changes occurred in the organization of the labor market. The rapid growth drew in much of the surplus labor, and with near full employ- ment conditions, the labor market started tightening by the early 1960s. West Germany went from a state of capital shortage to one of labor shortage, which, despite the pursuit of active labor immigration policies (Gastarbeiter), led to demands for higher wages. Reduced profits implied lower investment and growth. Moreover, as wages started rising, employment prospects steadily worsened during the 1970s. The response to this conjuncture was central to shaping the period from the 1970s through the late 1990s. Dew-Becker and Gordon (2012, p. 17) write: … policies adopted to fight unemployment had adverse effects on employment per capita (see Nickell, Nunziata, and Ochel, 2005). To deal with individual hardship caused by higher unemployment, governments increased the generosity and dura- tion of unemployment benefits. To limit the increase in unemployment itself, they attempted to regulate layoffs through employment protection legislation (EPL). To spread the available jobs across the population, they resorted to legislation favoring early retirement and shorter hours of work, so-called “work sharing.” (Alesina, Glaeser, and Sacerdote, 2006) New headwinds gathered momentum in the 1970s with the oil crises and the collapse of the Bretton Woods system, which abruptly changed the external envi- ronment for West Germany. Much of the industrial world experienced the angst of declining productivity growth as the pool of innovations appeared to run dry. Germany felt the first taste of competition from newly industrialized economies. German growth slowed to an average of 2.5 percent during the 1970s and 1980s. Domestic consumption remained subdued, and as a consequence import demand was low. Despite the greater competition faced by German exporters, current account surpluses continued (Figure 1.4). German unification in 1990 brought further challenges. The integration of the much less competitive economy of Eastern Germany proved to be economi- cally costly and had a long-lasting influence on economic developments. Unemployment increased substantially, and public finances came under pressure. GDP growth in the 1990s averaged just about 1.5 percent per year.1 Unification did bring about a temporary current account deficit because of a boom in pub- licly led investment, and the trade-to-GDP ratio, already on a mild downward path from the mid-1980s, fell sharply (Figure 1.5).

1 That is, about half of the potential growth rate of the U.S. economy.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 8 Tests of German Resilience

10 10th–90th percentile of OECD economies Germany United States 5 Japan China

0

−5

−10 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Figure 1.4 Current Account Balance in Comparative Perspective, 1970–2010 (Three year average, percent of GDP) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.

100 Germany 90 Emerging and developing economies 80 Advanced economies 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Figure 1.5 Trade Openness, 1960–2010 (Value of imports and exports, percent of GDP) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.

By the end of the 1990s, Germany was dubbed “the sick man of Europe.” Growth came to a standstill, and the economy underperformed for much of the early 2000s (Figure 1.6). Despite high unemployment, the institutional responses of the previous decades had raised wages to unsustainably high levels, and for the first time in decades Germany lost a competitive edge (Figure 1.7). Indeed, even as the global economy recovered in the early 2000s, Germany failed to respond, reinforcing the view that Germany faced serious problems. Pessimism about

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 9

Difference between actual and forecast (basis points, right-hand scale) 8 GDP growth 1000 GDP growth forecast (one year ago for the current year) 6 800 600 4 400 2 200 0 0

−2 −200 −400 −4 −600 −6 −800 −8 −1000 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012

Figure 1.6 Growth Expecations in Germany, 1992–2012 (One year consensus forecast vs. actual growth, percent) Sources: Consensus Forecasts; IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations.

4.0 1991–2000 2001–2010 3.5

3.0

2.5

2.0

1.5

1.0

0.5

0.0 Austria France Italy Germany Netherlands Spain

Figure 1.7 Change in Unit Labor Costs, Germany and Selected European Countries, 1991–2000 and 2001–2010 (Average annual percentage change) Source: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. economic prospects became widespread, with growth expectations trailing the actual growth rate for several years into the ensuing global boom.

REEMERGENCE The “reemergence” period, from 2004 to 2008, is a relatively short one, more so when compared to the previous period lasting nearly four decades, which we treated above in summary fashion. Yet this short period is noteworthy because of

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 10 Tests of German Resilience

the rapid turnaround experienced and because, along with the post-Great Recession recovery, it defined the prevailing sense of German dynamism. The transformation not only reestablished the German economy’s strengths but also brought calls from the international community for Germany to play a more active role as a “global citizen.” However, as German growth accelerated following years of secular decline, Germany developed large current account surpluses— large even by its own historical standards. Thus, while it came to be regarded with new respect, it was also caught in the storm of “global imbalances.” The essays in this book reflect on both the dynamics of this reemergence phase and on Germany’s role in the international economy. We focus on four themes characterizing this period, reflecting the break and renewed sense of confidence as well as the significant continuities. First, manu- facturing productivity growth remained solid, and services productivity growth picked up modestly. Second, wage restraint was widespread. Third, global growth buoyancy was key to maintaining export growth. And, to a large extent, current account surpluses were more a consequence of global developments and less of “distortionary” domestic policies. In Chapter 3 of this book, Hélène Poirson shows that productivity performance varied greatly across sectors. Manufacturing productivity continued to grow respect- ably, not just in absolute terms but also relative to international benchmarks. Productivity growth was relatively low in the newly emerging sectors of communi- cations and information technology and was also relatively low in the services sector. These sectoral distinctions are important, because they highlight the challenge ahead. Despite Germany’s manufacturing prowess, the share of manufacturing value-added in German GDP has steadily declined over the past several decades (Figure 1.8). This is not surprising. With the rise of lower-cost manufacturing in the newly industrializing nations of East Asia, manufacturing has played a small- er role in all advanced economies. Germany is remarkable only to the extent that the manufacturing share of total value-added remains somewhat higher than in Japan. Nevertheless, it is salient that Germany’s high manufacturing productivity growth cannot be a dependable source of greater well-being in the future as manufacturing inevitably continues to cede ground to international competitors. In this respect, Poirson’s analysis has an optimistic note. She finds some evi- dence of a rise in services productivity starting in the early 2000s. However, her analysis does not establish a clear trend. And since the Great Recession created so much dislocation, any trend may only be discernible in a few more years. Poirson offers advice that is in line with that of other students of productivity growth: greater use of information technology in the delivery of services and more impe- tus to small and innovative service firms through incubation in higher centers of learning and greater access to venture capital. More controversially, she suggests a role for the government in procuring services with a public-good purpose, espe- cially where that may help establish open standards. The second theme of this period is wage restraint. Wage moderation has become central to characterizing Germany—and hence to the policy measures it must adopt in deference to its global commitments. It is the case that German

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 11

40 Germany Japan United States

35

30

25

20

15 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Figure 1.8 Importance of the Manufacturing Sector, Germany, Japan, and the U.S., 1970–2010 (Value added manufacturing in percent of total value added, three year average) Sources: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and IMF staff calculations. wages have been relatively steady in the past several years (Figures 1.9 and 1.10). Yet, as described above, the restraint followed years of significant wage increases. Thus, even after the restraint, German wages are among the highest in Europe. What is remarkable about the recent years is the rapid rise in wages elsewhere in Europe. The Irish rise is particularly explosive. But wage increases elsewhere in the European periphery clearly outstripped productivity growth in those economies. There is an open question why German wage increases were modest during this phase. One explanation is the introduction of labor market reforms, in

60 140 Average salary per worker 2010 ('000 EUR) 120 50 Percent increase, 1995–2010 (right-hand scale) 100 40 80 30 60 20 40

10 20

0 0

Italy Spain Ireland Austria France Belgium Greece Germany Portugal Netherlands

Figure 1.9 Wage Levels and Wage Growth, Selected European Countries, 1995–2010 Sources: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and IMF staff estimates.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 12 Tests of German Resilience

60

55

50

45 1991 1996 2001 2006 2011

Figure 1.10 Wage Share in Germany, 1991–2011(Gross wages as percent of GDP) Sources: World Economic Outlook; IMF staff estimates.

particular the Hartz reforms, introduced around 2003 in association with a broader reform package to regain competitiveness.2 Posen (2007) concludes that the key reform was the reduced duration of unemployment benefits. This increased the labor supply, with the effect of dampening wage growth.3 In Chapter 4 of this book, Martin Schindler argues, as do Burda and Hunt (2011), that the remarkable stability of German unemployment during the Great Recession was due not just to the work-sharing schemes, discussed below, but also to the longer-term effects of the Hartz reforms. While a proper retrospective of the Hartz measures and wage moderation must necessarily be undertaken elsewhere, two cautionary notes on the policy measures are worth considering. First, Dew-Becker and Gordon (2012) point out that starting in the mid-1990s, similar reforms were undertaken throughout much of Europe. This was in response to the rigidities that had become increasingly evi- dent and onerous following the efforts to protect employment in the mid-1970s. The Hartz-like reforms that were undertaken throughout much of Europe had the broad effect of raising employment per capita. The essays in Buti (2009), especially that by Boeri (2009), indicate that more competition was also a feature of Italian labor reforms, with the growth in the incidence of temporary workers. That Germany seems to have harnessed these reforms particularly effectively is, in our view, due to a second consideration. German firms were facing

2 Slow German growth in the early 2000s, while the world economy was beginning to embark on a new dynamic phase, led to a concerted policy effort to renew growth. After years of political deadlock on key reform initiatives, the Agenda 2010 reform program agreed in the early 2000s led to wide- ranging changes in the labor market institutions, a reorganization of the economy, and changes to the pension system. 3 Posen is less convinced of the effectiveness of other elements of the reform package, including the so-called active labor market policies (see also Jacobi and Kluve, 2006).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 13

increasing competition in international markets and were able to reach an accom- modation on wage demands, much in the manner that occurred during the immediate postwar years. The pressure from international competition and glo- balization forced German enterprises to integrate with (Eastern) Europe and Asia in worldwide supply chains. Such links have been somewhat pejoratively described as the evolution of Germany as a “bazaar economy,” with German companies increasingly engaged in “outsourcing” (e.g., Sinn, 2006). However, this was clearly the way forward, both for Germany and for emerging Europe. Why companies in other countries were less successful in using this opportunity and how the differences in the particulars of reforms and the corporate response played out across Europe remains an important topic for further analysis. With wage moderation and despite the high level of wages, our analysis (see IMF, 2011; and Chapter 7) suggests that Germany’s export engine hummed dur- ing these years because of two factors. First, Germany specialized in a range of quality products that were in high demand during this period and for which German exporters faced limited competition. German firms have specialized in a large variety of capital goods, consumer durables, and pharmaceuticals, and they enjoy significant world market shares in these products (Figure 1.11). Germany was able to hold market share, allowing exports to ride the global trade wave (Figure 1.12). Second, because Germany was unable to gain global market share, German export success depended crucially on global prosperity. Before the crisis hit in 2008, global GDP and trade, in particular outside the euro area, expanded at an unusually strong pace (Figures 1.13 and 1.14), and Germany was well posi- tioned to take advantage of that growth.

12 CHN 10 DEU USA 8

6 ITA 4 JPN FRA product varieties NLD

2 KOR ESP MYS IND POL World market share in specialized World IRL PRT 0 GRC 0 100 200 300 400 500

Number of specialized product varieties

Figure 1.11 Product Specialization and Market Share, 2007 (Product varieties and market shares) Sources: IMF staff estimates based on Standard International Trade Classification 4 level trade data for 2007. Note: CHN: China; DEU: Germany; ESP: Spain; FRA: France; GRC: Greece; IND: ; IRL: Ireland; ITA: Italy; JPN: Japan; KOR: Korea; MYS: Malaysia; NLD: Netherlands; POL: Poland; PRT: Portugal; USA: United States.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 14 Tests of German Resilience

500 World trade effect Increased market share 400

300

200

100

0

−100

India Italy China Korea Spain Japan Poland Greece France Ireland Germany Portugal Malaysia Netherlands United States

Figure 1.12 Decomposition of Export Growth, 2001–2008 (Percent increase) Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: Increase in exports between 2001–08, as percent of exports in 2001, decomposed into the effect of world trade growth and that of increased market share, computed with Standard International Statistical Trade Classification 4 level trade data.

7 EME and DCa US UK Eurozone World 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 −1 −2 1979–88 1989–98 1999–2008 2009–11

Figure 1.13 GDP Growth Rates: World and Major Regions, 1979–2011 (Average annual percentage growth). Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates. a Emerging markets and developing countries.

These developments paralleled the emergence of so-called intra-European imbalances, whose sources and implications have been generally misinterpreted. German surpluses vis-à-vis other European economies grew through the 2000s, and Germany is sometimes called on to reverse these surpluses by allowing its wages to rise faster. Aside from the fact that there are no direct ways in which policy can cause wage increases, the analysis focusing on German policies as the reason for intra-European imbalances does not take into account competitiveness gains realized by countries outside of Europe. Thus, Germany continued to

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 15

16

14 World U.S. Euro area

12

10

8

6

4

2

0 1991–1998 1999–2008 2009–2011

Figure 1.14 Import Growth Rates, World, U.S., and Euro Area (Average annual percentage growth) Sources: Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis (CPB); and IMF staff estimates. maintain its traditional exports to Europe, where it was able to fend off competition from Asian sources. But while it continued European imports of intermediate goods, especially from Visegrad countries (Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, and Slovakia), German imports increasingly tilted toward products pro- duced most cost-effectively by China (Figure 1.15), which became Germany’s second most important import partner in 2011, after the Netherlands, overtaking France. In other words, German exports stayed largely insulated from Asian and lower-wage European competition due to Germany’s specialization, but much of

6

4

2

0

−2

−4 China Visegrad Rest of the ESP, GRC, Rest of United countries World ITA, IRL, PRT EU-27 States

Figure 1.15 Change in German Import Sources, Selected Countries and Regions, 2000–2009 (Change in Germany’s import shares between 2000–2009) Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: Visegrad countries include Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, and Slovakia.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 16 Tests of German Resilience

advanced Europe—including the periphery—faced the new reality of global low-wage competition, including when selling to Germany. This suggests that even if higher German wages were to reduce German exports to Europe, those exports would most likely be replaced by imports from Asia, thus making little dent in the European current account deficits. There is the more complex issue of Germany’s current account surplus vis-à-vis the rest of the world. Here there are two separate questions: First, why did the surplus rise to such high levels by 2007–8? Second, even absent that rise, is the surplus too large by some benchmark? In Chapter 7, Ivanova deals with both these questions. On the first, she concludes that the rise in surplus was mainly cyclical. In other words, there was a parallel increase in Chinese, Japanese, and German surpluses that largely mirrored the increased U.S. deficits. The point she makes is that these shifts occurred over a short period of time and so could not principally reflect structural (e.g., labor market policies, regulation) causes. More precisely, her econometric analysis is unable to attribute the rise in the German imbalances to particular policy choices. Ivanova does note that as German exports boomed, corporate profits rose handsomely but investment stayed moribund. Thus, there was a big increase in the domestic savings-investment imbalance, which mirrored the current account surplus. Corporate profits also rose elsewhere, for example in China and Japan. But in China and, to a lesser extent, in Japan, investment also picked up. Why investment in Germany remained so low during these buoyant years is a mystery, although demographic trends combined with the prevailing pessimism about the viability of the German business model in the early 2000s may point to the answer (IMF, 2012). On the second question—whether the German external surplus is too large by some benchmark—Ivanova does find that Germany’s current account surplus implied by fundamentals is somewhat smaller than its observed surplus. But she cautions that the difference is small and the policy measures to engineer it are imprecisely known. That said, she concludes that measures to raise both domestic investment and employment generation (and hence consumption) would be the right way to go. There remains the longer-standing question of Germany’s low consumption growth. After the early postwar years of satisfying pent-up demand, consumption growth tended to fall along with GDP growth. Moreover, as Figure 1.16 shows, there was an inverse relationship between consumption growth and the unem- ployment rate. In the 1970s, unemployment became a structural problem, and during every downturn until the mid 2000s the unemployment rate rose signifi- cantly, whereas subsequent recoveries did not see meaningful reductions. The depressed labor market outlook lowered consumption growth, and by placing an additional burden on the fiscal sector it limited the scope for fiscal policy to stimulate domestic demand (Figure 1.17). With weak domestic demand, the role of exports in generating growth became particularly important in the 2000s. And, while incomes rose, so did household income uncertainty. Despite GDP growth, unemployment remained stubbornly

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 17

12 05 06 10 07 04 08 98 00 99 03 97 95 85 87 8 02 96 01 88 86 09 10 11 9484 89 93 90 6 83 92 91 82 78 4 81 77 80 79 76 Unemployment rate 75 2 74 72 73 71 0 –2 0 2 4 6 Private consumption growth rate

Figure 1.16 Unemployment and Consumption in Germany since 1971 (Unemployment rate and annual private consumption growth rate) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.

14 Germany 12 West Germany 10

8

6

4

2

0 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Figure 1.17 Unemployment in Germany since 1950 (Unemployment rate, percent) Source: German Statistical Office. high, amplified by the uncertainty over the outcome of labor market reforms. At the same time, the unification shock and specialization of the manufacturing sec- tor toward external markets raised growth volatility. Growth volatility had been lower in Germany than in the United States until the end of the 1980s, but since then it has been typically higher—and even higher than in Japan since the crisis (Figure 1.18 and Carare and Mody, 2010). High GDP volatility in Germany is therefore partly the result of the growth model Germany pursues. Income is volatile, the level of uncertainty is high, saving ratios are higher, and consumption growth is low. These dynamics are

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 18 Tests of German Resilience

4.0 Germany United States Japan 3.5

3.0

2.5

2.0

1.5

1.0

0.5

0.0 1975–1979 1980–1984 1985–1989 1990–1994a 1995–1999 2000–2004 2005–2008 2009–2011

Figure 1.18 Output Volatility, Germany, U.S., and Japan (Average of 20 quarter rolling standard deviation of year-to-year GDP growth) Sources: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and IMF staff estimates. a German unification falls in this period.

reinforced by a longer-standing risk aversion, reflected in relatively high stock market volatility (which has consistently been higher than in the United States) and relatively low short-term risk-free rates (which have typically been lower than in the United States except for a brief period after unification and in the most recent crisis period) (Figures 1.19 and 1.20). Similar factors apply to Japan. Weitzman (2008) suggests that persistent high stock market volatility and low interest rates are a reflection of deep consumer uncertainty about structural parameters of the economy.

35 Germany United States Japan 30

25

20

15

10

5

0 1993–1997 1998–2002 2003–2007 2008–2011

Figure 1.19 Stock Market Volatility (Five year average of the VDAX, VIX, and VNKY) Sources: Datastream; IMF staff estimates. Note: VDAX: volatility index for the DAX (Germany’s stock index); VIX: volatility index for Standard and Poor’s 500 index; VNKY: volatility index for Nikkei index, Japan.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 19

Germany United States Japan 14

12

10

8

6

4

2

0 1980–1984 1985–1990 1990–1994 1995–1999 2000–2004 2005–2009 2010–2011

Figure 1.20 Short-Term Interest Rates since 1980, Germany, U.S., and Japan, 1980– 2011 (Yield on Government paper with residual maturity of one year) Sources: Haver Analytics; IMF staff estimates.

THE GREAT RECESSION Although Germany initially took a big hit, the recovery has strengthened its reputation for resilience. With that success have come new demands on Germany to play a more active role in resolving the problems of peripheral Europe. In this section, we describe the German recovery, the policy measures that contributed to it, the interaction of those measures (especially the incentives for work sharing) and corporate strategies, and, finally, the possibilities and limits of Germany’s ability to help beyond its borders. Four of the six subsequent chapters in this book cover themes that deal with the analysis of this period and the policy approaches that are implied.

The Recovery In the immediate wake of the crisis, the fall in German output was substantial, but the recovery was impressive. The decline in output, at over 5 percent, was greater than in the United States and in France and about the same as in the United Kingdom (Figure 1.21). Only with respect to Japan was the fall less severe. Note that both the United Kingdom and Japan have continued to underperform, as if their initial contraction represented, in part, some longer-term downward shift. German exports fell by 14 percent, and German investment also fell pre- cipitously. However, by the end of 2011, Germany had not only recovered past its precrisis output level but, despite its greater initial fall, the German excess over precrisis GDP was greater than in the United States or France. It is important to recognize that the German output recovery impresses mainly because it compares favorably with even weaker performances elsewhere in the advanced world. Almost four years after the start of the crisis, the German output level is now only a few percentage points above its precrisis levels.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 20 Tests of German Resilience

Japan France Germany U.K. United States 104

102

100

98

96

94

92

90

88 2008 2009 2010 2011

Figure 1.21 GDP during the Great Recession, Germany and Selected Economies (Real GDP, 2007=100) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations. Germany has recovered, but it would be a mistake to characterize Germany as “booming.” The slow pace of the recovery in Germany and elsewhere and the persistent sense of crisis in the eurozone have meant that this period continues to be described as the Great Recession. With respect to employment, the German story is more remarkable. Employment did not fall much and is significantly above its precrisis levels (Figure 1.22). Forecasters, including the IMF and the German authorities, did not see this coming. In mid-2009, when the unemployment rate stood at about 9 percent, the projections were pointing to a continued rise into double-digit rates. In retrospect, the German performance is noteworthy not only in com- parative terms (with other major advanced economies still struggling well below their precrisis employment levels) but also in absolute terms; the gain in employ- ment relative to that before the crisis is a major achievement. Three factors stand out in explaining the German recovery. First, active and coordinated policy measures taken across the globe were crucial in preventing a free fall and fostering a resumption of growth. Eichengreen and O’Rourke (2010) highlight the fact that the initial output collapse in what was subse- quently dubbed the Great Recession was, in fact, more severe than in the Great Depression of the 1930s. They attribute the more rapid pace of recovery this time around to a keener perception of the danger of inaction. With the G-20 economies acting in a rare moment of policy coordination to support the global economy, the significantly greater monetary and financial stimulus on this occasion prevented another Great Depression. There was equally a major

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 21

Japan France Germany U.K. United States 104

103

102

101

100

99

98

97

96

95

94 2008 2009 2010 2011

Figure 1.22 Employment during the Great Recession, Germany and Selected Economies (2007=100) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations. effort to backstop the financial sector in order to prevent its meltdown. Germany played its role in the coordinated action, through both its financial sector operations and its fiscal stance. In the financial sector, lifelines were pro- vided to banks through the newly constituted SoFFin.4 Although there were some initial concerns that the German authorities might be reluctant to use fiscal stimulus, the German stimulus between 2009 and 2011 was above the average of that in the advanced G-20 economies and only modestly less than that in the United States or Japan (Figure 1.23). Indeed, as Krugman (2010) pointed out, German government consumption between 2007:Q4 and 2010:Q2 rose at a significantly faster clip than in the United States. It may well be that such expansion of consumption had a greater multiplier effect than the tax cuts did in the United States.5

4 The Sonderfonds Finanzmarktstabilisierung (SoFFin) was created in late 2008 to stabilize the financial system by providing bank guarantees, funds for bank recapitalizations, and the transfer of risky assets by creating “bad banks” (IMF 2010). 5 Allen (2005) argues that there has been a historical aversion in Germany to Keynesian demand- oriented remedies in favor of a policy more driven by the goal of expanding the economy’s supply capacity (see also Carlin and Soskice, 2009). Yet, this has also meant a significant social safety net, which provides so-called automatic stabilizers to protect the vulnerable and thereby operates to stabi- lize the economy. Moreover, as this crisis showed, further discretionary stimulus is pragmatically used in Germany, even if it is often downplayed in public discourse.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 22 Tests of German Resilience

7

6

5

4

3

2

1

0

Italy Japan Korea France Canada Australia Germany

United States G-20 Advanced United Kingdom Figure 1.23 Fiscal Stimulus During the Great Recession, Germany and Selected Countries (2009–2011, cumulative, percent of GDP) Source: IMF, Fiscal Monitor, November 2010.

Second, some parts of the world, in particular Asian economies, recovered quickly, and their demand boosted Germany’s exports. China’s investment-driven growth was a major source of world growth (as the advanced world struggled) and played directly to Germany’s strength. Chinese imports of German goods ranged from cars to high-speed rail. And although the Chinese share of German exports was small before the crisis, its incremental contribution to German exports during the recovery phase was substantial (Figure 1.24). China advanced to become

50 Total exports Exports to China 40

30

20

10

0

−10

−20

−30 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Figure 1.24 Growth of German Exports to China, 2005–2011 (Average annual percentage change) Sources: Deutsche Bundesbank; and IMF staff estimates.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 23

180 Private consumption 170 Employment 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 19952000 2005 2010

Figure 1.25 Employment and Consumption, Germany, 1970–2011 (Levels, 1970=100 and 1991=100) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.

Germany’s sixth most important export destination country in 2010, almost on par with the United Kingdom and Italy. Finally, the labor market played a key role. Its resilience is important in itself—both for minimizing the social costs and for the consumption gains it brought to support the economy. However, looking ahead, the strength of the consumption trends remains unclear. The recovery has been driven primarily by exports, especially to areas beyond the eurozone. In turn, exports have pulled up investment. The steadiness of employment notwithstanding, the contribution of consumption to growth has been erratic from quarter to quar- ter; over the period 2009–2012:Q2 it has been about 30 percent. This is not a surprise. As Figure 1.25 shows, the relationship between employment and consumption growth has weakened since reunification. Note also from Figures 1.18 and 1.20 that GDP and stock market volatility have risen sharp- ly during the Great Recession, with the United States still the lowest, and Germany and Japan maintaining their historically higher uncertainty. Thus, while incomes have grown, so has uncertainty, with the net effect yet to be resolved.

Labor Market Performance The factors behind the strength of Germany’s labor market are discussed in this volume by Schindler (Chapter 4). He concludes that the outcome is a mix of at least four different factors. First, much attention has been paid to government subsidies to maintain employment while reducing the number of hours worked. In Germany, this was implemented through the Kurzarbeit scheme. When the

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 24 Tests of German Resilience

crisis hit, the government increased both the duration and the coverage of subsidies. This allowed work to be shared and human capital to be maintained.6 Boeri and Bruecker (2011) point out that similar approaches were adopted in a number of countries, but with less success. They argue that complementary institutions are needed to make this policy effective, pointing especially to employment protection legislation and collective bargaining. Schindler, in Chapter 4, points to a second factor. He notes that the strategy and response of German firms was important. Firms and workers had prior agreements that they could deviate from collectively bargained work arrangements to avoid lay- offs, and introduced work-time accounts at the firm level. For workers in the core labor market, this was a reasonable approach: in the face uncertainty in export markets, they opted for job security and flexibility at the firm level. Thus, work-sharing schemes were already a part of the relationship between German firms and their workers. Burda and Hunt (2011) note, moreover, that because workers had credits on these accounts, firing them in the midst of the downturn would have required compensating them for the credits. In this set- ting, the subsidies were helpful in reinforcing the preexisting contractual rela- tionship. Third, as Schindler concludes in Chapter 2, for Germany the Great Recession was mainly an external export shock, not a supply shock. Despite the uncertainty, firms largely saw this as a temporary shock and relied on accumu- lated work time and short work schemes instead of layoffs. With the recovery, this judgment was vindicated. Burda and Hunt (2011) argue that the precrisis expansion of exports was viewed by firms as temporary, so firms held back their hiring—this is consistent with the relatively low level of corporate investment in the boom years, as Ivanova has noted. Thus, firms did not have as much of a need to fire people. Looking beyond the near term, Schindler in Chapter 4 suggests that German unemployment had begun a secular downward trend prior to the cri- sis, possibly triggered by the Hartz reforms. The evidence for this conclusion is still preliminary, although it is plausible since these reforms increased labor flexibility both among the core work force and also at its margins. Once again, it helps to look beyond Germany. As noted above, other European countries adopted similar labor market reforms in the mid-1990s. Boeri (2009) finds that similar reforms to the Italian labor market led to favorable labor market responses in that country: he estimates that the level of unemployment consis- tent with non-accelerating inflation came down. However, Boeri goes on to argue that Italian firms’ essential lack of dynamism implied that employment did not respond in meaningful numbers. Here again, Germany’s historical strengths and corporate-labor relationships distinguish it from other European nations.

6 This would be of particular importance if skilled labor was in short supply. In chapter 3 of this vol- ume, Schindler notes that the firms’ more intensive use of the core labor force, combined with an adjustment in the temporary workforce (typically less skilled) is consistent with such considerations.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 25

Germany’s International Role Germany’s economic size and its recovery from the Great Recession have led to calls for more German support to global growth, especially to the euro area. We do not deal here with the broader issues of euro area governance and financial arrangements to support “bailouts.” Rather, our focus is on the specific role that German economic policy can play in fostering growth and stability in the euro- zone. In this context, three sets of issues arise7: • Germany as a growth “locomotive,” • German fiscal policy as stimulus for Europe, and • The support provided to peripheral nations through the Target 2 system. Germany’s ability to act as either a global or even a European locomotive is limited. This follows from the theme that this essay has developed, namely, that German growth has itself depended to a large extent on global growth. While there is some optimism that growth will become more domestically driven with structural improvements in the labor market, the evidence for that, as discussed above, is at best preliminary. For a nation to act as a growth locomotive for others, it must originate growth impulses. This, in essence, is the finding of Hélène Poirson and Sebastian Weber in Chapter 5 of this vol- ume. Growth spillovers from Germany to the rest of the world remain limited because domestically originated growth is limited. Rather, Germany acts as a transmitter of global trade impulses, mainly from the United States and Asia to Europe. German supply chains that seek inputs for the delivery of Germany’s own exports extend to its eastern trading partners. But these supply chains are set in motion by demand that predominantly originates outside of Europe. For Germany to assume more of a locomotive role would require autonomous sources of demand from within the country. There are no easy policy steps to achieve this outcome. Ultimately, efforts to raise German growth potential in a manner that raises labor participation and emphasizes the production and deliv- ery of services are likely to raise both German economic welfare and the contribu- tion to global growth. But what if Germany used its fiscal space to stimulate demand for goods and services produced in the periphery? Would that not provide much needed tempo- rary relief? The answer is, in principle, yes. However, Anna Ivanova and Sebastian Weber in Chapter 6 of this volume conclude that the quantitative effect would be small. Spillovers from an activist fiscal policy in Germany to the periphery are small, because trade links are weak. The chapter shows that the arithmetic works against fiscal spillovers, because the quantitative effect is further reduced if the German domestic multiplier is less than one, and is further diluted since only a

7 We have addressed above the issue of intra-European imbalances. As noted, a policy that weakens German competitiveness may reduce German surpluses but not necessarily improve the current account positions of the peripheral countries.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 26 Tests of German Resilience

800 Germany Netherlands

600 Belgium France Italy Greece, Ireland, and Portugal 400 Finland Luxembourg 200

0

−200

−400 Jan 05 Jan 06 Jan 07 Jan 08 Jan 09 Jan 10 Jan 11 Jan 12

Figure 1.26 Target 2 Balances, Germany and Selected Euro Area Countries, 2005– 2012 (EUR billion) Sources: IFS; National Central Banks; and staff estimates.

share of domestic spending is diverted to imports, of which only a small share benefits the periphery. While support to European growth, either through general economic activity or through fiscal policy, is likely to be limited, as part of the Eurosystem Germany has somewhat unwittingly played an important role in providing financial stability and hence preventing a more serious growth col- lapse. This has occurred through the so-called Target 2 system. Target bal- ances are the mechanism through which national central banks within the Eurosystem lend to each other. Target positions are intended to smooth over temporary liquidity needs of the member countries, and the system has typically been close to balance. Since 2007, however, imbalances have grown steadily, and as of this writing Germany has a large creditor position (Figure 1.26), while a number of countries have become net debtors (Bornhorst and Mody, 2012). In effect, as the crisis deepened, capital flows in the eurozone reversed. The creditor countries (especially Germany and the Netherlands) opted not to roll over their financial exposure to much of the rest of the eurozone (especially to the most stressed economies), including to the cross-border interbank market. This was yet more evidence that the flows in the first place had not generated productive investments. The process gained momentum in the fall of 2011, and with the debtor nations unable to meet these repatriation obligations, the only vent to ease what would have been unbearable pressure was the ECB’s Target 2 system (Figures 1.27 and 1.28). Essentially, the ECB mediated excess balances in the creditor central banks to banking systems of the stressed economies.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 27

600 Financial flows ex target (+ outflow) Change in target claims (+ increase) 400 Current account

200

0

−200

−400 2005:Q1 2006:Q1 2007:Q1 2008:Q1 2009:Q1 2010:Q1 2011:Q1 2012:Q1

Figure 1.27 Current and Financial Account of Germany, Finland, and the Netherlands since 2005 (Billions of euros, rolling four quarter sum) Sources: Haver Analytics; IFS; IMF staff calculations.

600 Financial flows ex target (+ outflow) 400 Change in target claims (+ increase) Current account 200

0

−200

−400

−600 2005:Q1 2006:Q1 2007:Q1 2008:Q1 2009:Q1 2010:Q1 2011:Q1 2012:Q1

Figure 1.28 Current and Financial Account of Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain since 2005 (Billions of euros, rolling 4 quarter sum) Sources: Haver Analytics; IFS; IMF staff calculations.

The Emerging Challenges We end this review with a cautionary gaze into the future. We ask two questions. Can Germany continue to assume leadership in high-end manufacturing as the basis for its economic strength? And, how important could the consequences of population ageing be? Over the past few decades, advanced economies have gradually ceded ground in manufacturing to newly industrializing economies. The initial challenge came

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 28 Tests of German Resilience

in labor-intensive products, such as garments, shoes, and consumer electronics, where cheap labor played an important role. But over time, as their wages have risen and their industrial competency has grown, the new competitors have expanded their line of products and raised their quality standards. While the first televisions from Korea came in boxes with Japanese brand names, today Korean televisions can carry their own premium. Similar progress has been achieved in semiconductors and automobiles. The entry of China as the export machine has rendered this process even more dynamic. The gap between emerging and advanced nations is narrowing fast, and know-how is increasingly mobile. Germany has so far warded off this challenge. First, German specialization has been particularly resistant to international competitive challenge. Thus, German producers have continuously built on their strengths to maintain their lead in their product niches. Also, they have recognized the opportunities from the open- ing up of lower wage economies and brought them in as partners who supply various inputs and assembly services. But will this be sufficient? The United States also enjoys specialization in a large number of products, but it has been losing market share in the past decade. Similarly, Japan has been ceding ground in an increasing range of products. It would be a surprise if even the areas of traditional German dominance do not face stepped-up competition in the next generation. The threat from ageing is well recognized. As this essay has highlighted, Germany and Japan share a number of common features. Japan, however, has aged much faster. As Figure 1.29 shows, the ratio of Japanese over age 65 shot up in the two decades from 1990 to 2010 and now stands at about 22 percent. This has resulted in important changes in the Japanese economy.

24 Germany Japan United States 22

20

18

16

14

12

10 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Figure 1.29 Population Ageing, Germany, Japan, and the U.S., 1990–2010 (Popula- tion over 65 years, in percent of total population) Source: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 29

Recent research (Braun, Ikeda, and Joines, 2007) shows that the single most important cause of the decline in Japanese savings rates is lower savings as people get older. Yet this has not necessarily meant a consumption boom. Rather, even with the fall in savings, Japan has experienced subdued demand and deflation. The relationship between ageing and deflation is, of course, more tenuous, but it is presumably related to the shrinking workforce (Figures 1.30 and 1.31). Germany is about to go through a more intensive ageing phase, following Japan. The

40 Percent 65+ 2010 Percent 65+ 2050

30

20

10

0 United States Germany Japan OECD

Figure 1.30 Population Ageing, Germany, U.S., Japan and the OECD, 2010–2050 (Population over 65, in percent of total population) Source: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Labour Force and Demographic Database, 2010.

250 Forecast France

Japan Germany 200 UK US

150

100

50 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050

Figure 1.31 Working-Age Population, Germany and Selected Countries, 1950 to Present and Projected (1950=100) Source: United Nations.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 30 Tests of German Resilience

10th–90th percentile of OECD economies Germany

80 Nordic economies (DNK, FIN, SWE, NOR) Average 75 70 65 60 55 50 45 40 35 30 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Figure 1.32 Female Labor Force Participation, Germany and Nordic and OECD Countries, 1970–2010 (18–64 years old, percent) Sources: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and IMF staff estimates.

10th–90th percentile of OECD economies GermanyGermany

Nordic economies (DNK, FIN, SWE, NOR) AverageAverage 9090

8585

8080

7575

7070 1970197019751975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Figure 1.33 Male Labor Force Participation, Germany and Nordic and OECD Countries, 1970–2010 (18–64 years old, percent) Sources: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and IMF staff estimates.

pressures are rising as the population ages, and migration, even by the most opti- mistic scenarios, cannot fill the emerging gap in the working-age population. This will call for policies, possibly following the Nordic model, directed toward increasing the labor force participation especially of women (Figure 1.32 and 1.33). This in turn implies adjustments to effective tax rates to enhance female labor supply along with supportive child care policy.

Conclusion: Germany in an Interconnected World Despite economic ups and downs, Germany has held a commanding position in the global economy over the past half century. This position primarily reflects

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 31 an industrial strength that has been tested in global competition over decades and has proven resilient to severe setbacks. Most recently, the period after German unification saw the economy in doldrums with seemingly intractable high unemployment rates. Yet the German economy has continually displayed a capacity to regenerate itself. Its emergence from the Great Recession—and espe- cially the ability to generate jobs—has been widely, and rightly, lauded. In turn, this resilience is due to a network of innovative firms that have adapted to global changes, for example through increased sourcing from Eastern Europe and exploiting new market opportunities in Asia. It is also due to the ability of firms and labor to find common ground. Finally, it is due to a pragmatic bent in policymaking. Following World War II, Germany experienced a particularly robust reconstruction phase. This was followed by an extended period of slowing growth. First, there was a natural slowing after the rapid postwar catch-up. Then the external shocks of rising oil prices and the collapse of the Bretton Woods system caused further deceleration. The unification episode was unique to Germany. After a short-lived unification boom in the early 1990s, growth fell again. When in the 1990s the world economy began a new expan- sion phase, the German economy appeared ill-prepared to take advantage of the favorable environment. But by the mid-2000s, economic reform and corporate and labor responses to the changed circumstances led to a German reemergence. Since then, the German economy has displayed considerable strength and maturity, not least by robustly navigating the crisis of 2008–9. In particular, German employment levels weathered the recent crisis surpris- ingly well. With its success, Germany has been called on to assist the global recovery, questions about its current account surplus have resurfaced, and Germany’s wage moderation and proposed pace of fiscal consolidation following the recovery from the 2008–9 crisis have, at times, been regarded with concern. However, while proposals for more rapidly raising German wages or delaying fiscal con- solidation have a plausibility, a closer examination suggests that they could com- promise German strengths with dubious short-term stimulative value for other countries. The real German challenge is to strengthen its areas of weakness. Although significantly down from their peak levels, unemployment rates remain elevated, including when judged by Germany’s own past history. These high rates, along with the emergence of relatively low-paying and temporary jobs, also act as a drag on German consumption growth. The key is to counteract medium-term growth constraints in a way that also supports sustainable rebalancing via higher domestic demand growth. Meeting this challenge will require a new generation of pragma- tism in policy decisions. A greater emphasis is needed on innovation that extends Germany beyond its traditional manufacturing strengths and on a new model of social safety nets, drawing possibly on the Nordic experience, to increase labor force participation needed to counter rapid ageing. Such actions would also be good for Europe and the global economy.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 32 Tests of German Resilience

REFERENCES Alesina, Alberto F., Edward L. Glaeser, and Bruce Sacerdote, 2006, “Work and Leisure in the U.S. and Europe: Why So Different?” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2005, ed. by Mark Gertler and Kenneth Rogoff (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press), pp. 1–100. Allen, Christopher S., 2005, “Ordo-Liberalism Trumps Keynesianism: Economic Policy in the Federal Republic of Germany,” In Monetary Union in Crisis: The European Union as a Neo-Liberal Construction, ed. by Bernard Moss London (Palgrave), pp. 199–221. Boeri, Tito, 2009, “Comments to ‘Two Italian Puzzles: Are Productivity Growth and Competitiveness Really So depressed?’ by Lorenzo Codogno,” in Italy in EMU: The Challenges of Adjustment and Growth, ed. by Marco Buti (London: Palgrave Macmillan). ———, and Herbert Bruecker, 2011, “Short-time Work Benefits Revisited: Ssome Lessons from the Great Recession, Economic Policy, vol. 26, pp. 697–765. Bornhorst, Fabian, and Ashoka Mody, 2012, “Target Imbalances: Financing the Capital- Account Reversal in Europe,” article published online by VoxEU.org. http://voxeu.org/ article/target-imbalances-financing-capital-account-reversal-europe. Braun, R. Anton, Daisuke Ikeda, and Douglas H. Joines, 2007, “The Saving Rate in Japan: Why It Has Fallen and Why It Will Remain Low,” CIRJE Working Paper F-535, CIRJE, Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo. Burda, Michael C., and Jennifer Hunt, 2011, “What Explains the German Labor Market Miracle in the Great Recession?” SFB 649 Discussion Paper No. 2011-031, Humboldt Universität Berlin. Buti, Marco, ed., 2009, Italy in EMU: The Challenges of Adjustment and Growth (London: Palgrave Macmillan). Carare, Alina, and Ashoka Mody, 2010, “Spillovers of Domestic Shocks: Will They Counteract the ‘Great Moderation?’” IMF Working Paper No. 10/78 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Carlin, Wendy, and David Soskice, 2009, “German Economic Performance: Disentangling the Role of Supply-Side Reforms, Macroeconomic Policy and Coordinated Economy Institutions,” Socio-Economic Review, Vol. 7, pp. 67–99. Dew-Becker, Ian, and Robert J. Gordon, 2012, “The role of Labor Market Changes in the Slowdown of European Productivity Growth,” Review of Economics and Institutions, Vol. 3, No. 2, pp. 1–45. Eichengreen, Barry, 2006, The European Economy Since 1945: Coordinated Capitalism and Beyond (Princeton: Press). ———, and Kevin O’Rourke, 2010, “A Tale of Two Depressions,” article published online by VoxEU.org. http://voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3421. Giersch, Herbert, Karl-Heinz Paque, and Holger Schmieding, 1992, The Fading Miracle: Four Decades of Market Economy in Germany (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press). International Monetary Fund, 2010, “Germany: Staff report of the 2010 Article IV Consultation” (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/ external/pubs/ft/scr/2010/cr1085.pdf. ———, 2011, “Germany: Staff report of the 2011 Article IV Consultation” (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2011/cr11168.pdf. ———, 2012, “Germany: Staff report of the 2012 Article IV Consultation” (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2012/cr12161.pdf. Jacobi, Lena, and Jochen Kluve, 2006, “Before and After the Hartz Reforms: The Performance of Active Labour Market Policy in Germany,” IZA Discussion Paper No. 2100. Krugman, Paul, 2010, “Ever Expanding Government,” September 10 posting in “The Conscience of a Liberal” blog, New York Times. http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/ 2010/09/10/ever-expanding-government/

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Bornhorst and Mody 33

Nickell, Stephen, Luca Nunziata and Wolfgang Ochel, 2005, “Unemployment in the OECD Since the 1960s: What Do We Know? Economic Journal Vol. 115, No. 500, pp. 1–27. Posen, Adam, 2007, “Hartz IV Worked—As Far As It Went,” Op-ed in Die Welt, March 14. http://www.iie.com/publications/opeds/oped.cfm?ResearchID=717. Sinn, Hans Werner, 2006, “The Pathological Export Boom and the Bazaar Effect – How to Solve the German Puzzle,” CESifo Working Paper No. 1708 (Munich: CESifo Group). Weitzman, Martin L., 2008, “Subjective Expectations and Asset Return Puzzles,” American Economic Review, Vol. 97, No. 4, pp. 1102–30.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution This page intentionally left blank

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CHAPTER 2 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters

MARTIN SCHINDLER

While the German economy, with a GDP decline of 4.75 percent in 2009, was among the hardest hit during the financial crisis, the impact of the crisis on its potential output is estimated in this chapter to have been comparatively mild and transitory, with virtually no potential output loss in the long term. This outcome reflects both a more flexible economic structure, resulting from past reforms, and, importantly, the nature of the shock—a temporary drop in external demand. The temporary nature of the shock meant that no large-scale structural shifts in employ- ment were necessary, so employers were inclined to retain workers and adjust hours per worker instead. This incentive was buttressed by policy measures during the crisis, but more importantly also by longer-standing labor market improvements regarding hourly flexibility. With employment levels and, especially, hours, returning to pre-crisis levels, the impact on potential GDP was limited, and the evidence sug- gests that a medium-term convergence of potential output to its pre-crisis trend is likely. However, there is little indication that long-term potential growth will rise above its meager historical rate of about 1.25 percent. Increasing potential growth in the medium and long term will require sustained efforts to reverse the declining secular trend in Germany’s productivity growth and to raise its low total factor pro- ductivity (TFP) growth.

INTRODUCTION Germany’s economic structure has changed dramatically over the past four decades. Until about the mid-1990s, the contribution of external trade to aggre- gate growth—in either direction—was similar to that in most other advanced

The author has benefitted from comments and suggestions by Ashoka Mody, Hélène Poirson, Anna Ivanova and participants at the Germany in an Interconnected World Conference at the Ministry of Finance in Berlin (May 2011), especially the paper’s discussant, Malte Hübner. Roberto Garcia-Saltos, Petar Manchev, and colleagues at the IMF’s Research Department Economic Modeling Unit provided helpful advice on implementing the Matlab code. Susan Becker provided excellent research assistance. 35

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 36 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters

1.5 1971–1995 1996–2010

1.2

0.9

0.6

0.3

0.0 Germany Japan United States United Euro area Kingdom (excluding Germany)

Figure 2.1 Foreign Contributions to Growth (Annual percentage points) Sources: IMF; World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations.

economies.1 Since the mid-1990s, however, the importance of foreign trade in cyclical fluctuations (in an accounting sense) has increased dramatically in Germany, exceeding that in other advanced economies by far, even as its real GDP growth rate ranked among the lower rates during that period. That is, dur- ing 1996–2010, annual growth on average was almost exclusively driven by increases in net exports, with domestic growth contributing a negligible amount (Figures 2.1 and 2.2). The increased importance of external trade also featured prominently during the recent crisis. More so than elsewhere, Germany’s crisis contraction and its recovery were correlated with fluctuations in external demand. (Figure 2.3) In particular, the downturn was markedly different from that in most other econo- mies in that it almost exclusively reflected a decline in net exports: between 2007:Q4 and 2009:Q1, real GDP declined by a cumulative 5.8 percent, of which 5.1 percentage points were due to the cumulative decline in real net exports.2, 3

1 Time-series data exhibit a V-shaped pattern, with the German foreign contribution to growth more elevated in the 1970s and 80s, though still substantially below the more recent uptick in the trade surplus. The increase in the foreign contribution to growth is even more pronounced in relative terms, i.e., the foreign growth contribution relative to total growth. For a more detailed analysis of Germany’s historical growth drivers, see Vitek (2010), which also illustrates the increasing importance over time of foreign demand in German business cycle fluctuations, especially during the Great Recession. 2 Exports of goods and services dropped by over 15 percent in real terms during that period, with the impact on net exports somewhat offset by an import decline of just under 6 percent. 3 The theme of strong external growth drivers alongside relative moderate contributions from domestic sources raises deeper questions regarding their causal connection: has weak domestic demand led firms to focus on external markets? Or has a dominant external sector, e.g., through its increased volatility, led individuals to raise (precautionary) savings and lower their consumption? Or are there unrelated causes for the two? This is an important theme that, however, cannot be addressed in the context of this chapter.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 37

4.0 1971–1995 1996–2010 3.5

3.0

2.5

2.0

1.5

1.0

0.5

0.0 United United Euro area Germany Japan States Kingdom (excluding Germany)

Figure 2.2 Average Real GDP Growth (Annual percentage points) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations.

8 6 Domestic Net exports 4 2 0 –2 –4 –6 –8 –10 France Germany Japan Sweden United United Kingdom States

Figure 2.3 Growth Composition during Crisis and Recovery Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates. Note: The bars represent cumulative contributions to growth from domestic and external sources during 2008:Q2–2009:Q1 (left bar) and 2009:Q1–2010:Q3 (right bar).

The reliance on external demand affects how growth shocks are transmitted to potential GDP. Generally speaking, any given change in actual GDP may reflect either a fluctuation of actual GDP around a stable potential GDP path (that is, fluctuations in demand) or a change in potential GDP (that is, fluctuations in supply), or both. The assessment of what type of shock is the source of the observed fluctuations in GDP therefore has strong implications for the assess- ment of the extent to which potential GDP may be affected.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 38 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters

Building on the notion that external demand has been the main driver of German business cycles—at least since the mid-1990s—the analysis in this paper concludes that potential growth was only minimally affected by the crisis, in contrast to many other countries during the crisis (including the United States) and in contrast to the effects typically associated with past financial crises.4 Thus, the demand shock has pulled down actual GDP, but it has not set in motion firm activities that would substantially alter Germany’s growth potential in the medi- um term, as reflected particularly in the moderate crisis impact on capital stock and employment. Consistent with this, a robust recovery in actual GDP has pulled up potential growth, which has been seen to overshoot its long-term rate in the medium term, making up for the small potential growth losses during the crisis. The key result is that there is likely to be no permanent loss of potential GDP relative to the pre-crisis trend. On a more somber note, however, the underlying assumption of a low long- term potential growth rate of only about 1¼ percent leaves Germany lagging behind many of its peers, especially the United States, which, despite a more severe crisis impact, is set to continue to grow at a faster rate than Germany. Given Germany’s adverse demographic pressures, only continued structural improvements to raise productivity and the supply of labor can lift German GDP to a higher trajectory. This chapter provides some background on the existing literature on potential GDP, including its definition and selected findings; describes the methodology and the main results; and presents these results within the context of a growth accounting exercise that decomposes German growth into that deriving from total factor productivity dynamics, (physical) capital accumulation, and employ- ment growth. An appendix provides further details on the underlying model that was used to estimate potential GDP.

BACKGROUND: CONCEPTS AND RELATED LITERATURE Potential GDP has been defined in different ways in the related literature. Some authors provide an essentially statistical definition, such as Gordon (2008, p. 1) who “uses the adjectives ‘potential’ and ‘trend’ as synonyms to describe the long-run growth rate of real GDP… after cyclical elements of the observed data are factored out by a statistical de-trending procedure.” Others define potential output more conceptually as the full-employment level of output, that is, “the level of output at which the economy’s resources are fully employed” (Mankiw, 2002, p. 246), where full employment is understood to mean that capacity utilization and unemployment rates are at their “normal”

4 For example, Furceri and Mourougane (2009) estimate that financial crises have on average perma- nently reduced potential GDP by 1.5–2.4 percent in OECD economies during 1960–2007.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 39 or “natural” levels. In the latter definition, potential growth is typically viewed as the maximum growth rate that is sustainable without an acceleration of inflation. The different definitions of potential output are reflected in different approach- es to measuring or estimating it. The more statistical definition has the advantage of being easily implemented through various statistical de-trending methods, such as simple averaging or the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Definitions relying on economic concepts require the use of economic models that help to estimate dif- ferences between actual and potential output, often based on estimates of equilib- rium levels of labor and capacity utilization rates. The approach in this paper falls on the side of the latter approach. Applied to Germany, a simple averaging of annual growth rates suggests a long-term potential growth rate of 2 percent annually during 1970–2011 (Figure 2.4). However, the German reunification represents an important struc- tural break—prior to that, annual growth averaged 2.7 percent, while it has been averaging a lower rate of 1.3 percent during the post-unification period. The secular decline in potential growth is consistent with, but sharper than, Gordon’s (2008) estimates for the United States. Based on simple growth averaging between “benchmark dates” (Figure 2.4), Gordon finds a decline in the United States from nearly 3.5 percent in the early 1970s to about 2 percent in 2007–08. Notably, this decline is much more moderate than in Germany—according to these simple estimates, Germany’s potential growth was broadly on par with the United States in the 1970s and 1980s, but is now substantially lower. That said, the analysis that follows in this chapter suggests that this gap may once again

8 United States averages (Gordon, 2008) Annual 6 Pre-/post-reunification averages

4

2

0

−2 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

−4

−6

Figure 2.4 Germany and the United States: GDP Growth (Percent) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; Gordon (2008); and IMF staff estimates.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 40 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters

shrink as the damage that the financial crisis has caused to medium-term potential growth is likely to be more substantial in the United States than in Germany.5 Over longer horizons, such trend-based estimates should conform closely with what would be obtained based on the economic definition of potential output, since on average an economy should not operate at a level substan- tially different from its potential over long periods. Thus, over long horizons, simple trend estimates are likely to be reasonable estimates of potential output and can serve as inputs in the type of modeling approach used here to anchor the estimates. However, as shown below, more substantial differences often arise over shorter frequencies, where atheoretical methods may be unable to sufficiently differentiate between changes in actual output and changes in potential output. A number of studies have examined potential output in Germany. Based on a production function methodology, De Masi (1997) estimates potential growth in Germany at 2.25–2.5 percent, which is consistent with the long-term growth rate reported above, given her 1980–1997 sample. Also following a production- function approach and considering the 1986–2003 time period, Baghli, Cahn and Villetelle (2006) find a secular decline in potential growth rates in Germany, although their post-unification average of about 1.9 percent is somewhat higher than the average calculated above, reflecting the absence of post-2003 data, especially the low growth rates until 2005 and the more recent crisis (see also Cahn and Saint-Guilhem, 2007). That potential output growth estimates are subject to considerable uncertainty is exemplified by Horn, Logeay, and Tober (2007) who find, for various versions of their model, annual potential growth rates during 2006–2010 of 2.4, 2.1 and 1.3 percent, respectively, owing to dif- ferent assumptions on total factor productivity (TFP) dynamics and the level of the NAIRU.6 At the lower end are both the Sachverständigenrat (2011) and Deutsche Bank Research (2011) studies, which find potential growth to be on the order of 1.25 percent, at least starting in 2000 (and about 1.5 percent during the 1990s).7

5 The notion that Germany’s potential output held up well during the crisis but lags from a longer- term perspective also holds in a broader cross-country comparison. For example, as the discussion in Section D of this chapter indicates, German potential GDP growth from 2000 until the onset of the crisis fell behind that of the United States, the United Kingdom, Japan, and the Euro Area as a whole. As also shown there, TFP growth, the main driver of a country’s long-term growth potential, is low in Germany compared to other OECD economies. 6 Also, while Horn, Logeay and Tober (2007) utilize data dating back to 1970, they do not explicitly model a structural break at the time of reunification. (NAIRU = Non-Accelerating-Inflation Rate of Unemployment). 7 Consistent with the main message of this chapter, both Sachverständigenrat (2011) and Deutsche Bank Research (2011) expect potential growth to be little affected by the crisis. El-Shagi (2011) comes to a similar conclusion.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 41

TABLE 2.1 Model Input Data Variable Description Source Real GDP Gross Domestic Product (SA/WDA, Bil.Chained.2000. Statistisches Euros) Bundesamt Core Inflation HICP: Total excluding Energy and Unprocessed Food Haver (SA, 2005=100) Capacity Utilization Harmonized Capacity Utilization: Manufacturing European (SA, percent) Commission Inflation Expectations CPI percent chg. 6–10 years ahead, interpolated to Consensus Forecasts quarterly frequency Unemployment Unemployment Rate (SA, percent) Statistisches Bundesamt

Sources: See third column. Note: SA: seasonally adjusted; WDA: work day adjusted; Bil.Chained.2000: billions of 2000 euros, chained; HICP: Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices; CPI: Consumer Price Index.

METHODOLOGY AND RESULTS Following Benes and others (2010), potential output is estimated here using a Bayesian methodology, namely, the regularized maximum likelihood following Ljung (1999). Benes and others have produced a template for such a model- based, multivariate filtering technique which avoids some of shortcomings of previous approaches. It also provides a common yet flexible framework in which different countries can be more easily compared. The multivariate model incor- porates relevant empirical relationships between actual and potential GDP, including unemployment, core inflation, and capacity utilization. The model is applied here to quarterly data for Germany from 1991:Q1 to 2010:Q4. For com- parison purposes, some estimates for the United States are also shown. The model is in many ways a standard, reduced-form macroeconomic model built around three gaps: an output gap, an unemployment gap, and a capacity utilization gap. These gaps are pinned down by a number of identifying equa- tions, including an inflation equation that relates inflation to the output gap through a Taylor-rule relationship; an unemployment equation that estimates an Okun’s law relationship; and a capacity utilization equation to exploit the infor- mation that capacity utilization rates can provide in the estimation of the aggre- gate output gap. Thus, to run the model, five standard data series are needed (Table 2.1). The appendix contains a more detailed summary of the main model features, as does Benes and others (2010). The methodology requires taking a stance on prior beliefs regarding a number of variables. Consistent with past economic patterns, a key assumption fed into the model’s estimation is that demand shocks are the primary source of real GDP fluctuations in Germany. As discussed above, Germany’s economy has been increasingly (export) demand driven, and especially so during the most recent crisis. An accurate understanding of potential GDP in Germany must take into consideration these facts.

In the model, the importance of demand versus supply shocks is implemented GU Y through the (relative) priors on the standard deviations of εt (demand) and εt

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 42 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters

Multivariate model (demand) Multivariate model (supply) 7.0 Hodrick-Prescott filter Moving average (12 quarters) 5.0

3.0

1.0

−1.0

−3.0 −5.0 −7.0 1997:Q1 1997:Q4 1998:Q3 1999:Q2 2000:Q1 2000:Q4 2001:Q3 2002:Q2 2003:Q1 2003:Q4 2004:Q3 2005:Q2 2006:Q1 2006:Q4 2007:Q3 2008:Q2 2009:Q1 2009:Q4 2010:Q3 Figure 2.5 Output Gaps Based on Alternative Methodologies (Percent of potential GDP) Sources: IMF staff estimates.

(supply) (see the appendix regarding where these variables enter the model). For example, a prior belief that supply is more volatile than demand would lead the model to assign much of the observed volatility of real GDP to potential GDP fluctuations. Put differently, actual and estimated potential GDP would move in sync, and the output gap would be less volatile. Conversely, if most GDP volatil- ity is attributed to demand shocks, then potential GDP (supply) would remain more stable, resulting in a more volatile output gap. Both the model assumptions and the choice of methodology matter, affecting the results that are obtained. Alternative methods of calculating potential GDP (and the resulting output gaps) include simple filters that take a moving average of actual GDP and methods based on the Hodrick-Prescott (HP) approach (see Hodrick and Prescott, 1981), which estimates a statistically smoothed series.8 Also, within the framework used here, as discussed, different priors on the distri- bution of shocks to GDP (demand versus supply shocks) matter. Notably, with the exception of the fairly crude moving-average approach, all approaches deliver fairly similar results historically—they do differ, however, in their output gap dynamics during the current crisis (Figure 2.5). That is, all atheoretical approaches assign most of the variation in actual GDP to supply variations (i.e., variations in potential GDP) and thus exhibit a similar pattern as that resulting from the multivariate approach with supply-sided priors. Given the nature of the shock that Germany experienced during this crisis, these other approaches are likely to be misleading. That is, not utilizing information on the underlying economics, including especially the nature of the shock, provides a very different view of the evolution of potential GDP than otherwise.

8 That is, the HP-filter does not use economic information in its estimation. It also suffers from end- of-sample measurement problems.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 43

France Germany Japan 12.0 United Kingdom United States

10.0

8.0

6.0

4.0

2.0

0.0 2001:Q1 2001:Q3 2002:Q1 2002:Q3 2003:Q1 2003:Q3 2004:Q1 2004:Q3 2005:Q1 2005:Q3 2006:Q1 2006:Q3 2007:Q1 2007:Q3 2008:Q1 2008:Q3 2009:Q1 2009:Q3 2010:Q1 2010:Q3 Figure 2.6 Unemployment Rates (Percent) Sources: IMF; World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.

The projected potential growth patterns imply virtually no medium-term loss in potential German GDP. The mild drop in potential growth in Germany, com- bined with potential growth slightly above the precrisis trend growth in the medium term, suggests that Germany may not suffer any medium-term losses in its level of potential output. According to the model projections, by 2016 poten- tial GDP should converge with the level of potential output that would have been reached had precrisis growth rates prevailed throughout the projection period.9 By contrast, the sharper drop in potential growth in the United States, combined with model-based potential growth projections that fall short of precrisis rates, implies that the United States may suffer a substantial permanent loss in potential GDP. Even at end-2016, U.S. potential GDP is estimated to be nearly 10 percent below the level based on precrisis trends. The mild potential GDP dynamics in Germany have been mirrored by a similarly mild labor market response (Figure 2.6). A shock that leaves medium- term potential GDP relatively unharmed in both its level and its growth reduces the incentives for firms to shed employment, particularly when such labor hoard- ing is supported by additional policy measures. The moderate and only short- lived uptick in German unemployment partly reflects a shock that was temporary and demand-sided. In turn, the low unemployment impact reinforces the positive potential GDP dynamics: keeping unemployment down helps avoid many of the

9 Using a multivariate state-space model, El-Shagi (2011) reaches a very similar conclusion for Germany and finds “that the crisis mostly opened the output gap and did not reduce potential GDP (as suggested by other models)” (p. 737).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 44 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters

5 Euro Area Germany United States 3

1

−1

−3

−5

−7 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 Figure 2.7 Output Gaps (Percent of potential GDP) Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook.

adverse short-term effects of unemployment on potential output.10 Thus, poten- tial output and labor market dynamics form a consistent equilibrium. By con- trast, the United States appears to have embarked on a different equilibrium path, where a more supply-side shock has led to a larger impact on potential GDP and reduced incentives for firms to retain employment. The different labor market experiences observed in Germany and the United States therefore provide a con- sistent mirror image to their estimated potential GDP dynamics. The robust recoveries in actual GDP and capacity utilization imply an output gap that was projected to be closed by end-2011 at the time of estimation11 (Figure 2.7). Given the fairly stable path of potential output, the drop in actual GDP during the crisis led to a large negative output gap; conversely, the growth recovery implies a shrinking of the output gap, closing in 2012 and remaining near zero from then onwards. Capacity utilization follows a similar path (Figure 2.8). The broad output gap dynamics are similar across most sectors, with gaps in most sectors still negative, though close to closed in some (Figure 2.9). With a still negative output gap, inflationary pressures remain moderate (Figure 2.10). Based purely on the projected output gap dynamics, core inflation was projected to increase only moderately, to about 1.3 percent in 2011, from

10 Job creation is a more sluggish process than job destruction, suggesting some persistence in unem- ployment even after a (temporary) shock has subsided; also, unemployment is often associated with losses in human capital associated with unemployment spells. Both factors imply a reduction in effec- tive labor supply and thus potential output. In “What Does The Crisis Tell Us About the German Labor Market?”—Chapter 4 in this volume—I examine in more detail some of the factors behind the moderate labor market response. In addition to the potential GDP dynamics, past reforms, including the Hartz IV in 2005, were likely contributors. 11 The work underlying this chapter was completed in early 2011.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 45

4 Relative to historical average (1991:Q1–2008:Q1) Relative to pre-crisis peak 2

0

−2

−4

−6

−8 Consumer Intermediate Capital goods Consumer durables goods nondurables

Figure 2.8 Capacity Utilization Gaps (Percent) Sources: Federal Statistical Office; Deutsche Bundesbank; and IMF staff estimates.

25 Agriculture Manufacturing Total Value Added Services 20 15 10 5 0 −5 −10 −15 −20 1991:Q1 1992:Q1 1993:Q1 1994:Q1 1995:Q1 1996:Q1 1997:Q1 1998:Q1 1999:Q1 2000:Q1 2001:Q1 2002:Q1 2003:Q1 2004:Q1 2005:Q1 2006:Q1 2007:Q1 2008:Q1 2009:Q1 2010:Q1 Figure 2.9 Sectoral Output Gaps (Percent) Sources: Federal Statistical Office; Deutsche Bundesbank; and IMF staff estimates. Note: Measured as log-differences between actual value added and an estimated linear time trend. about 0.8 percent in 2010.12 Second-round effects on wages have also so far remained moderate, not least reflecting a still-positive unemployment gap (i.e., actual unemployment above equilibrium). And lastly, aggregate capacity utiliza- tion is set to remain substantially below precrisis levels. However, continued and sharper commodity price pressures do represent an upside risk to core inflation. Based on the model estimated here, the crisis impact on potential GDP is more limited in Germany than in the United States. From a historical (post-unification) average of about 1.3 percent, German potential growth declined moderately to

12 An increase in the output gap by one percentage point is associated with about a 2/5 percentage point increase in inflation.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 46 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters

Output gap Core inflation (year on year) 8 Capacity utilization gap Unemployment gap 6 4 2 0 −2 −4 −6 −8 −10 −12 1995:Q3 1996:Q3 1997:Q3 1998:Q3 1999:Q3 2000:Q3 2001:Q3 2002:Q3 2003:Q3 2004:Q3 2005:Q3 2006:Q3 2007:Q3 2008:Q3 2009:Q3 2010:Q3 2011:Q3 2012:Q3 2013:Q3 2014:Q3 2015:Q3 2016:Q3 Figure 2.10 Germany: Gap Measures and Inflation (Percent) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; Deutsche Bundesbank; and IMF staff estimates.

about 1.0 percent in 2009. However, in the medium term, pulled up by a strong growth recovery, potential growth is expected to move slightly above historical rates, peaking at about 1.7 percent in 2013 before eventually converging back to its long-term rate of 1.3 percent by 2016. By contrast, the U.S. economy is much more closed; and the crisis there originated from the financial and real estate sec- tors, suggesting a domestic supply shock. Thus, U.S. potential growth declined more dramatically, to about 1.5 percent in 2009 from over 2.5 percent histori- cally. In the medium term, potential growth in the United States is projected to pick up to about 2¼ percent by 2016 (Figures 2.11 and 2.12).

3 Germany USA

2

1

0 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015

Figure 2.11 Germany and the U.S.: Potential Growth (Percent) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 47

125 Germany Germany pre-crisis trend 120 United States 115 United States pre-crisis trend 110

105

100

95

90 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015

Figure 2.12 Germany and the U.S.: Potential GDP Relative to Pre-crisis Trends (2007=100) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.

GERMANY’S GROWTH SOURCES THROUGH A GROWTH ACCOUNTING LENS Though the crisis did little damage to Germany’s growth potential, that potential remains low in cross-country comparisons. Germany’s economic potential has sur- vived the crisis remarkably intact. In contrast, U.S. potential growth may be reduced by a significant fraction of its historical rates. Yet, even at reduced growth rates, U.S. potential growth is still nearly twice Germany’s long-term potential of 1.3 percent. What accounts for Germany’s low potential growth rate? The growth account- ing approach, which decomposes GDP growth into that arising from TFP growth, changes in the capital stock and employment growth, can yield valuable insights (See Table 2.2). Building on the estimates by Bosworth and Collins (2003) and applying their approach to quarterly data suggests that: • short-term fluctuations in output are largely driven by fluctuations in TFP (the residual); and • longer-term trends in German growth prior to the crisis have been driven by both TFP growth and capital accumulation. During 1991–2010, GDP grew at an average 1.3 percent per year, of which 0.5 percentage points were due to TFP growth, 0.6 percentage points due to growth in the capital stock, and 0.1 percentage points due to employment growth.13

13 Different labor measures can be used, but do not affect the estimates substantially. When labor input is measured as the labor force rather than employment, its contribution is higher at 0.2 percent, but TFP growth remains at about 0.5 percent annually. Estimated average TFP growth rises to a slightly higher value of about 0.75 percent annually when labor is measured as total hours, reflecting a secular decline in total hours worked.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 48 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters

TABLE 2.2 Decomposing growth (percent, quarter-on-quarter, annualized) GDP TFP Capital Labor 2000:Q1–2005:Q4 0.9 0.4 0.5 0.1 2006:Q1–2008:Q2 4.7 2.2 0.9 0.2 2008:Q3–2009:Q1 –5.5 –6.0 0.5 0.0 2009:Q2–2010:Q2 3.9 3.3 0.3 0.3 2010:Q3–2010:Q4 2.1 1.1 0.4 0.4 Average 1991–2010 1.3 0.1 0.6 0.1

Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: TFP: total factor productivity.

6 5 Staff estimates EU Klems Conference Board 4 GGDC OECD 3 2 1 0 −1 −2 −3 −4

1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

Figure 2.13 Germany: Total Factor Productivity Growth Estimates (Percent). Sources: IMF staff estimates. Note: GGDC: Groningen Growth and Development Centre; Klems: growth and productivity accounts.

These estimates are broadly consistent with a variety of other estimates. The EU KLEMS project, the Conference Board, the Groningen Growth and Development Centre (GGDC) and the OECD are the main alternative sources of TFP estimates. While these measures differ somewhat in detail, they provide broadly similar estimates and are highly correlated.14 In particular, they all point to a secular downward trend in TFP growth that only briefly picked up in the run-up to the crisis. Consistent with our estimates of a limited impact of the crisis on potential GDP, the post-crisis TFP estimates exhibit a sharp rebound15 (Figure 2.13).

14 Differences in a number of variables and parameters can affect TFP estimates, including capital and labor shares and capital stock estimates, with the latter especially sensitive to different assumptions (such as the initial stock and the rate of depreciation). 15 According to staff estimates, TFP declined by more than 5 percent in 2009, but grew by nearly 3 percent in 2010.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 49

1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0

Italy Japan Spain Austria France Canada Sweden AustraliaBelgium Denmark Netherlands United States New Zealand United Kingdom Germany (OECD) Germany (IMF staff)

Figure 2.14 Total Factor Productivity Growth (Average annual growth, 1992–2009, percent) Source: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and IMF staff estimates.

In the medium term, further labor market improvements would temporarily sustain a higher potential growth rate. The downward trend in the unemploy- ment rate that started around 2005, interrupted only briefly by the crisis, may reflect ongoing dividends from the Hartz IV labor market reforms. If so, the continued transition to a lower structural unemployment rate could temporarily support potential growth above its long-term rate of 1.3 percent.16 In addition, higher labor market participation rates and increased immigration could help ease the impact of demographic pressures and further support employment growth (Figure 2.14). However, a longer-lasting increase in the growth potential can only be achieved through higher TFP growth or faster capital accumulation. Germany’s TFP growth lags that of many of its peers (see the discussion in section B). While the United States experienced annual TFP growth of about 1.2 percent annually during 1992–2009, German productivity expanded by only 0.4 percent a year (0.9 percent according to OECD data). (Figure 2.15) Sectoral data suggest that the productivity shortfall reflects lags in investment in information and commu- nication technology (ICT) capital and related innovations, especially in private services (see Chapter 3, by Helene Poirson, in this volume). Higher investment rates could boost both capital accumulation and the adoption and development of new technologies.17

16 See also Schindler (2012) for an argument that the Hartz reforms (which lowered social transfer payments and deregulated temporary employment) had a long-lasting effect on job creation that is still being felt. In particular, in that view, the secular downward trend since 2005 represents the tran- sition to a lower steady-state unemployment rate. 17 High-skilled immigration, in addition to expanding the labor supply, may also contribute to TFP growth. See West’s (2011) case for revamping the U.S. immigration system.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 50 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters

120 USA UK Germany Japan Euro Area 115

110

105

100

95

90

85

80 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016

Figure 2.15 Real Per Capita Potential GDP (2007=100) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.

The importance of productivity improvements is especially pertinent in a long-term context. Given Germany’s declining population, although its potential GDP is set to rise more strongly than elsewhere in per-capita terms, standard growth theory suggests that long-run growth in living standards is driven by pro- ductivity growth. Thus, policies that support TFP to maintain the medium-term improvement in living standards are also crucial in the long term.

CONCLUSION Germany has mastered the crisis well, but long-term challenges remain. Reflecting the nature of the shock and the structure of its economy, Germany has emerged from the crisis remarkably unblemished. However, it is set to return to its previous trajectory of only moderate growth. Raising that growth rate will require policy measures on many fronts, including higher labor-force participation, higher investment rates, and—especially—stronger productivity growth. More recent developments in Germany’s growth recovery also pose some downside risks to the view taken here. The medium-term growth prospects have fallen short of most observers’ expectations, inducing downward revisions of many analysts’ growth projections, including those by the IMF. The absence of a permanent loss in the level of potential output depended on above-average poten- tial growth in the near term, to compensate for the (mild) potential growth slowdown during the crisis. To the extent that lower-than-expected growth also reduces potential growth, potential output might not fully recover to its precrisis trend. Such downside risks underscore the need for further reforms to accelerate long-term potential growth in Germany.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 51

REFERENCES Baghli, Mustapha, Christophe Cahn, and Jean-Pierre Villetelle, 2006, “Estimating Potential Output with a Production Function for France, Germany and Italy,” Banque de France Working Paper No. 146 (Paris: Banque de France). Benes, Jaromir, Kevin Clinton, Roberto Garcia-Saltos, Marianna Johnson, Douglas Laxton, Petar Manchev, and Troy Matheson, 2010, “Estimating Potential Output with a Multivariate Filter,” IMF Working Paper No. 10/285 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Billmeier, Andreas, 2004, “Ghostbusting: Which Output Gap Measure Really Matters?,” IMF Working Paper No. 04/146 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Bosworth, Barry, and Susan M. Collins, 2003, “The Empirics of Growth: An Update” (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution). Cahn, Christophe, and Arthur Saint-Guilhem, 2007, “Potential Output Growth in Several Industrialised Countries: A Comparison,” ECB Working Paper No. 828 (Frankfurt am Main: European Central Bank). De Masi, Paula, 1997, “IMF Estimates of Potential Output: Theory and Practice,” IMF Working Paper No. 97/177 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Deutsche Bank Research, 2011, “Outlook 2011: German Growth Remains Robust,” Germany: Current Issues, February 14, 2011, downloaded from http://www.dbresearch.com. El-Shagi, Makram, 2011, “Did the Crisis Affect Potential Output?,” Applied Economics Letters, Vol. 18, pp. 735−38. Furceri, Davide, and Annabelle Mourougane, 2009, “The Effect of Financial Crises on Potential Output: New Empirical Evidence from OECD Countries,” OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 699 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Gordon, Robert J., 2008, “The Slowest Potential Output Growth in U.S. History: Measurement and Interpretation,” Paper prepared for presentation at the CSIP Symposium, “The Outlook for Future Productivity Growth” (San Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco). Hodrick, Robert J., and Prescott, Edward C., 1981, “Postwar U. S. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation.” Discussion Paper No. 451 (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota). Horn, Gustav, Camille Logeay and Silke Tober, 2007, “Estimating Germany’s Potential Output,” IMK Working Paper No. 2/2007 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Ljung, Lennart, 1999, System Identification: Theory for the User (Princeton, New Jersey: Prentice- Hall). Mankiw, N. Gregory, 2002, Macroeconomics, 5th edition (New York: Worth Publishers). Sachverständigenrat (Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung), 2011, “Herausforderungen des demografischen Wandels,” Expertise im Auftrag der Bundesregierung, May 2011. Vitek, Francis, 2010, “Output and Unemployment Dynamics During the Great Recession: A Panel Unobserved Components Analysis,” IMF Working Paper No. 10/185 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). West, Darrell M., 2011, “Creating a ‘Brain Gain’ for U.S. Employers: The Role of Immigration,” Brookings Policy Brief No. 178 (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 52 The Crisis’s Impact on Potential Growth in Germany: The Nature of the Shock Matters

APPENDIX This appendix briefly summarizes the key features of the model. A more detailed description is provided in Benes and others (2010). The model is built around three gaps—the output gap (y), the unemployment gap (u), and the capacity utilization gap (c)—and three identifying equations: The inflation equation relates the level and the change of the output gap to core inflation:

πΩ=π +β + − +επ4 44tt−−11yyy t() ttt.

The dynamic Okun’s law defines the relationship between the current unem- ployment rate and the output gap. Based on Okun’s law, an unemployment equation links the unemployment gap to the output gap:

=++εu uxuxytt11− 2 tt.

Finally, the model also relies on a capacity utilization equation, on the assump- tion that capacity utilization contains important information that can help improve the potential output and output gap estimates. The equation takes the following form:

=++εc cttk11c − k 2y tt.

Given the three identifying equations, the equilibrium variables are assumed to evolve dynamically as follows. A stochastic process including transitory (level) shocks and more persistent shocks guides the evolution of equilibrium unemploy- U ment ()t (the NAIRU equation): ωλ USSU UU=+−tt−−11 G y− −() U −+ε U ttt1001 100 t

U Persistent shocks to the NAIRU (Gt ) follow an autoregressive process:

U GGUUG=−α(1 ) +ε (1) ttt−1

And potential output ( Yt ) is modeled to be a function of the underlying trend Y growth rate of potential output (Gt ) and changes in the NAIRU. Specifically:

YY YY=−θ−−−θ−t −1 ()( UUtt−−−11201 )( U t U t )/19 + G /4 +ε (2) t tt where θ is the labor share in a Cobb-Douglas production function. This specifica- tion allows for short- and medium-term growth of potential to differ from trend Y growth. Note that Gt is not constant, but follows serially correlated deviations

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 53

Y (long waves) from the steady-state growth rate GSS . Similar dynamic equations are specified for equilibrium capacity utilization. The full model is estimated by regularized maximum likelihood (Ljung, 1999), a Bayesian methodology. This method requires the user to define prior distributions of the parameters. While this can improve the estimation procedure by preventing parameters from wandering into nonsensical regions, the choice of priors has also non-negligible implications for the final estimates as the data are uninformative about some parameters. The choice of priors matters also in the German case. In addition to the prior distributions of parameters, the analyst has to provide values for θ and the steady-state (long-run) unemployment rate (U SS ) and poten- Y tial GDP growth rates (GSS ), which were set to 0.55, 6.7 percent and 1.3 percent, SS Y respectively. While values especially for U and GSS matter conceptually, as the (endogenous) estimates converge to these (exogenously given) values in the long term, from a practical point of view, the dynamics over the time horizon of inter- est are relatively little affected by the choice of the steady-state values.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution This page intentionally left blank

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CHAPTER 3 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

HÉLÈNE POIRSON

Germany had the advantage of a catch-up phase through the early 1970s, but there- after, and especially since the mid-1990s, productivity growth has been relatively slow. This aggregate picture masks considerable intersectoral differences. This chapter reports that while Germany has maintained an enduring strength in its traditional manufac- turing competencies, it has lagged in services delivery and, perhaps more importantly, in the so-called knowledge economy—both in the production of information and com- munication technology (ICT) goods and in the use of ICT to raise productivity in private services provision. These “new” areas have been key engines of productivity growth since the mid-1990s in the United States and some other advanced countries. An uptick in German services productivity growth occurred from 2005 to 2007. This is indicative of the scope and potential for progress, but it could have been a cyclical phenomenon. To foster more efficient production and widespread use of ICT in ser- vices delivery will require complementary measures: (a) further development of venture capital and private equity markets (backed by a more efficient insolvency process); (b) increased commercial use of intellectual property rights held by university and research institutions; (c) removal of uncertainties regarding tax treatment; and (d) further European integration in services provision.

INTRODUCTION In the years after World War II, Germany increased its productivity at a fast clip, thereby rapidly shrinking the United States’ lead in income levels. However, this productivity catch-up was interrupted in the mid-1990s. Between 1995 and 2007, Germany’s private economy experienced annual productivity growth of 1.7 percent, slightly above the European average but lagging behind the United States, the United Kingdom, Sweden, Austria, and Finland (Inklaar, Timmer, and van Ark, 2008, Table 1, page 142; and Molagoda and Perez, 2011, Table V.1, page 70).

For their constructive comments, the author wishes to thank Fabian Bornhorst, Malte Hübner, Anna Ivanova, Ashoka Mody, Martin Schindler, and participants in the Germany in an Interconnected World Conference at the BMF in Berlin (May 2011). 55

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 56 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

BOX 3.1 The Productivity Resurgence in the United States

Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh (2008) argue that the sources of U.S. productivity growth have changed twice since 1995. From 1995 to 2000, productivity growth was led by the ICT- producing sectors and investment in them. Since 2000, the sources of productivity growth have shifted to sectors that were the most intensive users of information technology. Triplett and Bosworth (2006) highlight the role of the services sector. They find that the post-1995 ICT investment boom contributed both directly to higher U.S. productivity growth in the services industries via capital deepening and indirectly via higher TFP growth. Their results suggest that in the United States, both labor productivity in the ser- vices sector and TFP growth rates more than doubled after 1995, and the services sector became the source of economic growth. In a subsequent paper, the same two authors extend the industry-based approach to consider the post-2000 period and find that the services sector again accounts for the post- 2000 rise in U.S. productivity (Bosworth and Triplett, 2007). Both the 1995–2000 increase in productivity growth and the more recent uptick were driven by strong investment that increased U.S. labor productivity through capital deepening and by accelerating productiv- ity (particularly TFP) in services.

This aggregate performance masks considerable sectoral differences—both within Germany and in Germany’s performance relative to other industrialized economies. While Germany’s productivity growth in manufacturing industries was above the EU-15 average from 1995 to 2005, its productivity growth in the information and communication technology (ICT) industries, while strong, has been lagging that in other advanced countries (U.S, France, Netherlands, and Sweden), and productivity in the private services sector has been weak and below that in both the United States and the EU-15. Within Germany, the deceleration in overall productivity growth in the pri- vate economy—from 2.4 percent in the 1980s to 1.9 percent during 1995–2000 and dropping further to 1.2 percent in 2000–05—appears to be largely due to the slowing growth of productivity in private services (The Conference Board, 2009). This contrasts with the experience of the United States and selected other countries over the same period, when productivity accelerated from 1995 to 2005 on the back of ICT’s widespread and quick deployment in many sectors of the economy, especially the traditionally less productive service sectors (Box 3.1).1 Germany’s experience mirrors that of Europe as a whole. An industry-based analysis applied to European countries finds that while the EU-15’s manufactur- ing and utilities performed in line with the United States during 1995–2005, local services—not just financial services, but more broadly distribution and busi- ness services—accounted for the bulk of the productivity growth difference with the United States during that period (van Ark, O’Mahony, and Timmer, 2008,

1 Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh (2004) first highlighted the role of the production and use of ICT in accounting for productivity gains in the case of the United States.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson 57 and Molagoda and Perez, 2011).2 Unlike in the United States, where total factor productivity (TFP) growth in the services sector accelerated after 1995, in Europe it declined (especially in distribution, finance, and business services). Several studies have argued that low TFP growth in the service sectors in EU countries in turn reflects the delay in investing in ICT assets and implementing the related new technologies and processes (McKinsey Global Institute, 2010). These delays have been attributed, among other factors, to the relatively less attractive conditions in Europe for venture capital and other market-based sources of financing for high-growth, high-risk projects (Box 3.2).3 In addition to the availability of long-term financing, traditional explanations for Europe’s lag- ging productivity growth also emphasize policy and institutional factors such as strict regulations in product and labor markets.4 But these seem less relevant in the case of Germany, which is one of the most deregulated advanced countries in retail trade, according to OECD indicators, and where some reforms (e.g., trans- port services deregulation) constitute an example of best practice in Europe. It is true, however, that despite a recent improvement Germany remains more heavily regulated in professional services than most other advanced countries. This study applies the industry-based approach to Germany during the 1980–2007 period to help shed light on the historical sources of growth and productivity trends. We use the best available data on cross-country comparisons of the sources of productivity growth at the industry level from the EU KLEMS database. This enables us to document a pick-up in labor productivity growth in the private economy in Germany since 2005, led by higher TFP growth. This is indicative of the scope and potential for progress. However, it remains too early to conclude that a structural shift has taken place. The fact that TFP is measured as a residual and the finding that the TFP growth acceleration was not accompa- nied by a boom in ICT investment—unlike the U.S. experience in the late 1990s and early 2000s—suggests that the recent improvement may be short-lived and driven by cyclical rather than structural factors.

2 An argument is often made that productivity differentials, particularly in the services industries, are biased or illusionary because of differences in data across countries. The results in Inklaar, Timmer, and van Ark (2006), however, suggest that the productivity gap findings are robust to the use of vari- ous productivity measurement models. A related argument is that the strong post-1995 productivity growth in the U.S. services sector was illusionary because it was the result of an unsustainable boom in consumer expenditure and household debt. While scale effects from increased demand may have played a role in productivity improvements—notably for the distribution sector—the fact that the acceleration in retail output and productivity occurred mainly during the late nineties and early 2000s, whereas the rise in household debt occurred later, from 2003 to 2007, makes it difficult to attribute all the productivity improvements to the credit boom (van Ark, 2010). 3 Allard and Everaert (2010) argue that measures to develop capital markets further in Europe will not only result in the establishment of more attractive conditions for venture capital but also create room for banks to focus more on supporting smaller firms—in relatively large numbers in the euro area; these smaller firms are at a higher risk of being constrained in financing but at the same time are key for innovation. 4 See Allard and Everaert (2010) for a discussion of the role of labor and service market reforms in lifting euro area long-term growth.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 58 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

BOX 3.2 The Slowdown in Europe’s TFP Growth

There is no shortage of attempts to explain the post-1995 weak European TFP growth performance. Several studies have documented that Europe’s lag in adopting ICT technolo- gies in the service sectors and shifting to a “knowledge economy” is a key factor behind Europe’s poor TFP performance (see for example van Ark, O’Mahony, and Timmer, 2008). Empirical research has confirmed the role of “new economy” factors, such as human capital and ICT investments, in explaining subsequent TFP growth rates. For example, Molagoda and Perez (2011) find that a significant impact is made by human capital levels (proxied by the share of high skilled labor to overall labor) and ICT capital intensity (mea- sured by the ratio of ICT capital to non-ICT capital) on TFP growth differences across indus- tries and countries (see also Nahuys and van der Wiel, 2005, and EU ICT Task Force, 2006). Other studies argue that policy/institutional factors (e.g., rigidities in product, labor, and financial markets) have reduced incentives to shift rapidly to ICT and to adjust produc- tion processes accordingly. Using micro establishment level data from the U.S. and Germany, the results in Bartelsman and others (2010) suggest that the degree of market experimentation by firms (i.e., the degree to which firms experiment with different ways of conducting business) is lower in Germany compared to the United States, among both young businesses and businesses actively changing their technology. The authors conjec- ture that this result could be related to the financial system being more market-based in the United States than in Europe, which possibly lowers risk aversion to project financing and creates greater financing possibilities for entrepreneurs with small and innovative projects.a The effect of strict employment protection legislation (EPL) is less clear-cut and largely depends on the institutional system in which firms operate and the type of technol- ogy used in the sector.b

a Voss and Müller (2009) similarly find that financing aspects are a key limiting burden for young German start-ups. Venture capital is hard to access and concentrates on ICT, medical research, medical appli- ances, and biotech. b Bartelsman and others (2010) investigate the impact of EPL on ICT adoption. They find evidence that both the share of employment and productivity levels in ICT-intensive sectors are relatively lower in high-protection EU countries, suggesting that EPL slows the adoption of new ICT. However, they do not investigate the direct impact of EPL on TFP growth and innovation.

Using the historical experience of the United States as a productivity leader from 1995–2004 as a benchmark, our conclusions highlight the importance of raising TFP growth more durably through innovation policy and greater incen- tives for the use of ICT in the service sectors5: • Over 1995–2004, Germany’s lower TFP growth was the single most impor- tant factor driving German-U.S. productivity growth differences in the private economy, contributing almost three-quarters of the productivity growth differential.

5 The importance and cross-cutting nature of ICT is reflected in Germany’s high-tech strategy and, more broadly, in Europe’s 2020 growth agenda, which also notes the link between ICT usage and services’ productivity.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson 59

• Germany’s lower investment in ICT assets was also important, explaining over a third of the productivity gap with the United States during that period. • At the industry-level, the productivity growth differences are driven by TFP and are particularly large for service industries, especially for distribution, finance, and business services. • Productivity lags in the service sectors in turn appear to reflect Germany’s delay in shifting to a knowledge economy, as indicated by a lower share of ICT in total research and development expenditure, lower internet penetra- tion (relative to the United States), and lower ICT readiness scores relative to some other advanced countries. Notably, Germany lags several other OECD countries in some key areas of ICT infrastructure (e.g., availability of secure servers) and financing for high-risk, high-innovation potential projects. The purpose of this chapter is to provide background on the question of why Germany has not enjoyed higher productivity growth, despite several favorable competitiveness indicators, including levels of innovation and spending on research and development above the EU-15 average (Figure 3.1).6 It does so by providing essential facts and placing Germany’s experience in international per- spective. The next section provides facts on aggregate output and growth patterns in Germany relative to the United States (considered as the productivity bench- mark) during 1950–2009. A further section does the same for a number of

Finland Sweden Netherlands Germany Denmark Japan Austria Belgium United States Norway France United Kingdom Italy Spain

0 100 200 300 400 500 600

Figure 3.1 Selected Countries: Patent Applications (Number of applications per million population, 2010) Sources: European Patent Office and Conference Board.

6 See McKinsey Global Institute (2010). Recent structural reforms to support competitiveness include the 2008 business tax reform, the Hartz IV reforms, and deregulation in transport services.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 60 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

industry-level sectors, including goods, ICT, and private services, extending ear- lier work by van Ark, O’Mahony, and Timmer (2008) through 2007. Within the services sector, we separately analyze the drivers of growth and German-U.S. productivity differentials in distribution services, finance and business services, and personal services. The section also documents Germany’s relative progress in adopting a knowledge economy, as measured by a number of variables and busi- ness survey indicators usually viewed as related to higher ICT investments and a favorable environment for innovation.

GERMAN AND UNITED STATES PRODUCTIVITY: STYLIZED FACTS Germany’s postwar productivity catch-up with the United States was interrupted in the mid-1990s. During the period 1950–1995, labor productivity grew at a relatively fast clip, and Germany achieved parity with the United States by 1995. In 1995, however, German productivity growth started lagging the United States, and by 2009 its levels of hourly output were almost 10 percent below U.S. levels (Figure 3.2 and Table 3.1). During 1995–2004, the productivity gap with the United States widened despite higher labor input in the latter country, where the productivity resurgence in the mid-1990s was accompanied by significant job creation. Instead, the pro- ductivity gap reflects both slower capital accumulation and slower TFP growth in Germany. Germany’s overall slower capital accumulation contributed almost three-quarters (74 percent) of the total productivity gap during 1995–2004. In particular, its lower investment in ICT assets—including computing equipment,

120 GDP per hour 100

80 GDP per capita

60

40

20

0 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

Figure 3.2 Total Economy GDP per Hour Worked and GDP per Capita (Percent of U.S. levels) Sources: The Conference Board Total Economy Database, September 2010; Timmer, Ypma, and van Ark (2003); and IMF staff estimates.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson 61

TABLE 3.1 Levels of Labor Productivity and Factor Inputs (Percent of U.S. levels) 1950 1973 1995 2004 2007 2008 2009 GDP per capitaa 43.6 82.5 85.1 77.7 78.9 80.7 79.5 Hours worked per capita 124.8 104.4 88.3 84.3 83.7 83.8 82.7 GDP per hour workeda 34.1 70.2 100.3 94.0 95.9 95.2 90.6 Capital input per hour workedb 83.9 107.9 102.7 n.a. n.a. n.a.

Sources: The Conference Board Total Economy Database, September 2010; Timmer, Ypma, and van Ark (2003); and IMF staff estimates. a Output levels are converted by GDP purchasing power parities for 2009 using the Elteto-Koves-Szulk (EKS) method. b Measured as gross fixed capital stock per hour worked. Entries for 1973 refer to 1980. communication equipment, and software—was the single biggest factor explain- ing the productivity gap during that period, contributing over half of it (0.6 percent out of an annual productivity gap of 1.1 percent with the United States). The contribution of non-ICT capital growth and TFP growth to the productiv- ity growth differential with the United States were also important: the former contributed 0.3 percent (22 percent of total) and the latter 0.2 percent (15 per- cent of total) to the productivity gap. Lower growth in labor skills in Germany relative to the United States explained the remainder (0.1 percent, or about 10 percent of the total). When focusing on developments over time in Germany and the United States, a deceleration in TFP growth explains the bulk of Germany’s weak performance since the mid-1990s.7 German labor productivity growth slowed by 1 percentage point between the 1990–1995 period and the 1995–2004 period, mainly reflect- ing a reduction in TFP growth by 0.6 percentage points between the two periods (Table 3.2). In other words, slower TFP growth accounts for 60 percent of the deceleration in annual labor productivity growth during 1995–2004, with lower investment and (to a much lesser extent) slower growth in labor quality explain- ing the rest.8 Investment in ICT assets in Germany increased only moderately between 1995–2004 and 1990–1995, not enough to offset the decline in TFP and investment in non-ICT assets. In contrast, higher TFP growth and invest- ment—especially in ICT assets—contributed in almost equal parts to the U.S. revival in the mid-1990s. Specifically, the 1 percentage point increase in U.S. labor productivity growth between 1995–2004 and 1990–1995 reflects a 0.5 percent increase in the contribution of capital accumulation (the bulk of which is from investment in ICT assets), accompanied by a 0.4 percent acceleration in TFP growth. This simultaneous acceleration in ICT investments and TFP has been linked to the emergence of a so-called “knowledge economy” in the United States and other advanced countries during the mid-1990s, as discussed in

7 TFP is computed as a residual, thus it also includes measurement errors and the effects from unmea- sured outputs and inputs, such as research and development and other intangible improvements, including organizational improvements. 8 Lower investment in non-ICT assets and labor quality contributed 37 percent and 10 percent, respectively, to the declining trend in productivity growth between the two periods.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 62 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

TABLE 3.2 Contributions to Growth of GDP (Annual average growth rates, in percentage pointsa) Germany United States 1990–1995 1995–2004 2004–2007 1990–1995 1995–2004 2004–2007 1GDP (2)+(3)+(4)+(7) 2.2 1.4 2.1 2.5 3.3 2.5 Contributions from 2 Hours worked –0.4 –0.2 0.3 0.8 0.7 1.7 3 Labor quality 0.2 0.1 –0.1 0.2 0.2 0.3 4 Capital stock (6)+(7) 1.0 0.7 0.8 1.0 1.5 0.9 5 ICT capital 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.6 1.0 0.4 6 Non-ICT capital 0.7 0.3 0.5 0.4 0.6 0.5 7 TFP 1.4 0.7 1.2 0.5 0.9 –0.5

Memo item: Labor productivity 2.6 1.6 1.8 1.7 2.7 0.8 growth

Source: The Conference Board Total Economy Database, September 2010; and IMF staff estimates. a Based on the difference in the log of the levels of each variable.

Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh (2004), Triplett and Bosworth (2006), Bosworth and Triplett (2007), and more recently Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh (2008). In 2005, a productivity catch-up resumed, mainly reflecting a U.S. slowdown. Germany’s annual labor productivity growth accelerated only moderately (by 0.2 percent) in 2004–2007 relative to 1995–2004, as a pick-up in employment offset higher TFP growth (by 0.5 percent) and a higher contribution of non-ICT capi- tal investment (by 0.2 percent). However, since TFP is measured as a residual, the recent turnaround could be largely due to unmeasured cyclical factors—including higher capacity utilization immediately precrisis in Germany. Moreover, unlike in the United States in the mid-1990s, the recent productivity acceleration in Germany was not accompanied by higher investment in ICT assets, which also suggests that cyclical factors might have been at play rather than a structural shift to a more “knowledge-driven” economy. The results discussed so far apply to the total economy, including both public and private services. When public services—including health, education, and other public services—are excluded, the productivity growth gaps between Germany and the United States that emerged in the mid-1990s are magnified and TFP, rather than capital accumulation, explains the bulk of the gap.9 Germany’s labor productivity in the private economy grew at broadly the same rate during 1995–2004 as the total economy (including public services) grew, namely at 1.6 percent (Table 3.3). The acceleration in U.S. productivity growth therefore becomes even more striking when focusing only on the private economy: productivity

9 Other excluded services are public administration and defense. Following van Ark, O’Mahony, and Timmer (2008), we also exclude real estate (ISIC 70), because output in this industry mostly reflects imputed housing rents rather than sales of firms.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson 63 growth in the private economy there rose by 3.1 percent annually over that peri- od, compared to 2.7 percent for the total economy. The U.S. productivity lead is thus especially pronounced in the private economy. Specifically, we find that: • The annual productivity gap with the United States during 1995–2004 for only the private economy is 1.5 percent, compared to 1.1 percent for the total economy (including public services). • Since 2005, the results continue to show the resumption of a productivity catch-up when only the private economy is considered. During 2004– 2007, the German resurgence is more pronounced when public services are excluded, and the U.S. slowdown is less extreme. Both trends suggest that a catch-up process has resumed more recently, although as noted above it is too early to conclude that the overall lag in German productivity growth has reversed, given the importance of cyclical factors over this relatively short period and the lack of a pick-up in ICT investments. • TFP growth drives the differences between the two countries’ private- economy productivity growth rates during 1995–2004, contributing over two-thirds (72 percent) of the productivity gap (compared to 15 percent for the total economy, including public services). The effect of slower investment in ICT capital on Germany’s private economy is also an impor- tant factor, accounting for more than a third (35 percent) of the slower labor productivity growth in Germany relative to the United States over that period (compared to more than half when the total economy is con- sidered). The contribution of differences in the pace of labor skill growth increases marginally (to 12 percent of total) when only the private econo- my is considered.10 • When focusing on developments over time in the two countries, a U.S. slowdown, rather than significantly higher productivity growth in Germany, continues to account for most of the recent turnaround since 2005. Within Germany’s private economy, the pick-up in TFP growth (by 1.2 percent) since 2005 is more pronounced than for the total economy including public services (by 0.5 percent). Similar to the result for the total economy, the contribution of ICT capital accumulation to productivity growth in the private economy fails to accelerate in 2004–2007, unlike the U.S. experi- ence of the mid-1990s, suggesting that recent developments may reflect

10 The overall contribution of human capital would be underestimated in a growth-accounting frame- work if human capital mainly influences labor productivity growth through its impact on TFP growth. Higher education, in particular, arguably has a supportive role in fostering technological improvements and enabling a fast adjustment to new technologies. Using a sample of 13 EU countries plus the U.S., Molagoda and Perez (2011) confirm empirically the significant role of human capital in explaining TFP differences across countries through both its direct impact on innovation by the productivity leader and indirectly by increasing the size of knowledge spillovers. The largest impact of human capital is found for countries at or close to the productivity frontier, possibly because innova- tion is a relatively more skill-intensive activity than imitation. See also Vandenbussche, Aghion, and Meghir (2006).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 64 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

TABLE 3.3 Contributions to Growth of Real Output in the Market Economy (Annual average growth rates, percentage points) Germany United States 1980–1995 1995–2004 2004–2007 1980–1995 1995–2004 2004–2007 1GDP (2)+(3) 1.9 1.1 2.4 3.3 3.8 2.8 2 Hours worked –0.5 –0.6 0.5 1.3 0.7 1.4 3 Labor productivity 2.4 1.6 1.9 2.0 3.1 1.4 (4)+(5)+(8) Contributions from 4 Labor composition 0.2 0.1 –0.2 0.2 0.3 0.1 5 Capital stock per 1.3 1.1 0.6 1.0 1.4 0.6 hour (6)+(7) 6 ICT capital per 0.3 0.5 0.4 0.7 1.0 0.5 hour 7 Non-ICT capital per 1.0 0.6 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.1 hour 8 TFP 0.8 0.4 1.6 0.8 1.4 0.6

Labor productivity 1.4 1.1 1.7 1.7 2.8 1.2 contribution from the knowledge economy (4)+(6)+(8)

Sources: EU Klems database, November 2009 release; and IMF staff estimates. Note: ICT: information and communications technology; TFP: total factor productivity. Numbers may not sum exactly due to rounding.

temporary cyclical factors rather than the emergence of a knowledge econo- my typically associated with both higher investment in ICT assets and higher TFP growth. The results above are broadly consistent with existing empirical evidence sug- gesting that slow increases in ICT investments and TFP growth were the two most important contributors to the aggregate productivity gap with the United States in the mid-1990s. According to Molagoda and Perez (2011), these two factors account for 42 percent and 33 percent, respectively, of the German-U.S. labor productivity differential in the private economy over the 1995–2007 precrisis period.11 Based on their results, similar findings would be obtained using the United Kingdom or Sweden as productivity leader benchmarks instead of the United States.

AN INDUSTRY PERSPECTIVE This section shifts from the aggregate perspective of the previous section to a sector-level (more disaggregated) perspective, allowing us to document the contri- butions of each sector to aggregate labor productivity growth and the key sources of productivity growth at the sector and industry level. Based on industry-level

11 Molagoda and Perez (2011) do not provide the breakdown over 1995–2004 and 2004–07, only the full sample average results.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson 65

200 Germany United States 180

160

140

120

100

80

60

40 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

Figure 3.3 Value Added in the Services Sector (Gross value added, volume indices, 1995=100) Sources: EU Klems database, November 2009 release; IMF staff estimates.

800 Germany United States 700

600

500

400

300

200

100

0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

Figure 3.4 ICT Capital Services (Volume indices, 1995=100) Sources: EU KLEMS database, November 2009 release; IMF staff estimates. measures of output, inputs, and TFP from the EU KLEMS database, the results show that productivity differences are strong across industries too. In the case of the German-U.S. differential in productivity growth, we find that private services and, to a lesser extent, ICT production are the main sectors accounting for the aggregate productivity gaps in the private economy (Figures 3.3 and 3.4).12 Private services (including wholesale and retail trade, hotels and restaurants, transport services, and financial and business services) also explain the bulk of

12 ICT production includes production of electrical machinery and telecommunication services.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 66 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

BOX 3.3 The Rising Importance of Service Sectors

Both Germany and the United States have experienced a major shift of production and employment from manufacturing and other goods-producing industries (such as agriculture and mining) toward services. Over the period 1980–2007, the share of hours worked in manufacturing declined by more than 30 percent in Germany and was almost halved in the United States. Private services—including trade and transportation services, hotels and restaurants, and business and financial services—now account for 60 percent of private employment in Germany (compared to over two-thirds in the United States). In the United States, the number of hours worked is now nearly five times larger than in market services than in manufacturing. Even in Germany, where manufacturing plays an important role (accounting for 28 percent of total private output), the number of hours worked in market services is almost three times greater than that for manufacturing. This shift has important potential implications for productivity growth. Historically, innovation and technical change in manufacturing have been the central source of produc- tivity growth. With the emergence of the knowledge economy in the mid-1990s, the center of gravity of productivity improvements may have shifted to service industries. The experi- ence of the United States in the mid-1990s bears out this hypothesis. The U.S. revival reflected the rising growth contributions of ICT productivity and investment, especially in the distribution (trade and transportation) and other private services sectors. Due to the rising importance of the service sectors, durable productivity gains in Germany will need to extend to these industries in order to have a lasting impact on both real incomes and potential growth.

Germany’s long-term declining trend in productivity growth since the mid- 1990s, and the reverse trend in the United States over the same period (Box 3.3, Table 3.4, and Figure 3.5). We also find that productivity gaps in the private services industries largely reflect slower investment in ICT assets and the atten- dant slower TFP growth. By contrast, productivity in the goods production sectors (including agricul- ture, mining, and manufacturing other than electrical machinery, utilities, and construction) has consistently been higher in Germany than in the United States. This principally reflects the traditional German strength in manufacturing, a

TABLE 3.4 Major Sector Contribution to Average Annual Labor Productivity Growth in the Market Economy (Annual average growth rates, percentage points) Germany United States 1980–1995 1995–2004 2004–2007 1980–1995 1995–2004 2004–2007 1 Market economy 2.4 1.6 1.9 2.0 3.1 1.4 (2)+(3)+(4)+(5) 2 ICT production 0.3 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.9 0.7 3 Goods production 1.1 1.1 0.6 0.8 0.5 –0.1 4 Market services 0.9 0.2 0.9 0.8 1.9 0.9 5 Reallocation 0.0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2

Source: EU KLEMS database, November 2009 release and IMF staff estimates. Notes: ICT: information and communications technology. “Reallocation” refers to labor productivity effects of reallocation of labor between sectors. ICT production includes manufacturing of electrical machinery and post and telecommuni- cations services. Goods production includes agriculture, mining, manufacturing (excluding electrical machinery), con- struction, and utilities. Market services include distribution services; financial and business services, excluding real estate; and personal services. Numbers may not sum exactly due to rounding.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson 67

Germany's private sector fell behind in the mid-nineties. Although productivity in the goods sector remained strong. . . 4.5 Private Economy: Productivity Per Hour Worked 4.0 Goods Production: Productivity Per Hour Worked (Five-Year Average Annual Percent Change) 4.0 3.5 (Five-Year Average Annual Percent Change) 3.5 3.0 3.0 2.5 2.5 2.0 2.0 1.5 1.5 1.0 1.0 Germany Germany 0.5 United States 0.5 United States 0.0 0.0 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

. . .it lagged in information and communication technologies (ICT)...... and it was especially slow in the services sector.

14 ICT Production: Productivity Per Hour Worked 4.0 Private Services: Productivity Per Hour Worked (Five-Year Average Annual Percent Change) (Five-Year Average Annual Percent Change) 12 3.5 3.0 10 2.5 8 2.0 6 1.5

4 1.0

2 Germany 0.5 Germany United States United States 0 0.0 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

Total factor productivity (TFP) led the US revival since . . .while German TFP lagged until just before the crisis. 1995. . . United States: Private Economy Productivity Growth Germany: Private Economy Productivity Growth 3.5 Decomposition (Five-Year Average Contribution, 3.5 Decomposition (Five-Year Average Contribution, in Percent) in Percent) 3.0 3.0

2.5 2.5

2.0 2.0

1.5 Factor Intensity 1.5 TFP Factor Intensity 1.0 1.0

0.5 0.5 TFP

0.0 0.0 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Figure 3.5 Germany: Productivity Trends in the Private Economy, 1985–2007 Sources: EU KLEMS database; and IMF staff estimates. strength that makes Germany a formidable exporter of a wide range of precision manufactured products. Productivity growth in the ICT production sectors (including production of electrical machinery and telecommunication services) has been rising in line with worldwide trends but has lagged the United States since the mid-1980s (Figure 3.5). Within the services sector, German-U.S. productivity differentials are concen- trated in a handful of industries. Productivity gaps during 1995–2004 were especially large in distribution services (including trade and transportation) and in financial and business services. The distribution sector contributed a third of the overall annual productivity gap of 3 percent during 1995–2004. In finance and business services, the gap was even bigger, at almost 2 percent (nearly two- thirds of the total). In both cases, productivity growth differences reflect to a large

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 68 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

TABLE 3.5 Contributions of Sectors to Average Annual Labor Productivity Growth in Market Services (Percentage points) Germany United States 1980–1995 1995–2004 2004–2007 1980–1995 1995–2004 2004–2007 Market services labor 2.1 0.3 1.7 1.6 3.3 1.6 productivity

Distribution services 1.0 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.9 0.7 contribution from factor intensity 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.3 growth from TFP growth 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.7 1.3 0.4

Finance and Business 0.6 –0.7 0.4 0.0 1.2 0.2 services contribution from factor intensity 1.4 1.4 0.7 0.9 1.2 0.3 growth from TFP growth –0.8 –2.2 –0.2 –1.0 0.0 –0.1

Personal services 0.1 –0.2 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.3 contribution from factor intensity 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 growth from TFP growth –0.2 –0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.3

Contribution from 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.0 0.3 labor reallocation

Sources: EU KLEMS database, November 2009 release; and IMF staff estimates. Note: Factor intensity relates to the total contribution from changes in labor composition and in capital deepening of information and communications technology (ICT) and non-ICT assets. The reallocation effect refers to the impact of changes in the distribution of labor input between industries on labor productivity growth in market services. Numbers may not add up due to rounding. TFP: total factor productivity.

extent differences in TFP growth at the sectoral level (i.e., efficiency of input use) rather than differences in factor intensity growth (i.e., growth in both human and physical capital inputs). The closure of the gap vis-à-vis the United States between 2005 and 2007 mainly reflected slower productivity growth in the United States’ distribution and financial and business services and improved performance in Germany’s financial and business services. In Germany, the turnaround in financial and business services reflects higher TFP growth rather than larger contributions of capital accumulation and labor quality. However, international experience sug- gests that sustaining this trend will require concurrent improvements in TFP and investment—especially in ICT assets—since both are drivers of innovation effects on services productivity. The continuing productivity gaps in the services sector reflect in part Germany’s lag, by advanced country standards, in the use of ICT. Compared to some other advanced economies, Germany lags in research and use of ICT. This is evidenced by the low share of ICT in total research and development spending, compared to the average in OECD countries, and by the relatively low extent of

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson 69

70 Germany United States OECD total 60

50

40

30

20

10

0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

Figure 3.6 Internet Subscribers (Percent of population) Source: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. business and government internet use. The latter in turn seems caused by several infrastructure and financing factors, including: • a relatively low number of secure internet servers; • low public investment in advanced technologies compared to some other OECD countries; and • a comparatively low willingness of the financial system to provide financing for high-risk, innovative projects (Box 3.4). Internet penetration in Germany (measured by the number of subscribers as a share of total population) is in line with the average for OECD countries, but it is lower than in the United States (Figure 3.6). A limited initial public offering (IPO) market and tax obstacles appear to be contributing to the limited development of German private equity and venture capital markets and thus to the limited availability of risk financing. Difficulty in achieving successful exits, lack of entrepreneurial talent, and unfavorable tax policies (including tax obstacles to cross-border investments and double taxation) are the main unfavorable climate factors for venture capital in Germany, accord- ing to a 2010 survey of 516 firms in nine countries: 72 percent of respondents cited lack of entrepreneurial talent and tax policies as the main obstacles, and 67 percent considered exit difficulties the main issue. Eliminating tax obstacles to cross-border investments and double taxation would require coordinated action at the EU level to remove these and other regulatory barriers (e.g., separate regis- tration requirements), thus allowing even smaller funds to invest EU-wide more efficiently, develop specialized sectoral expertise, and reap economies of scale.13

13 While there is a consensus among the member states on promoting mutual recognition of national frameworks, no significant measures have yet been taken that would make fundraising and investing across borders easier (European Commission Enterprise and Industry Directorate General, 2009).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 70 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

BOX 3.4 Productivity Growth in the Information Age

International experience suggests that innovation and productivity growth in ser- vices are closely related to the wider use of information and communication technol- ogy (ICT). In the U.S. private services sector since 1995, high levels of investment in ICT have been followed by rapid productivity growth. Other high-performing economies, such as Sweden, Finland, and the U.K. also have relatively high ICT uptake; in addition, the high- productivity countries are characterized by a relatively high level of human capital employed in the services sector (Molagoda and Perez, 2011). Germany lags some advanced countries both in the use of ICT and in human capi- tal in the services sector. Government usage of ICT and the number of secure servers are in the mid- to lower-range. The ratio of high-skilled labor employed in the services indus- tries in 2007 is below 20 percent, compared to almost 50 percent for the U.S. and more than 40 percent for Finland (Molagoda and Perez, 2011). In the group of advanced nations, Germany’s ICT research and development share in total research and development also falls in the mid- to lower-range. While public policy to support ICT development and use remains controversial, the evidence suggests that ICT development and use can be fos- tered through innovation policies, including promoting the availability of risk capital and increasing the commercial use of intellectual property rights held by universities and research institutions. A common European market for services would also generate econo- mies of scale and raise incentives to invest in new technologies.

The share of investment and research in information The number of secure servers is low relative technologies is relatively small in Germany. to peers. 70 6.0 ICT R&D expenditure as a share of total R&D, 2007 KOR USA 60 (Percent) 5.5 SWECAN CHE DEU NLD 50 FIN UK DNK 5.0 FRA JPN 40 AUS BEL AUT NOR 4.5 30 ESP 20 4.0 PRT ITA 10

ICT Usage (index 1–7) 3.5 0 GRC 3.0 Korea OECD Finland Sweden 0 500 1000 1500 Germany Netherlands Secure internet servers per milllion population, 2008 United States

Public procurement of high-tech products is High-risk financing is less available than in low by advanced-economy standards. other OECD countries. 6.0 6.0 KOR KOR CHE CHE USA 5.5 SWEUSA 5.5 SWE UK UK CAN NLD CAN DNK DEU NLD DEU DNK FIN 5.0 JPN FRA 5.0 JPN FRA NOR FIN AUT AUS NOR AUT AUS BEL BEL 4.5 4.5 ESP ESP 4.0 PRT 4.0 PRT ITA

ICT Usage (index 1–7) 3.5 ICT Usage (index 1–7) 3.5 GRC GRC 3.0 3.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5 5.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5 5.0 Government procurement of advanced Venture Capital Availability (survey index 1–7) technology products (survey index 1–7)

Figure 3.4.1 Research and Use of Information and Communication Technology Sources: The Global Information Technology Report, 2009–10; and Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson 71

The lack of exit opportunities in Germany reflects the small share of global IPO listings in Deutsche Boerse.14 Reasons for a limited IPO market in Germany compared to other key financial centers seem related to market liquidity: a shal- lower pool of equity capital compared to the United States, the United Kingdom, or the countries associated with the Euronext exchange, and a narrower investor base compared to the United States or the UK. It is these factors that limit the IPO market, rather than cost factors such as listing requirements and underwrit- ing fees, where Germany appears very competitive (Oxera, 2006). Another reason for Germany’s delay in adopting the Internet economy and constraining factors for innovation is deficiency in the insolvency law, which results in relatively less creditor-friendly legislation than in the United Kingdom and thus less willingness of banks to lend to high-risk projects. Specifically, German banks face costlier and lengthier proceedings relative to the United Kingdom and thus potentially higher legislation-induced credit risk (Schmieder and Schmieder, 2011). In response, they demand relatively more credit risk miti- gation than U.K. and U.S. banks do, but still recover less than do U.K. banks. Banks’ lower willingness to lend to risky projects in turn could hinder entrepre- neurship and risk-taking. To be on par with U.K. banks, Schmieder and Schmieder (2011) calculate that formal bankruptcy proceedings in Germany would have to be shortened by about one half. Relatively limited use of public procurement to provide sustained ICT demand in Germany, as compared to other advanced countries such as Korea, Sweden, and the United States, may be another factor explaining the compara- tively low investment in new, high-risk technologies. The premise is that there are positive externalities in the use of ICT caused, for example, by network effects or complementary investments, such as organizational change, that go unmeasured, and large fixed costs from the required infrastructure investments (servers, infra- structure software, storage).15 Business models for ICT companies or services companies that make heavy use of ICT are thus reliant on scale to be profitable. A transparent procurement process that enables greater usage based on open standards can create synergies. Greater European integration in services provision would also help raise investment in new, high-risk technologies, It would generate economies of scale and raise incentives to invest in and provide risk financing for innovative applica- tions of ICT in services. Obstacles to an integrated European market for online and off-line services include a variety of compliance and regulatory issues,

14 The number of IPOs expected in Germany in 2011 is 20, compared to a backlog of 150 deals in the U.S at end-February; Deutsche Boerse lagged other IPO markets in China, London, New York, Tokyo, Mumbai, Australia, and Korea in 2010, both in number of deals and funds raised (Ernst & Young, 2011). 15 See, for example, Stiroh (2002) and McKinsey Global Institute (2010). While the potential offered and challenges posed in using public procurement as an instrument for innovation have been largely ignored or downplayed, a number of empirical studies conclude that over long time periods, state procurement triggered greater innovation impulses in more areas than did research and development subsidies (see Edler and Georghiou, 2007, for a review of the evidence).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 72 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

including country-specific consumer-protection laws, VAT rules, electronic waste regulations, varying copyright rules, and postal systems. Moreover, the need to tailor products to each national market requires maintaining region- specific teams and translating every item, website, and online application, in several different languages. Finally, price-comparison websites, which make online shopping attractive in the United States, are relatively few in Europe, where existing sites remain national.16 While these obstacles can be overcome,17 they result in higher costs of doing business for services firms that attempt to operate across borders, and they further add to barriers to entry for smaller, start- up firms that do not have the administrative and personnel resources to cope with different national regulations. Closing the productivity gap with the United States in private services could raise TFP growth, and thus potential growth, by up to 0.6 percentage points annually. The overall impact on potential growth could be higher if the TFP increase is associated with higher investment in new technologies, as was the case in the United States in the mid-1990s. Shifting adoption patterns for new IT services and products, such as cloud computing (forecast to grow at more than five times the rate of traditional IT products), suggest that the share of these growing markets, currently heavily concentrated in the United States at 70.2 percent, is likely to decline in the United States to 51.4 percent by 2014, while the share of Western Europe and Asia/Pacific, excluding Japan, is set to grow rapidly (IDC, 2010). Countries that plan for this shift by creating a favorable market environment, in terms of availability of risk financing and significant additional investment in broadband and complementary infrastructure, are likely to benefit disproportionately from this catch-up effect.18 EU regulations that hinder the development of new IT service industries, such as EU laws that restrict the movement of data and access to databases across borders, may also need to be revisited, for example to allow storage of data by companies based in the EU with vendors based outside the region.

CONCLUSION International experience suggests that ICT applications in traditionally low-tech industries such as the retail and wholesale sectors lead to technology and innova- tion effects, which in turn raise TFP growth. While large and internationally

16 See The Economist, October 28, 2010. 17 Successful internet start-ups, such as Berlin-based Wooga, illustrate the scope for exploiting the synergies of a European user market. 18 Much of the available empirical research refers to the impact of the Internet or the “digital economy” rather than ICT infrastructure. A recent study using data for the 48 U.S. states over 2003–05 suggests that for every 1 percentage point increase in broadband penetration in a particular area, employment growth is estimated to increase 0.2–0.3 percentage points per year (Crandall, Litan, and Lehr, 2007). The study also finds that state output is positively associated with broadband use, although the impact is not statistically significant.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson 73 connected German companies are perceived to be at the forefront of innovation and usage of new technologies, overall ICT uptake and the prioritization of ICT in national growth strategy are both low in Germany relative to some other advanced countries. In this paper we argue that policy measures are needed to raise the low annual TFP growth rate of only 0.5 percent during the last decade (see Chapter 2). While the more recent pick-up in productivity growth in Germany since 2005 is encouraging, the improvement could be largely cyclical, since it has not been accompanied by a concomitant rise in ICT investments. The experience of other fast-growing advanced countries suggests that to ensure a sustained rise in pro- ductivity and TFP growth in the private economy and to close the productivity gaps in the service sectors, Germany needs to encourage more widespread usage of ICT and human capital as well as investment and innovation, particularly in the private services sector (i.e., outside Germany’s traditional strengths). The required measures to raise incentives to invest in higher-risk, higher-growth sec- tors include: 1. further development of venture capital and private equity markets (backed by a more efficient insolvency process); 2. increased commercial use of intellectual property rights held by universities and research institutions; 3. removal of uncertainties regarding tax treatment; and 4. further European integration in services provision. Strong supply-side policies alone—including improvements of insolvency law system and the financing environment—are important to kick-start innova- tion and encourage risk-taking, but they may not be sufficient to sustainably raise incentives to invest in new technologies. Some have argued that ICT uptake is also importantly shaped by the availability of a large enough market due to the presence of network effects and large fixed costs to IT infrastructure investments. In Germany’s case, there may be scope for greater but transparent public pro- curement of high-tech products to support overall incentives for innovation and the development of new ICT applications. Greater harmonization of rules and regulations to foster greater European integration in services provision could help raise competition among service providers and thus lower prices and increase incentives for ICT investments and ICT usage, in a more efficient way than tar- geted subsidies. A common European market for services would also enable the realization of economies of scale, with expected positive effects on TFP growth and investment incentives.

REFERENCES Allard, Céline, and Luc Everaert, 2010, “Lifing Euro Area Growth: Priorities for Structural Reforms and Governance,” IMF Staff Position Note SPN/10/19 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 74 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

Bartelsman, Eric, Andrea Bassanini, John Haltiwanger, Ron Jarmin, Stefano Scarpetta, and Thorsten Schank, 2008, “The Spread of ICT and Productivity Growth: Is Europe Really Lagging Behind in the New Economy?,” unpublished paper, OECD. Bosworth, Barry P., and Jack E. Triplett, 2007, “The Early 21st Century Productivity Expansion is Still in Services,” International Productivity Monitor, 14 (Spring). The Conference Board, 2009, “Productivity, Performance, and Progress: Germany in International Comparative Perspective.” Available online at http://www.conference-board. org/publications/publicationdetail.cfm?publicationid=1682. Crandall, Robert W., Robert E. Litan, and William Lehr, 2007, “The Effects of Broadband Deployment on Output and Employment: a Cross-Sectional Analysis of U.S. Data,” Issues in Economic Policy, No. 6 (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution). Deloitte, 2010, Results from the 2010 Global Venture Capital Survey, available at www.nvca.org. The Economist, 2010, “Europe’s Need for E-Freedom,” available at http://www.economist .com/node/17361454. Edler, Jakob, and Luke Georghiou, 2007, “Public Procurement and Innovation—Resurrecting the Demand Side,” Research Policy, Vol. 36, 949–63. Ernst & Young, 2011, Global IPO Trends, available at http://www.ey.com/GL/en/Services/ Strategic-Growth-Markets/Global-IPO-trends-2011. European Commission Enterprise and Industry Directorate General, 2009, Cross-Border Venture Capital in the European Union: European Commission Work on Removing Obstacles (Brussels: European Commission). EU ICT Task Force, 2006, “Fostering the Competitiveness of Europe’s ICT Industry.” Available online at http://ec.europa.eu/information_society/eeurope/i2010/docs/high_level_group/ ict_task_force_report_nov2006.pdf. IDC, 2010, Worldwide and Regional Public IT Cloud Services 2010–14 Forecast. Inklaar, Robert, Marcel P. Timmer, and Bart van Ark, 2008, “Market Services Productivity,” Economic Policy, January, pp. 139–94. Jorgenson, Dale W., Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh, 2004, “Will the U.S. Productivity Resurgence Continue,” Current Issues in Economics and Finance, Vol. 10, No. 13 (New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York). ———, 2008, “A Retrospective Look at the U.S. Productivity Growth Resurgence,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 3–24. McKinsey Global Institute, 2010, “Beyond Austerity: A Path to Economic Growth and Renewal in Europe” (McKinsey & Company). ———, 2011, “European Growth and Renewal: The Path from Crisis to Recovery, Updated Research” (McKinsey & Company). Molagoda, Nandaka, and Esther Perez, 2011, “Raising Potential Growth in Europe: Mind the Residual,” Chapter V in Euro Area Policies—Selected Issues, SM/11/160, pp. 62–79 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Nahuys, Richard, and Henry van der Wiel, 2005, “How Should Europe’s ICT Ambitions Look Like? An Interpretative Review of the Facts,” Discussion Paper No. 05–22 (Utrecht: Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute.) Oxera Consulting Ltd, 2006, The Cost of Capital: An International Comparison). Available at http://www.nd.edu/~carecob/May2008Conference/Papers/OxeraCostofcapitalreport ExecSummary.pdf. Schmieder, Christian, and Philipp Schmieder, 2011, “The Impact of Legislation on Credit Risk—Comparative Evidence from the United States, the United Kingdom, and Germany,” IMF Working Paper No. WP/11/55 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Stiroh, Kevin J., 2002, “Information Technology and the U.S. Productivity Revival: What Do the Industry Data Say?” American Economic Review, Vol. 92, No. 5, pp. 1559–76. Timmer, Marcel P., Gerard Ypma, and Bart van der Ark, 2003, “IT in the European Union: driving productivity divergence?” GGDC Research Memorandum 200363, Groningen Growth and Development Centre, University of Groningen.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson 75

Triplett, Jack E., and Barry P. Bosworth, 2006, “Baumol’s Disease Has Been Cured: IT and Multifactor Productivity in U.S. Services Industries,” in The New Economy and Beyond: Past, Present, and Future, ed. by Dennis W. Jansen (Cheltenham, U.K.: Edgar Elgar). van Ark, Bart, 2010, “Productivity, Sources of Growth, Potential Output in the Euro Area and the United States,” Intereconomics, Vol. 1, pp. 17–20. van Ark, Bart, Mary O’Mahony, and Marcel P. Timmer, 2008, “The Productivity Gap Between Europe and the United States: Trends and Causes,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 25–44. Vandenbussche, Jérôme, Philippe Aghion, and Costas Meghir, 2006, “Growth, Distance to Frontier, and Composition of Human Capital,” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 11, No. 2, pp. 97–127. Voss, Romy, and Christoph Müller, 2009, “How Are the Conditions for High-Tech Start-Ups in Germany?,” International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business, Vol. 7, No. 3, pp. 284–311.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 76 German Productivity Growth: An Industry Perspective

APPENDIX

TABLE 3A.1 Germany and the United States: Average Annual Growth Rates of GDP, G DP per Capita, and GDP per Hour Worked, 1950–2009 (Percent) Average annual growth in GDP GDP per capita GDP per hour worked 1950–1973 Germany 6.0 5.3 5.8 US 3.9 2.5 2.6 1973–1995 Germany 2.1 1.8 2.8 US 2.9 1.7 1.2 1980–1995 Germany 2.1 1.8 2.8 US 3.0 1.9 1.4 1995–2004 Germany 1.4 1.3 1.7 US 3.4 2.3 2.4 2004–2007 Germany 2.1 2.1 1.7 US 2.6 1.6 1.0 2008 Germany 1.3 1.3 0.1 US 0.0 –0.9 0.8 2009 Germany –4.9 –4.9 –2.4 US –2.6 –3.5 2.5

Sources: The Conference Board Total Economy Database, September 2010; and IMF staff estimates. Note: Germany’s pre-1988 population is estimated as the sum of West Germany and East Germany. Relative levels are based on Elteto-Koves-Szulc (EKS) purchasing power parities for GDP for 2009.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CHAPTER 4 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

MARTIN SCHINDLER

Germany’s employment fell only marginally during the crisis, despite a sharp drop in output and in contrast to historical employment patterns over the business cycle. This paper offers new perspectives on the apparent “puzzle” of the German labor market response. Labor market developments during the crisis are consistent with a view that Germany experienced mainly a temporary demand shock, necessitating relatively little sectoral reallocation and with employers therefore adjusting hours of work while retaining workers. The labor market dynamics also provide evidence that past reforms, including especially the Hartz reforms during the early 2000s, enabled the labor mar- ket to react in a way that previously had not been possible to the same extent. These reforms facilitated a shift from adjustment in the number of individuals employed to adjustments in hours. Thus, while the employment decline was smaller than expected based on past dynamics, the reduction in hours worked was more in line with the drop in output. And lastly, the moderate employment decline during the crisis reflected the longer-term structural changes in the labor market. The upward momentum in employment stemming from the earlier reforms held back the adverse crisis impact.

INTRODUCTION The German labor market has gone through a remarkable transformation over the past two decades. From being labeled the “sick man of Europe” as unemploy- ment rates steadily went up during the 1990s, and even reached double-digit territory during the mid-2000s, to references to the “German labor market mir- acle” during the recent financial crisis when unemployment, after a brief rise at its onset, continued the downward trend that had started around 2005. This transformation is particularly striking in comparative perspective: Germany was one of the European countries that motivated Ljungqvist and Sargent’s (1998) study of how and why the U.S. labor market performed so much better, espe- cially in turbulent times. Now, economists are puzzling over why the German

The author has benefitted from comments and suggestions by Ashoka Mody, Helène Poirson, Fabian Bornhorst and participants at the Germany in an Interconnected World conference at the Ministry of Finance in Berlin (May 2011), especially the paper’s discussant, Werner Eichhorst. Susan Becker provided excellent research assistance. 77

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 78 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

labor market has proven to be so much more resilient than the U.S. market, even worrying about a jobless recovery there while German unemployment continues to decline. This chapter aims to provide new perspectives on the recent labor market dynamics and to understand how “miraculous” the crisis performance actually was. It also aims to answer the question of what the crisis can tell us about the German labor market, and in particular whether the recent experience reflects something more fundamental. The analysis suggests that, broadly speaking, the labor market response has been benign, but less so than meets the eye, and that the German labor market does indeed appear to be structurally different from what it was even a decade ago. The chapter proceeds by providing some general background on longer-term and more recent developments, discussing a number of factors that help to better understand the recent labor dynamics. The appendix provides details on the labor market reported here.

BACKGROUND Germany has long been labeled the “sick man” of Europe, owing in large part to its ailing and sluggish labor market with its high and increasing unemployment (e.g., The Economist, 1999). Indeed, starting from an unemployment rate of less than one percent in 1970, German unemployment has almost continuously trended upwards, interrupted only by brief cyclical declines in unemployment, such as those during 1976–1980, 1985–1990, 1997–2001, and the most recent decline since 2005 (with only a moderate uptick in 2009). In each of those cases, the decline in unemployment was paralleled by a growth recovery in output (Figure 4.1). 12

10

8

6

4 West Germany Unified Germany

2

0 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Figure 4.1 Germany: Unemployment Rate (National definition and International Labour Organization, percent) Source: German Statistical Office.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 79

France Italy Japan United Kingdom 15 United States Germany 12

9

6

3

0

−3

−6 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Figure 4.2 Unemployment in Advanced Economies (ILO definition, percent) Source: International Labour Organization (ILO).

However, the cyclical upswings in GDP were not sufficient to turn around the secular increase in unemployment. With the exception of the most recent (ongo- ing) episode, each trough in unemployment was higher than the previous one. Thus, from nearly zero unemployment in the early 1970s, German unemploy- ment peaked in 2005 at over 11 percent. Notably, the deterioration in labor market outcomes was somewhat unique to Germany (Figure 4.2). Along with Japan, Germany had one of the lowest unemployment rates among the large advanced economies in the 1970s, substantially lower than in the United States, where unemployment was on the order of 6 percent at that time. However, while U.S. unemployment peaked at nearly 10 percent in 1982 and declined thereafter, German unemployment continued to rise. By the early 2000s, Germany had one of the highest unemployment rates among its peers. The long upward trend that began as early as the 1970s suggests that Germany’s labor market problems were not specific to the structural challenges posted by German unification in 1990. A broad consensus has emerged on the main under- lying causes. Siebert (2003) views the secular step-wise increase in unemployment as the result of weak job creation, in turn caused by the German institutional design for wage formation, which at times has led to binding negotiated wage increases and insufficient wage differentiation; and as the result of a high reserva- tion wage, resulting from high unemployment and social welfare benefits.1

1 This notion of “binding wage increases” is based on the observed decline in the “wage drift” (the difference between actual and negotiated wage increases), especially during the 1990s (Siebert, 2003, p. 8).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 80 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

With its combination of high unemployment and welfare benefits, rigid wage determination mechanisms, and high firing costs, Germany was typical of what many authors saw as the main differences between European and U.S. labor mar- ket models (Siebert, 1997; Ljungqvist and Sargent, 1998). In addition, Prescott (2004) and Rogerson (2010) cite high taxation that restricts the labor supply. In this comparison, U.S. labor market flexibility is seen as the result of low unem- ployment benefits, low firings costs, and low labor taxation, leading to a more dynamic labor market that can more easily adjust to economic shocks. The exploding cost of unemployment along with public pressure to reduce the high levels of unemployment eventually triggered the largest social policy reform in post-war Germany (Wunsch, 2005; see also Box 4.2). This reform agenda limited the duration and level of unemployment benefits and aimed to improve job creation. As argued in this chapter, these reforms led to a labor market per- formance in Germany during the recent financial crisis that was quite different from its historical performance as well as from that in other economies.

RECENT DEVELOPMENTS German employment, measured as the number of employed individuals, has performed remarkably during the crisis. Employment decreased only by a mod- erate 0.6 percent from peak (2008:Q4) to trough (2009:Q4). By contrast, the cumulative peak-to-trough decline in real GDP (2008:Q1–2009:Q1) reached over 6.6 percent. The change in employment is one of the smallest among advanced economies, even compared with those that experienced smaller GDP declines. A comparison with the United States is particularly telling: despite a smaller decline in real GDP, U.S. employment was about 6 percent lower at the trough, a larger decline than that in output (Figure 4.3). These differences were reflected also in terms of recovery—by end-2010, the United States had nearly recovered its precrisis level of GDP, but still remained about 4 percent below its pre-crisis employment level. Conversely, in Germany employment has moved back to precrisis levels quickly, but with output remaining more sluggish (Figure 4.4). Germany’s experience stands out not only in cross-country comparison, but also from the perspective of its historical business cycle dynamics. Despite the unique nature of the financial crisis—both in terms of magnitude and in terms of its global reach—most countries’ labor markets responded in a fashion consis- tent with historical dynamics. Germany was among only a small group of coun- tries whose labor markets responded so strikingly differently. Figure 4.5 shows actual versus predicted unemployment patterns, based on the cross-country analysis in the 2010 World Economic Outlook (IMF, 2010, ch. 3). Most countries experienced increases in unemployment either close to their predicted values or, in many cases, substantially larger. By contrast, the increase in unemployment in Germany fell substantially short of its predicted value, unique among all countries in the sample.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 81

18 Real GDP Total employment 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0

Italy Japan Spain IrelandFinland Greece Austria France Canada Germany Portugal Netherlands Switzerland United States United Kingdom

Figure 4.3 Peak-to-Trough Declines in Output and Employment (Percentage points) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates. Note: Calculated as the percent-difference between peak and trough during 2007:Q1–2010:Q3.

101 Germany 100 Sweden 99 United Kingdom 98 France Japan 97 Denmark

96 Finland USA 95

Employment 94 93 92 91 GIPS 90 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 Real GDP

Figure 4.4 Recovery to Pre-Crisis Levels (2010:Q4, 2008:Q2 = 100) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates. Note: GIPS: Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain.

An alternative version of Okun’s law can provide additional insights into the German labor market dynamics (Box 4.1). The past pattern between employment and growth would have predicted a much larger employment decline than observed, given the output loss, on the order of more than one percent (Figure 4.6). In contrast to employment levels, total hours worked declined substantially, by a cumulative 4.4 percent between their pre-crisis peak in 2008:Q2 and their trough in 2009:Q2. When re-estimating a modified Okun’s relationship between economic growth and total hours worked, the peak-to-trough decline implied by

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 82 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

8.0 7.0 Actual change Predicted change 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 −1.0

Italy USA Japan Spain France GreeceAustria Finland Ireland Norway BelgiumPortugal Sweden Canada Germany Denmark SwitzerlandNetherlands New Zealand United Kingdom

Figure 4.5 Actual versus Predicted Change in Unemployment (Percentage points) Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook (WEO). Note: Based on figure 3.8 in IMF (2010). The predicted changes in unemployment are based on Okun’s law specifications that include additional control variables, including measures of financial, housing and equity market stress.

40.4 Actual employment Predicted

40.2

40.0

39.8

39.6

39.4

2007:Q12007:Q22007:Q32007:Q42008:Q12008:Q22008:Q32008:Q42009:Q12009:Q22009:Q32009:Q42009:Q12010:Q22010:Q3

Figure 4.6 Germany: Employment During the Crisis (Millions) Sources: Deutsche Bundesbank; and IMF staff estimates. Note: The predicted path is based on a regression of total employment on contemporaneous real GDP growth during 1991:Q1–2008:Q1. The estimated coefficient is used to predict employment from 2008:Q2 onwards.

this modification is about 3.9 percent (Figure 4.7). Interpreted in this sense, the labor market response has been less out of line with historical patterns than the employment dynamics suggest, at least during the first stage of the crisis (i.e., from onset to trough). Notably, however, the dynamics in hours and (to a small- er extent) employment were more positive than predicted during the second, recovery stage. This is consistent with a continuation of the longer-term down- ward trend in unemployment. As argued below, that trend would require

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 83

BOX 4.1 Okun’s Law

Unemployment typically increases when economic growth slows down. Okun (1962) first documented this casual observation, which became known as “Okun’s law,” by postulating various equations that formalized this relationship, including a gap version, which relates the output gap to the deviation of actual unemployment from its natural rate (see also Abel and Bernanke, 2005), and the more commonly used changes version, which relates output growth to changes in the unemployment rate, e.g.:

'Y/Y = α + β'u

where Y is real GDP and u is the unemployment rate. (Different versions of Okun’s law have been estimated in a large literature focusing on the relationship between unemployment and output. See, e.g., Knotek, 2007, and the references therein.) The coefficient β (“Okun’s coefficient”) can be interpreted as the (semi-)elasticity of output growth with respect to 1 percentage changes in the unemployment rate. Okun (1962) estimated a value of β | 3 /3 for the United States during 1947–1960, while later studies have typically found lower val- ues on the order of 2. While Okun’s law has received much empirical support, different versions of it are appropriate in different contexts. In particular, in this paper an alternative version is esti- mated, namely, the relationship between changes in total employment and real GDP growth, as well as a second specification that considers the relationship between changes in total hours worked and real GDP growth. These specifications are preferable for a number of reasons. First, the particular interest here is on the distinction between adjustment on the external margin—individuals being hired or laid off—and adjustment on the internal margin—changes in hours worked by each worker. The distinction between these two margins turns out to be important in understanding recent labor market dynamics in Germany, but it cannot be made using the traditional specification of Okun’s law that is focused on unemployment. Secondly, and more broadly, employment is arguably the more preferable object of interest, since the unemployment rate may change over the business cycle, not only due to flows between employment and unemployment, but also because of flows into and out of the labor force. Thus, employment is likely to be a more direct measure of economic well- being than unemployment. That said, the broader result in this paper, that Germany’s his- torical Okun’s law did not hold during the current crisis, is a finding that is not unique to any specification. See, e.g., Figure 4.1 in this chapter and Chapter 3 in IMF (2010).

employers to “overshoot” in the hours/employment recovery, relative to the pre- dicted dynamics, in order to resume the prior downward trend. The dynamics of employment and hours worked during the crisis suggest that German firms may have switched to new adjustment patterns. Historically, employment and total hours typically moved together at shorter frequencies, while hours per worker remained fairly stable around a secular downward trend (Figure 4.8). That is, traditionally, the employment response to short-term fluc- tuations has largely been on the extensive margin (employment) and less on the intensive margin (hours per worker). In contrast, during this crisis, the adjustment has mainly been on the intensive margin, that is, in hours worked, both during the period of the sharp output fall and during the initial recovery (implying that hours per worker and total hours

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 84 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

14.5 Actual hours Predicted 14.4 14.3 14.2 14.1 14.0 13.9 13.8 13.7 13.6 13.5

2007:Q12007:Q22007:Q32007:Q42008:Q12008:Q22008:Q32008:Q42009:Q12009:Q22009:Q32009:Q42010:Q12010:Q22010:Q3 Figure 4.7 Germany: Hours Worked during the Crisis Sources: Deutsche Bundesbank; and IMF staff estimates. Note: The predicted path is based on a regression of total hours worked (on contemporaneous real GDP growth) during 1991:Q1–2008:Q1. The estimated coefficient is used to predict thours from 2008:Q2 onwards.

400 15.5 Hours worked per worker, left axis 390 Total hours worked (in billions), right axis 380 15 370 14.5 360 350 14 340

330 13.5 320 310 13 1991:Q1 1992:Q1 1993:Q1 1994:Q1 1995:Q1 1996:Q1 1997:Q1 1998:Q1 1999:Q1 2000:Q1 2001:Q1 2002:Q1 2003:Q1 2004:Q1 2005:Q1 2006:Q1 2007:Q1 2008:Q1 2009:Q1 2010:Q1 Figure 4.8 Germany: Hours Worked Sources: Federal Statistical Office; and Deutsche Bundesbank.

moved in sync).2 This crucial change in labor dynamics reflected a number of factors, outlined in what follows. The many factors include increased flexibility in hourly adjustments, the temporary nature of the shock (together with the fact that it is less costly to increase hours per worker after a crisis rather than to re-hire workers), and lastly, emerging signs of a shortage of skilled workers.

2 More recently, the continued labor market recovery appears to have started to shift back to the extensive margin, with the increase in total hours worked driven, once again, by employment gains.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 85

UNDERSTANDING GERMAN LABOR MARKET DYNAMICS To understand Germany’s labor market dynamics, it is useful to view labor mar- ket outcomes as a function of institutions, policies, and shocks. Changes in each of these values, along with the interactions between them, shape how labor markets evolve during a crisis. The following discussion brings together a variety of possible factors behind the observed labor market response in each of these categories.

Hartz IV Reforms: Secular Trends Over the past decade, Germany has undertaken a variety of reforms and policy measures that have significantly altered its labor market institutions. A key pack- age has been the so-called Hartz IV reforms, which took effect in 2005 and contained a number of features (Box 3.2). The reforms streamlined and reduced the generosity of social transfers, including benefits associated with unemploy- ment insurance (UI) and welfare payments, and also deregulated temporary employment. A key effect was to lower unemployed individuals’ reservation wages and thus increase the flows from unemployment into employment. The reforms came after a cyclical acceleration of the longer-term trend increase in unemployment—starting from around 5 percent around the time of German unification, the unemployment rate rose to a peak of over 11 percent in 2005. Although GDP growth had the ability to lower unemployment at shorter (cycli- cal) frequencies, the structural increase dominated (Figures 4.9 and 4.10). Near zero real output growth during 2001 through 2003 then provided an additional “boost” to unemployment and helped create the political economy that laid the groundwork for the Hartz reforms to take place. Model simulations suggest that the Hartz reforms, especially those in stage IV, contributed strongly to reducing structural unemployment. Analyzing and assess- ing the payoffs from a single reform episode is empirically difficult, as the reform’s impact cannot easily be disentangled from the contributions of simulta- neous changes in other factors. In such cases, a theoretical framework can provide guidance on the isolated impact of reforms, since it allows one to construct a counterfactual prediction of how the unemployment dynamics would have evolved post-reform, holding other factors constant. In the context of labor mar- ket reforms and their impact on employment and unemployment, the search framework is ideally suited for this task. Labor search models center on the flows that occur between unemployment and employment and the various factors that may affect these flows.3 In particu- lar, simple search models involve variables regarding the payoff from working (in particular, the wage) as well as the payoff from being unemployed (the monetary

3 More complex models may include also the flows from outside the labor force into employment or unemployment, and vice versa. For tractability, the model considered here abstracts from these.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 86 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

10.0 Real GDP (Percent change over 4 quarters 3.0 ago), left axis 8.0 Unemployment rate (ILO, percentage point 2.0 6.0 change over 4 quarters ago), right axis

4.0 1.0 2.0

0.0 0.0

−2.0 −1.0 −4.0

−6.0 −2.0 −8.0

−10.0 −3.0 1991:Q1 1992:Q1 1993:Q1 1994:Q1 1995:Q1 1996:Q1 1997:Q1 1998:Q1 1999:Q1 2000:Q1 2001:Q1 2002:Q1 2003:Q1 2004:Q1 2005:Q1 2006:Q1 2007:Q1 2008:Q1 2009:Q1 2010:Q1 Figure 4.9 Germany: Cyclical Changes in Output and Unemployment Sources: Federal Statistical Office; and Deutsche Bundesbank.

Real GDP (Seasonally and work day adjusted, 115.0 2000 = 100), left axis 12.0 Unemployment rate (ILO, percent), right axis 110.0 10.0 105.0

100.0 8.0

95.0 6.0 90.0 4.0 85.0

80.0 2.0 2000:Q1 2006:Q1 1991:Q1 1992:Q1 1993:Q1 1994:Q1 1995:Q1 1996:Q1 1997:Q1 1998:Q1 1999:Q1 2001:Q1 2002:Q1 2003:Q1 2004:Q1 2005:Q1 2007:Q1 2008:Q1 2009:Q1 2010:Q1 Figure 4.10 Secular Trends in Output and Unemployment Sources: Federal Statistical Office; and Deutsche Bundesbank.

and nonmonetary value derived from being unemployed). These factors directly impact the extent to which an unemployed individual will actively search, as well as which job opportunities might be taken up. Another important factor for labor market outcomes is the matching efficiency, that is, the ease with which firms encounter the right candidates and unemployed individuals seeking work find the

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 87

14 Unemployment rate (actual) 13 Simulated unemployment (USS = 5.25 percent) Simulated unemployment (USS = 6.0 percent) 12 Simulated unemployment (USS = 7.0 percent) 11 Simulated unemployment (USS = 8.1 percent (historical average))

10

9

8

7

6

5 2000:Q1 2000:Q3 2001:Q1 2001:Q3 2002:Q1 2002:Q3 2003:Q1 2003:Q3 2004:Q1 2004:Q3 2005:Q1 2005:Q3 2006:Q1 2006:Q3 2007:Q1 2007:Q3 2008:Q1 2008:Q3 2009:Q1 2009:Q3 2010:Q1 2010:Q3 Figure 4.11 Actual and Simulated Unemployment (Percent) Sources: Deutsche Bundesbank; and IMF staff estimates. Note: Hypothetical paths are model-based transition paths under the assumption that the Hartz IV reforms lowered the structural (steady-state) unemployment rate (USS) to various levels. See text for details. right jobs. The appendix outlines a reduced-form version of a search model, with a focus on the implied transition dynamics.4 Model simulations suggest that the decline in unemployment observed since 2005 is likely to continue. From an average of about 8.1 percent during 1991– 2005 and a peak of 10.6 percent in 2005, the unemployment rate subsequently started a downward trend that was interrupted only briefly at the height of the financial crisis. Most recently, the unemployment rate, at just under 6 percent in 2011:Q2, has reached a level not seen in nearly two decades. The model suggests that an increase in the rate at which workers encounter the right jobs can explain much of the precrisis trend in the unemployment rate. More specifically, the model as described by equation (1) in the appendix contains two key parameters: the rate at which unemployed individuals find work, α, and the rate at which workers lose employment, δ. This equation describes the unemployment dynamics, given that current unemployment is equal to last period’s unemployment minus the share of unemployment that has found employment plus the share of the employed that has lost employment.5 Different parameterizations of the equation imply different structural (steady-state) unem- ployment rates. To the extent that the Hartz reforms raised the job-finding rate, these reforms imply a lower steady-state unemployment rate (Figure 4.11).

4 An important feature of this reduced-form model is that one can write down an explicit search- model which, for the right set of parameters, can rationalize the reduced form model used here. 5 As previously mentioned, these simplifying assumptions include ignoring movements into and out of the labor force, as well as any heterogeneity in the workforce, whereby different worker groups may have potentially different job finding/separation rates. Another important assumption is that of con- stant parameters over time (with the exception of discrete changes at the time of a shock).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 88 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

Starting from the pre-Hartz IV unemployment rate of about 10½ percent, and assigning various parameter values to the post-reform value of α, equation (1) can also be used to trace out the simulated unemployment transitions to a hypo- thetical new steady-state (Figure 4.9).6 From the peak in 2005 through the onset of the crisis, the simulated path based on a 5.25 percent long-term unemploy- ment rate gives an almost perfect fit with the post-2005 data. In this view, the crisis temporarily halted the trend decline, but employment quickly recovered and is likely to continue its downward trend.7 The simulations based on a 5.25 percent long-term rate imply that the job-finding rate would be about 50 percent higher than prior to Hartz IV, an implication that is broadly supported by other research (Lam, 2011). The interpretation of the post-2005 path as a transition to a lower structural unemployment rate also affects the interpretation of the observed labor market response. If the downward trend since 2005 is indeed a transition to a new and lower steady-state unemployment rate, rather than a low-frequency cyclical variation around the previous unemployment rate of more than 8 percent, then the unemployment dynamics during the crisis are best assessed relative to the counterfactual transition path rather than relative to precrisis levels of unemploy- ment. Thus, compared to what unemployment might have been in the absence of the crisis, unemployment at its crisis peak in 2009:Q3 had increased by over one percentage point relative to the counterfactual—this is more than twice the change calculated as the difference between the precrisis level of 7.2 percent and the crisis peak of 7.6 percent. In this reading, then, the German labor market response has not been quite as mild as typically understood.8

Hourly Flexibility Measures Some reforms, prior to and during the crisis, were targeted at hourly flexibility. The most prominent such measure included extensions to the German short-time scheme (Kurzarbeit), which subsidized workers and firms to reduce hours worked. This measure was taken up extensively by workers and firms. However, it was only a second or third step for many firms. In years prior, employers and unions had agreed on a number of measures that facilitated reductions in the work week (with commensurate income reductions) and also helped firms to smooth hours per worker over time through work-time accounts (Arbeitszeitkonten) (Box 4.2). Many workers had accumulated large surpluses in their work-time accounts (i.e., worked more than their regular work weeks), and thus firms had substantial buf- fers to adjust labor input by exhausting these measures before turning to short- time subsidies (see Sachverständigenrat, 2009).

6 See the appendix for details on the construction of the hypothetical paths. 7 However, the simulations are suggestive that unemployment may have shifted to a different trend line. 8 As a corollary, employment growth could also have been stronger absent the crisis, suggesting that the above- noted mild employment response may underestimate the true damage from the crisis.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 89

BOX 4.2 Recent Changes in German Labor Market Institutions

Recent reforms in the German labor market were mainly in two broad areas: (i) the Hartz reforms, which, broadly speaking, facilitated movements from unemployment to employ- ment, and (ii) measures to increase hourly flexibility, facilitating firms’ adjustment of labor input without necessarily changing the number of employees. This box outlines some of the key features of the various reforms. i. The Hartz reforms were a sequence of reform packages aimed at implementing the 2002 proposals by the committee on “Modern Services in the Labor Market.”a Their overall intent was to facilitate the flow from unemployment to employment, both by lowering benefits during unemployment (Hartz IV) and by adding measures to improve intermediation (Hartz I through III). More specifically: – Key aims of the first installments, the Hartz I and II reforms (both effective January 2003) were to increase and facilitate temporary employment (e.g., through personnel service agencies) and to raise the incentives for individuals receiving social benefits to engage in productive work (e.g., the Ich-AG and job centers). – The Hartz III package, effective January 2004, restructured the federal labor agency. – The last, and arguably most important, stage came with the Hartz IV measures, effec- tive January 2005. This fourth stage shortened the eligibility for unemployment insur- ance benefits (Arbeitslosengeld) to 18 months from the previous 24 months and set subsequent unemployment benefits (Arbeitslosenhilfe) at the substantially lower level of social welfare benefits (Sozialhilfe). ii. A second set of changes in the labor market regards hourly flexibility. The following list summarizes some of the key measures: – In the early 2000s, an increasing number of sectors and industries, through agree- ments between workers and employers, introduced opening clauses (Öffnungsklauseln) that allowed them to deviate from collectively bargained work arrangements, e.g., to reduce worktime without compensation, or to reduce pay in exchange for avoiding layoffs. – Firms have also increasingly taken advantage of worktime accounts (Arbeitszeitkonten). The main feature of these is to allow firms to vary workers’ hours worked over time, reducing the need for overtime pay and minimizing workers’ income fluctuations. The worktime account ensures that hourly fluctuations balance out inter-temporally. – Short-time subsidies (Kurzarbeit) by the government have been a feature of German labor market institutions for nearly a century. They facilitate work-time reductions by partially compensating workers for up to 67 percent of their lost income. The subsidy was made more generous in 2008–09 through a temporarily longer maximum dura- tion (24 months) and through increased coverage of firms’ social contributions.

a The committee was chaired by Peter Hartz, then-member of the executive board of Volkswagen Aktiengesellschaft in charge of human resources and personnel management.

The Nature of the Shock Germany experienced a different shock than, for example, the United States. While the German economy was affected strongly and real GDP declined by more than in the United States, the shock was largely externally driven, channeled to Germany through a decline in export demand. Given Germany’s strong export dependence, the impact on GDP was severe, but at the same time it was short- lived—exports recovered almost as quickly as they had deteriorated. Partly as a

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 90 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

result, Germany’s growth potential was also little affected. (See Chapter 2). The nature of the shock differed substantially from that in the United States, which suffered a more domestic and structural shock to its economy.

Interactions between Institutions, Policies and the Shock Firms’ expectations of a temporary shock only partially explain the strong reliance on hourly adjustment. Although the downturn has indeed proven temporary, with a strong recovery that started in mid-2009, the cumulative loss has been large—for example, compared to precrisis output levels, despite its robust recov- ery Germany still lags behind the United States, while the latter has suffered a large and persistent increase in unemployment.9 The labor market dynamics may reflect the still-high layoff costs. While the level of employment protection legislation (EPL) has not markedly changed in the recent past10 or during the crisis, and so cannot by itself explain the devia- tion in Germany’s labor market response from its past behavior, it is possible that the increased hourly flexibility has tilted firms’ cost-benefit analysis, mak- ing reductions in hours per worker a less costly alternative to employment reductions.11 Labor supply constraints in the form of a shortage of skilled workers may also have contributed, but the evidence is not fully conclusive. A shortage of skilled workers is frequently cited by firms, academics, and policy makers alike as being at the root of firms’ labor hoarding behavior during the crisis. Consistent with this, a duality has started to emerge in the German labor market, whereby firms have largely relied on extensive labor adjustment among temporary workers, who

9 The notion that firms rationally responded to a temporary shock by hoarding labor does not require the assumption of perfect foresight—e.g., if firms use some form of Bayesian updating, then the low level of external demand at the trough of the crisis would not have been perceived as the new equilib- rium without it persisting for a sufficiently long time. 10 Germany continues to rank high according to the OECD’s employment protection legislation (EPL) indicators, especially on regular employment (on temporary employment, Germany was below the OECD average in 2008, the latest available data point). Consequently, the OECD has repeatedly called on Germany for further reform in this area (OECD, 2011). In addition, Berger and Neugart (2012) point to an additional cost of reducing employment in the form of uncertainty over labor court decisions. In terms of labor market implications, because EPL tends to reduce both job destruction and job creation, the impact on the level of employment is conceptually unclear, reflected in simi- larly ambiguous empirical findings (Garibaldi and Mauro, 2002, versus Takizawa, 2003). But there is a broader consensus that high EPL inhibits labor market dynamism and its ability to respond to economic shocks. See Barone (2011) and Schindler (2009) for reviews of related literatures. In addi- tion, Boeri (1999) argues that the asymmetric type of EPL, as increasingly observed in Germany (i.e., regular versus temporary employment) can lead to labor market dualism. 11 That is, the same level of employment protection legislation may have a larger impact on allocations when firms have new ways of avoiding layoff costs, as in this case through more hourly flexibility. See Ljunqvist and Sargent (1998) for a similar reasoning on the interactions of institutions and shocks.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 91 are typically less skilled, while relying on more intensive adjustment for their more skilled core workforce.12 However, despite much anecdotal evidence, labor market outcomes do not fully bear out the signs of a true shortage: Brenke (2010) has noted that such a shortage should put upward pressure on their relative wages, something that has not been observed. Also, university enrollment rates in engineering and the natu- ral sciences remain at a high level and have in recent years increased substantially, suggesting that supply is relatively strong.13 While these statistics suggest that excess demand for skilled labor in the German labor market may not be as broad- based and severe as some may fear, there is little doubt that demographic pressures will pose problems in the medium term. Matching inefficiencies appear to have diminished. Even without shortages of skilled labor, firms may opt for “labor hoarding” if they find it difficult to rehire the workers they need in an upswing. The relationship between vacancies and unemployment over time (the so-called Beveridge curve, first discussed by Dow and Dicks-Mireaux, 1958) is a frequently used gauge for a country’s matching efficiency.14 It is especially insightful in the context of search models—in such models, labor supply (unemployed workers) and labor demand (firms’ vacant positions) are brought together through a matching technology, or matching function. A more efficient matching technology then implies that a given level of vacancies translates into a lower unemployment rate than would be the case with a less efficient matching technology. Graphically, shifts in the Beveridge curve toward the origin suggest gains matching efficiency, while movements along the curve are the result of equilibrium dynamics for a constant matching technology. The plot for Germany suggests that around 2007, the matching process started to improve, with the Beveridge curve now at a substantially lower level (i.e., a shift toward the origin) than pre-2007 (Figure 4.12). This apparent improvement in matching efficiency is consistent with the previously noted faster unemployment-to-employment transition associated with the Hartz reforms, including, importantly, the measures taken during the first two stages that facili- tated the development of atypical employment. All else equal, a higher matching efficiency should increase firms’ willingness to shed labor, on the expectation that finding a good match in the future will be relatively easy. While the shift in the Beveridge curve makes it at first sight more difficult to understand the stable employment during the crisis, the aggregate data hide the fact that the Hartz reforms mostly added labor supply on the lower end of the income and skill distribution. That addition is consistent with the fact that employment losses were larger among low-wage segments, suggesting that

12 Employment of temporary workers declined by 2 percent in Germany during 2009, compared with an increase of 0.4 percent in total employment (IMF, 2010, Box 3.1). 13 However, enrollment rates in these fields were broadly flat during 2004–2008, suggesting that in the coming years, graduation rates may not keep up with demand of a growing economy. 14 Vacancies and unemployment are negatively correlated, since strong hiring demand by firms (high level of vacancies) helps reduce unemployment.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 92 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

12

11

10

9 2000–07 8

7 2008–present 6 150 200 250 300 350 400 450

Figure 4.12 Beveridge Curve Source: Deutsche Bundesbank. Note: The Beveridge curve plots monthly unemployment rates (in percent, sa) against the monthly number of job vacancies (in thousands, sa).

improvements in employment flexibility and matching efficiency were more pro- nounced in those segments.

CONCLUSION The apparent puzzle of the German labor market during the crisis can be explained by a combination of factors. The German economy suffered a demand shock, which firms presumably expected to eventually reverse. Hence, firms adjusted mainly by taking advantage of options to reduce the hours worked, keep- ing employment levels relatively high (i.e., relative to that predicted by Okun’s law). At the same time, the German unemployment rate had been on a downward path since about 2005, most likely reflecting the Hartz IV reforms. This also had the effects of dampening the decline in employment and helping the employment recovery. While authors in the existing literature place emphasis on different factors (Box 4.3), most agree that the likely explanation involves some combination of hourly flexibility measures, including work-time accounts and short-time subsi- dies, low precrisis hiring, and long-standing wage moderation. While these views are consistent with the interpretation put forth in this paper, the emphasis here is different: namely, in this analysis most of the credit belongs to the Hartz reforms, which have put Germany in a position to deal well with a temporary demand shock. This still leaves ample room for further reforms. The increased flexibility of the lower-wage segment has introduced an uneven distribution of employment and wage risk: more secure high-skill and high-wage employment along with less secure low-wage work. Also, while job creation has been made easier, rigidities still remain on the job termination side, resulting in part from

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 93

BOX 4.3 The Literature on the “German Employment Miracle”

The academic literature on the German performance during the crisis is still small, unsur- prisingly so given the proximity of events. No clear consensus has yet emerged on the key drivers of the German performance. Burda and Hunt (2011) cite three main factors as the reasons for the German “labor market miracle:” relatively low precrisis hiring, due to a lack of confidence by firms in the robustness of the precrisis boom, provided a buffer during the crisis and accounted for about a third of the missing employment decline; the secular trend in wage moderation, which tends to raise employment, is seen as explaining 10 percent of the employment decline that would have otherwise been expected; and work-time accounts are seen as the third factor. Burda and Hunt do not discuss the possibility that the low precrisis hiring and accumulation of large surpluses in the work-time accounts may have similar sources and thus may not be truly separate explanations of the German labor market performance. They also do not fully explain how low precrisis hiring is consistent with the fairly strong employment gains that were made almost immediately after the ini- tial crisis shock had worn off. Lastly, just under half of the unexplained employment strength is explained in their analysis. Other authors emphasize different reasons for Germany’s labor market performance. Gartner and Merkl (2011) also emphasize precrisis wage moderation as the main source of the crisis performance, since it had in their view induced a permanent labor supply shock. It is not obvious, however, how a permanent shift would impact the employment dynamics in a cyclical downturn. It is also possible that this link between wage moderation and reduced employment losses during the crisis reverses causality—if, as argued in this chap- ter, the Hartz reforms were the underlying reason for the expansion in employment, then it is the “Hartz supply shock” that weakened workers’ bargaining positions and put further moderating pressure on wages, rather than wage moderation causing employment. Boysen-Hogrefe and Groll (2010) and Gartner and Klinger (2010), in turn, place stronger emphasis on work-time accounts as the key source of the robust employment dynamics during the crisis. Fahr and Sunde (2009) and Klinger and Rothe (2010) take a view that is most closely aligned with that in this chapter. Namely, they argue that the Hartz reforms raised the effi- ciency of the matching function increased, consistent with Gartner and Klinger’s (2010) observation of a continued shift in the Beveridge curve.

still-high employment protection and uncertainties related to labor court pro- ceedings. Lastly, demographic pressures in the medium term will necessitate broader measures, including in education and immigration, to moderate the emergence of bottlenecks. Policy conclusions for other countries are to be drawn cautiously. As argued in this note, the German crisis performance reflected the type of shock, crisis poli- cies, and initial conditions at the time of the shock. The latter, notably, reflected reforms initiated several years prior to the crisis, which put German unemploy- ment on a declining trend that mitigated the increase during the crisis. A country with differences in any of these aspects may well require a different policy response, so blindly applying measures such as the Kurzarbeit extensions could well have adverse effects if, for example, the shock were more structural in nature. One broader lesson, however, is that the “right” reforms are likely to eventually pay off.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 94 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

REFERENCES Abel, Andrew B., and Ben Bernanke, 2005, Macroeconomics, 5th edition. Addison-Wesley. Barone, Andrea, 2011, “Employment Protection Legislation: A Critical Review of the Literature.” Published online at http://jpkc.ojc.zj.cn/ldfx/UploadFiles/2010928214832623. pdf, downloaded October 18, 2011. Berger, Helge, and Michael Neugart, 2012, “How German Labor Courts Decide—An Econometric Case Study,” German Economic Review, Vol. 13, pp. 56–70. Boeri, Tito, 1999, “Enforcement of Employment Security Regulations, On-the-Job Search and Unemployment Duration,” European Economic Review, Vol. 43, pp. 65–89. Boysen-Hogrefe, Jens, and Dominik Groll, 2010, “The German Labour Market Miracle,” National Institute Economic Review, Vol. 214, pp. R38–R50. Brenke, Karl, 2010, “Fachkräftemangel kurzfristig noch nicht in Sicht,“ DIW Berlin Wochenbericht No. 46 (2010). Burda, Michael, and Jennifer Hunt, 2011, “What Explains the German Labor Market Miracle in the Great Recession?,” NBER Working Paper No. 17187 (Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research). Dow, J. C. R., and L. Dicks-Mireaux, 1958, “The Excess Demand for Labour: A Study of Conditions in Great Britain, 1946–1956,” Oxford Economic Papers, No. 10, pp. 1–33. The Economist, 1999, “The Sick Man of the Euro,” June 3rd (downloaded from http://www. economist.com/node/209559). Fahr, René, and Uwe Sunde, 2009, “Did the Hartz Reforms Speed Up the Matching Process? A Macro-Evaluation Using Empirical Matching Functions,” German Economic Review, Vol. 10, pp. 284–316. Garibaldi, Pietro, and Paolo Mauro, 2002, “Anatomy of Employment Growth,” Economic Policy, Vol. 17, pp. 67–113. Gartner, Hermann, and Sabine Klinger, 2010, “Verbesserte Institutionen für den Arbeitsmarkt in der Wirtschaftskrise,” Wirtschaftsdienst, Vol. 90, pp. 728–34. Gartner, Hermann, and Christian Merkl, 2011, “Die ökonomische Basis des Arbeits- marktwunders,” http://www.oekonomenstimme.org/artikel/2011/03/die-oekonomische-basis- des-arbeitsmarktwunders/. IMF (International Monetary Fund), 2010, World Economic Outlook: Rebalancing Growth, April (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Klinger, Sabine, and Thomas Rothe, 2010, “The Impact of Labour Market Reforms and Economic Performance on the Matching of Short-Term and Long-Term Unemployed,” IAB Discussion Paper No. 13/2010 (Nuremburg: Institute for Employment Research (IAB) of the German Federal Employment Agency (BA)). Knotek, II, Edward S., 2007, “How Useful is Okun’s Law?,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, Vol. 4, pp. 73−103. Lam, W. Raphael, 2011, “Does Labor Market Flexibility Explain Unemployment Dynamics in the Great Recession?,” IMF Working Paper, forthcoming (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Ljungqvist, Lars, and Thomas Sargent, 1998, “The European Unemployment Dilemma,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 106, pp. 514−50. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development), 2011, Economic Policy Reforms 2011: Going for Growth (Paris: OECD). Okun, Arthur M., 1962, “Potential GNP: Its Measurement and Significance,” Proceedings of the Business and Economics Statistics Section, American Statistical Association, pp. 98–104. Pissarides, Christopher A., 2000, Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, 2nd edition (Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press). Prescott, Edward C., 2004, “Why Do Americans Work So Much More Than Europeans?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Vol. 28, pp. 2–13. Rogerson, Richard, 2010, The Impact of Labor Taxes on Labor Supply: An International Perspective (Washington, DC: AEI Press).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Schindler 95

Sachverständigenrat für Wirtschaft (Sachverständigenrat), 2009, “Die Zukunft nicht aufs Spiel setzen,” Jahresgutachen 2009/10. Schindler, Martin, 2009, “The Italian Labor Market: Recent Trends, Institutions, and Reform Options,” IMF Working Paper No. 09/47 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Siebert, Horst, 1997, “Labor Market Rigidities: At the Root of Unemployment in Europe,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 11, pp. 37−54. ———, 2003, “The Failure of the German Labor Market,” Kiel Working Paper No. 1169 (Kiel: Kiel Institute for World Economics). Takizawa, Hajime, 2003, “Job-Specific Investment and the Cost of Dismissal Restrictions—The Case of Portugal,” IMF Working Paper No. 03/75 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Wunsch, Conny, 2005, “Labour Market Policy in Germany: Institutions, Instruments and Reforms since Unification,” University of St. Gallen, Department of Economics, Discussion Paper Nr. 2005–06.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 96 What Does the Crisis Tell Us about the German Labor Market?

APPENDIX A simple search model framework can help in understanding the impact of the Hartz IV reforms on unemployment. In labor markets with search frictions, tran- sitions from unemployment to employment are not instantaneous. Ignoring changes to the labor force, unemployment can thus be seen to evolve over time according to:

ut + 1 = ut(1 − α) + (1 − ut) δ (1)

where ut is unemployment at time t and α,δ are the probabilities (hazard rates) of exiting unemployment and employment, respectively. This equation also implies that steady-state unemployment can be expressed as uSS = δ / (δ + α ). (2) The Hartz IV reforms have likely lowered structural unemployment through a higher job finding rate. The pre-Hartz IV average unemployment rate was about 8.1 percent. Lam (2011) estimates the German job destruction rate at about 0.5 percent. These two values imply a pre-2005 average job finding rate of about 6.1 percent.15 Assuming δ to have remained unchanged since 2005, the steady-state equation provides a one-to-one correspondence between estimates of the (new) long-term steady-state and the implied (new) job finding rate α.16 The figure in the main text plots the resulting transition paths for a variety of possible values of the new structural unemployment rate. See also Fahr and Sunde (2009), Klinger and Rothe (2010), and Gartner and Klinger (2011) for a similar view of events.

15 Lam (2011) estimates job finding and destruction rates for 1970–2009 and for 1996–2009 and finds little difference for the different time periods (for the latter period, he estimates δ = 0.6 percent). The implied value for α corresponds to Lam’s estimate who also finds a value of also 6.1 percent dur- ing 1970–2009. 16 For the purpose of this reduced-form exercise, we take the job arrival and destruction rates as exog- enous. In a more general search model, both margins would be endogenous due to changes in indi- viduals’ reservation wages. Generally speaking, a reduction in unemployment benefits would raise job creation and lower job destruction (Pissarides, 2000)—in such models, the key channel is through wage bargaining.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CHAPTER 5 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

HÉLÈNE POIRSON AND SEBASTIAN WEBER

Can positive growth shocks from the faster-growing countries in Europe spill over to the slower-growing countries, providing useful tailwinds to their recovery process? This study investigates the potential relevance of growth spillovers in the context of the crisis and the recovery process. Based on a Vector Autoregression (VAR) framework, our analysis suggests that the United States and Japan remain the key sources of growth spillovers in this recovery, with France also playing an important role for the European crisis countries. Notwithstanding the current export-led cyclical upswing, Germany generates relatively small outward spillovers compared to other systemic countries, but it likely plays a key role in transmitting and amplifying external growth shocks to the rest of Europe given its more direct exposure to foreign shocks compared to other European countries. Positive spillovers from Spain were important prior to the 2008– 09 crisis, but Spain is generating negative spillovers in this recovery due to its depressed domestic demand. Negative spillovers from the European crisis countries appear lim- ited, consistent with their modest size.

INTRODUCTION Can positive growth impulses from the faster-growing countries in Europe spill over to the slower growing countries, providing useful tailwinds to their recovery process? This analysis investigates the relevance of such potential growth spillovers and seeks to identify the countries most likely to serve as “growth leaders.” In particular, we examine the extent to which Germany’s current upswing may spill over to other countries and accelerate recovery elsewhere. A simple correlation between the lagged quarter-on-quarter output growth rates of Germany and other euro area countries shows an increasing co-movement between Germany and other countries, including the European crisis countries (Greece, Ireland, and Portugal) in the last 20 years. A similar pattern can be

The authors thank Ashoka Mody for insightful comments and valuable suggestions. They also would like to thank Céline Allard, Ansgar Belke, Rupa Duttagupta, Felix Huefner, Irina Tytell, and Francis Vitek, participants in the Germany in an Interconnected World Economy conference (Berlin, 2011) and in the Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies internal seminar (Geneva) for useful discussions and comments; and Susan Becker for excellent research assistance. 97

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 98 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

observed for the correlations of the lagged growth rates of France and Italy with the current GDP growth rate of the rest of the euro area. The correlation of the lagged U.S. growth rate with other countries’ current GDP growth rates has also increased markedly (Figure 5.1). While more synchronized business cycles suggest increased growth spillovers, they do not provide a measure of the spillover effects of individual countries. Moreover, they could also reflect the growing influence of common factors, such as euro area monetary policy, or global factors, such as oil price developments or financial conditions in major financial centers including the United States and the United Kingdom. To disentangle the independent impact of growth shocks in individual coun- tries from the effect of common factors and measure the country-specific spillover effects, we use a structural vector autoregression (SVAR) approach with an iden- tification scheme similar to that proposed in Bayoumi and Swiston (2009). Using this framework, we undertake the following analysis: • We characterize countries by their international growth spillovers, outward and inward. Unlike former studies, which rely on regional aggregates, we use country-level data for a sample of 17 countries (accounting for almost 60 percent of global GDP, at market exchange rates), which includes 11 of the euro area countries (representing 98 percent of euro area output). Focusing on individual members rather than treating the euro area as an aggregate as in earlier studies allows us to shed light on the country-by-country spillovers and inter-linkages that drive growth dynamics. • We describe the dynamics of these spillovers during the recent crisis and recovery. This is done by applying a dynamic growth accounting calculation to the SVAR estimation results to quantify the contribution of individual countries to the recent decline and recovery in output growth. • We quantify the relevance of different channels of transmission of spillovers. We use counterfactual analysis and smaller country–by-country regressions, which include exports as an additional variable to assess the empirical rele- vance of various transmission channels, including trade and third-country effects (e.g., transmission through a common trade partner). • We analyze the determinants of the spillover size by relating outward spill- overs to both the country’s size and the relative importance of the domestic demand contribution to the country’s growth. Our main findings can be summarized as follows: • Confirming earlier results, we find evidence of significant spillover effects from the United States to the rest of the world. Outward spillovers from Germany are found to be surprisingly small (relative to growth impulses emanating from other large systemic countries), and they are largely con- fined to smaller trade partners. • The results suggest that despite the increased correlation of Germany’s growth rate with that of the rest of the euro area, the United States and Japan remain the key sources of growth spillovers in this recovery, with

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 99

1 Correlation(Country (t-1), EMU) 1 Correlation(Country (t-1), GIP) United States Japan United Kingdom Germany 0.8 France Italy 0.8

0.6 0.6

0.4 0.4

0.2 0.2

0 0

−0.2 −0.2 1975- 1980- 1985- 1990- 1995- 2000- 2005- 2009- 1975- 1980- 1985- 1990- 1995- 2000- 2005- 2009- 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 2008 2010 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 2008 2010

Figure 5.1 Growth Correlation with EMU and GIP Countries over Time: Selected Economies (1975–2010) Source: OECD, IMF staff calculations. Note: EMU: Austria, Belgium, Finland, Greece, Ireland, Netherlands, Portugal, and Spain, weighted by their respective share in the group; GIP: Greece, Ireland, and Portugal.

France also playing an important role for the European crisis countries. Positive spillovers from Spain were important prior to the crisis. However, Spain is generating negative spillovers in this recovery due to its depressed domestic demand. • In line with earlier VAR-based evidence on channels of spillover transmission across regions, the results of a country-by-country estimation of a smaller SVAR model (augmented with exports) suggest that financial and other non- trade channels explain the biggest share of cross-border growth spillovers. However, trade effects are particularly relevant in the case of Germany. • Taking the analysis one step further, we find that countries that generate the largest estimated outward spillovers are the ones where growth is largely driven by autonomous sources of domestic demand. In contrast, countries highly sensitive to external shocks, such as Germany, tend to have a rela- tively small independent, aggregate impact on other countries. This result, together with the finding that third-country effects play a significant role in the international transmission of shocks, suggests that Germany plays an important role as a transmitter and amplifier of growth shocks originating in other countries. Three main caveats should be mentioned at the outset. All three provide inter- esting avenues for future research but are beyond the scope of this paper. • Countries outside our sample might play an important role in global spill- overs, either as recipients or as a source of shocks. For instance, several

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 100 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

Eastern European countries are highly integrated with Germany and have become an integral part of the production chain of German products. For these countries, empirical evidence supports the idea that Germany has played a more prominent role in recent years (see Danninger, 2008). In recent years, China and other large emerging countries probably play an important role as a source of shocks as well, reflecting their size and increased trade linkages.1 • There may be other sources of growth spillovers beyond the business-cycle fluctuations considered in this study. For example, foreign direct investment (FDI) outflows between advanced countries and from advanced to develop- ing countries could generate significant spillovers over time, including through knowledge transfer and employment creation. Quantifying such FDI-related spillovers would require a different approach, one focused on a long-term horizon, since such effects are likely to develop only over time. • The analysis here is backward looking and does not allow for continuous time-varying relationships among the countries. In addition to full sample results, we present estimation results for a more recent sub-sample (since 1993) to account for the possibility of changed responses, in line with rap- idly increasing cross-border trade and financial linkages. The results confirm that the potential size of cross-border growth spillovers has generally increased, with the notable exceptions of Japan and Germany, for which we find no evidence of higher outward spillovers on average in the recent period. Finally, it should be noted that this analysis is descriptive. An analysis of wel- fare implications is beyond the scope of this chapter. The remainder of this chapter reviews the related literature on cross-country spillovers, outlining the main empirical approaches that have been pursued and the key findings; discusses the empirical strategies employed in this study; and high- lights the main findings and provides estimates of individual countries’ relevance for other countries’ growth dynamics. The potential reasons for the relevance of particular countries as a source of spillovers are also discussed.

GROWTH LINKAGES AND SPILLOVERS: RELATED LITERATURE The empirical literature on growth spillovers has dealt with three interrelated questions: What is the size of growth spillovers? Which countries or regions are

1 While data availability constrains the inclusion of China and other emerging countries in the sample, we indirectly attempted to test this hypothesis in an earlier version of the study by including exports to China, to developing Asia, and to the world as additional control variables. Those variables were not statistically significant and the results remained largely unchanged, suggesting that the sample countries already capture the bulk of relevant global demand shocks for the period under consider- ation (1975–2010).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 101 the main sources of growth spillovers? and, What are the main channels of trans- mission of growth spillovers? Existing empirical studies generally confirm the existence of spillover effects, but the empirical evidence about the size of spillovers is inconclusive, as results are not robust to different samples and specifications. Previous studies frequently divide the world into regions,2 the euro area being one of them, and examine spillovers from large advanced countries to these regions.3 The general finding of these studies is that the United States is the main source of growth spillovers. Relatively few studies have examined the channels through which growth shocks are transmitted to the other regions and countries. Existing findings vary across studies, with simulation-based results suggesting a bigger role for the trade chan- nel—perhaps due to the difficulty of empirically modeling asset price spillovers or confidence channels—while VAR analyses, which impose less structure on the interlinkages, point to the relative importance of financial and other nontrade channels. The finding that international spillovers are relatively small under standard trans- mission channels was first established by Helbling and others (2007). Their study finds a limited extent of U.S. growth spillovers into other regions—excluding the euro area and Japan—and even smaller effects of spillovers from the euro area or Japan, when controlling for possible channels of transmission including commodity prices (terms of trade) and financial conditions (Libor interest rate). The results obtained are similar using three alternative approaches (simple panel regressions, a more sophisticated dynamic analysis, and model simulations). The estimated spill- overs are moderate in magnitude: the results from annual panel regressions for 130 countries over 1970–2005 suggest that a 1 percentage point decline in U.S. growth is associated in the long run with an average 0.16 percent drop in growth across the sample. The findings based on a VAR approach for 46 countries, both advanced and developing, also suggest that U.S. growth disturbances have on average moderate dynamic effects on growth in other regions. The simulation results in Helbling and others (2007) also suggest that the potential spillovers from a temporary, U.S.- specific demand shock via trade channels alone are moderate, roughly of the same magnitude as the results from the panel and VAR analyses. However, alternative simulations, assuming correlated disturbances across countries, generate larger spill- over effects. The authors of the study conjecture that such a higher impact of U.S. shocks could arise, for example, if the transmission had also involved asset price spillovers or confidence channels. Using a long-run (five-year average) panel regression approach for 101 coun- tries over 1960–1999, Arora and Vamvakidis (2006) find much larger spillovers.

2 See, for example, Helbling and others (2007), Arora and Vamvakidis (2006), Bayoumi and Swiston (2009), and Swiston (2010). For an example of similar approaches applied to the case of China spill- overs, see Arora and Vamvakidis (2010). 3 For the latter, see Bayoumi and Swiston (2009). This study examines the extent of spillovers across industrial regions including the U.S., the euro area, Japan, and an aggregate of small industrial coun- tries, using VARs of growth across the four regions.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 102 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

In most specifications, a roughly 1 point increase in U.S. and EU growth is asso- 1 ciated with, respectively, a roughly 1 point and ⁄3 point increase in other coun- tries’ growth (while Japan has an insignificant effect). However, the results could capture forces beyond short-term demand and business cycle effects transmitted via trade channels, such as technology spillovers, and are thus not directly com- parable to those of Helbling and others (2007). Similar to Helbling and others (2007), Bayoumi and Swiston (2009) focus on short-run dynamics across industrial regions during 1970–2006. Their main results suggest significant U.S. spillovers to other industrial regions, including the eurozone, Japan, and a group of smaller advanced economies (of one-quarter to one-half the size of the U.S. shock after two years). Spillovers from the euro area or Japan are found to be smaller than spillovers from the United States and insig- nificant in most cases, except for spillovers from Japan to the euro area (which are found to be of similar size to those from the United States). Helbling and others (2007) generally find lower spillovers from the United States to other countries compared to Bayoumi and Swiston (2009). This is due to two main reasons: First, Helbling and others use the London Interbank Offered Rate (Libor) rate as a control variable. This amounts to some extent to shutting off a potential transmission channel and thus implies a lower estimated growth spill- over from the U.S. GDP. In fact, Bayoumi and Swiston provide estimates of this transmission channel and show that the interest rate channel accounts for close to 50 percent of the transmission of U.S. growth shocks. Thus, once Helbling and others’ results are adjusted by this gap, spillover effects from the United States to other countries are closer to Bayoumi and Swiston’s estimates. Second, Helbling and others look at responses in countries which exclude the eurozone and Japan. As the authors themselves note, countries that have higher financial and trade link- ages with the United States respond more strongly to growth shocks in the United States. In fact, for Canada and Mexico they find responses to U.S. growth shocks comparable in size to the average response found by Bayoumi and Swiston to U.S. shocks. Thus, the sample choice appears to explain the remaining difference in the estimated impact. Our results are comparable to Bayoumi and Swiston (2009) when looking at the entire sample period, but show an even higher response to U.S. GDP when looking at the more recent episode from 1993 to 2010. This largely reflects the higher financial integration of the United States with other countries in this period compared to the 1975–1993 period. To our knowledge, few studies have examined growth spillovers and linkages within Europe. For Germany, empirical results suggest relatively small growth spillover effects. Danninger (2008) estimates a VAR model for the growth rates of the United States, Japan, Germany, an aggregate of other euro area members, and an additional aggregate for the new EU member countries, for the period 1993–2007. While he finds significant spillovers from the euro area aggregate to the new EU member states and to Germany, he finds very limited spillovers from Germany to other countries. However, his estimation results for a more recent sample (since 1998) suggest stronger spillovers from Germany to the euro area

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 103 and the new member countries, with 40 percent and 100 percent, respectively, of any German growth shock transmitted after three quarters. A related literature examines fiscal policy spillovers within Europe. Bénassy- Quéré and Cimadomo (2006) generally find positive cross-border spillovers from Germany, in the sense that a fiscal expansion in Germany raises GDP abroad, at least in neighboring and smaller countries. Similarly, Beetsma, Giuliodori, and Klaassen (2005) find that, averaged across all partner countries, the effect on foreign GDP of a fiscal stimulus in Germany of 1 percent of GDP is estimated to be 0.12 percent for a spending increase and 0.03 percent for a net tax cut. In Chapter 6 of this volume, Ivanova and Weber find spillovers of a similar order of magnitude for fiscal consolidation in Germany, France, the United Kingdom, and the United States. The authors argue that even when multipliers are very large, spillovers are limited, in particular from core EU countries to peripheral countries, since trade links between the two areas are not very strong. Few studies have examined the transmission channels of spillovers, that is, the major international channels through which shocks are propagated. Using model- based simulation analysis, Helbling and others (2007) find that most of the U.S. spillover effects are trade-related, and the effects are relatively small, roughly of the same magnitude as identified in the panel and VAR analyses. To generate larger effects, alternative simulations need to assume that disturbances are corre- lated around the world. The authors posit that such correlated disturbances could be related to increased trade and/or financial integration and could particularly arise in times of financial crisis. The simulation results in Bagliano and Morana (2011) also suggest a rela- tively more important role for the trade channel as a mechanism for transmitting U.S. economic developments to the rest of the world. Based on a large-scale open- economy factor VAR macroeconometric model, Bagliano and Morana find no clear-cut impact of adverse U.S. financial developments on foreign economic activity. While increases in a U.S. credit spread index lead to an output contrac- tion abroad, U.S. stock price dynamics do not have any relevant effect on foreign GDP, and U.S. house price dynamics only affect the non-OECD group. Hence, the authors of the study conclude that the trade channel appears to be the key transmission mechanism of U.S. shocks to the rest of the world. By contrast, Bayoumi and Swiston (2009) find that the largest estimated con- tributions to spillovers come from financial rather than trade variables. Their result is based on a comparison of the response of GDP growth in a basic VAR model to that in a model augmented with a potential spillover source (either trade, commodity prices, or financial conditions) to measure the contribution of this source to the estimated spillovers. In particular, short-term interest rates and financial conditions more generally (bond yields and equity prices) are found to play an important role in the international transmission of U.S. growth shocks. Galesi and Sgherri (2009), using a global VAR approach, also report that equity prices are the main channel through which—in the short-run—financial shocks are transmitted from the United States to other countries. They find that other

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 104 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

variables—including real credit growth, real GDP growth, and real interbank rate—become more important over a two-year horizon. The analysis of cross-country growth spillovers and, more generally, multicoun- try estimations is generally hampered by dimensionality constraints. Four different VAR-based approaches have been suggested to tackle this issue:4 Bayesian VARs, factor model VARs, global VARs, and VARs based on regional groupings. All four techniques also require an approach for resolving the identification issue. • The Bayesian VAR approach tackles the problem with the use of priors about the cross-country correlation patterns, which are subsequently updat- ed with the data (Banbura et al., 2008, and Canova and Ciccarelli, 2006). • Factor models, instead, collapse cross-country co-movements of several variables into common factors that are then allowed to affect the dynamics of the individual countries (Bénassy-Quéré and Cimadomo, 2006). • Global VARs reduce the individual countries’ spillovers to their share in a weighted average for the variable of interest, which then affects the individual countries’ dynamics.5 The spillover in the global VAR therefore has a direct interpretation, unlike the spillover in the factor VAR (Bussière, Chudik, and Sestieri, 2009; Galesi and Sgherri, 2009; and Dees and others, 2007). • A fourth approach focuses on a small set of countries or regions—usually two to four—and then uses the traditional structural VAR (SVAR) approach (Bayoumi and Swiston, 2009; and Danninger, 2008). The degrees of free- dom are preserved by reducing the number of regressors, that is, by reducing either the number of countries involved or the number of variables consid- ered, or a combination of both. Bayesian VARs and SVARs are more general than global VARs or factor VARs, since they impose less structure on the inter-linkages. Compared to SVARs, Bayesian VARs require making more assumptions on the data generating process in return for more degrees of freedom, which makes the estimation feasible if the number of regressors is high relative to the size of the available data sample. The SVAR approach proposed by Bayoumi and Swiston (2009) requires an extensive dataset, but has the advantage that it imposes no structure on the inter-linkages, and thus the coefficient estimates are purely data-driven. Our analysis takes the existing literature further in the following way: • We confirm the finding of earlier studies, based on the assessment of spill- overs across regions, that the United States remains the main source of growth spillovers, using an approach that involves a larger set of 17 indi- vidual countries.

4 Another possibility is to use model-based simulation analysis. See, for example, the analysis based on structural estimated macro models using panel unobserved components estimation as suggested by Vitek (2009 and 2010). 5 Cross-border trade weights are generally used to estimate the country-specific aggregate foreign vari- able, although one study uses annual bank lending exposures over 1999–2007 (Galesi and Sgherri, 2009).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 105

• We provide a decomposition of countries’ growth rate into the contribu- tions from domestic and foreign components during the recent crisis and the recovery process. • We confirm the importance of financial transmissions channels for growth spillovers, but find that trade channels are also relevant for several countries. • A more general distinction made evident by the analysis in this paper is the distinction between autonomous country demand and transmission of global demand shocks. Our findings suggest that while spillovers vary positively with country size, they also reflect the extent to which growth is domestically driven. This has implications for the extent to which some economies can be consid- ered engines of global or regional growth or, alternatively, can be considered transmitters of growth shocks that originate elsewhere.

EMPIRICAL APPROACH Given our focus on a univariate growth spillover framework, we follow Bayoumi and Swiston (2009) and minimize the structure we impose on the data. The resulting coefficient estimates thus capture all potential channels of transmission of shocks, including both trade and financial channels (the latter of which may be the most relevant in times of financial crises, when correlations between all risky assets tend to rise). The main specification is based on a reduced-form VAR estimation. Identification is obtained by weighting different orderings. The results from the different orderings can then be summarized by focusing on the average impulse response. This approach has the additional advantage that it provides not only a measure of uncertainty regarding the coefficient estimates but also a measure of uncertainty associated with the variation of responses across different orderings. The following derivations are reduced to a minimum when referring to the Bayoumi and Swiston (2009) approach.

Estimation Framework The general model is given by the following reduced-form model for the growth rate of output:

BLy()ttt=+ DLx () e where the vector y is given by stacking each country’s GDP growth rate ( yi,t): yy=  y y tt()1, itIt , ,

We consider the following sample of 17 countries: Austria, Belgium, Canada, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, and United States. The model is estimated on quarterly real PPP-adjusted GDP data, from 1975:Q1 to 2010:Q3, from the OECD Economic Outlook database. The control vector x includes two dummy variables for

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 106 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

the oil shocks in 1979 and in 1990, respectively, and a constant term. When discuss- ing the results we refer to the baseline regression as the regression which includes additionally a crisis dummy that takes the value 1 from 2008:Q4–2009:Q1, to reflect estimates of “normal times,” while the framework without the crisis dummy also reflects the relationship across growth rates in crisis times.6 Identification is obtained using the Choleski ordering of the countries in the sample, which provides the structural errors and coefficients: ε=−−11 =() = ()−1 () ttAeA(0) (l )AB (0) (lFl )AD 0 l

For the ordering, we distinguish three sets of countries according to their share in the total sample size, measured in USD PPP-adjusted GDP: Countries that surpass the 8 percent threshold are considered large countries and can be a leading country (U.S., Japan, and Germany). Countries that contribute less than 4 per- cent to the total output are considered small economies (Canada, Netherlands, Belgium, Sweden, Austria, Switzerland, Greece, Portugal, Ireland, and Finland). These latter countries are ordered last in the order of their size. Since we focus on shocks from the major countries to other nations, the ordering for the group of the remaining smaller countries does not affect the results. The intermediate group of countries comprises the medium-size countries (United Kingdom, France, Italy, and Spain). While they are never ordered first, they are generally ordered before the small countries. We arrange the orderings roughly according to the respective country’s relative size. The orderings assign a probability of 50 percent to the United States, being the lead country (in line with Bayoumi and Swiston, 2009), that is, the country that is not contemporaneously affected by other countries, and respectively a 25 percent probability to the United States to be ordered second or third. Japan and Germany are treated symmetrically throughout (although Japan is somewhat larger than Germany). Germany and Japan both have a chance of being ordered first, second, or third of 25 percent and a 12.5 percent probability of being ordered fourth or fifth. The United Kingdom, France, and Italy are also treated symmetrically, given their comparable average size. Each of these three countries 1 has a probability of being ordered second or third of 8 /3 percent, of being ordered fourth or sixth of 25 percent, and of being ordered fifth or seventh of 2 16 /3 percent. Spain has a probability of being ordered fifth or sixth of 25 percent and of being ordered seventh of 50 percent. This size-based procedure results in 48 different orderings, the details of which are provided in the Appendix.

6 Alternative control variables, including the oil and non-oil commodity price indices, U.S. and German short-term and long-term interest rates, U.S. investment grade and high-yield credit spreads, German corporate bond spreads, U.S. and German real equity prices, world trade, and Asia trade, were also included as a robustness check in an earlier version of the analysis. However, none of these control variables except the U.S. credit spreads and, to a lesser extent, U.S. real equity prices was significant, and their inclusion left the results unchanged. The impact of the U.S. credit spread, how- ever, becomes insignificant when included in addition to the 2008–09 crisis dummy, suggesting that this variable is essentially a proxy for the global financial crisis.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 107

The computation of the standard errors and the ordering uncertainty follow Bayoumi and Swiston (2009).

Dynamic Growth Contribution The dynamic contribution is computed by applying to each ordering the follow- ing algorithm: Step 1: Determine the structural errors at each point in time using the Cholesky decomposition. ε=ˆ ˆ −1 ∀∈ ttAe(0) ˆ t T

Step 2: Compute the moving average (MA) representation of the entire history of each country’s growth rate.

T =εˆ yMTT∑ ()t −t t =0

Step 3: Create an identity matrix of dimension N and combine the MA repre- sentation and the structural errors to derive the contribution of the respective country’s shocks to the quarterly growth rate of GDP of the country under con- sideration.7

t ˆ =εˆ ˆ CMttt∑ ()t I − t =0

Step 4: Apply the relevant compounding rule to compute the annualized con- tribution.8 While the ordering of the small countries matters in theory for this exercise, in practice the ordering of these countries is of minor importance for the decom- position of the growth contribution, since growth dynamics are dominated by the larger economies. A similar calculation applies to the constant term, which allows decomposing the long-run growth rate into the contributions from the individual countries in the sample.

Transmission Channels To gain a better understanding of the transmission channels of the shocks, we employ a twofold strategy. The first approach uses a counterfactual analysis. We maintain the estimation framework as outlined above, but contrast the results to a scenario under which only the direct impact of the shock in country i is allowed

 7 = ˆ Note that yCitt where i is a column vector of ones, with dimension N in the absence of any exogenous controls. 8 The rule will depend on whether the dependent variable and the shock are a level variable or a growth rate.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 108 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

to affect country j and all spillovers through third countries are prevented. This provides us with information about the relevance of inter-linkages across coun- tries for the transmission of shocks. In a second approach, we estimate country- wise VARs, in which we include real exports as an explanatory variable to test for the importance of the trade channel. Counterfactual Analysis In the counterfactual analysis, we constrain the structural coefficients, which are associated with third-country effects, to equal zero. Thus, if we are interested in looking at the direct spillover from country i’s growth shocks to country k’s growth rate, we set all structural coefficients corresponding to the impact of coun- try j’s growth shocks on country k equal to zero:9 α= kj ()l 0

for all l = 0,…,L and all j ≠ i and j ≠ k, where α are the structural coefficients. Impulse responses are then recalculated under the counterfactual assumptions. Country-by-Country Regressions To arrive at a parsimonious specification, we assume the sensitivity to specific countries to be homogenous within a region and the difference in the slopes within a group to be random. The United States, Japan, Canada, Sweden, Switzerland and the United Kingdom comprise the non-European Monetary Union (non-EMU, or RoW) group, and the rest of the countries constitute the EMU group. For each country we then run the following regression: = A()L yett

= RoWEMU EMU where the vector y is given by: yyt ()i,,t yi t EXPi ,,t yi t and Yi,t is EMU = k the growth rate of the output of the EMU area (YYi,tt∑ ) where k runs k≠i over all EMU members except for country i (when it is an EMU country) and Y RoW YYRoW = ∑ j i,t is the growth rate of the output of the non-EMU group ( i,tt) ji≠ where j runs over all non EMU members except for country i (when it is not an EMU country).10 While throughout this exercise we keep the ordering as above, we also allow in a robustness test for different orderings.11 This approach has the

9 This is likely to underestimate the relevance of the third-country effects since it is still possible that third countries can have a positive feedback to country i and via this to country k. In practice these are very small. 10 For all EMU members, the RoW shock is identical, while for all RoW members the EMU shock is identical. 11 In particular, we look at the average response to an EMU and a non-EMU shock ordering once RoW and once EMU first. This leaves the point estimates mostly unchanged. Allowing addi- Yi,t Yi,t = RoWEMU tionally for the following ordering Yt ()EXPi,,,t Yi t Yi t Yi ,t affects the point estimates, but not the relative magnitude across countries, leaving the interpretations unchanged.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 109 advantage that it provides a more convenient framework to distill the importance of the trade channel as a transmission channel and reduces the problem of ordering to a simpler choice. By grouping countries and using the group’s growth rate, we implicitly allow for an increasing weight of a country as it grows bigger relative to other countries. To see this, consider the coefficient on the growth rate of the non-EMU variable:

⎛⎞∑Y j t I ⎛⎞ ⎜⎟j≠k YY−− α=α−=α(0)y RoW (0) 1 (0)∑ i,1t ⎜⎟i ,1t − 1 kt, ⎜⎟j ⎝⎠ ⎜⎟∑∑YYt −−1,1i≠k j t Yi,1t − ⎝⎠j≠≠k j k

The right-hand version of the coefficient may be conveniently rewritten in the following form: I Y αα=αi,1t − ∑ i,,t(0)yi t i ,t (0) (0) i≠k ∑Y j,1t − j≠k

Thus, this model and the baseline estimation are identical under the assump- α=α=α =  = tion that i,,t ()llli tt−  ()i () for all lL1,.., and all t 1,..,T for this α =α + = =σ model and all ki ()llkk () v i with E()v 0 and E()vvv I in the baseline model and the extension that the real exports of country k are included as an additional variable.12

RESULTS This section provides an overview of the key transmission channels (trade vs. finan- cial linkages) to help interpret the results, followed by a discussion of the main results derived from the estimation framework. The first set of results focuses on the potential impact of spillovers from a one percent growth shock in selected countries on other European countries. The second set of results presents the actual impact of selected countries on all other countries in the run-up to, during, and in the recovery from the recent financial crisis by combining the country-specific shocks with the impulse response functions. A third and fourth set of results, respectively, point to the relevance of the different transmission mechanisms of growth shocks and of different potential determinants of spillover size.

Cross-Border Linkages To interpret our results on the growth linkages, it is helpful to understand some key facts about the relative exposures of countries in the sample to the largest economies and regions. The most obvious channel is trade linkages: a rise in tra- ding partners’ growth leads to an increase in their demand for imports, which

12 Unsurprisingly, this turns out not to hold, and the aggregation bias causes responses to be more pronounced (Imbs and others, 2005). Results are discussed in more detail in the respective section.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 110 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

TABLE 5.1 Exports to Selected Countries and Regions, 2010 (Percent of GDP) With With With With Euro United With United With With Rest of Germany Area1 States Kingdom Japan China World Austria 12.7 9.3 1.4 1.2 0.3 0.9 13.6 Belgium 16.5 37.0 4.6 6.2 0.8 1.4 20.1 Canada 0.2 0.8 18.4 1.0 0.6 0.8 2.8 Finland 2.9 6.4 2.0 1.4 0.5 1.4 14.0 France 3.2 6.5 1.0 1.3 0.3 0.5 6.8 Germany ... 15.7 2.0 2.4 0.4 1.8 14.2 Greece 0.8 2.2 0.3 0.4 0.0 0.1 3.2 Ireland 4.5 18.2 12.1 8.9 1.1 1.0 9.2 Italy 2.8 6.6 1.2 1.2 0.3 0.5 8.8 Japan 0.4 0.8 2.2 0.3 ... 2.7 7.8 Netherlands 18.8 26.2 2.7 5.6 0.5 0.9 17.7 Portugal 2.8 10.9 0.7 1.2 0.1 0.1 5.4 Spain 1.8 7.9 0.6 1.1 0.1 0.2 5.4 Sweden 3.5 9.9 2.1 2.6 0.4 1.0 13.5 Switzerland 7.2 10.9 3.8 2.2 1.2 1.4 10.6 United Kingdom 1.9 6.5 1.9 ... 0.2 0.4 5.8 United States 0.3 0.9 ... 0.3 0.4 0.6 6.1

Source: Direction of Trade Statistics (DOTS); IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations. 1 Excluding Germany.

then contributes directly to an increase in the net exports of the home country (Table 5.1). With growing financial integration and cross-border ownership of assets, growth spillover effects may also be transmitted through financial linkages (Table 5.2). Both trade and financial exposures highlight the importance of intra- euro area transmission channels. For most European countries in our sample, the euro area as a whole is by far the biggest export market and accounts for the larg- est single banking sector exposure. The United States is also a key source of financial spillover risk for European countries. Within the euro area, it is note- worthy that for most countries (except the smaller trading partners), trade expo- sures to Germany are relatively smaller than trade exposures to the rest of the euro area as a whole, reflecting Germany’s relatively limited demand for imports from other European advanced countries. Several European countries, however, have large financial exposures to Germany. Trade exposures follow a strong regional pattern. In particular, they suggest a limited relevance of Asia for the sample countries (although growing in impor- tance in the case of China). More specifically, we find that: • Trade links within Europe are important, as is evident in Table 5.1. The euro area is the largest export market for member countries in the sample, except Greece. For the Netherlands and Belgium, exports to the euro area account for about half of GDP, with a sizeable share (30 to 40 percent) directed to Germany alone.13 Even for Ireland, which has close trade ties with the

13 This holds also true when controlling for re-exports.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 111

TABLE 5.2 Banking Exposures to Selected Countries and Regions, 2010 (Percent of GDP)1 With With European Of which: With With Rest With Developed with Euro United With With United of Germany Countries2 Area3 States Japan China Kingdom World Austria 14.1 37.0 ... 4.7 0.4 0.5 5.4 67.1 Belgium 4.1 41.2 ... 8.1 0.2 0.3 8.5 22.0 Canada 1.0 4.3 ... 30.6 0.4 0.3 5.5 10.2 Finland 1.0 6.7 ... 0.2 0.0 0.0 1.0 1.3 France 11.0 54.0 49.4 21.5 6.0 0.8 12.4 23.7 Germany ... 41.2 37.8 15.7 1.7 0.5 14.4 16.6 Greece 1.8 7.1 ... 1.5 0.0 0.0 5.5 30.3 Ireland 21.7 67.2 ... 41.7 5.9 ... 91.0 31.5 Italy 12.9 15.2 14.1 2.1 ... 0.2 2.2 11.7 Japan 3.0 7.1 5.9 24.8 ... 0.7 2.9 5.4 Netherlands 22.0 57.6 ... 32.2 2.1 1.5 16.5 40.9 Portugal 2.0 31.7 ... 3.7 0.0 0.1 3.6 22.4 Spain 3.1 15.8 14.4 3.2 0.1 0.5 14.1 42.8 Sweden 16.3 94.3 ... 9.9 0.1 0.5 8.8 24.1 Switzerland 24.5 53.0 47.6 132.6 15.8 2.7 36.7 56.2 United 8.0 42.5 38.4 48.6 6.5 3.7 ... 62.2 Kingdom United States 1.6 5.1 4.1 ... 5.1 0.5 4.7 4.4

Source: Bank for International Settlements; IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations. 1 International bank claims of domestically-owned banks, consolidated - ultimate risk basis. 2 Excluding Germany and the UK. 3 Excluding Germany.

United States, the share of exports going to the euro area exceeds that going to the United States. • The euro area is also the largest importer for the United Kingdom and Switzerland, and the second largest for the United States. However, it is only the fourth export destination for Japan, which relies more on U.S., Chinese, and other regional markets. • Despite its size and reflecting a relatively closed economy, the United States is generally not the major trading partner for European countries. • Trade exposures to Japan are even more limited. Trade exposures to China are also limited (except in the case of Japan), although the growing impor- tance of China is underscored by the fact that China has now overtaken Japan in its importance as importer for all sample countries (except Ireland). • Similar to the United States and Japan, Germany’s relevance as an importer is relatively limited—including for other eurozone countries. While Germany is the second largest export destination for Austria and the Netherlands, it is only at best the third largest export exposure for the other European countries. These countries export relatively more either to the non-German euro area as a whole or to the rest of the world (excluding the

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 112 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

euro area, the United States, the United Kingdom, China, and Japan). In the case of non-euro area countries, exports to Germany account for less than 0.5 percent of GDP. Financial linkages single out the United States and Europe, in the aggregate, as main sources of global spillover risks, while Germany’s importance is mostly regional. Overall, financial exposures—proxied by bilateral bank lending expo- sures on an ultimate risk basis—follow a broadly similar regional pattern as trade exposures, illustrating the relative importance of intra-European linkages: • For European countries, exposure to European developed countries is the single largest source of spillover risks, amounting to 30 percent of GDP or more (except in Finland and Greece).14 For the United States, exposure to Europe also ranks as the first source of risks; however, relative to GDP many European countries (including Switzerland, the United Kingdom, France, Germany, and the Netherlands) have much larger exposures to the United States than the United States does to Europe. • Within Europe, some countries have high exposures to Germany of 10 percent of GDP or more (France, Austria, Switzerland, Netherlands, Ireland, Sweden). By contrast, non-European countries (United States, Canada, and Japan) have banking exposures to Germany at or below 3 per- cent of GDP, well below their level of exposures to the United Kingdom in the case of the United States and Canada. • For Canada and Japan, financial linkages highlight the key role of the United States as a source of spillover risks, with European exposure the second largest source of risk. • Exposures to Japan are at or below 6 percent of GDP for all countries (except Switzerland), and exposures to China are below 1 percent of GDP in most cases (except the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, and Switzerland).

Country-Specific Outward and Inward Growth Spillovers We illustrate the potential cross-border spillovers by calculating the maximum weighted cumulative impulse response of the other countries to a one percent growth shock in the originating country. Detailed impulse responses of single countries are shown in the Appendix. Outward Growth Spillovers The baseline regression results (full sample, including a dummy for the 2008–09 crisis) suggest that the United States remains the largest source of spillovers to all countries in the sample. By contrast, Germany plays a minor role for the sample

14 In all cases, except for Greece, Spain, Austria, and the U.K., which also have significant exposures to the rest of the world (excluding the U.S., Japan, and Europe) and Switzerland (which has the largest single exposure to the U.S.), European developed countries are the single largest source of banking exposures.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 113 in aggregate, although some smaller European countries are strongly affected by German growth. The United Kingdom and Japan fall between the two, as do France, Italy, and Spain. Since the regressions include a crisis dummy, this first set of results can be interpreted as the “normal” response outside times of crisis. Regression results for an alternative specification, excluding the crisis dummy, show much higher outward spillover effects from all regions, supporting the view that nonstandard transmission channels are at play during times of crisis. Such channels could include, for example, correlated downturns in asset prices and/or confidence effects, which amplify the effect of a given growth shock over and above the standard transmission of shocks through trade and/or lending channels. While spillovers from all the large countries are found to increase during times of crisis, the increase is especially pronounced during the recent period for the United States, the United Kingdom, and the non-German euro area. This could reflect the fact that the 2008–09 crisis was triggered by the housing correction in the United States and the United Kingdom, which later affected other countries, like Spain, where the real estate market was similarly overheated. In contrast, Germany was not an independent source of shocks during the recent financial crisis. Estimates for the more recent subsample (1993:Q1–2010:Q3) do not suggest an increasingly important role of Germany for spillovers to other countries. By contrast, we find evidence of Italy’s and the United States’ increased importance for spillovers to other countries in recent years (Figure 5.2). Looking at disaggregated results within Europe, Germany’s role in generating outward spillovers appears limited despite the economy’s large size, in part reflect- ing Germany’s own dependence on growth in the rest of the eurozone (as dis- cussed in the next section). Germany is particularly sensitive to growth shocks in the other three large euro area countries (France, Italy, and Spain) and in Japan, while the United Kingdom is less relevant. France is sensitive to Spain and, to a lesser extent, to Italy, and is much less sensitive to growth shocks in Germany than Germany is to growth shocks in France. Italy’s growth reacts relatively simi- larly to growth shocks in the other three large euro area countries, the United States, and Japan, but shows little sensitivity to the United Kingdom in normal times. Spain’s growth is potentially strongly affected by growth shocks in the United Kingdom and in France (possibly due to Spanish banks’ relatively large exposures to the United Kingdom) and to a lower extent by growth shocks in Italy. Germany and Japan generate only minor outward growth spillovers to Spain, reflecting limited trade and financial linkages. In particular, there is little support for the view that euro area peripheral coun- tries could benefit strongly from Germany’s ongoing recovery. The results suggest that positive growth shocks in France and Italy generate larger spillover effects to the European periphery. The impact of Germany and other large countries on Greece, Ireland, and Portugal (GIP) can be summarized as follows: • Germany plays a less prominent role for the GIP than France and, to a lesser extent, than Italy. However, this result masks considerable heterogene- ity in the responses across the GIP. Italy and France appear to have a relevant

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 114 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

2.50 Response by all other countries to a growth shock in...

1993Q1:2010Q3 Excluding crisis dummy 2.00 1993Q1:2010Q3 1975Q1:2010Q3 Excluding crisis dummy 1975Q1:2010Q3

1.50

1.00

0.50

0.00 United States Japan Germany United Kingdom Rest of EAb GIP

2.50 Response of the GIP to a growth shock in...

1993Q1:2010Q3 Excluding crisis dummy 2.00 1993Q1:2010Q3 1975Q1:2010Q3 Excluding crisis dummy 1975Q1:2010Q3 1.50

1.00

0.50

0.00

United States Japan Germany United Kingdom France Italy

−0.50

Figure 5.2 Cumulative Peak Impulse Response after 10 Quarters to a 1 Percent Growth Shock (In percent)a Source: IMF staff estimates. aGDP-weighted average response of other countries. bExcluding Germany. influence on Ireland and Portugal. This is much less the case for Germany. However, Germany tends to have a higher impact on Greece than Italy does, but it still has less impact on Greece than France does. • The United States has much more of an impact on Ireland than on the other GIP countries, consistent with results in Kanda (2008) and the close trade and financial linkages between the two countries. The United States also has

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 115

a more pronounced impact on Greece and Portugal in the context of the financial crisis and the more recent episode. • Japan and the United Kingdom play a relatively minor role for the GIP, although the United Kingdom’s impact during the crisis was more pro- nounced. Finally, the results suggest that potential negative growth spillovers from the GIP to other countries are limited, although a broadening of the crisis to larger eurozone countries would have significant real implications. The impact of Greece, Portugal, and Ireland as a group on other countries appears relatively small, con- sistent with their modest size. A shock to Spain’s growth, however, has potentially a much larger impact, particularly on other European countries (see Appendix). Inward Growth Spillovers Turning to the sensitivity of the four large euro area members to inward spillovers, the results underline Germany’s high sensitivity to external shocks. A first set of estimates from the small-country VARs shows that Germany responds to a growth shock in EMU countries more strongly than any of the other large EMU countries and exhibits the second largest response (after Italy) to growth shocks in non-EMU countries (Figure 5.3). Thus, Germany’s growth is more sensitive to foreign shocks than is that of other large EMU countries, especially to shocks originating within the EMU. This is consistent with Germany’s large trade and banking exposures to the rest of Europe. The result that Germany is highly sensi- tive to foreign shocks also supports the view that Germany is less of a source of

2 0.7 After 1 year After 10 quarters Large model 1.8 0.6 1.6

1.4 0.5

1.2 0.4 1 0.3 0.8

0.6 0.2

0.4 0.1 0.2

0 0.0 Germany Italy France Spain Germany Italy France Spain EMU shock Non-EMU shock

Figure 5.3 Sensitivity to a 1 Percent Growth Shock in the Large European Countriesa Source: IMF Staff estimates. a Right axis = weighted impact on growth in percentage points in response to shock under the large model; left axis = impact on growth in percentage points in response to shock under the small model.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 116 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

independent spillovers and more of a conduit for U.S. and other external shocks to the rest of Europe. A second set of estimates from the main baseline estimation (i.e., large model)15 yields the same rank ordering of sensitivity to external shocks as the smaller country-specific VARs.16 Regression results for the more recent period (since 1993, based on the large model) show that inward spillovers from the United States to the four large EMU member states have increased, while the United Kingdom and Japan have become less relevant (Figure 5.4). In the baseline estimation, in normal times a 1 percent growth shock in the United States tends to increase output growth within 10 quar- ters by about 0.3 percent in Germany, 0.4 percent in Italy and France, and 0.1 percent in Spain. These values increase to 0.4 percent in Germany and Spain, 0.5 percent in France, and 0.6 percent in Italy when not controlling for the effect of crisis times. The respective values more than double for Germany and Spain, in the more recent episode (estimation for 1993:Q1–2010:Q3 including a crisis dummy), as both become more sensitive to the United States than France and Italy. The increased sensitivity to the United States is in line with the increased cor- relation of the EMU countries’ GDP growth with the lagged GDP growth of the United States (Figure 5.1). This reflects rising financial linkages, which have become more important, particularly in the latter half of the sample period. It is consistent with similar findings by Helbling and others (2007), who find spill- overs to be increasing in financial and trade linkages and significantly higher spillovers from the United States to other countries in the 1987–2006 period as compared to the entire 1970–2006 period. Since our sample includes years that mark the peak of financial linkages (2007 and 2008), we find even higher effects. Within the EMU, inward spillovers from Germany, Italy, and France to the other large EMU members are relatively stable across the two sample periods and are robust to the inclusion of the crisis dummy (i.e., likely to persist even outside of crisis times) (Figure 5.4). Specifically, we find that: • Germany’s effect on the other three large euro area countries ranges at the lower end for Spain and France, causing output there to rise by 0.1–0.2 percent, although Italy’s growth rate rises by around 0.4 percent in response to a 1 percent growth shock in Germany. • France affects Italy and Germany roughly by the same order of magnitude, yielding an increase in growth by 0.4 percent in normal times and above 0.5 percent in crisis times. The effect on Spain is only marginally higher. • A 1 percent growth shock in Italy causes German and French growth to increase by 0.4 percent and Spanish growth by 0.2 percent in the baseline

15 While estimates from the smaller model are directly obtained for “EMU” and “Non-EMU” shocks, the corresponding values from the baseline VAR (large model) is obtained by weighting the responses to the single countries’ shocks which constitute the EMU and the non-EMU group in the country- specific VARs. 16 However, it should be noted that the small country-specific VARs overestimate the impact, due to the aggregation bias which tends to increase the persistence of the shocks and thus overestimate the response.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 117

2.50 Inward Spillovers to Germany from Selected 2.50 Inward Spillovers to France from Selected Large Countries Large Countries

2.00 2.00 1993Q1:2010Q3 Excl. crisis dummy 1993Q1:2010Q3 Excl. crisis dummy 1993Q1:2010Q3 1993Q1:2010Q3 1975Q1:2010Q3 Excl. crisis dummy 1975Q1:2010Q3 Excl. crisis dummy 1.50 1975Q1:2010Q3 1.50 1975Q1:2010Q3

1.00 1.00

0.50 0.50

0.00 0.00 USA JPN DEU GBR FRA ITA ESP USA JPN DEU GBR FRA ITA ESP

−0.50 −0.50

2.50 Inward Spillovers to Italy from Selected 2.50 Inward Spillovers to Spain from Selected Large Large Countries Countries

2.00 2.00 1993Q1:2010Q3 Excl. crisis dummy 1993Q1:2010Q3 Excl. crisis dummy 1993Q1:2010Q3 1993Q1:2010Q3 1975Q1:2010Q3 Excl. crisis dummy 1975Q1:2010Q3 Excl. crisis dummy 1.50 1975Q1:2010Q3 1.50 1975Q1:2010Q3

1.00 1.00

0.50 0.50

0.00 0.00 USA JPN DEU GBR FRA ITA ESP USA JPN DEU GBR FRA ITA ESP

−0.50 −0.50

Figure 5.4. Inward Spillovers to the Four Large Euro Area Countries 1993–2010 and 1975–2010 Source: IMF Staff estimates.

estimation. The effect increases by an additional 0.2 percent for Germany and France and 0.3 percent for Spain in crisis times. In the more recent period, Spain’s sensitivity to Italy’s growth shocks has increased to a higher level than its sensitivity to growth shocks in Germany or France. • Spain has been an important source of growth shocks for other large euro area countries. Under the baseline regression for the full sample, a 1 percent shock to Spain’s growth increases GDP growth in Germany by 0.7 percent, in France by 0.5 percent, and in Italy by 0.3 percent. This position is reaf- firmed in the regression for the more recent episode, which shows a general increase in the importance of Spain’s growth spillovers. In particular, posi- tive spillovers from Spain have become more important for France and Italy

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 118 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

TABLE 5.3 Long-Run Growth Spillover (1975:Q1–2010:Q3) Percent spillover from: Average USA JPN DEU GBR FRA ITA ESP CAN Others growth USA 0.4 0.0 –0.2 –0.1 –0.1 0.3 0.1 0.0 3.0 JPN 0.5 –0.1 –0.1 0.0 –0.1 0.5 0.1 0.0 2.2 DEU 0.7 0.6 –0.1 0.1 –0.2 0.6 0.1 0.0 1.5 UK 1.5 0.3 0.0 0.1 –0.1 0.7 0.2 0.0 2.1 FRA 0.8 0.4 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 0.5 0.2 0.0 1.9 ITA 0.9 0.6 –0.2 –0.2 0.1 0.4 0.2 0.0 1.5 ESP 0.7 0.3 0.0 –0.3 0.1 –0.1 0.2 0.1 2.1 CAN 2.1 0.3 0.0 –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 0.4 0.0 2.7 NLD 1.3 0.3 –0.2 –0.2 0.0 –0.1 0.6 0.2 1.9 BEL 0.7 0.4 –0.1 –0.1 0.1 –0.2 0.5 0.2 –0.1 1.6 SWE 1.4 0.2 0.1 –0.4 0.1 –0.2 0.6 0.2 0.0 2.1 Percent spillover to: spillover Percent AUT 0.5 0.2 –0.2 –0.1 0.2 –0.1 0.5 0.1 –0.5 1.3 CHE 0.8 0.4 0.0 –0.2 0.2 –0.3 0.5 0.1 –0.1 1.4 GRC 0.8 0.1 –0.3 –0.1 0.3 –0.1 0.8 0.1 –0.3 1.7 POR 0.2 0.5 –0.2 –0.1 0.4 –0.2 0.9 0.2 –0.7 1.7 FIN 1.6 0.4 0.2 0.3 0.3 –0.2 0.7 0.4 0.5 2.8 IRL 2.3 0.1 –0.1 0.2 0.2 –0.2 1.1 0.4 –0.7 3.6

Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: USA: United States; JPN: Japan; DEU: Germany; GBR: United Kingdom; FRA: France; ITA: Italy; ESP: Spain; CAN: Canada.

in recent years, consistent with the increase in trade and financial integra- tion following EMU and euro adoption as well as with a domestic demand and property boom in Spain, both partly fuelled by unsustainable increases in corporate and household indebtedness.17

Domestic and Foreign Growth Contributions in Crisis and Recovery While the impulse responses measure the potential impact of growth spillovers across countries, they do not provide insight into the actual effect of idiosyn- cratic growth shocks originating in one country on other countries over time. The latter reflects both the size of the impulse response and the country-specific growth shock in the originating country. We investigate this question using a decomposition of the individual countries’ growth rates into the contribution from other countries over time. The results are summarized in Table 5.3, which provides estimates of the G7 individual countries plus Spain’s contribution to the other countries’ growth in the long run (i.e., in the absence of idiosyncratic shocks), and in the next series of graphs (Figure 5.5), which show the evolution

17 While the subsequent deflation of the property bubble and private sector deleveraging has resulted in negative dynamic contributions of Spain to other countries’ growth during the 2008–09 global recession, we find that on average, over the long run, Spain has been one of the major sources of positive growth spillovers to other countries, especially in Europe (see section D). However, the poten- tial positive impact of Spain in future episodes could be lower than suggested by historical results if the unwinding of Spain’s imbalances is protracted and durably undermines Spain’s growth prospects.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 119

Germany France 8 8 6 6 4 4 2 2 0 0 −2 −2 −4 −4 −6 −6 −8 −8 −10 −10

2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3 2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3

Italy Netherlands 8 8 6 6 4 4 2 2 0 0 −2 −2 −4 −4 −6 −6 −8 −8 −10 −10

2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3 2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3

Austria Finland 8 10 6 4 5 2 0 0 −2 −4 −6 −5 −8 −10 −10

2005:Q1 2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3 −15 2005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3

United States Japan 6 6 4 4 2 2 0 0 –2 –2 –4 –4 –6 –6 –8 –8 –10 –10

2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3 2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3

own GBR others DEU CAN JPN ESP USA ITA Long-run FRA Growth rate

Figure 5.5 Growth Contribution in Crisis and Recovery (Percent)

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 120 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

United Kingdom Canada 6 6 4 4 2 2 0 0 –2 –2 –4 –4 –6 –6 –8 –8 –10 –10

2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3 2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3

Sweden Switzerland 6 6 4 4 2 2 0 0 –2 –2 –4 –4 –6 –6 –8 –8 –10 –10

2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3 2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3

8 Spain 8 Belgium 6 6 4 4 2 2 0 0 −2 −2 −4 −4 −6 −6 −8 −8 −10 −10

2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3 2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3

Greece Ireland 8 8 6 6 4 4 2 2 0 0 −2 −2 −4 −4 −6 −6 −8 −8 −10 −10

2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3 2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3

Portugal 8 own others 6 CAN ESP 4 ITA FRA 2 GBR DEU 0 JPN USA -2 Long-run Growth rate -4 -6 -8 -10

2005:Q12005:Q32006:Q12006:Q32007:Q12007:Q32008:Q12008:Q32009:Q12009:Q32010:Q12010:Q3 Figure 5.5 (continued) Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: CAN: Canada; DEU: Germany; ESP: Spain; FRA: France; ITA: Italy; JPN: Japan; GBR: United Kingdom; USA: United States.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 121 of the growth rate from 2005:Q1 to 2010:Q3 for all countries in the sample, splitting a country’s growth rate into its own contribution (light grey bar), the cyclical contribution stemming from each G7 member and Spain, and the long- run growth rate (dark grey bar). The height of the individual bars represents the overall contribution at each moment in time. We first examine the long-term impact of each country on the other countries in the sample. The long-run decomposition in Table 5.3 shows that the United States has been the largest positive contributor to long-term growth in other countries. The United States matters particularly for the Anglo-Saxon countries and the smaller Northern European countries. Long-run spillovers from Japan and Spain have also been positive and relatively important, with Spain more relevant for European countries. Canada and France provide relatively minor long-run growth support to other countries, although spillovers from France are particularly relevant for the GIP. By contrast, long-run external growth spillovers from Germany are close to zero, and the United Kingdom and Italy’s long-run spillovers have been small and negative. In the case of Italy, this reflects rela- tively weak GDP growth over the period (similar to Germany), while the result for the United Kingdom could reflect the United Kingdom’s dependence on U.S. prospects. The dynamic contribution analysis—focusing on the recent period, including the global financial crisis—highlights for all countries the dominant contribution of external growth shocks and the relatively low contribution of domestic shocks to overall GDP growth. This is particularly true for the smaller open economies such as the Netherlands, Austria, Belgium, and Finland. Even for the United States, the results suggest that synchronized downturns in Japan and the European advanced countries contributed to amplify the depth of the U.S. recession in 2008–09. The finding that external spillovers have been large and significant in the recent period may be regarded as supporting the appropriateness of the model, since it implies that the model captures most of the likely sources of global growth spillovers and thus generates a limited idiosyncratic error compo- nent, which in turn implies a relatively high explanatory power.18 Turning to a finer analysis of growth contributions pre-, during, and post- crisis, the main findings are as follows: • The boom period before the crisis is reflected in the significant domestic contribution to each country’s GDP growth, which cannot be accounted for completely by growth fluctuations in other countries. In terms of outward spillovers, the United States and Spain have been major sources of positive growth support in the precrisis period, with the United States mattering most for Canada, the United Kingdom, and Ireland. France played an important role for some countries in the run-up to the crisis, notably the southern peripheral countries, as well as Belgium, Austria, and Finland.

18 The average (adjusted) R-squared value of the reduced form equations for the baseline model is around 0.6 (0.4). Including the crisis dummy implies an increase by 0.04 in explanatory power in both cases.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 122 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

Germany initially weighed negatively on most countries’ growth, but in the latter half of the precrisis period contributed positively, in particular to GDP growth in the Netherlands, Italy, Greece and Austria—although at lower levels than was the case for the contributions from the United States, Spain, Italy, or France. Italy and the United Kingdom have contributed negatively to growth in other European countries in the years preceding the crisis. • During the crisis, large negative domestic contributions to growth are observed in Italy, the United States, Japan, Sweden, Ireland, the United Kingdom, and since the first quarter of 2010 in Greece. Japan has generated negative spillovers for virtually all countries in the sample, reducing German output growth by over 1.5 percentage points, Italian growth by 1.4 percent- age points, and U.S. growth by 1.2 percentage points. The effect on other countries has been less strong. Similarly, the U.S. shock has affected growth in almost all countries in 2009, with the strongest effect on Anglo-Saxon countries—Canada and Ireland (−2 percent) and the United Kingdom (−1.5 percent)—but also significant effects on European economies led by the Netherlands (−1 percent). Italy also had a strong negative spillover effect during the crisis on several European countries, most severe for Switzerland but also significant for growth in the peripheral countries. Germany’s nega- tive external spillovers have dragged down growth primarily in neighboring countries, with the strongest impact on the Netherlands. The United Kingdom has primarily been relevant for Finland, Sweden, Spain, and Ireland, dragging down GDP growth in these countries especially toward the later part of the crisis. • The recovery, in turn, is led by the United States and Japan, which account for most of the countries’ positive external support to growth in 2010 (through the third quarter).19 This is supported by additional positive domestic growth momentum in Germany, France, Canada, Switzerland, and Sweden. By con- trast, the recovery has been hampered by continued negative domestic growth contributions in Italy, Spain, and Ireland, and by falling dynamic support from domestic demand in the Netherlands, Greece, and Portugal. Both the analysis of growth contributions and the impulse response functions yield broadly similar conclusions. However, the former provides a more nuanced description of the spillovers by quantifying how growth contributions change over time in terms of their magnitude and the relevance of individual countries. It also confirms the role of the United States and Japan as important sources of spillovers on a global scale, while Spain is primarily relevant for Europe. France, Italy and Germany are also relevant on a European-wide scale, although their impact appears to be regionally concentrated, focused on the smaller neighbors in the case of Germany and concentrated on southern European countries in the

19 While the cyclical contributions of U.S. and Japan growth dynamics on other countries are gener- ally small, both countries provide the bulk of the long-run growth rate support.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 123 case of France and Italy. The United Kingdom in turn appears mostly relevant for the northern European economies and for Spain.

CHANNELS OF GROWTH SPILLOVER TRANSMISSION The pattern of spillovers identified in the previous two sections hinges on the relevance of regional linkages, consistent with the regional dimension of cross- border linkages highlighted in Section B. This section attempts to quantify the importance of trade as a transmission mechanism for growth spillovers, based on country VARs that include real exports as an additional variable. We also seek to shed light on the shock transmission mechanisms underlying the outsized impact of the United States and Japan on advanced European countries by presenting empirical evidence on the size of third-country transmission effects based on counterfactual analysis. While financial channels are not directly analyzed in this study, both the finding that third-country effects tend to be larger during times of financial distress and the finding that trade effects play only a limited role in the international transmission of shocks to European countries suggest that an analysis of financial channels would be a fruitful avenue for future research.20

Third-Country Transmission In a first approach, we analyze the extent to which third-country effects are relevant for the transmission of shocks. In particular, we identify the countries most directly affected by global shocks versus those primarily affected by shocks through third- country effects and that therefore tend to be affected only with a lag. Further, if third- country effects are important, countries less relevant as a source of shocks may still play a central role as transmitter and amplifier of shocks to other countries, through either trade or financial linkages, and therefore they matter on a systemic level. The relevance of third-country effects is calculated as the fraction of the inward spillover from a shock in a given country that is transmitted through other coun- tries after one year. The lower this indicator of third-country effects, the more directly sensitive the country is to the impact of a given external shock. Conversely, the higher the indicator, the more likely it is that the country will only respond after a lag, since the entire spillover effect needs more time to trickle down through trade or financial channels. Since the measure of third-country transmission is only meaningful in cases where a significant impact is observed, we calculated third- country effects only for such constellations.

20 In an earlier version of the paper, we attempted to test for the relevance of financial transmission channels by following the approach of Bayoumi and Swiston (2009), i.e. by including global financial variables (such as the U.S. equity prices, interest rates, and U.S. and German credit spreads) as addi- tional control variables. The U.S. credit spread was found to be the most significant variable, with an impact similar to that of including the crisis dummy (i.e. reducing estimated outward spillovers from the U.S. and other large countries); however, the spread variable had not statistically significant effect once the crisis dummy is also included, suggesting that this channel of transmission is only relevant during times of crisis.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 124 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

Germany stands out as a country that tends to respond swiftly and directly to shocks to growth in the United States or Japan. For France, Italy, and the small core euro area members, similar shocks are channeled to a larger extent through third countries before they impact growth in the home economy. The relatively high values of the third-country indicator for the non-German euro area suggest that inter-linkages between euro area countries are highly relevant in the transmission of shocks to Europe from outside the euro area. Combined with the relative directness with which Germany reacts to shocks in the United States and Japan, this finding suggests that Germany acts as an important transmitter and amplifier of shocks originating outside the euro area to other euro area members (Figure 5.6). When looking at the relevance of third-country effects for intra-European shocks, the regional patterns are again noticeable. Growth shocks from Italy and Spain affect Dutch growth primarily through third countries, while growth shocks from Germany affect Dutch growth mostly directly and hardly at all through third countries. Switzerland’s growth is directly affected by growth shocks in Italy, and Belgium’s growth is most directly affected by French growth shocks. Austrian growth is most directly affected by France and Germany, less directly by Italy, and least by Spain. Italy’s growth is most directly affected by Germany followed by France and then Spain (Figure 5.7). Interestingly, Germany’s impact on Greece and Portugal appears to be less direct than the impact of France and Italy on these two countries, which is com- parable to the impact of Spain on Portugal. This confirms the relevance of France and Italy for the southern peripheral countries. Finally, it is worth noting that in

120 United States Japan Average over United States and Japan 100

80

60

40

20

0 Germany France Italy Netherlands, Belgium, Austria, and Finland

Figure 5.6 Relative Importance of Third-Country Effects for Inward Spillovers to Selected European Countries from the United States and Japana Source: IMF Staff estimates. aBased on the regression incling no crisis dummy. Incling the dummy causes all value to drop slightly. Netherlands, Belgium, Austria, and Finland refers to the GDP PPP weighted average response. PPP: pur- chasing power parity.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 125

100 From Italy to... 90 No crisis 80 70 Crisis 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 GRC CHE FRA SWE PRT DEU NLD BEL AUT ESP

100 From France to... 90 No crisis 80 70 Crisis 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 DEU SWE BEL GRC PRT AUT CHE ITA FIN ESP IRL

100 From Germany to... 90 No crisis 80 Crisis 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 NLD AUT ITA GRC FIN PRT FRA BEL

100 From Spain to... 90 No crisis 80 Crisis 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 FRA IRL CHE GRC DEU SWE PRT BEL NLD AUT ITA

Figure 5.7 Relative Importance of Third-Country Effects for Spillovers from the Four Large European Countries to Selected European Countries Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: AUT: Austria; BEL: Belgium; CHE: Switzerland; DEU: Germany; ESP: Spain; FIN: Finland; FRA: France; GRC: Greece; IRL: Ireland; ITA: Italy; NLD: Netherlands; PRT: Portugal; SWE: Sweden. crisis times, third-country effects appear to play a larger role, confirming earlier results on the importance of confidence and asset-price spillover effects during times of financial distress.21

21 Although the VAR modeling framework does not allow testing directly for asymmetry in the pattern of spillovers, the importance of third-country effects during times of financial distress could explain why negative spillovers originating during a crisis tend to be empirically larger than either positive or negative spillovers outside of crisis times: unlike “normal” spillovers, “crisis” spillovers tend to be amplified to a greater extent by confidence and asset price effects.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 126 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

An important caveat to the counterfactual analysis should be noted. It is sub- ject to the Lucas (1976) critique in the sense that the deep parameters underlying the reduced-form estimates are likely to be different under the counterfactual scenario. However, several authors have argued that the change in the deep parameters may be too small to have a major implication for the reduced-form estimates of the VAR in the context of various policy changes.22 Nevertheless, this problem may be somewhat reflected in certain estimates of the relevance of third- country effects in our simulations, such as in the rather low role of third-country effects for the transmission of Italian shocks to Sweden. Trade Channel Transmission The second counterfactual analysis is based on the small-country VAR specification, which reduces the variables of interest to four variables. The estimation is repeated for each country in the sample, in the case of both EMU and non-EMU shocks. The results shown for the four largest countries in the euro area highlight in all cases the dominance of non-trade channels, especially for shocks originating within the EMU. The finding that trade is relatively less important as a transmission mechanism for inward spillovers is somewhat surprising, given the high degree of trade links within the EMU. This result, however, is consistent with the increased relevance of monetary and credit channels and other links that are crucial within a mone- tary union but not between two currency blocks.23 Compared to other large EMU members, Germany exhibits the highest reli- ance on trade effects for inward growth spillovers, with a share of growth spill- overs from non-EMU countries’ shocks due to trade of close to 40 percent. The respective value for France is around 30 percent, for Spain 15 percent, and for Italy only 10 percent. A similar pattern emerges for EMU shocks, although France appears to rely on trade effects proportionally more than Germany for EMU shocks. However, France’s overall sensitivity to shocks in the EMU is far below the sensitivity of Germany (Figure 5.8). Not surprisingly, trade accounts for around 50 percent of the spillovers for the small open economies such as Belgium, Sweden, Austria, and Ireland in the case of non-EMU shocks. For EMU shocks, the respective values for Austria and Belgium drop by about 20 percentage points and for Sweden by about 40 per- centage points, though for Ireland there is only a minor drop of 5 percentage points. It therefore remains the case for smaller economies in Europe that trade effects are more relevant for non-EMU shocks than for EMU shocks. Determinants of Spillover Size This section analyzes the extent to which the size of outward spillovers originating in a given country is related to the economy’s size (measured by PPP-adjusted

22 See for instance Rudebusch (2005) for the case of monetary policy. 23 See Vitek (2010) for model simulation-based evidence of a strong transmission of supply shocks via non-trade channels in a monetary union.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 127

1.8 In response to an EMU shock 1.6 In response to a non-EMU shock 1.6 Trade channel 1.4 Trade channel Non-trade channel 1.4 1.2 Non-trade channel 1.2 1 1 0.8 0.8 0.6 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0 0 Germany Italy France Spain Germany Italy France Spain

Figure 5.8 Relative Importance of Trade Channel for Inward Spillovers for Large EMU Members Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: EMU: Austria, Belgium, Finland, Greece, Ireland, Netherlands, Portugal, and Spain.

GDP) and to the existence of autonomous domestic drivers of growth. While size is a natural a priori determinant of spillovers, we also conjecture that countries that are relatively more sensitive to external shocks are more likely to receive large inward spillovers but less likely to generate large outward spillovers; by contrast, countries that rely more on domestic drivers of growth are more likely to generate large outward spillovers. To identify the presence of autonomous sources of domestic demand growth, we look at two dimensions: (i) the average contribution of trade to GDP, and (ii) the co-movement of GDP growth and net exports. The former gives us an indi- cation of the relevance of the external sector for overall GDP growth. The latter helps us to understand whether GDP growth and net exports move in tandem or whether net exports and GDP growth move in opposite directions. In the latter case, a country is a potential spillover risk (positive or negative) for other countries, since its growth relies to a greater extent on autonomous domestic demand fluctuations, while in the former the country is more likely to import spillovers through trade and other links, and possibly re-export them to others by serving as a third-country transmitter rather than acting as an independent engine of growth. Countries that exhibit a positive average net contribution of trade to GDP include Japan, Germany, Netherlands, Belgium, Sweden, Austria, Switzerland, Finland, and Ireland; those that do not include the United States, the United Kingdom, France, Italy, Spain, Canada, Greece, and Portugal (Table 5.4).24 In terms of relevance of external demand for overall GDP growth, Germany is the leading country, followed by Ireland, Switzerland, Japan, Austria, Sweden, Finland, Belgium and the Netherlands. In the last decade, exports have become the major engine of growth for Japan, Austria, and particularly for Germany. Regarding the co-movement of external demand and GDP growth, the coun- tercyclical pattern of domestic and external contribution to growth indicates the

24 Note that this concept is not identical to whether a country is a net exporter or net importer, since it refers to the change in the net trade position rather than the level.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 128 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

greatest spillover risk is in the case of the United Kingdom, the United States, Canada, Spain, Portugal, and Greece (Table 5.5). These countries have a high negative correlation between the contribution of domestic and external demand and a high positive correlation between domestic demand and GDP. This represents

TABLE 5.4 Contribution of Domestic and External Demand to GDP Growth (1996:Q1–2010:Q3)a Due to External demand Average GDP in percent of GDP growth rate Domestic demand External demand growth United States 2.6 2.8 –0.2 –7.3 Japan 0.7 0.5 0.2 49.0 Germany 1.2 0.7 0.4 59.8 United Kingdom 2.2 2.5 –0.2 –8.9 France 1.7 2.0 –0.3 –12.9 Italy 0.9 1.2 –0.3 –22.4 Spain 2.9 3.4 –0.5 –14.1 Canada 2.6 3.2 –0.5 –16.6 Netherlands 2.3 2.1 0.2 11.6 Belgium 1.9 1.6 0.2 13.8 Sweden 2.5 2.1 0.4 21.2 Austria 2.1 1.5 0.6 37.5 Switzerland 1.6 1.1 0.5 49.3 Greece 2.8 2.9 –0.1 –3.8 Portugal 1.8 2.3 –0.5 –20.9 Finland 2.9 2.6 0.4 15.8 Ireland 4.3 2.8 1.6 57.9

Sources: Eurostat; national authorities; and IMF staff calculations. a Due to rounding and statistical discrepancies, values do not necessarily add up.

TABLE 5.5 Correlation of Contributions with GDP Growth (1996:Q1–2010:Q3) Correlation Between Domestic and external External and GDP Domestic and GDP United States –0.9 –0.8 1.0 Japan 0.3 0.6 0.9 Germany 0.0 0.7 0.7 United Kingdom –0.8 –0.6 1.0 France –0.4 –0.1 0.9 Italy 0.1 0.4 0.9 Spain –0.9 –0.8 1.0 Canada –0.6 0.1 0.7 Netherlands –0.2 0.1 1.0 Belgium 0.0 0.4 0.9 Sweden 0.1 0.5 0.9 Austria 0.5 0.8 0.9 Switzerland 0.1 0.8 0.6 Greece –0.9 –0.6 0.9 Portugal –0.8 –0.6 0.9 Finland 0.4 0.7 0.9 Ireland –0.5 –0.3 1.0

Source: Eurostat; national authorities; and IMF staff calculations.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 129 a pattern under which high domestic demand drives growth and worsens the net trade position due to increased domestic demand. Germany, Japan, Austria, and Finland illustrate the opposite, export-driven growth pattern (Table 5.5). These countries exhibit a positive correlation between the external contribution to growth and GDP and a positive correlation between the domestic contribution and the external contribution to GDP. Higher external demand accelerates growth, which in turn stimulates domestic consumption and investment. For the Netherlands, Sweden, France, and Belgium, the patterns appear less pronounced according to these indicators. Plotting the correlation between external contribution to growth and GDP against the weighted outward spillovers from the main (baseline) regression, we find that the link between the presence of domestic drivers of growth and the relevance of a country as a source of growth spillovers to other countries is con- firmed.25 While we also find evidence of a positive relationship between a coun- try’s size and the estimated outward spillover, the presence of clear outliers such as Canada and Spain (larger spillovers than predicted by size alone), or Germany (smaller spillovers than expected based on size) suggest that size alone fails to explain spillover risk (Figure 5.9).

0.60 External Contribution to Growth and Size of Growth 0.6 Economic Size and Size of Growth Spillovers Spillovers

0.50 0.5

Canada Canada 0.40 USA 0.4 USA Spain Spain

0.30 0.3 Italy Italy

0.20 UK Japan 0.2 UK Japan Belgium France Belgium France Sweden Sweden Germany 0.10 Germany 0.1 Switzerland Switzerland Growth spillover, 1975:Q1–2010:Q3, percent 1975:Q1–2010:Q3, spillover, Growth Growth spillover, 1975:Q1–2010:Q3, percent 1975:Q1–2010:Q3, spillover, Growth R² = 0.494 Austria R² = 0.3315 Netherlands Austria Netherlands 0.00 0 −1.00 −0.50 0.00 0.50 2.22.73.23.74.2 Correlation between external contribution and growth Economic Country Size, log (GDP, PPP US dollar)

Figure 5.9 Correlation of Outward Spillovers, Size and Export-Driven Growth, Selected Countries Source: IMF staff estimates.

25 The relationship also holds when excluding the crisis dummy. Regressing the size of the outward spillover on a constant, the log size of the country, and the correlation between GDP growth and the external contribution to growth yields a positive significant effect for the former and a negative sig- nificant effect for the latter. Increasing the size of the country by 10 percent increases the outward spillover by 0.1 percentage points, and reducing the correlation of external demand and GDP growth from +0.5 to −0.5 increases the size of outward spillovers by 0.14 percentage points. The smallest four counties are excluded from the graph. While Finland confirms the pattern, Greece, Portugal and Ireland are too small to generate significant growth spillovers.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 130 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

CONCLUSION The divergent growth recovery paths in Europe in the aftermath of the 2008–09 financial crisis have brought the question of growth spillovers again to the fore- front, since spillovers from faster growing countries could provide positive growth impetus to the slower growing countries, whose recovery is hampered by domes- tic demand constraints. Furthermore, against the background of renewed sover- eign debt concerns in the euro area, negative growth shocks originating in the crisis countries could spill over to other countries through trade linkages or extensive cross-border asset ownership. Our empirical analysis suggests that growth spillovers can indeed explain a significant fraction of the variation in output growth for some euro area members, in particular the small open economies. In terms of spillover origins, we find that the United States remains the key source of growth spillovers in this recovery. Despite the increased correlation of Germany’s GDP growth with several other countries’ GDP growth, its spillover impact remains primarily confined to its smaller neighbors, while France and Italy are more relevant for the southern peripheral countries. Both Japan and Spain also appear to be significant sources of potential growth spillover risk to European countries, although the positive spillover impact of Spain in future episodes could be much smaller than indicated by our results if domestic demand growth is persistently hampered by the ongo- ing unwinding of longstanding imbalances. To some extent, a similar caveat applies to the U.S. results in light of uncertainties surrounding the sustainability of the current U.S. recovery. Our analysis of transmission channels suggests that trade channels matter rela- tively less than financial and other non-trade channels. Trade effects seem to mat- ter relatively more for Germany’s inward spillovers, compared to other large euro area countries, reflecting Germany’s relatively high trade exposures. For all euro area members, we find that growth shocks from outside the EMU are more likely than those originating within the EMU to be transmitted through trade; those originating within the EMU appear to be predominantly transmitted through monetary and financial linkages. We fail to find an increasingly important role for Germany as an independent source of growth shocks in the euro area in recent years, which reflects the country’s relatively high sensitivity to external shocks. Finally, the results suggest that growth spillover risks from the European crisis countries to the rest of Europe remain limited, although stronger effects could be expected if the debt crisis were to spread to larger countries, such as Spain. Our results are consistent with the premise that for countries to be an impor- tant source of growth spillovers, their growth should rely to a greater extent on autonomous domestic sources. Germany fails to meet these criteria, since it is more sensitive to growth shocks in other countries than other large advanced countries and its GDP growth tends to closely follow the performance of its external sector. However, consistent with the view that Germany’s imports are very sensitive to demand for German exports (due to the high import content of German exports), our results suggest that Germany may be acting as an

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 131 important “third country” or transmitter of shocks, since it is more directly affected by external growth shocks than other large euro area countries and third- country effects are found to account for much of the transmission of external shocks to the other euro area members. While our results appear to be robust across variations of the sample and carry over to estimates restricted to the more recent period, some caveats remain. First, we cannot infer much about the role that the sample countries might play for other countries, which are not included in the sample. Second, the analysis is backward looking and does not allow for time-varying relationships between the countries. And third, our approach does not allow us to uncover the particular source or nature of the country-specific shock, masking potential variations stemming from supply as opposed to demand shocks which stand behind the growth shocks. All three caveats provide an interesting avenue for future research. Another worthwhile avenue for future research would be to explore the financial transmission channels that likely underlie the finding that both spillover estimates and third-country effects tend to become larger for most countries during periods of financial distress.

REFERENCES Arora, Vivek, and Athanasios Vamvakidis, 2006, “The Impact of U.S. Growth on the Rest of the World: How Much Does It Matter?” Journal of Economic Integration, Vol. 21, No. 1, pp. 21–39. ———, 2010, “China’s Economic Growth: International Spillovers?” IMF Working Paper No. WP/10/165 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Bagliano, Fabio C., and Claudio Morana, 2011, “The Great Recession: U.S. Dynamics and Spillovers to the World Economy,” Journal of Banking and Finance, forthcoming. Banbura, Marta, Domenico Giannone, and Lucrezia Reichlin, 2008, “Large Bayesian VARs,” Working Paper No. 966 (Frankfurt: European Central Bank). Bayoumi, Tam, and Andrew Swiston, 2009, “Foreign Entanglements: Estimating the Source and Size of Spillovers Across Industrial Countries,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 56, No. 2, pp. 353–83. Beetsma, Roel, Massimo Giuliodori, and Franc Klaasen, 2005, “Trade Spillovers of Fiscal Policy in the European Union: A Panel Analysis,” DNB Working Paper No. 52 (Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank). Bénassy-Quéré, Agnès, and Jacopo Cimadomo, 2006, “Changing Patterns of Domestic and Cross-Border Fiscal Policy Multipliers in Europe and the U.S.,” Working Papers, Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales No. 2006–24 December. Bussière, Matthieu, Alexander Chudik and Giulia Sestieri, 2009, “Modelling Global Trade Flows - Results from a GVAR Model,” Working Paper Series 1087, European Central Bank. Canova, Fabio, and Matteo Ciccarelli, 2006, “Estimating Multi-Country VAR Models” Working Paper Series 603, European Central Bank. Danninger, Stephan, 2008, “Growth Linkages within Europe“, in IMF Country Report No. 08/81, Germany: Selected Issues, International Monetary Fund. (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Dees, Stephane, Filippo di Mauro, L. Vanessa Smith and M. Hashem Pesaran, 2007, “Exploring the international linkages of the euro area: a global VAR analysis,” Journal of Applied , John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., vol. 22(1), pages 1–38. Galesi, Alessandro, and Silvia Sgherri, 2009, “Regional Financial Spillovers Across Europe: A Global VAR Analysis,” IMF Working Papers 09/23, International Monetary Fund.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 132 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery

Helbling, Thomas, Peter Berezin, Ayhan Kose, Michael Kumhof, Doug Laxton, and Nicola Spatafora, 2007, “Decoupling the Train: Spillovers and Cycles in the World Economy,” Chapter 4 in World Economic Outlook, April 2007 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Imbs, Jean, Haroon Mumtaz, Morten O. Ravn, Hélène Rey, 2005, ”PPP Strikes Back: Aggregation and the Real Exchange Rate,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 120, No. 1 (Feb.), pp. 1–43 (Oxford: Oxford University Press). Kanda, Daniel, 2008, “Spillovers to Ireland,” IMF Working Paper No. 08/2 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Lucas, Robert, 1976, “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Supplementary Series 1, pp. 19–46. Pesaran, M. Hahsem, Til Schuermann, and Scott M. Weiner, 2004, “Modeling Regional Interdependencies Using a Global Error-Correcting Macroeconometric Model,” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 22, pp. 129–62. Rudebusch, Glenn D., 2005, “Assessing the Lucas Critique in Monetary Policy Models,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 37, pp. 245–72. Swiston, Andrew, 2010, “Spillovers to Central America in Light of the Crisis: What a Difference a Year Makes,” IMF Working Paper No. WP/10/35, (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Vitek, Francis, 2009, “Monetary Policy Analysis and in the World Economy: A Panel Unobserved Components Approach,” IMF Working Paper No. WP/09/238 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). ———, 2010, “Monetary Policy Analysis and Forecasting in the Group of Twenty: A Panel Unobserved Components Approach,” IMF Working Paper No. WP/10/152 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund)International Monetary Fund).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Poirson and Weber 133

APPENDIX TABLE 5A.1 Size-Based Ordering of Spillovers between Countries (From left to right, in order of independence from other regions1)

DEU JPN USA FRA GBR ESP ITA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU JPN USA FRA ITA ESP GBR CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU JPN USA GBR FRA ESP ITA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU JPN USA GBR ITA ESP FRA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU JPN USA ITA FRA ESP GBR CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU JPN USA ITA GBR ESP FRA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA JPNDEU GBR ESP ITA FRA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA JPNDEU ITA ESP GBR FRA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA JPNDEU FRA ESP ITA GBR CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA JPNDEU GBR ESP FRA ITA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA JPNDEU ITA ESP FRA GBR CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA JPNDEU FRA ESP GBR ITA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPNDEU USA FRA GBR ESP ITA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPNDEU USA FRA ITA ESP GBR CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPNDEU USA GBR FRA ESP ITA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPNDEU USA GBR ITA ESP FRA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPNDEU USA ITA FRA ESP GBR CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPNDEU USA ITA GBR ESP FRA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USADEU JPN GBR ESP ITA FRA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USADEU JPN ITA ESP FRA GBR CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USADEU JPN FRA ESP ITA GBR CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USADEU JPN GBR ESP FRA ITA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USADEU JPN ITA ESP GBR FRA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USADEU JPN FRA ESP GBR ITA CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPN USA FRA DEU ITA GBR ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPN USA FRA DEU GBR ITA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPN USA ITADEU GBR FRA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPN USA ITADEU FRA GBR ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPN USA GBRDEU ITA FRA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL JPN USA GBRDEU FRA ITA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU USA FRA JPN ITA GBR ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU USA FRA JPN GBR ITA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU USA ITA JPN GBR FRA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU USA ITA JPN FRA GBR ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU USA GBR JPN ITA FRA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL DEU USA GBR JPN FRA ITA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA FRA DEU GBR JPN ITA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA FRA DEU ITA JPN GBR ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA FRA JPN GBRDEU ITA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA FRA JPN ITADEU GBR ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA GBRDEU FRA JPN ITA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA GBRDEU ITA JPN FRA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA GBR JPN FRA DEU ITA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA GBR JPN ITADEU FRA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA ITADEU FRA JPN GBR ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA ITADEU GBR JPN FRA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA ITA JPN FRA DEU GBR ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL USA ITA JPN GBRDEU FRA ESP CAN NLD BEL SWE AUT CHE GRCPRTFIN IRL

Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: AUT: Austria; BEL: Belgium; CHE: Switzerland; DEU: Germany; ESP: Spain; FIN: Finland; FRA: France; GBR: United Kingdom; GRC: Greece; IRL: Ireland; ITA: Italy; NLD: Netherlands; PRT: Portugal; SWE: Sweden. 1 Each line corresponds to a different country ordering. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 134 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery GBR USA JPN 12345678 12345678 12345678 .2 .4 .4 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.3 –0 –0 –0 FRA ESP BEL 12345678 12345678 12345678 .4 .4 .4 1.6 1.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 0.6 0.1 –0 –0 –0 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution ITA NLD DEU esponse to a 1 Percent Growth Shock in the United States (Percent) States Shock in the United Growth a 1 Percent esponse to R

12345678 12345678 12345678 .4 .4 .4 1.6 1.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 0.6 0.1 –0 –0 –0 Figure 5A.1 Figure Poirson and Weber 135 : Italy; A L: Ireland; IT R C: Greece; I C: Greece; R CAN SWE IRF Counterfactual IRF Ordering uncertainty Parameter uncertainty : United Kingdom;: United G R 12345678 12345678 : France; GB : France; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 RA : Finland; F : Finland; N EU: Germany;Spain; FI ESP: FIN CHE GRC D 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Canada; CHE: Switzerland; CHE: Switzerland; : Canada; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 AN : United States. : United A ustria; BEL: Belgium; C ustria; BEL: Belgium; A ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution UT: UT: A T: Portugal; SWE: Sweden; US SWE: Sweden; Portugal; T: R ) IRL AUT PRT etherlands; P N continued : D L ( N F staff estimates. M F: impulse response function. impulse response F: R 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Japan; N ote: I ote: JP Source: I Source: N 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.1 Figure 136 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery 8 GBR USA JPN 1234567 12345678 12345678 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.3 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.2 –0.4 –0.4 FRA ESP BEL 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.1 0.6 1.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution ITA NLD DEU esponse to a 1 Percent Growth Shock in Japan (Percent) Growth a 1 Percent esponse to R

12345678 12345678 12345678 1.1 0.6 1.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.2 Figure Poirson and Weber 137 : Italy; A L: Ireland; IT R C: Greece; I C: Greece; R SWE CAN IRF Counterfactual IRF Ordering uncertainty Parameter uncertainty : United Kingdom;: United G R 12345678 12345678 .4 .4 : France; GB : France; 1.61.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0 –0 RA : Finland; F : Finland; N EU: Germany;Spain; FI ESP: FIN CHE GRC D 12345678 12345678 12345678 .4 .4 .4 : Canada; CHE: Switzerland; CHE: Switzerland; : Canada; 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0 –0 –0 AN : United States. : United A ustria; BEL: Belgium; C ustria; BEL: Belgium; A ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution UT: UT: A T: Portugal; SWE: Sweden; US SWE: Sweden; Portugal; T: R ) IRL PRT AUT etherlands; P N continued : D L ( N F staff estimates. M F: impulse response function. impulse response F: R 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Japan; N ote: I ote: JP Source: I Source: N .4 .4 .4 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.61.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 –0 –0 –0 Figure 5A.2 Figure 138 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery GBR JPN USA 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.3 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.2 –0.4 –0.4 BEL FRA ESP 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution ITA NLD DEU esponse to a 1 Percent Growth Shock in the United Kingdom Shock in the United (Percent) Growth a 1 Percent esponse to R

12345678 12345678 12345678 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.3 Figure Poirson and Weber 139 : Italy; A L: Ireland; IT R C: Greece; I C: Greece; R CAN SWE IRF Counterfactual IRF Ordering uncertainty Parameter uncertainty : United Kingdom;: United G R 12345678 12345678 : France; GB : France; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 RA : Finland; F : Finland; N FIN CHE GRC EU: Germany;Spain; FI ESP: D 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Canada; CHE: Switzerland; CHE: Switzerland; : Canada; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 AN : United States. States. : United A ustria; BEL: Belgium; C ustria; BEL: Belgium; A ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution UT: UT: A T: Portugal; SWE: Sweden; US SWE: Sweden; Portugal; T: R IRL AUT PRT ) etherlands; P N continued : D L ( N F staff calculations. M F: impulse response function. impulse response F: R 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Japan; N ote: I ote: JP Source: I Source: N 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.3 Figure 140 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery GBR JPN USA 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.3 0.8 0.3 1.8 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.2 –0.4 –0.4 BEL ESP FRA 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution ITA NLD DEU esponse to a 1 Percent Growth Shock in Germany (Percent) Shock in Germany Growth a 1 Percent esponse to R

12345678 12345678 12345678 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.4 Figure Poirson and Weber 141 : Italy; A L: Ireland; IT R C: Greece; I C: Greece; R CAN SWE IRF Counterfactual IRF Ordering uncertainty Parameter uncertainty : United Kingdom;: United G R 12345678 12345678 : France; GB : France; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 RA : Finland; F : Finland; N FIN CHE GRC EU: Germany;Spain; FI ESP: D 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Canada; CHE: Switzerland; CHE: Switzerland; : Canada; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 AN : United States. : United A ustria; BEL: Belgium; C ustria; BEL: Belgium; A ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution UT: UT: A T: Portugal; SWE: Sweden; US SWE: Sweden; Portugal; T: R IRL AUT PRT ) etherlands; P N continued : D L ( N F staff estimates. M F: impulse response function. impulse response F: R 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Japan; N ote: I ote: JP Source: I Source: N 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.4 Figure 142 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery GBR JPN USA 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.3 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.2 –0.4 –0.4 BEL ESP FRA 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution ITA NLD DEU esponse to a 1 Percent Growth Shock in France (Percent) Shock in France Growth a 1 Percent esponse to R

12345678 12345678 12345678 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.5 Figure Poirson and Weber 143 : Italy; A L: Ireland; IT R C: Greece; I C: Greece; R CAN SWE IRF Counterfactual IRF Ordering uncertainty Parameter uncertainty : United Kingdom;: United G R 12345678 12345678 : France; GB : France; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 RA : Finland; F : Finland; N FIN CHE GRC EU: Germany;Spain; FI ESP: D 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Canada; CHE: Switzerland; CHE: Switzerland; : Canada; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 AN : United States. : United A ustria; BEL: Belgium; C ustria; BEL: Belgium; A ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution UT: UT: A T: Portugal; SWE: Sweden; US SWE: Sweden; Portugal; T: IRL R AUT PRT ) etherlands; P N continued : D L ( N F staff calculations. M F: impulse response function. impulse response F: R 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Japan; N ote: I ote: JP Source: I Source: N 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.5 Figure 144 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery GBR JPN USA 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.3 –0.4 –0.4 –0.2 BEL FRA ESP 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution ITA NLD DEU esponse to a 1 Percent Growth Shock in Italy (Percent) Growth a 1 Percent esponse to R

12345678 12345678 12345678 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 Figure 5A.6 Figure –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Poirson and Weber 145 : Italy; A L: Ireland; IT R C: Greece; I C: Greece; R CAN SWE IRF Counterfactual IRF Ordering uncertainty Parameter uncertainty : United Kingdom;: United G R 12345678 12345678 : France; GB : France; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 RA –0.4 –0.4 : Finland; F : Finland; N FIN CHE GRC EU: Germany;Spain; FI ESP: D 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Canada; CHE: Switzerland; CHE: Switzerland; : Canada; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 AN : United States. : United A ustria; BEL: Belgium; C ustria; BEL: Belgium; A ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution UT: UT: A T: Portugal; SWE: Sweden; US SWE: Sweden; Portugal; T: R IRL AUT PRT ) etherlands; P N continued : D L ( N F staff calculations. M F: impulse response function. impulse response F: R 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Japan; N ote: I ote: JP Source: I Source: N 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.6 Figure 146 Growth Spillover Dynamics: From Crisis to Recovery GBR JPN USA 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.3 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.2 –0.4 –0.4 BEL FRA ESP 12345678 12345678 12345678 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 2.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution ITA NLD DEU esponse to a 1 Percent Growth Shock in Spain (Percent) Growth a 1 Percent esponse to R

12345678 12345678 12345678 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.7 Figure Poirson and Weber 147 : Italy; A 78 L: Ireland; IT R C: Greece; I C: Greece; R CAN SWE IRF Counterfactual IRF Ordering uncertainty Parameter uncertainty : United Kingdom;: United G R 123456 12345678 : France; GB : France; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 RA : Finland; F : Finland; N FIN CHE GRC EU: Germany;Spain; FI ESP: D 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Canada; CHE: Switzerland; CHE: Switzerland; : Canada; 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 AN : United States. : United A ustria; BEL: Belgium; C ustria; BEL: Belgium; A ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution UT: UT: A PRT T: Portugal; SWE: Sweden; US SWE: Sweden; Portugal; T: R IRL AUT ) etherlands; P N continued : D L ( N F staff calculations. M F: impulse response function. impulse response F: R 12345678 12345678 12345678 : Japan; N ote: I ote: JP Source: I Source: N 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 Figure 5A.7 Figure This page intentionally left blank

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CHAPTER 6 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

ANNA IVANOVA AND SEBASTIAN WEBER

This chapter assesses the impact of fiscal spillovers on growth in the context of a coor- dinated exit from crisis management policies. We find that despite potentially sizeable domestic effects from consolidation, aggregate negative spillovers to other countries are likely to be contained in 2011–12 unless fiscal multipliers and/or imports elasticities are very large. However, small and open European economies will be substantially affected. In contrast, the coordinated exit from fiscal stimulus will have a limited direct effect on European peripheral countries, since they are relatively closed, with the notable exception of Ireland.

INTRODUCTION Under normal circumstances, when business cycles and fiscal policies are unsyn- chronized, changes in domestic fiscal stances are unlikely to have a significant global impact because the reduction in domestic demand can be partly offset by the increase in net exports, as documented, for example, in the 2010 World Economic Outlook (IMF, 2010). However, the current situation is not normal. Countries went through a global 2008–09 financial crisis and in response have implemented synchronized fiscal stimuli, which have left substantial amounts of public debt that now need to be reduced. For many governments, fiscal consoli- dation has thus become a major objective, and since 2011 these governments have embarked on ambitious fiscal consolidation plans. This implies that many coun- tries will consolidate at the same time. Does the ongoing synchronized fiscal consolidation have the potential to lead to significant spillover effects? In other words, will fiscal actions in one country convey to economic activity in other countries? Some would argue that such a risk exists. Several considerations favor such a view: Exchange rates cannot adjust if many countries consolidate simultaneously. Additionally, a large number of coun- tries undertaking consolidation are in the eurozone, where the real exchange rates can adjust only slowly anyway. Hence, the offsetting effect of adjustments in net exports may not be feasible. Moreover, empirical evidence suggests that fiscal

The authors would like to thank Ashoka Mody for detailed suggestions and insightful comments, and Daniel Leigh and Vladimir Klyuev for helpful discussions. They also would like to thank Emre Alper, Bas Bakker, Xavier Debrun, Peter Doyle, Lorenzo Figliuoli, Kevin Fletcher, Doug Laxton, Ester Perez Ruiz, Francis Vitek, and Erik de Vrijer for useful comments. 149

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 150 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

multipliers are likely to be higher at the time of financial stress and when interest rates are close to the zero bound (Blanchard and others, 2009; Christiano Eichenbaum, and Rebelo, 2009; IMF, 2010; Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2010; Corsetti et al. 2010b). Both aspects have thus the potential to magnify spillover effects from fiscal consolidation. We use a simple analytical framework to evaluate the relevance of fiscal spill- over effects through trade channels based on estimates of fiscal multipliers and import elasticities obtained in other studies. The methodology is applied to a sample of 20 countries covering more than 70 percent of world GDP.1 The approach accounts for carry-over effects from previous years’ fiscal positions and allows differentiating between revenue and expenditure measures. The baseline estimates of multipliers obtained in the literature are based on the premise that monetary policy is accommodative. To reflect the current environment, in which exchange rate adjustments to “soften the blow” may not be feasible, we perform a series of robustness checks with higher multipliers and a range of import elas- ticities. We also assess the sensitivity of the results to various measures of the fiscal stance. The results do imply that the domestic contractionary effects of fiscal consoli- dation could be sizable. However, aggregate spillovers of these contractionary impulses to other countries are likely to be contained in 2011–12 unless fiscal multipliers and/or imports elasticities are significantly larger than seems reason- able now. However, the effect will be different across countries. Small and open European economies, including Ireland, Belgium, Austria and the Netherlands will be substantially affected. European peripheral countries other than Ireland will face limited direct impacts, because they are relatively closed. Ireland would benefit from a more relaxed pace of fiscal consolidation elsewhere, but such sup- port would be meaningful only if it were coordinated across the major economies, including the United States and the United Kingdom. In contrast, a reduced consolidation effort by Germany alone would have a limited impact on the European periphery. Our analysis consists of two parts. First, we estimate the impact of a uniform shock (1 percent of GDP reduction in expenditure) in 20 major economies to gauge the relative strength of the impact on growth across countries. Second, we estimate the growth impact based on the projected fiscal position in these econo- mies in 2011–12, which also reflects the size of the expected fiscal change for each country under the current plans. In both cases, we quantify the potential effect of fiscal consolidation on output growth and the trade balance and calculate the contribution of spillovers from other countries’ consolidation plans to the respec- tive changes. The approach only quantifies the direct demand impact and does not reflect credibility or other non-demand-driven effects (to the extent that they

1 The full list of countries includes Austria, Belgium, Brazil, China, France, Germany, Greece, India, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Korea, Netherlands, Portugal, Russia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, and United States.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 151 are not embedded in the underlying multiplier estimates). Moreover, the approach focuses on a short-term impact (two years) and may not fully capture the effects of exchange rate and price adjustments on growth and the trade balance, which are also likely to reduce the spillovers in the longer term. Hence, the results can be viewed as upper-bound estimates of fiscal spillovers from consolidation, since the other effects would reduce the negative impact on growth. The remainder of the chapter briefly discusses the findings of the related literature on fiscal multipliers and spillover effects; derives the analytical frame- work; presents the simulation results and discusses the global effects of spillovers; and provides concluding policy implications.

LITERATURE The literature on economic spillovers across borders has grown in recent years. However, there are only a few quantitative studies measuring the growth impact of fiscal spillovers, that is, the impact of domestic fiscal changes on growth in other countries. This is not surprising, since aggregate fiscal spillovers are negli- gible when the fiscal cycles of countries are independent from each other, because the sum of fiscal changes in the rest of the world is likely to be small as consolida- tion and expansion in different countries offset each other. But in the event of a global downturn, fiscal spending tends to become syn- chronized as countries step up spending to bolster output during the recession. For example, in the aftermath of the financial crisis of 2008–09, governments simultaneously implemented fiscal stimulus packages, while now there is a global tendency to reduce fiscal deficits. Estimates of growth spillovers in the context of crises and synchronized fiscal consolidation are scarce. Thus, our understanding of the international growth impact of fiscal changes derives from studies that focus on the domestic effect of fiscal consolidation. Since the size of the domestic effect of fiscal consolidation on growth is rather important for evaluating the potential for cross-country spillover effects, we also review the literature on the domestic effects of fiscal policy. We focus on studies that investigate the difference in the effects on growth between times of crises and ‘normal’ times. In reviewing the literature, we reach two main conclusions. First, the existing estimates of fiscal spillovers suggest that they are limited, although spillovers from the United States may be relevant. In most cases, however, the analysis of spill- overs is based on the effect of an individual country while keeping fiscal policy in other countries unchanged. Hence, the effect of coordinated consolidation may not be fully captured. Furthermore, the estimates of growth spillovers are based on ‘normal times’ and simulation results often rely on forward-looking agent models; both favor the finding that the impact of fiscal changes on growth is low. Second, while estimates of the impact of fiscal multipliers from domestic policy action in a single country on its own growth vary widely, the evidence suggests

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 152 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

that the multipliers are likely to be on the higher side in the current environment. In particular, interest rates are close to the zero bound and cannot fall much fur- ther to crowd in investment. Also, the shares of liquidity-constrained households and firms are likely to be high in the aftermath of the financial crisis. Some recent studies investigate the spillover effects of fiscal policy.2 Beetsma, Giuliodori, and Klaassen (2006) find that the average effect of a fiscal stimulus of 1 percent of GDP in Germany is an increase of 0.23 percent in foreign GDP for a spending increase and 0.06 percent for a net tax cut, within two years.3 Spillovers from France are found to be lower but still non-negligible. The authors employ a two-step procedure. In the first step, they use a standard panel vector autoregression (VAR) approach to identify fiscal shocks. In the second step, a panel bilateral trade model is estimated to obtain the effects of changes in domes- tic output on foreign exports. Merging the responses from the two blocks allows them to compute the overall effect of the fiscal impulses on bilateral exports and thereby on the output of other countries. However, their estimates do not repre- sent the full extent of the spillovers, since they do not account for further feed- back effects among the economies.4 Bénassy-Quéré and Cimadomo (2006) find positive cross-border spillovers from Germany, at least in neighboring and smaller countries. The authors find tax multipliers to be larger than spending multipliers and the effect of tax shocks on output to be more persistent.5 They estimate a factor-augmented VAR model, appending the GDP and the real exchange rate of one country at a time to the German model. Their focus is on the seven biggest European Union (EU) mem- ber countries. Germany is assumed to be contemporaneously unaffected by the foreign variables, while German shocks can affect the country under analysis. The estimation procedure constrains the analysis to direct effects from Germany to the respective country while not accounting for multi-country spillovers and poten- tial feedback loops. Some authors have employed multi-country macro models to simulate the extent of spillovers from fiscal policies. For instance, Gros and Hobza (2001) provide an overview of results from four major macroeconomic models on the

2 Another study which looks at fiscal spillovers is Canova and Pappa (2007). However, the authors focus on the effect of regional expenditure and revenue shocks on the price differentials, and not growth, in monetary unions using the example of the U.S. states as well as nine EMU member coun- tries. Since the authors run separate BVARs for each unit and construct average responses from these estimates, they also cannot account explicitly for spillovers across regions. 3 German fiscal expansion has a particularly strong effect on its small neighbors. An increase in public spending (a decrease in net taxes) by 1 percent of GDP in Germany leads to a more than 0.4 percent (0.1 percent) normalized increase in the GDP of Austria, Belgium, Luxemburg, and the Netherlands after two years. 4 The authors thus argue that the effects should be regarded as lower bounds and that further research is needed on the feedback between all countries. 5 The authors find that German tax shocks have a beneficial impact on foreign GDP. However, this effect seems to be limited to neighboring countries. Cross-border spillovers from fiscal spending shocks are found to be low and rarely significant, except for a few countries (Belgium, Austria, and the Netherlands).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 153 cross-country spillover effects of fiscal policy, focusing on the effect of a govern- ment spending shock of 1 percent of GDP in Germany.6 Effects are found to be relatively small. The effects are generally positive for small open economies, which trade extensively with Germany, ranging around 0.02 percent of baseline GDP (Austria, Belgium, and the Netherlands). However, they tend to be negative for the bigger countries and the small countries with few trade links with Germany, ranging around −0.05 percent of baseline GDP (France, Italy, Spain, Greece, and Portugal). Cwik and Wieland (2009) use five different empirical macroeconomic models to evaluate the impact of fiscal stimulus in the financial crisis.7 Spillover effects from German expansion during the crisis are found to increase GDP in France by 0.04 percent after one year, while the effect is found to be negative for Italy with −0.001 percent. The authors explain the negative effect by the fact that the direct-demand effects are overwhelmed by the indirect effect of a euro appre- ciation.8 The OECD (2009) provides some aggregate spillover results for the United States, Japan, the Euro area, and other OECD countries. Spillovers are lowest to the United States and to the euro area as a whole, but they are sizeable to other OECD countries in 2009 and even more so in 2010, mainly due to U.S. fiscal expansion. The 2011 World Economic Outlook demonstrates potentially large spillovers from a coordinated fiscal consolidation to a small open economy like Canada (IMF, 2010). In the single-country context, estimates of fiscal multipliers vary substantially across various studies and across countries.9 Blanchard and Perotti (2002) find that, consistent with theory, an increase in government spending in the United States boosts output, while an increase in taxes reduces output. They do not find a significantly lower impact of taxes compared to spending in terms of cumulative multipliers, but the tax shocks appear to be less persistent. Multipliers are close to one. Spending shocks tend to have a negative effect on investment, while con- sumption tends to rise. Romer and Romer (2010), in contrast, find much stron- ger effects of tax changes for the United States. Their results, however, are not strictly comparable, since in Romer and Romer (2010) fiscal shocks are not based

6 The impact on German GDP in the first year amounts to a change of 0.4 to 1.2 percent. The origi- nal paper includes results from four models including MULTIMOD (IMF), NiGEM (NIESR), QUEST (EC), and Marmotte (CEPII). We excluded results from the latter for the discussion here, since it is based on a multi-country framework that assumes full flexibility of output prices and rational forward-looking agents. 7 The four models based on the New-Keynesian approach do not support a textbook Keynesian mul- tiplier effect. The reason is the forward-looking behavior of households and firms. They anticipate higher tax burdens and higher interest rates in the future and therefore reduce consumption and investment. Only the ECB’s area-wide model, which largely ignores forward-looking behavior, is found to generate government spending multipliers that are significantly above one. 8 It should be noted that the results are based on a G7 country model and on the assumption of no fiscal change in the other countries. Thus, positive spillovers from third country effects are likely to be underestimated (due to the country sample) and negative repercussions from the appreciation of the euro overestimated (due to the country sample and the absence of a fiscal expansion in the other countries). 9 For a summary of literature on multipliers see Schindler, Spilimbergo, and Symansky (2009).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 154 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

on the standard estimation framework but derived from a narrative approach. An exogenous tax increase of one percent of GDP lowers real GDP, typically by over 1.5 percent after one year and by 2.5 percent after two years. Investment falls sharply in response to exogenous tax increases. Using the change in the cyclically adjusted revenues yields a smaller impact of about 0.5 percent after one year and 1.3 percent after two years. The 2010 World Economic Outlook, which uses a similar narrative approach to construct the measure of fiscal policy in a sample of advanced countries, concludes that expansionary effects of consolidation are unusual in the short run, with an estimated average reduction in GDP of about ½ percentage point after two years from a 1 percent of GDP fiscal contraction. Several recent studies have focused on the effects of fiscal policy during the financial crisis. This literature argues that during the recent financial crisis, spill- over effects were prone to be particularly high, since conditions were relatively favorable (Blanchard and others, 2009; IMF, 2010): interest rates were very low, inflation pressure was low, and investment had collapsed. With interest rates often at the zero lower bound, crowding out was minimized (Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo, 2009). Almunia and others (2009) employ the experience of the Great Depression to estimate fiscal multipliers at the time when the banking system is dysfunctional and monetary policy is constrained by the zero bound. They employ a VAR technique, instrumental variables, and qualitative evidence for a panel of 27 countries in the period 1925–1939, and they find large fiscal multipliers; for example, for expenditure they find a multiplier of 2.5 on impact and 1.2 after one year. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2010) find a stark contrast between multipli- ers in recessions and expansions.10 Estimates for spending multipliers in recession are about 2–2.5 times higher than estimated multipliers when not accounting for different stages in the business cycle. Shocks also appear to be of a much more permanent nature during recessions, as opposed to expansions. Tagkalakis (2008) finds that liquidity constraints can explain these asymmetric effects of fiscal poli- cy on output over the business cycle. In recessions, liquidity constraints are bind- ing for a wider range of firms and households, which makes the fiscal policy more effective by stimulating consumption spending through either tax cuts or govern- ment spending. Similarly, Corsetti, Meier, and Müller (2010b), analyzing a panel of countries, find that multipliers for government spending shocks are much higher in times of crises, causing output to increase twofold relative to the spending increase. The authors use a two-step procedure, first identifying country-specific spending shocks and then using a panel approach to regress spending shocks interacted with country characteristics. The confidence bands, however, are very wide, sug- gesting caution in interpreting these results.

10 On the other hand, the OECD (2009) argues that multipliers may be lower in the current crises, about 0.5 percent, due to households’ higher propensity to save.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 155

While the recent literature provides some results on the impact of fiscal spillovers on growth, the analysis is generally conducted in an “all else being equal” manner, that is, it looks at the direct effect of a single country’s fiscal policy on others without taking into account indirect second-round effects through trading partners, which could amplify the impact. We contribute to the literature by accounting for these second-round effects. Moreover, unlike earlier studies, we study not only the potential spillover effects but also the spillovers that are implied by the announced global fiscal consolidation plans for 2011–12.

FRAMEWORK Fiscal Spillover Framework The spillover framework is based on a representation of the national accounts and behavioral assumptions for government spending, taxes, consumption, invest- ment, exports, and imports. Starting from the national accounting identity, we know that: =+++− YCIGXMt ,,,,,j t j t j t j t j t ,j (1.1)

Where Yt , j is the real output, It , j is real investment, Gt , j is the real government spending, X t , j is real exports and Mt , j is real imports of country j in time t denominated in a common currency. The single elements of output are respec- tively given by:11

=+ − =μ CCcYTt ,01,,j ( t j t j ) Mt ,jj Yt ,j

I =+ − = ωμ (1.2) IIt ,01,2,j d Yt j d rXt j t ,jiji∑ Yt ,i ij≠ i=1

μ 12 i is the marginal propensity to import of a trading partner i, Yt,i is the output ω of a trading partner i, and ij is the weight of imports from country j in total imports of country i. Substituting the definitions (1.2) in (1.1) yields

I =+ − + ωμ YexmGmcTmt ,,j t jjt ,jj 1,t jj∑ iji Yt ,i (1.3) ij≠ i=1

11 The model does not account for potential crowding-out effects. Allowing consumption and invest- ment to react to fiscal changes (beyond the output effect) potentially reduces the contractionary effect of fiscal consolidation. While this is clearly a simplifying assumption, it is not unreasonable in the current economic environment. 12 In the calculations, the marginal propensity to import μi was computed as the ratio of imports to GDP multiplied by the imports elasticity for each country.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 156 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

− =+− =−−+μ1 Where ext ,002,j C I d rt j and mcjj(1 11d ) is the expenditure multiplier, which is also the multiplier for exports. Taking the first difference and dividing by real output in t-1 yields the contribution of the fiscal change to out- put growth: ΔΔYG⎡⎤ ⎡⎤ Δ TI Δ Y t ,,j =−t j t ,j +ωμYi t −1,i mmcmjj⎢⎥1 ⎢⎥ jiji∑ (1.4) YYt −−1,j ⎣⎦⎢⎥t 1,j ⎣⎦⎢⎥ Yt − 1,j ij≠ YYt −− 1,i t 1, j i=1 Converting expenditure and revenue ratios into nominal terms with respect to GDP we have:13

⎡⎤⎡⎤NNI N ΔΔGP−− TP Y =−⎢⎥⎢⎥t ,,1jjtt ,jj ,1t +ωμi,1t − ymj,1t jjNN mc m jijii∑ y N(1.5) ⎣⎦⎣⎦⎢⎥⎢⎥YPj,1t −−j ,t YPj ,1t j ,t i=1 Yj ,1t − ij≠

Where Pj,t is the price level at time t, which is measured by the GDP deflator. Consistent with empirical findings, we allow the fiscal measures to incorporate a current period as well as a lagged period effect from fiscal measures imple- mented in the previous period:

⎡⎤ΔGPN ⎢⎥t ,,1jjt − =+GG,1 ,2 mmjjjN g ,,1t mjjg t − ⎣⎦⎢⎥YPj,1t − j ,t

⎡⎤ΔTPN ⎢⎥t ,,1jjt − =+TT,1 ,2 mcjjj1,,1N m t t mjjt t − (1.6) ⎣⎦⎢⎥YPj,1t − j ,t

Equation (1.5) is a system of I linear equations that can be written in matrix notation and solved for the change in expenditures and revenues according to:  Y =−W ⎣⎦⎡⎤AG AT (1.7) ttt12 −  Where W =−()IB1 is an I-by-I identity matrix, B is an I-by-I matrix, Y is an

I-by-1 vector of real GDP growth rates, A1 and A2 are diagonal I-by-I matrices,

and Gt and T are I-by-1 vectors. It is possible to derive country i’s contribution to country j’s GDP growth by evaluating:

yw =−ji⎣⎦⎡⎤ag ji i at ji i t ,12ji tt (1.8)

*** N *N YYYq YsPsY−− − 13 t−−−1,i ==ij t 1,iijt 1,iijt 1,i ==t 1,i t 1,i Note that we used the following transformation: NN YYt−1,j t − 1,j PYYYt −−−− 1,j t 1,j t 1,j t 1, j

where qij and sij are respectively the real and the nominal exchange rate between country i and country j and stars denote values in foreign currency. The nominal exchange rate is assumed to be stable across the period of analysis.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 157

We can use the definitions in (1.2) to derive the implicit change in the real trade balance that is caused by the change in fiscal spending. To do so, we first compute the real change in exports and imports relative to real GDP in t-1: Δ I Δ X t , j YYt ,1,i t − i ΔΔ =ωμ∑ MYt ,,j t j ij i =μ (1.9) YYYt −−−1,j ij≠ t 1,i t 1, j j = YY i 1 t −−1,j t 1, j Converting into nominal terms with respect to GDP and subtracting gives the real change in the trade balance relative to GDP in t-1:

XPNNNN( // P) −− X MP( P) M j,,1,t j t −−−−j t j ,1,,1,t − j t j t j t j ,1t NN YYj,1t −−j ,1t (1.10) I Y N =ωμi,1t −  −μ ∑ ij i N yyt ,,ijt j ij≠ Y j,1t − i=1

Measures of Fiscal Stance An important question in identifying the growth impacts of fiscal changes is the choice of the measure of fiscal stance. In theory, the multiplier is defined with respect to the change in real fiscal variables; in particular, it provides an answer to the question, By how many units does the output change if the fiscal variable (say, expenditure) changes by one unit, keeping other things constant? In practice, however, policymakers often use the measure of fiscal policy changes in relation to GDP or potential GDP, which facilitates comparison across countries. In addi- tion, a measure of cyclically adjusted fiscal changes is often employed to separate the impact of discretionary fiscal policy on output. While the latter allows one to make a clear link between fiscal changes and growth, since it can be viewed as largely exogenous to output changes, it misses an important component of auto- matic stabilizers, which contribute to output dynamics. To assess the robustness of our results, we employ three different measures of fiscal stance: • Changes in cyclically adjusted revenues/expenditures in percent of GDP, using Girouard and André (2005) estimates of elasticities and European Comission (EC) approach for calculating cyclical adjustment;14 • Changes in headline revenue/expenditure in percent of GDP; and • Changes in headline revenue/expenditure in real terms. All three measures have their advantages and disadvantages and capture different aspects of fiscal policy. Cyclically adjusted measures attempt to capture discretionary fiscal action. However, they might not provide an accurate picture when historical

14 We compared the estimates of fiscal changes based on cyclically adjusted revenue/expenditure in per- cent of GDP with those in percent of potential GDP and found the differences to be small. We chose to report the results for the measure scaled by GDP to facilitate comparison with the headline measure.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 158 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

elasticities of revenues/expenditures do not correctly capture automatic stabilizers, for example in countries where asset prices play an important role (e.g., the United Kingdom) or where there might have been structural changes (e.g., the German labor market, where developments have recently decoupled from developments in the output gap). Estimation of potential output is also inherently difficult. The measure of fiscal balance based on revenue/expenditure in percent of GDP is a commonly used indicator that captures not only discretionary policy but also automatic stabilizers. While it does not require additional assumptions on the output gap and elasticities, it is endogenous in the sense that it is itself affected by developments in the GDP. Resolving the issue of endogeneity, how- ever, is rather difficult and is beyond the scope of this study. Moreover, the fact that the denominator—be it actual GDP or potential GDP—is changing implies that any measure in ratios is bound to reflect those changes, which may be distortive in terms of measuring fiscal contribution to growth. The following example demonstrates this for government spending: The change in expenditure in real terms, which is relevant for computing fiscal con- tribution to growth (see formula (1.4)), can be written as rr− Δ=real GGtt−1 G r Yt −1

r r where Gt is real fiscal spending at time t and Yt −1 is real output at time t-1. Then the change in expenditure in ratios to GDP or potential GDP can be written as rr r Δ=−ratiosGPtt G t−−11 P t =Δ− real G t GGg r rr rYt YPtt Y t−−11 P t Y t

where g r is a real GDP or potential GDP growth at time t. Therefore, provided Yt that the growth in GDP or potential GDP is non-zero, the differences can be substantial for revenue/expenditure subcomponents, since the ratio of expendi- ture/revenue to GDP is typically large. The differences for the overall balance, however, will be small, since the differences for revenue and expenditure largely offset each other. While the theoretical definition of multiplier is based on a concept of real change in revenue/expenditure, the empirical estimates of fiscal multipliers are sometimes geared towards the measure based on ratios to GDP or potential GDP. Therefore, none of the measures mentioned above is perfect, and the three mea- sures capture different aspects of fiscal policy, so all three can be useful in assessing the impact on growth.

SIMULATION RESULTS For practical reasons we limit our discussion to 20 countries, with a focus on European countries but a fair representation of major international actors. More precisely, our exercise includes all nations with a ratio of domestic output to world output above 2 percent. Given our particular interest in the euro area countries,

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 159 we also include in the sample a range of euro area members and their relevant trading partners. The final sample includes the following 20 countries:15

Austria Germany Japan† Spain Belgium Greece Korea† Sweden Brazil† India† Netherlands Switzerland‡ China†‡ Ireland Portugal United Kingdom†‡ France Italy Russia† United States†‡ The sample represents more than 70 percent of world GDP and covers on aver- age two-thirds of a country’s imports and of its exports. For the euro area members in the sample, the values are roughly three-quarters for imports and exports. The OECD (2009) reports revenue and spending multipliers for current peri- ods and lagged effects for subcomponents of revenues and expenditures for a wide sample of countries. We draw on these multipliers for specific tax and revenue T ,1 policies to compute the respective values for the current-period revenue ( mj ) G ,1 T ,2 and expenditure ( mj ) as well as the lagged effect revenue ( mj ) and expendi- G ,2 16 ture ( mj ) multiplier. We use each country’s share of specific revenue compo- nents to compute an overall revenue multiplier and similarly an overall spending multiplier. In some cases, the resulting average multipliers are adjusted in line with country-specific estimates provided by IMF country desks. Import elasticities are taken from Kee, Nicita, and Olarreaga (2008). The μ marginal propensity to import ( i ) is then computed by multiplying the elastic- ity with the respective imports-to-GDP ratio in 2009. An overview of the multi- pliers and import elasticities is provided in Table 6A.1. The fiscal measures are based on the IMF’s April 2011 World Economic Outlook data. The simulation framework implies that the differences in the impact of fiscal consolidation are a combination of the following elements: • The country-specific revenue and expenditure multipliers • The composition of the consolidation (revenue versus expenditure measures), and • The trade links between countries (and thus these countries’ characteristics for sub-points 1 to 2) and their propensity to import when income changes. We will refer to variations in the above in the respective robustness checks. Uniform Fiscal Shock Baseline Multipliers and Import Elasticities We first demonstrate an impact of a 1 percent of GDP shock to expenditures to gauge the relative size of spillovers between countries under the baseline assumption

15 Countries marked by † account for more than 2 percent of world output, and countries marked with ‡ are major trading partners for one or more of the euro member countries. We excluded Canada and Mexico in favor of several smaller euro zone members. Both Mexico and Canada have negligible effects on the European countries but are very much subject to U.S. shocks. 16 More precisely we employ the country-specific multipliers labeled “high multipliers” by the OECD (2009). The term “high” in this context refers to the fact that the OECD’s “reference” multiplier employed in its study is “judgmentally scaled down, by more for tax cuts than for government spending,” since the current eco- nomic circumstances are “more likely to reduce multipliers.” Thus we use effectively the original series.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 160 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

on multipliers and import elasticities. The baseline multipliers average at 0.5 for revenue and 0.8 for expenditure after two years across the sample of 20 countries. Consequently, the baseline multipliers are relatively high. The import elasticities average at 1.15. To clarify the mechanics and the intuition behind the reported results, we present the calculation of the first-round spillover effects from a 1 percent decline in government spending in Germany to the peripheral European countries after one year in Table 6.1. The first-round effect of the fiscal consolidation in Germany on growth in Portugal can be approximated as follows. German imports from Portugal com- prise only 0.7 percent of total German imports,17 while Germany’s marginal propensity to import out of income is 0.5 (imports share in GDP times imports elasticity). Therefore, out of every additional euro of income Germany will import only 0.35 cents from Portugal, and the opposite is true for income reduction. Since fiscal spending in Germany has a multiplier of only about 0.4 after one year, a one percent of GDP decline in fiscal spending in Germany will reduce German GDP due to domestic consolidation by only about 0.4 percent after one year, which would result in a decline of about 10 billion euros. As a result, Germany will import 0.03 billion euros less from Portugal, and Portuguese exports will decline by this amount. However, this does not trans- late to the equivalent amount of income loss for Portugal since, for example, some of this reduction will be compensated by lower imports. Since exports have the same multiplier as expenditures (see equation (1.3)), which is about 0.5 for Portugal, the actual income loss for Portugal would only be about 0.015 billion euros, which corresponds to about 0.009 percent reduction in Portuguese GDP in the first year (German GDP is 15 times larger than Portuguese GDP). This calculation, however, does not incorporate second-round effects, since a reduction in German GDP will result in lower growth in other common trading partners of Germany and Portugal. Taking into account these second-round effects will result in a slightly greater reduction in GDP growth in Portugal, namely 0.011 percent. The impact on Ireland is somewhat greater but on Greece it is almost negligible.18 Consequently, the impact of Germany’s fiscal policy on the peripheral coun- tries is likely to be rather small. As we demonstrate below, even very high multi- pliers result in only a moderate impact from Germany alone. The matrix of results of a coordinated 1 percent decline in fiscal spending across all 20 countries is reported in Table 6A.2 in the Appendix. The table

17 In fact, the share is even smaller; the results in the table were rescaled by the total over the sample of 20 countries to sum up to 1. 18 It should be noted that the calculation results are based on the pattern of trade in goods. Greece, however, has a substantial share of trade in services, hence the estimates are biased downward. Nonetheless, the impact is likely to be very small; even assuming that trade in services is about 50 percent of total trade in Greece and, hence, by roughly doubling the results would yield very small spillovers from Germany.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution TABLE 6.1 An Example of a Simple Calculation of a Spillover Effect from Germany to the Peripheral European Countries, Baseline Multipliers Total Spillover Effect on First-Round Effect on Growth after First-Round Effect on German GDP First-Round Effect on Peripheral Exports Peripheral GDP One Year The solution Share of given by (1.8), country’s Ratio of Export First round reflects imports in German German German multiplier spillover effect indirect effects Expenditure Expenditure total German imports marginal output to First-round effect of the on growth through other shock in multiplier First-round effect German imports share in propensity country’s on peripheral peripheral after one year countries Germany in Germany on German GDP imports elasticity GDP to import output exports country (percent) (percent)

N ⎡⎤N N ΔX N ΔX ΔGP ΔGPti,,1 it− M M Yit,1− tj, Yit,1− tj, ti,,1 it− ym = ⎢⎥ ti−1, μ=ε ti−1, =ω μ y m Peripheral N iiYPN ii Y N YYij i i N j Y YP m ⎣⎦it,1− it , ω ε Y Y jt,1− tj−−1, jt , 1 m tj−1, y Country it,1− it , i ij i ti−1, ti−1, j tji, Greece –1.000 0.410 –0.410 0.004 1.140 0.422 0.481 10.975 –0.008 0.555 –0.004 –0.005 Ireland –1.000 0.410 –0.410 0.013 1.140 0.422 0.481 16.124 –0.042 0.395 –0.017 –0.024 Portugal –1.000 0.410 –0.410 0.007 1.140 0.422 0.481 14.604 –0.021 0.453 –0.009 –0.011

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 162 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

reports the growth impact (percent deviation from the baseline of no fiscal change) after two years. Countries where the fiscal shock originates are reported in columns, while recipient countries of the growth impact are in rows. Hence, the diagonal elements of this matrix show the growth impact of the country’s domestic fiscal policy while the off-diagonal elements show the spillovers—the impact on country’s growth due to the fiscal changes in other countries. The total at the end of the row, therefore, is the total growth impact on a particular country reported in this row from the coordinated fiscal consolidation. The PPP-weighted average at the bottom of the table can be interpreted as an individual country’s impact on the whole group of 20 countries—a proxy of the impact on world growth. The PPP-weighted average, however, includes both the impact on global growth from the changes in domestic growth of a country and through the spill- overs from this country to other countries weighted by the PPP GDP of each country. The results indicate that the overall impact of a 1 percent of GDP coordinated fiscal consolidation is sizeable, reducing growth in the 20 countries on average by about 0.9 percent after two years (PPP-weighted basis), largely due to the impact on growth from domestic consolidation, with only about 15 percent being accounted for by spillovers from one country to another. The largest contribu- tions to the PPP-weighted average growth decline come from the United States and China (close to 0.2 percent) reflecting their large weight in the world econo- my, followed by Japan and India (close to 0.1 percent) with Germany, France, Brazil, Italy and Russia contributing close to 0.05 percent while United Kingdom, Spain, and Korea contributing about 0.03 percent each. Total inward fiscal spillovers to most countries are limited, not exceeding 0.3 percentage points over two years and averaging at 0.1 on PPP-weighted basis and 0.2 on simple average basis. However, spillovers to Ireland, Belgium, Austria, the Netherlands and Korea are more substantial, close to ½ percentage points over two years. (Figure 6.1) In the case of Ireland, the largest single-country contribu- tion comes from the United States (Table 6A.2). For Austria and the Netherlands, spillovers from Germany are particularly pronounced, while for Belgium spill- overs from Germany and France are equally important. In Korea, spillovers from China play an important role. However, individual country spillovers to other individual countries are rather small, not exceeding 0.16 percentage points over two years. Higher Multipliers and Import Elasticities There are several arguments why multipliers in the current economic environ- ment are likely to be higher than under the usual circumstances (see Corsetti, Meier, and Müller, 2010b; Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2010, and IMF, 2010). To reflect such a possibility, we analyze the extent to which a multiplier level of one standard deviation above the respective baseline value for expenditure multiplier changes the growth impact and, in particular, spillovers. This implies that expenditure multipliers are about 25 percent above their baseline values and

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 163

0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.4 –0.5 –0.6 –0.7 –0.8 Simple average PPP–weighted average –0.9 –1 l n e

Italy India apan China Spai J Brazi Ireland Austria France Greec Belgium Portugal Sweden Germany

Netherlands Switzerland United States United Kingdom Korea, Republic of Russian Federation Figure 6.1 Inward Fiscal Spillovers (Impact on real GDP from a 1 percent of GDP reduction in fiscal spending in other countries, baseline multipliers, cumulative after two years, percent) Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity. the resulting multiplier close to 1. In principle, higher multipliers could be caused by a higher propensity to consume or a lower propensity to import (see explana- tion to equation 1.3 above). If multipliers are higher due to higher marginal propensity to consume, with unchanged marginal propensity to import, then spillovers would be higher since they would raise the impact on domestic demand. The impact on spillovers from higher multipliers due to lower propen- sity to import is ambiguous, since lower propensity to import would contribute to lowering spillovers while higher multipliers would tend to increase them. We analyze the impact of higher multipliers under the assumption that it is a result of higher propensity to consume to give spillovers a higher chance to play out. It should be noted that the resulting average high multiplier (close to 1 after two years) is consistent with the estimates obtained under constrained monetary policy in the 2010 World Economic Outlook (IMF, 2010). There is also evidence that import elastitices vary over the cycle, with higher elasticities during the downturn (e.g. Leibovici and Waugh, 2011). We therefore also perform a robustness check with higher import elasticities while leaving unchanged the baseline assumption on expenditure multipliers. We assume that in this scenario, higher import elasticities were combined with higher marginal propensities to consume such that the opposing effects of these changes lead to unchanged expenditure multipliers. Higher import elasticities are calculated as baseline elasticities plus five standard deviations, resulting in an average elasticity of 1.64, that is, about 40 percent higher than the baseline elasticities (Table 6.2).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 164 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter? Inward spillovers a Elasticities Baseline Expenditure Multipliersand Higher Imports a Inward spillovers Total Domestic higher imports elasticity. higher imports elasticity. ase when imports elasticities were increased, expenditure multipliers were assumed to assumed to multipliers were expenditure ase when imports increased, elasticities were fter Two Years (Percent) Years fter Two A Higher Multipliersand Baseline Imports Elasticities a F staff estimates. M Inward spillovers Total Domestic irection of Trade Statistics; and I Trade irection of ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution eduction in Fiscal Spending on Growth Spending on Growth eduction in Fiscal D R P D Baseline Multipliersand Imports Elasticities utlook database, and utlook database, O From: Total Domestic verage –1.0 –0.8 –0.2 –1.4 –1.0 –0.4 –1.2 –0.8 –0.3 epublic of –1.2 –0.8 –0.3 –1.6 –1.0 –0.5 –1.3 –0.8 –0.5 A R remain unchanged from the baseline as marginal propensity to consume is assumed to compensate the decline in multipliers due to compensate is assumed to consume to propensity the baseline as marginal unchanged from remain etherlands –1.1 –0.8 –0.4 –1.6 –1.0 –0.7 –1.4 –0.8 –0.6 ustria –1.5 –1.1 –0.4 –2.0 –1.3 –0.7 –1.8 –1.1 –0.7 ussian Federation –1.0 –0.8 –0.2 –1.3 –1.0 –0.3 –1.1 –0.8 –0.2 Impact of a 1 Percent of G Impact of a 1 Percent To: A BelgiumBrazilChinaFranceGermanyGreeceIndiaIreland –1.3ItalyJapan –0.9 Korea, –1.0 –1.3 –1.0 –0.7Portugal –0.9R –0.8Spain –0.9 –0.8 –1.3Sweden –1.1 –0.8 –0.5Switzerland –1.2 KingdomUnited –0.8 –0.9 –0.1 StatesUnited –0.2 –0.8 averagePPP-weighted –0.2 –0.8 –0.2 –1.0Simple –1.8 –1.0 0.0 –0.8 –0.8 –0.9 –1.1 –1.2 –1.0 –0.9 –0.1 –1.4 –0.5 –1.7 –0.8 –0.6 –1.4 –0.9 –0.2 –0.1 –1.1 –0.7 –0.8 –1.0 –1.0 –0.7 –0.7 –1.1 –1.0 –0.2 –1.9 –1.3 –0.6 –1.0 –0.9 –1.4 –1.1 –0.1 –0.1 –1.0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.1 –0.3 –1.0 –0.4 –1.0 –0.4 –1.3 0.0 –1.6 –1.2 –0.1 –1.0 –1.1 –1.2 –0.9 –1.5 –1.4 –1.2 –0.1 –1.1 –0.9 –1.5 –1.0 –1.2 –0.8 –0.8 –0.3 –0.1 –0.9 –0.8 –1.0 –0.8 –1.2 –0.9 –0.9 –0.9 –0.8 –0.3 –1.6 –1.1 –0.8 –0.8 –0.8 –1.3 –0.9 –0.2 –0.2 –0.8 –0.1 –0.3 –0.5 –0.2 –0.3 –0.8 –0.4 –0.8 –0.3 –1.1 –0.1 –1.0 –0.1 –0.8 –0.8 –1.0 –1.3 –1.1 –1.0 –0.1 –0.8 –0.8 –0.7 –0.3 –0.1 –0.7 –0.8 –1.0 –0.7 –0.7 –0.3 –0.6 –0.2 –0.2 –0.3 –0.4 –0.2 –0.1 N See Table 5.1 for the assumptions on multipliers and imports 5.1 for In the c elasticities under the baseline and using higher values. Table See TABLE 6.2 TABLE Source: World World Economic Source: a Ivanova and Weber 165

0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.4 –0.5 –0.6 –0.7 –0.8 Simple average PPP–weighted average –0.9 –1

Italy India China Spain Japan Brazil Ireland Austria France Greece Belgium Portugal Sweden Germany

Netherlands Switzerland United States United Kingdom Korea, Republic of Russian Federation Figure 6.2 Inward Fiscal Spillovers (Impact on real GDP from a 1 percent of GDP reduction in fiscal spending in other countries, higher multipliers, cumulative after two years, percent) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity.

Results reported in the table above suggest that the average growth impact increases with higher multipliers. However, what is more striking is the non-lin- earity with which this affects the impact through spillovers. While multipliers are increased by only about 25 percent, the overall impact of fiscal consolidation on output growth is increased by more than 30 percent. This is primarily due to a more than 60 percent increase of spillovers from other countries’ consolidation efforts, while the domestic effect increased proportionally to the average increase in multipliers. In PPP-average terms, the increase implies a reduction of GDP growth due to spillovers by only 0.2 percentage points, while a simple average is now close to 0.4 percentage points. However, for some countries, spillovers now account for a sizable fraction of growth reduction, with the largest spillovers close to 1 percentage point for Ireland and Belgium (Figure 6.2). Import elasticities also have a magnifying effect on spillovers, although the effect is less pronounced. Import elasticities that are higher on average by 40 percent lead to an increase in spillovers by over 50 percent, while the domestic impact remains virtually unchanged. As a result, the overall growth impact increases by about 10 percent compared to the baseline, since the share of spill- overs remains relatively small (just over 20 percent on the PPP-average basis of the overall growth impact). After two years, the average spillovers on a PPP basis are close to 0.2 and on a simple-average basis are over 0.3 percentage points. The list of countries substantially affected by spillovers remains unchanged (Figure 6.3).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 166 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.4 –0.5 –0.6 –0.7 –0.8 –0.9 Simple average PPP–weighted average –1

Italy India China Spain Japan Brazil Ireland Austria France Greece Belgium Portugal Sweden Germany

Netherlands Switzerland United States United Kingdom Korea, Republic of Russian Federation Figure 6.3 Inward Fiscal Spillovers (Impact on real GDP from a 1 percent of GDP reduction in fiscal spending in other countries, higher imports elasticities, cumulative after two years, percent) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.

These results suggest that, on average, the size of spillovers remains limited under alternative assumptions on multipliers and import elasticities, with the exception of small open economies, where the effects can be substantial. However, even for those countries where spillovers can be substantial, the impact of fiscal changes in a single trading partner remains contained, not exceeding ¼ percentage point over two years. German fiscal policy, in particu- lar, has limited implications for growth in the European periphery. Very high multipliers would have to operate for Germany to exhibit a relatively modest impact on these countries. For example, with expenditure multipliers equal to the baseline plus four standard deviations (an average expenditure multiplier of 1.6 after two years), after two years a one percent of GDP fiscal expenditure stimulus in Germany would raise the GDP growth in Ireland by only 0.3 per- centage points, in Portugal by 0.1 percentage points, and in Greece with virtu- ally no effect on growth. Similarly, fiscal policy changes in Germany alone have only a small impact on the trade balance of the peripheral countries and are thus unlikely to contribute to the reduction in the peripheral countries’ imbalances (Figure 6.4).

Actual Consolidation Plans We now turn to the growth impact of the actual fiscal plans in the years 2011 and 2012. To assess the robustness of our conclusions, we employ all three measures previously discussed.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 167

0.9 Germany 0.8 France 0.7 United States

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

baseline after 2 years 0.2

0.1

Percent deviation of output level from the 0 Ireland Greece Portugal

Figure 6.4 Fiscal spillovers to Greece, Ireland, and Portugal Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: Government spending shock is 1 percent of GDP increase in spending. The simulation assumes large domestic fiscal multipliers on government spending averaging at 1.6 for Germany, USA and France.

Cyclically Adjusted Fiscal Measure (Percent of Potential GDP) Fiscal consolidation started in 2011 and is forecast to intensify in 2012. The aver- age adjustment to the cyclically adjusted balance is 0.3 percent of GDP in 2011 and 1.4 percent in 2012. The average adjustment is biased toward expenditure reductions (Table 6.3). The overall growth impact of fiscal consolidation is moderate in 2011 (0.2 percentage points) but more notable in 2012 (0.7 percentage points). This reflects not only the fact that the fiscal plans include a larger degree of consolidation in 2012, in particular in the United States, but also the fact that the impact in 2011 is somewhat cushioned by a lagged effect from 2010, when the fiscal stance was still expansionary on average. The cross-country variation in the growth impact reflects the respective countries’ extent of consolidation and the varying size of the spillovers from other countries (Table 6.4). There are hardly any aggregate spillovers from consolidation in 2011, and the small aggregate spillovers in 2012 largely reflect spillovers to small open econo- mies. Of the cumulative average decline in GDP in 2011 and 2012 (by about 1 percent on a PPP-weighted basis), only about 15 percent may be attributable to spillovers from one country to another, with the effect on GDP decline of only about 0.1 percentage points. The spillovers are somewhat bigger on a simple- average basis (0.2 percentage points), reflecting the fact that spillovers to larger countries tend to be smaller. While aggregate fiscal spillovers are limited, for small open economies such as Ireland, Belgium, Netherlands, and Austria, spillovers can be substantial, largely in 2012. Ireland, in particular, could substantially benefit from a coordinated

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 168 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter? P in 2010 and 2011, D P in 2009, 0.2 percent of G P in 2009, 0.2 percent D P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent of G 2010) and the US (2.4 percent P in ussia only non-oil revenues are assumed to have an impact on growth. have assumed to are non-oilussia only revenues D R P in 2009 and 5.3 percent of G P in 2009 and 5.3 percent D Fiscal (Fiscal measure = cyclically-adjustedchange in percent of GDP) revenue/expenditure 2010 2011 2012 ggregates Revenue Expenditure balance Overall Revenue Expenditure balance Overall Revenue Expenditure balance Overall A F staff estimates. M ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution pril 2011; and I A , djusted Fiscal Fiscal djusted A a P in 2012). Financial sector support is not expected to have a significant impact on demand. For sector support impact For a significant on demand. P in 2012). Financial is not expected have to D Country World Economic Outlook Economic World F, epublic of –1.2 –2.4 1.2 –0.3 –0.6 0.3 0.3 –0.1 0.4 R M and 0.1 percent of G and 0.1 percent etherlands –1.3 –0.9 –0.4 0.5 –0.9 1.4 0.3 –0.3 0.7 ustria –1.1 0.1 –1.2 0.1 –0.7 0.8 0.0 –0.3 0.2 ussian Federation –1.3 –1.5 0.3 0.1 –0.1 0.1 –0.5 –1.0 0.5 Changes in Cyclically Changes in Cyclically A BelgiumBrazilChinaFranceGermanyGreeceIndiaIrelandItalyJapan Korea, PortugalR –0.1SpainSweden 1.3Switzerland –1.0 0.0 KingdomUnited –3.0 0.3 StatesUnited 1.8 3.5 0.9 0.0 averagePPP weighted –1.1 –0.4 0.7Simple average 0.8 –0.6 –3.8 –0.8 –1.9 –0.7 0.0 –0.6 –0.4 0.3 0.5 7.4 2.2 –0.6 –0.2 –1.8 0.3 –0.5 –0.9 –0.2 0.5 –1.4 0.6 –0.5 –2.3 2.0 0.7 –0.2 0.5 –0.6 –1.2 –0.6 3.8 –1.0 –0.2 0.7 –0.2 –0.5 –0.2 –0.8 0.0 –0.3 0.2 1.0 1.6 –0.6 0.6 0.1 –0.6 –0.7 0.3 0.5 0.3 –0.3 –0.4 –1.3 1.1 –0.3 –3.3 2.2 1.5 –0.4 –0.6 –0.7 –1.2 3.5 0.7 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.6 0.6 –0.4 0.0 0.0 1.2 –0.6 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.4 0.0 –1.8 –0.3 0.0 0.0 –1.6 –1.0 –0.3 –0.1 –0.4 –0.1 0.3 0.0 –2.2 –0.8 0.1 1.1 2.6 0.4 –0.5 0.4 0.0 –0.9 2.2 0.6 0.3 –0.6 –0.6 0.5 0.5 2.6 0.9 0.7 0.2 –0.8 –1.0 –0.9 0.8 1.1 0.9 –0.2 0.9 0.6 0.3 0.5 1.3 0.2 –0.2 0.1 –0.1 1.4 0.7 –0.8 –1.7 –0.7 0.2 –0.4 –0.7 –1.9 1.2 1.4 2.0 –0.6 1.0 0.2 0.8 3.3 0.8 N ote: PPP: purchasing power parity. power purchasing PPP: ote: Financial sectorof G above-the-line support Ireland (2.5 percent Financial for recorded was excluded TABLE 6.3 TABLE N Sources: I Sources: a Ivanova and Weber 169 0.0 0.0 –0.1 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 –0.2 –0.1 –0.6 –0.2 –0.5 –0.3 –0.1 –0.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 –0.2 Of which: 2012 0.0 Domestic effect effect Spillover 0.0 Total Total –0.6 –0.5 impact –1.3 –1.1 –1.3 –1.2 –1.2 –1.0 –0.9 –0.9 –0.2 –0.1 –0.3 –0.3 –1.0 –0.8 –1.4 –0.8 –1.2 –1.2 –0.8 –0.5 –0.6 –0.4 –0.5 –0.2 –0.6 –0.2 –0.3–1.3 –0.3 –1.2 –0.9 –0.6 –0.6 –0.4 –0.6 –0.5 –0.7 –0.6 –0.8 –0.6 growth growth 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent of G D P in 2009, of G D P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent D P in 2009 and 5.3 percent G Of which: 2011 0.3 1.2 0.0 0.2 0.3 0.5 Domestic effect effect Spillover (In percentage points) Fiscal Contribution to Growth Fiscal Growth Contribution to 0.3 1.1 0.0 0.2 0.2 0.4 Total Total –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 –0.1 impact –2.0 –1.9 –1.5 –1.4 –0.5 –0.4 –0.3 –0.3 –0.8 –0.7 –2.4–0.5 –2.4 –0.4 –0.4 –0.4 –0.7 –0.7 –0.6 –0.5 –0.7 –0.7 –0.5 –0.5 –0.2 –0.1 –0.4 –0.4 growth growth 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.5 0.3 0.0 0.2 0.3 0.5 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.2 Fiscal (fiscal measure = cyclically-adjusted change in percent of GDP) revenue/expenditure ggregates on Growth ggregates A Of which: 2010 djusted djusted 0.6 0.8 0.7 1.3 1.7 0.8 1.5 0.2 0.6 1.1 0.5 1.7 0.7 0.8 1.1 0.5 1.6 0.7 0.8 0.7 Domestic effect effect Spillover ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 0.8 0.9 0.7 1.4 1.8 1.0 1.7 0.3 0.7 1.6 0.9 1.8 0.9 1.3 1.2 0.7 1.9 0.9 0.9 A pril 2011; and I M F staff estimates. Total Total , impact –1.7 –1.7 –0.5 –0.8 growth growth a World Economic Outlook Economic World Country R epublic of ussia only non-oil revenues are assumed to have have assumed to are R ussia only non-oil revenues impact For sector support on demand. a significant of G D P in 2012). Financial is not expected have to of G D P in 2010 and 2011, 0.1 percent 0.2 percent an impact on growth. ustria The Impact of Changes in Cyclically A ImpactThe of Changes in Cyclically A Brazil Belgium Spain Korea, R ussian Federation Portugal Sweden Germany France Switzerland India N etherlands Greece Italy Ireland Simple average PPP weighted averagePPP weighted 0.9 Japan R . of China, P. United KingdomUnited States United Financial sector support recorded above-the-line was excluded for the calculation of growth impact for Ireland (2.5 percent of impactIreland (2.5 percent sector above-the-line for support the calculation of growth Financial for recorded was excluded TABLE 6.4 TABLE Sources: I M F,Sources: a ote: PPP: purchasing power parity. power purchasing PPP: N ote: 170 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.4 –0.5 –0.6 –0.7 –0.8 Simple average PPP-weighted average –0.9 –1

Italy India Spain China Japan Brazil Ireland Austria France ingdom Greece Belgium Portugal Sweden Germany K Netherlands Switzerland United States United Korea, Republic of Russian Federation Figure 6.5 Inward Fiscal Spillovers (Impact on real GDP from cyclically adjusted fiscal changes in other countries, cumulative 2011–2012, percent) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity.

fiscal relaxation, although this would require contributions from the major economies, including the United States and the United Kingdom, both countries where such relaxation is not in the cards (Figure 6.5). The decomposition of spillovers by country (Table 6A.3) reveals the rela- tively large impact on PPP-weighted average from the United States and China followed by the United Kingdom, Spain, France, and Italy. This reflects both the size of the country and the actual amount of consolidation. For instance, while a uniform fiscal shock would result in a larger impact from Germany than the United Kingdom (Table 6A.2), Germany’s consolidation plans are much more moderate than the United Kingdom’s consolidation plans, resulting in a rela- tively larger impact from the United Kingdom under the actual consolidation plans. For some countries, the overall growth effect masks the various forces that are at work. This is evident once the effect is decomposed into the effects from cur- rent period consolidation and the carry-over effects from the last period’s fiscal change. For instance, in the case of the Netherlands and Belgium, the spillovers in 2011 are negative from the current period consolidation, but there are also small positive spillovers from the previous year’s mostly expansionary fiscal change in relevant trading partner countries, reducing the overall negative effect from spillovers in 2011. However, for countries that are large and not very open (e.g., the United States), spillovers tend to be negligible in both periods (Table 6.5).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 171 P in 2009, D Of which: impact ussia only non-oil revenues are assumed to have an have assumed to are ussia only non-oil revenues P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent of G P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent R D Total growth growth Total balance Change in the fiscal P in 2009 and 5.3 percent of G P in 2009 and 5.3 percent D G Of which: Domestic effect effect Spillover Domestic effect effect Spillover 2011 2012 impact Total growth growth Total P in 2012). Financial sector support is not expected to have a significant impact on demand. For impact For sector support on demand. a significant P in 2012). Financial is not expected have to D 0.30.9 –0.2 –0.4 –0.1 –0.3 –0.1 –0.1 1.4 0.8 –0.7 –0.8 –0.6 –0.6 –0.1 –0.2 balance ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution (Percentage points) (Percentage a Change in the fiscal P in 2010 and 2011, and 0.1 percent of G P in 2010 and 2011, 0.1 percent D F staff estimates. M 0.2 percent of G 0.2 percent impact on growth. - current year- current year- carry prev. over year- current year- carry prev. over year- current year- carry prev. over 0.7 –0.3 year- current year- carry prev. over 0.7 0.0 –0.2 –0.5 0.0 –0.1 –0.1 –0.2 –0.4 –0.4 0.1 –0.4 –0.2 –0.3 –0.2 –1.1 0.1 –0.3 –0.2 –1.0 –0.3 –0.4 0.0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2 –0.6 –0.3 –0.1 –0.1 –0.5 –0.4 –0.1 –0.2 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2 –1.0 0.1 –0.4 –0.2 –0.9 –0.3 –0.3 –0.1 –0.1 Fiscal Contribution to Growth to Contribution Fiscal Simple average Germanyof which: Netherlandsof which: Belgiumof which: 0.5Portugal 1.4 0.4of which: –0.5 average PPP weighted 0.5 0.7 –0.5 –0.1 –0.6 2.6 –0.1 –0.5 0.6 –1.5 0.7 –0.1 –1.4 –0.6 –0.9 –0.1 –0.5 –0.4 –0.6 –0.2 –0.6 1.2 –0.3 –0.2 –1.3 –0.5 –1.2 –0.2 ote: PPP: purchasing power parity. power purchasing PPP: ote: Financial sector support recorded above-the-line was excluded for the calculation of growth impact for Ireland (2.5 percent of impactIreland (2.5 percent sector above-the-line for support the calculation of growth Financial for recorded was excluded TABLE 6.5 TABLE Source: I Source: N a 172 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

Headline Fiscal Measure (Percent of GDP) We now turn to a headline measure of fiscal changes that incorporates not only the impact of discretionary fiscal policy but also that of automatic stabilizers. While this measure is likely to overstate the impact on fiscal changes due to the feedback effect to automatic stabilizers from changes in the GDP, it could be viewed as an upper bound, which together with the impact estimated based on the cyclically adjusted balance provides an estimate of the possible range of fiscal changes on growth. The change in the overall balance in percent of GDP is higher than that mea- sured by the cyclically adjusted balance (0.6 percent of GDP in 2011 and 1.6 percent of GDP in 2012), largely due to the contribution from automatic stabiliz- ers as the output gaps are closing. Automatic stabilizers also explain the differences for 2010. This is particularly the case for Germany, where the esti- mated impact on growth in 2010 using the headline measure almost doubled (Figure 6.6 and Table 6.6). These fiscal changes can be expected to reduce GDP growth in 2011 and 2012 cumulatively by about 1¼ percentage points. Again, the domestic effect of con- solidation dominates, contributing 80 percent to the growth contraction, with spillovers from one country to another contributing the remaining 20 percent. A large variation across countries remains. The domestic effect from fiscal changes will be substantial in Greece, Spain, Portugal, and the United Kingdom, exceed- ing 2 percentage points over the two years. The domestic impact of fiscal chang- es on growth in Sweden, Switzerland, and Brazil can be expected to be rather small, less than ½ percentage point. The German domestic drag on growth over

2.5 Domestic 2.0 Spillover Total 1.5

1.0

0.5

0.0

–0.5

–1.0

–1.5 2010 2011 2012

Figure 6.6 Germany: Growth Contribution of Domestic Fiscal Changes and Spillover from Fiscal Changes in Other Countries, 2010–2012 (Percentage points) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 173 P in 2010 and D P in 2009, 0.2 percent of G P in 2009, 0.2 percent D ussia only non-oil revenues are assumed to have an impact on growth. have assumed to are only non-oilussia revenues R P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent of G 2010) and the US (2.4 percent P in D (Fiscal change in percent of GDP) Fiscal measure = health revenue/expenditure Fiscal measure = health revenue/expenditure P in 2009 and 5.3 percent of G P in 2009 and 5.3 percent D 2010 2011 2012 F staff estimates. M ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution ggregates A Revenue Expenditure balance Overall Revenue Expenditure balance Overall Revenue Expenditure balance Overall pril 2011; and I A , P in 2012). Financial sector support is not expected to have a significant impact on demand. For sector support impact For a significant on demand. P in 2012). Financial is not expected have to D a Country World Economic Outlook Economic World epublic of –0.6 –2.4 1.9 –0.1 –0.6 0.5 0.2 –0.1 0.3 F, R M 2011, and 0.1 percent of G 2011, and 0.1 percent etherlands –0.9 –0.4 –0.6 0.8 –0.9 1.7 0.5 –0.3 0.8 ustria –0.9 0.1 –1.0 0.3 –0.7 1.0 0.1 –0.3 0.4 ussian Federation –0.7 –1.5 0.8 0.6 –0.1 0.7 –0.2 –1.0 0.8 Changes in Headline Fiscal Changes in Headline Fiscal A BelgiumBrazilChinaFranceGermanyGreeceIndiaIrelandItaly 0.2Japan Korea, 2.4 0.0 –1.9 0.5Portugal –1.0R 2.0Spain 1.8Sweden –0.2 0.0 –1.4 0.6Switzerland 0.7 1.3 KingdomUnited –0.5 –3.8 StatesUnited 0.5 0.5 –0.6 –0.5 0.0 averagePPP weighted –0.2 0.3 2.4Simple average –0.7 0.6 5.8 –0.2 –0.4 –1.1 –0.7 0.4 1.7 0.0 –1.8 –0.2 0.3 –0.1 0.5 0.5 0.9 –0.2 0.2 –0.3 0.7 0.1 –0.1 2.6 –0.2 –0.2 –1.2 0.7 –1.0 0.3 –0.5 0.0 1.9 –0.8 0.7 0.8 –0.4 –0.2 –0.4 –1.0 0.4 –0.6 –1.4 0.6 0.2 1.9 –0.3 0.9 –0.2 1.0 1.7 –0.6 –0.1 –1.2 –0.2 0.5 0.7 2.3 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.5 0.0 0.6 0.5 –0.2 –1.8 1.4 0.2 0.7 0.8 0.3 0.0 –1.6 –0.1 0.4 0.3 –0.4 –0.2 –2.2 0.0 0.0 –1.0 1.1 1.7 0.4 –0.8 0.1 –0.1 0.7 –0.2 2.3 –0.7 0.5 0.6 0.7 –0.9 –0.1 2.7 0.8 0.8 –0.2 0.2 1.1 –0.9 0.6 0.6 –1.0 1.0 0.4 0.9 –0.3 0.1 0.8 0.8 0.1 0.9 1.7 1.6 0.0 0.8 –1.7 0.4 –0.7 –0.8 1.1 –0.8 –0.4 –1.9 0.6 –0.6 2.1 0.8 1.6 1.6 0.5 3.6 1.0 N ote: PPP: purchasing power parity. power purchasing PPP: ote: Financial sectorof G above-the-line support Ireland (2.5 percent Financial for recorded was excluded TABLE 6.6 TABLE N Source: I Source: a 174 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

these two years will be noticeable—expected to reach 1 percentage point, with another ¼ percentage point subtracted from growth due to the spillovers from abroad.19 Most of this effect will be felt in 2012, since in 2011 the lagged effect of the fiscal stimulus from 2010 was still lingering. The impact on 2011 growth was muted due to the strong positive carry-over effects from the last period’s expansion. This observation is true for the countries on average—consolidation will have a stronger “bite” in 2012—though for some countries (e.g. the United States) it also reflects a larger fiscal adjustment in 2012 (Table 6.7). For most countries, spillovers to growth from fiscal policy in other countries remain limited when using headline balance as a fiscal measure (below ½ percent- age points over the next two years, Table 6A.4), though the average has slightly increased. As with the cyclically adjusted measure, Ireland, Belgium, Austria, and the Netherlands stand out (Figure 6.7). As in the case of the cyclically adjusted measure, German influence is primarily with respect to its direct neighbors: Austria, Belgium, the Netherlands and Switzerland. The United States is gener- ally exerting a greater influence on other countries, and the United States and China provide the largest contribution to the average (Figure 6.7). To summarize, using the change in the headline ratio rather than the change in the cyclical adjusted ratio does not substantially alter the main conclusions. While the growth impact is larger in this case, the cross-border spillovers remain limited in 2011 and 2012 with the exception of small and open European economies. Real Fiscal Changes The last measure of fiscal stance that we are employing is the change in real rev- enues and expenditures. As discussed above, this is the measure that is most consistent with the theoretical concept of the fiscal multiplier, but it is not com- monly employed by the policymakers and, more importantly, the estimates of fiscal multipliers obtained in the literature are often not based on this definition. Consequently, although we present estimates based on the real fiscal changes comparison, the results should be interpreted with caution. First, note that as explained previously, as long as real GDP growth between the two periods is non-zero the two measures of fiscal stance will differ, and since revenue/expenditure-to-GDP ratios are rather large numbers (e.g., expenditure is close to 40 percent on average in the sample of 20 countries), with even a moder- ate real GDP growth of 2.5 percent (simple average in the sample for 2011) the difference can be as large as 1 percent of GDP for revenue/expenditure measures. For the overall balance, however, the differences are likely to be small, since the overall balance is a relatively smaller number.

19 Given the recent divergence in the developments in the labor market in Germany and the output gap, possibly, reflecting structural changes in the labor market, the commonly used cyclically adjusted measure with elasticities estimated from historical data and the output gap is likely to understate the true degree of discretionary policy intervention. While for comparability we used a common cyclical adjustment method for all countries, we believe that for Germany the headline measure better cap- tures changes in the underlying fiscal position.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 175 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 0.0 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 –0.2 –0.4 –0.6 –0.3 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2 –0.4 –0.5 –0.2 –0.1 –0.2 Of which: 0.1 2012 –0.6 –1.0 –0.7 –1.3 –1.3 –0.8 –0.4 –0.5 –0.9 –0.7 –0.9 –0.2 –0.3 –0.9 –1.1 –0.4 –0.6 –0.3 –0.7 –0.7 –0.7 Domestic effect effect Spillover –0.8 –1.1 –0.8 –1.4 –1.4 –1.0 –0.7 –0.6 –1.1 –1.1 –1.6 0.0 –0.5 –0.3 –1.0 –1.3 –0.6 –0.8 –1.0 –0.9 –0.8 –0.9 impact Total growth growth Total –0.1 0.0 –0.1 0.0 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 0.0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2 0.0 –0.1 0.0 0.0 –0.1 –0.1 –0.3 –0.2 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent of G D P in 2009, of G D P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent D P in 2009 and 5.3 percent Of which: G 0.1 0.3 0.2 2011 –0.4 –0.8 –1.9 –1.2 –0.4 –0.8 –0.4 –0.4 –0.3 –0.8 –0.4 –1.8 –0.5 –0.4 –0.7 –0.2 –0.2 –0.3 –0.5 Domestic effect effect Spillover (In percentage points) Fiscal Contribution to Growth Fiscal Growth Contribution to –0.5 0.1 0.2 –0.9 –2.0 0.1 –1.4 –0.4 –0.9 –0.6 –0.6 –0.3 –1.0 –0.4 –1.8 –0.7 –0.5 –0.9 –0.4 –0.3 –0.4 –0.7 impact Total growth growth Total Fiscal measure = headline revenue/expenditure (Fiscal change in percent of GDP) (Fiscal change in percent of GDP) Fiscal measure = headline revenue/expenditure 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.5 0.6 0.1 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.3 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.2 0.3 ggregates on Growth ggregates A Of which: 2010 1.0 0.8 1.6 1.3 1.9 0.8 1.9 2.2 0.8 2.2 1.9 0.9 0.3 1.7 0.7 1.3 1.4 1.4 1.0 1.1 –0.8 –1.1 Domestic effect effect Spillover ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 1.3 0.8 1.8 1.4 2.1 1.2 2.2 2.2 1.0 2.7 2.5 1.0 0.4 2.0 2.0 1.9 1.7 1.4 –0.4 –1.1 A pril 2011; and I M F staff estimates. impact , Total growth growth Total a World Economic Outlook Economic World Country R epublic of ussia only non-oil revenues are assumed to have have assumed to are R ussia only non-oil revenues impact For sector support on demand. a significant of G D P in 2012). Financial is not expected have to of G D P in 2010 and 2011, 0.1 percent 0.2 percent an impact on growth. ustria The Impact of Changes in Headline Fiscal ImpactThe of Changes in Headline Fiscal PPP weighted averagePPP weighted 1.2 Switzerland States United Sweden Simple average United KingdomUnited Spain R ussian Federation Portugal N etherlands Korea, Korea, Japan Italy Ireland India Greece Germany France China, People’s R epublic ofChina, People’s 1.0 Belgium Brazil A Financial sector support recorded above-the-line was excluded for the calculation of growth impact for Ireland (2.5 percent of impactIreland (2.5 percent sector above-the-line for support the calculation of growth Financial for recorded was excluded TABLE 6.7 TABLE Sources: I M F,Sources: a ote: PPP: purchasing power parity. power purchasing PPP: N ote: 176 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.4 –0.5 –0.6 –0.7 –0.8 Simple average PPP–weighted average –0.9 –1

n es Italy at eden dom India t China Spai Brazil w Japan Ireland Austria France Greece Belgium Portugal S Germany

Netherlands Switzerland United S United King Korea, Republic of Russian Federation

Figure 6.7 Inward Fiscal Spillovers (Impact on real GDP from headlined fiscal changes in other countries, cumulative 2011–2012, percent) Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity.

With that in mind, the results presented below are not surprising. (Table 6.8) The changes in the overall balance using the real measure based on the CPI20 are rather close to those obtained by using the ratios to GDP. The composition of changes, however, is quite different. In particular, while the measure in ratios sug- gests that consolidation in 2011 and 2012, on average, includes both revenue and expenditure contributions, the measures based on real changes suggests that in real terms expenditures are in fact projected to increase, so consolidation is mainly revenue-based. Since the multiplier on revenue is lower than that on expenditure, this leads to a substantially smaller estimated negative impact on growth, with the contribu- tion to growth remaining positive, on average, in 2011, partly due to the lagged effect from 2010. However, for some countries (e.g., Greece) where growth is projected to remain in the negative territory in 2011, fiscal impulse measured by the real change implies a larger consolidation on the expenditure side, so the growth impact is more negative compared to the measure in ratio to GDP (Table 6.9). (See Table 6A.5 for detailed country-by-country estimates). The spillovers are also correspondingly much smaller on average than in the case of the fiscal measure in ratios. While the list of top countries affected by the spillovers (Ireland, Belgium, Netherlands, and Austria) is unchanged, the magni- tude of spillovers in 2011–12 has declined substantially, and for Korea spillovers have turned positive. However, the milder negative impact on growth should be interpreted with caution, since the empirical estimates of multipliers obtained

20 We use CPI rather than the GDP deflator because the majority of fiscal changes work through either private consumption decisions or government consumption. The results are not substantially different if we employ the GDP deflator.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 177 P in 2010 and D P in 2009, 0.2 percent of G P in 2009, 0.2 percent D ussia only non-oil revenues are assumed to have an impact on growth. have assumed to are only non-oilussia revenues R P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent of G 2010) and the US (2.4 percent P in D (fiscal change in real terms) Fiscal measure = headline revenue/expenditure Fiscal measure = headline revenue/expenditure P in 2009 and 5.3 percent of G P in 2009 and 5.3 percent D 2010 2011 2012 F staff estimates. M ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Revenue Expenditure balance Overall Revenue Expenditure balance Overall Revenue Expenditure balance Overall pril 2011; and I ggregates A , A P in 2012). Financial sector support is not expected to have a significant impact on demand. For sector support impact For a significant on demand. P in 2012). Financial is not expected have to D eal Fiscal eal Fiscal a R World Economic Outlook Economic World Country F, epublic of 0.9 –1.1 2.0 0.9 0.3 0.6 1.3 0.9 0.5 R M 2011, and 0.1 percent of G 2011, and 0.1 percent etherlands 0.1 0.8 –0.7 1.2 –0.4 1.7 1.0 0.2 0.8 ustria 0.1 1.1 –1.1 1.1 0.1 1.0 0.9 0.6 0.3 ussian Federation 1.6 1.9 –0.4 2.6 2.9 –0.3 1.1 0.9 0.2 Changes in A BelgiumBrazilChinaFranceGermanyGreeceIndiaIrelandItaly 1.1Japan Korea, 6.0 2.3 –0.1Portugal 0.8 –0.1R –0.3Spain 5.7Sweden 0.7 2.7 0.5Switzerland 0.5 1.0 1.2 KingdomUnited –6.6 –0.1 StatesUnited 1.3 0.3 –0.4 0.8 averagePPP weighted –0.6 –0.2 0.1 3.0Simple average –0.3 1.1 6.4 0.9 0.0 –0.3 1.3 1.2 –0.3 1.8 –0.1 0.4 2.6 1.2 0.5 0.7 1.5 0.2 0.3 1.0 0.5 1.1 0.3 –0.7 0.7 1.3 0.4 3.3 1.8 1.8 –0.2 1.8 –0.1 0.9 1.3 0.8 –0.1 –1.6 0.7 –0.3 –1.0 –0.1 2.0 –0.7 –1.5 0.8 1.9 0.8 –0.4 0.8 1.6 –1.2 0.1 –0.8 2.6 0.4 0.8 1.2 0.5 1.1 1.3 0.3 2.5 1.4 –0.1 –3.1 1.2 1.0 2.8 0.5 0.7 1.2 1.0 0.4 –0.9 1.1 0.3 –2.4 0.6 1.0 1.8 1.6 1.9 2.6 –0.2 1.4 2.3 0.1 1.5 –0.2 0.3 –0.5 2.1 0.1 2.7 0.4 0.5 –0.2 0.7 1.2 –0.5 2.4 0.8 0.5 0.4 1.1 –0.4 0.0 0.9 0.9 1.5 1.9 0.2 0.7 0.7 2.6 0.2 –0.2 2.5 0.7 1.5 –0.4 1.3 –0.1 0.6 1.0 0.2 1.0 0.6 –0.9 2.0 0.4 0.8 1.4 0.4 1.6 3.4 0.8 N ote: PPP: purchasing power parity. power purchasing PPP: ote: Financial sectorof G above-the-line support Ireland (2.5 percent Financial for recorded was excluded TABLE 6.8 TABLE N Sources: I Sources: a 178 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter? P in 2009, D –0.1 Of which: ussia only non-oil revenues are assumed to have have assumed to are ussia only non-oil revenues P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent of G P in 2010) and the US (2.4 percent R D impact Total growth growth Total P in 2009 and 5.3 percent of G P in 2009 and 5.3 percent D G Of which: (In percentage points) Fiscal Contribution to Growth Fiscal Growth Contribution to impact Total growth growth Total Fiscal measure = headline revenue/expenditure (fiscal change in real terms) Fiscal measure = headline revenue/expenditure P in 2012). Financial sector support is not expected to have a significant impact on demand. For impact For sector support on demand. a significant P in 2012). Financial is not expected have to D Of which: ggregates on Growth ggregates A F staff estimates. 2010 2011 2012 M Domestic effect effect Spillover Domestic effect effect Spillover Domestic effect effect Spillover ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution eal Fiscal eal Fiscal R pril 2011; and I A , impact Total growth growth Total P in 2010 and 2011, and 0.1 percent of G P in 2010 and 2011, 0.1 percent D a World Economic Outlook Economic World F, epublic of 0.2 –0.4 0.6 –0.3 –0.5 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.0 Country R M 0.2 percent of G 0.2 percent an impact on growth. etherlands 2.4 1.9 0.5 0.0 0.1 –0.1 –0.6 –0.4 –0.2 ustria 2.5 2.0 0.5 0.3 0.3 0.0 –0.4 –0.2 –0.2 ussian Federation 2.0 1.7 0.3 1.2 1.2 0.0 0.4 0.5 –0.1 The ImpactThe of Changes in A BelgiumBrazilChina 2.1 2.4 2.2 1.5 2.3 1.8 0.7 0.1 0.3 –0.5 0.6 –0.4 0.7 0.6 0.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 –0.3 0.7 0.0 0.5 0.7 0.6 –0.3 0.0 FranceGermanyGreeceIndiaIrelandItalyJapan Korea, 1.9 1.8Portugal –2.3R Spain 0.9 1.6 1.5 1.4Sweden –2.3Switzerland 0.8 2.3 KingdomUnited 0.7 StatesUnited 0.7 0.3 0.3 2.3 0.1 0.5 averagePPP weighted 2.2Simple average 1.2 1.6 1.3 1.6 2.1 0.1 2.0 0.7 1.0 –0.1 –0.1 0.2 –2.8 0.1 1.1 1.5 1.4 1.0 1.4 1.9 0.9 –0.1 0.2 0.0 –0.3 0.7 –2.8 1.2 –0.6 0.2 –0.2 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.2 –0.3 0.7 0.0 –1.5 0.0 –0.5 0.0 –0.2 0.3 0.0 –0.6 –2.1 0.3 –1.4 0.4 0.9 0.0 0.0 0.5 –0.7 –0.5 –0.6 –0.2 0.0 –2.1 –1.0 0.0 0.3 0.4 0.9 –0.1 0.5 –0.6 –0.3 –0.9 –0.2 –1.0 0.8 –0.7 0.0 –0.4 0.0 0.0 –0.5 0.0 0.0 –1.2 0.9 –0.1 –0.1 0.0 –0.6 –0.4 0.0 0.0 –1.0 –1.1 –1.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.4 –0.2 –0.7 0.0 –1.0 –0.1 –0.4 –1.1 –0.1 0.0 –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 –0.7 –0.3 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 0.0 –0.1 N ote: PPP: purchasing power parity. power purchasing PPP: ote: Financial sector support recorded above-the-line was excluded for the calculation of growth impact for Ireland (2.5 percent of impactIreland (2.5 percent sector above-the-line for support the calculation of growth Financial for recorded was excluded TABLE 6.9 TABLE N Sources: I Sources: a Ivanova and Weber 179

0.2

0.1

0

–0.1

–0.2

–0.3

–0.4 Simple average PPP-weighted average –0.5

Italy India Spain China Brazil Japan Ireland Austria France Greece Belgium Portugal Sweden Germany

Netherlands Switzerland United States United Kingdom Korea, Republic of Russian Federation Figure 6.8 Inward Fiscal Spillovers (Impact on real GDP from headline real fiscal changes in other countries, cumulative 2011–2012, percent) Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity. from the literature may not correspond to this fiscal measure and the effects may be underestimated (Figure 6.8). To summarize, using real changes rather than the change in the ratio of the fiscal position implies that the growth contribution of consolidation is generally less negative, due to the fact that consolidation is no longer dominated by expen- diture reductions but rather by revenue increases. While the net change in the fiscal balance is mostly unaffected, the combination of higher revenue adjustment and lower multipliers for revenue causes the contribution of fiscal changes to GDP growth to fall. Consequently, using the real fiscal change as the relevant fiscal measure leads to an even less important role of cross-country spillovers. Higher Multipliers and Higher Import Elasticities To evaluate the robustness of our results, we calculate growth impact under higher multipliers and higher import elasticities. Higher revenue and expenditure multipliers with unchanged import elasticity were calculated by assuming that higher multipliers are a result of the higher marginal propensity to consume. This is consistent with the proposition that higher multipliers after a financial crisis may reflect a higher share of liquidity-constrained households and firms. However, it implies a steeper rise in revenue multipliers, which are more sensitive to the changes in the marginal propensity to consume. Correspondingly, we raised revenue multipliers by 1.5 times the standard deviation of revenue multi- pliers across the sample of 20 countries, while expenditure multipliers were raised by one standard deviation of expenditure multipliers across the sample. This resulted in an average revenue multiplier of about 0.7 (almost 50 percent higher than in the baseline) and expenditure multipliers of about 1 (about 25 percent higher than in the baseline).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 180 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

Raising import elasticities is a more complex experiment, since higher import elasticities would reduce marginal propensities to import and, therefore, would reduce the size of fiscal multipliers. To evaluate the maximum impact on spillovers, we have assumed that expenditure multipliers remain unchanged compared to the baseline, which implies that the marginal propensity to consume has increased enough to compensate for the reduction in expenditure multipliers due to higher import elasticities. However, given the more elastic response of revenue multipliers to changes in the marginal propensity to consume, they would have to increase compared to the baseline. Therefore, we raised revenue multipliers by 0.5 times the standard deviation of revenue multipliers in the sample, which resulted in an aver- age revenue multiplier of about 0.5 (about 15 percent higher than in the baseline). The results of these robustness checks for all three measures of fiscal position are summarized in Figures 6.9a and 6.9b. They suggest that our main conclusions on spillovers hold under the alternative assumptions. In particular, although fiscal consolidation across the world may have a substantial impact on domestic growth, fiscal spillovers from one country to another will play a limited role in absolute terms—the aggregate spillovers not exceeding 0.3 percentage points over the two years (2011 and 2012) on a PPP-average basis and 0.5 percentage points on a simple-average basis. Fiscal spillovers will also play a limited role in relation to impact on domestic growth. However, small open economies, such as Ireland, Belgium, Austria, and the Netherlands, can be substantially affected. The effect of domestic fiscal policy on growth, however, varies substantially, depending on the choice of fiscal measure, the size of fiscal multipliers, and imports elasticities, but in most cases a substantial reduction in growth would be in the cards. It is also worth mentioning that while we simulated the impact under rela- tively large import elasticities, the assumption here was that the process of nor- malizing world trade after the collapse during the 2008–09 financial crisis will continue in 2011–12. Hence, the import elasticities assumed are not as high as those observed during the collapse of world trade in the course of the recent financial crisis. Extreme import elasticities could lead to larger fiscal spillovers if combined with an increase in the marginal propensity to consume. Therefore, if the downward spiral in world trade were to reoccur, the rationale for a coordi- nated fiscal relaxation would be strengthened.

Alternative Scenarios The Growth Impact of More Consolidation Continued market pressure and rising concerns about debt levels could lead gov- ernments to consolidate beyond the currently announced level in the forthcom- ing two years. We thus simulate the results for a scenario in which some countries in the euro zone (Eur I) reduce spending by an additional 0.5 percent of GDP in 2011 and 2012 or, alternatively, manage to increase structural revenues by an additional 0.5 percent of GDP in the two years. Under the baseline multiplier scenario, spillovers are hardly affected, in par- ticular if tax revenues increase in selected European countries. But even in the case

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 181

0.4 Domestic Spillover 0.2 0 –0.2 –0.4 –0.6 –0.8 –1 –1.2 –1.4 –1.6 –1.8 Baseline Higher Higher Baseline Higher Higher Baseline Higher Higher parameters multipliers imports parameters multipliers imports parameters multipliers imports elasticities elasticities elasticities Cyclically Headline Headline adjusted measure measure measure (ratios) (real)

Figure 6.9a Cumulative Domestic Growth Impact and Fiscal Spillovers in 2011–2012 Under a Range of Fiscal Multipliers and Imports Elasticities and Using Various Measures of Fiscal Changes (PPP-weighted average) Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity.

0.7 Domestic Spillover

0.2

–0.3

–0.8

–1.3

–1.8

–2.3 Baseline Higher Higher Baseline Higher Higher Baseline Higher Higher parameters multipliers imports parameters multipliers imports parameters multipliers imports elasticities elasticities elasticities Cyclically- Headline Headline adjusted measure measure measure (ratios) (real) Figure 6.9b Cumulative Domestic Growth Impact and Fiscal Spillovers in 2011–2012 Under a Range of Fiscal Multipliers and Imports Elasticities and Using Various Measures of Fiscal Changes (Simple average) Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 182 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

of additional expenditure cuts, spillovers are limited, not exceeding an additional growth reduction of 0.1 percentage points. Assuming higher multiplier values causes the effect to be slightly magnified, in particular for the small open economies. However, even in this case, growth spill- overs do not increase by more than an additional 0.2 percentage points in any of the exercises. Thus, greater consolidation in countries with no fiscal space (Eur II) appears to lead to only limited growth spillovers beyond their border, although such consolidation is likely to put an additional drag on growth in those countries themselves (Table 6.10). The Growth Impact of Coordinated Fiscal Relaxation If spillovers were sufficiently large, a coordinated fiscal effort could alleviate the negative impact of strong fiscal consolidation on GDP growth through positive spillovers. To simulate the effect of such a policy, we compare the baseline speci- fication to a specification in which (i) Germany reduces its expenditures by 0.5 percent of GDP less in 2011 and 2012; or (ii) an extended set of European coun- tries (Austria, Germany, Netherlands, and Switzerland) reduce their expenditures by 0.5 percent of GDP more in 2011 and 2012. In the baseline multiplier case under the scenario that Germany slows the reduction in spending by 0.5 percent of GDP, GDP growth in other countries is hardly affected in 2012 through lowered negative spillover. In the high multiplier scenario, the spillovers are also little affected; they are limited to an additional 0.1 percentage point higher growth rate in selected economies. Left alone to Germany, it would require an increase in fiscal spending of about 2.5 percent of GDP in 2011 and 2012 to move the growth rate in Ireland by 0.5 percentage points. Such a scenario, however, does not take into account a possible negative credibility effect of the German fiscal leadership in Europe as well as a narrower space left for the ECB’s interest policy maneuver. In a scenario in which Austria, the Netherlands, and Switzerland increase their fiscal spending by 0.5 percent of GDP, effects change little under the baseline assumption for the multipliers. Also, once the higher set of multipliers is applied, effects are contained to an increase by 0.1 percentage point, with the exception of the Netherlands, which grows by an additional 0.2 percentage point more due to the lower consolidation in Austria, Germany, and Switzerland. Only under sig- nificantly higher multipliers or import elasticities will the effect from less con- solidation translate into visible growth effects in other countries.

The Impact on Trade Balances We can also use the framework to evaluate the extent to which trade imbalances (measured by the change in the real trade balance relative to the GDP in the previous period) can be addressed by a coordination of demand management. More precisely, we can determine by how much Germany’s trade balance would deteriorate in comparison with the baseline if Germany were to consolidate by 0.5 percent less, and to what extent this would alter the trade balance of other

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 183 a Less consolidation –0.4 –0.4 –0.1–0.1–0.9 –0.1 –0.1 –0.9 –0.2–0.2–0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.7 –0.7 –0.3 –0.3 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.3 –0.3 –0.1–0.3–0.3 –0.1 –0.3 –0.3 –0.1–0.4–0.5 –0.1 –0.4 –0.4 –0.2 0.0–0.2 –0.2 0.0 –0.2 –0.3 –0.3 German stimulus Eur II cntry a High multiplier –0.6 –0.1 –0.1 –1.0 –0.2 –0.3 –0.2 –0.9 –0.4 –0.3 –0.3 –0.4 –0.1 –0.3 –0.3 –0.1 –0.4 –0.6 –0.2 0.0 –0.2 –0.3 Eur I cntry (T) a More consolidation –0.6 –0.1 –0.1 –1.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.2 –1.0 –0.4 –0.3 –0.3 –0.4 –0.1 –0.3 –0.4 –0.1 –0.4 –0.7 –0.2 0.0 –0.2 –0.4 Eur I cntry (G) –0.5 –0.1 –1.0 –0.2 –0.2 –0.8 –0.1 –0.3 –0.2 –0.3 –0.1 –0.3 –0.1 –0.3 –0.2 –0.2 –0.3 –0.3 –0.4 –0.6 0.0 –0.3 Baseline a etherlands, and Switzerland. N etherlands, ustria, Germany, A Less consolidation –0.3 –0.2 –0.1–0.5 –0.1 –0.5 –0.1–0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.4 –0.4 0.0–0.1 0.0 –0.1 –0.1–0.2 –0.1 –0.2 –0.1–0.2 –0.1 –0.2 –0.1–0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1–0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.2–0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2–0.2 –0.2 –0.2 0.0–0.2 0.0 –0.2 German stimulus Eur II cntry a a –0.4 –0.1 –0.6 –0.2 –0.1 –0.5 –0.2 –0.2 0.0 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.3 0.0 –0.2 Eur I cntry (T) Baseline multiplier a Fiscal measure = cyclical adjusted revenue/expenditure, change in percent of previous year GDP year change in percent of previous Fiscal measure = cyclical revenue/expenditure, adjusted More consolidation –0.4 –0.1 –0.6 –0.2 –0.1 –0.6 –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2 –0.3 –0.4 0.0 –0.2 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Eur I cntry (G) –0.3 –0.5 –0.1 –0.6 –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 –0.2 –0.1 0.0 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.3 –0.2 0.0 –0.2 Baseline R epublic of 2011 and 2012. “Eur I” includes Belgium, France, Italy, Ireland, Greece, and Portugal. “Eur II” includes II” “Eur and Portugal. Greece, Ireland, Italy, France, includes Belgium, I” “Eur 2011 and 2012. ustria ussian Federation Total Growth Spillovers from Fiscal Consolidation, 2012 Consolidation, Fiscal from Spillovers Growth Total A Belgium India Ireland Italy Spain Sweden Switzerland Brazil Greece Japan R KingdomUnited R . of China, P. France Germany Korea, N etherlands Portugal States United average PPP weighted Simple average P in 2011 and 2012, while more consolidation is either a reduction in expenditures (G) or an increase in revenues (T) in revenues or an increase (G) reduction in expenditures is either a consolidation of G D P in 2011 and 2012, while more of G D P in 0.5 percent 0.5 percent by by in expenditures is an increase consolidation Less TABLE 6.10. TABLE Source: I M F staff estimates. Source: parity. power purchasing PPP: N ote: a 184 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

countries. We provide an additional simulation in which surplus countries (defined as countries that had a current account surplus in the years 2008–10) increase their spending by 0.5 percent of GDP in comparison with the baseline (Tables 6.11 and 6.12). If consolidation proceeds as predicted according to the WEO estimates, the cumulative effect on the trade balance in 2012 will broadly contribute to a rebal- ancing. Several surplus countries, including Germany Belgium, Sweden, Switzerland, Russia, Korea, China, and Japan, are likely to experience a deteriora- tion of the trade balance due to the fiscal changes, while deficit countries includ- ing, Greece, Portugal, Spain, the United Kingdom, and the United States are likely to experience an improvement in the trade balance. However, Ireland is likely to experience no strong change in the trade balance. Overall, the magni- tudes are moderate, and the trade balances of relatively closed economies, such as Greece, Portugal and Spain, are primarily driven by domestic consolidation rather than by spillovers, while the contrary is true for open economies such as Belgium. It turns out that the cumulative change in the trade balance in the peripheral countries, implied by the scenario under which only Germany consolidates less, is with the exception of Ireland no different from zero. Even when we simulate a wider policy coordination effort encompassing other surplus countries, the

TABLE 6.11 Change in the Real Trade Balance in 20 Selected Countries, 2010–2012 Fiscal measure = cyclical adjusted revenue/expenditure, change in percent of previous year GDP Of which: Change trade balance Own effect Spillovers Austria 0.0 0.3 –0.3 Belgium –0.6 0.6 –1.1 Brazil –0.1 0.0 –0.1 China –0.1 0.2 –0.3 France 0.2 0.5 –0.3 Germany –0.6 0.0 –0.6 Greece 1.1 1.2 –0.1 Ireland 0.0 1.0 –1.1 Italy 0.2 0.5 –0.3 India 0.1 0.2 –0.1 Japan –0.2 0.0 –0.2 Korea, Republic of 0.1 0.5 –0.4 Netherlands 0.0 0.8 –0.8 Portugal 0.6 1.1 –0.5 Russian Federation 0.0 0.2 –0.2 Spain 0.7 1.0 –0.3 Sweden –0.9 –0.5 –0.4 Switzerland –0.5 0.1 –0.5 United Kingdom 0.5 0.7 –0.2 United States 0.1 0.1 –0.1

Source: IMF staff calculations.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 185 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.1 –0.4 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.1 –0.1 Difference to baseline to Difference 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 –0.4 High multiplier ustria, China, Korea, Japan, Germany, Japan, Germany, ustria, China, Korea, a German stimulus Selected surplus country countries is given by A by is given countries 0.3 1.6 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.9 0.6 0.0 0.8 0.1 0.0 0.1 –0.5 –0.2 –0.1 –0.7 –0.2 –1.1 –0.6 Baseline 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.3 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 –0.1 –0.1 –0.3 –0.2 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 Difference to baseline to Difference 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 –0.3 Baseline multiplier German stimulus Selected surplus country Fiscal measure = cyclical adjusted revenue/expenditure, change in percent of GDP Fiscal measure = cyclical revenue/expenditure, adjusted ue to Fiscal Consolidation in 20 Selected (2010–2012) Consolidation Countries Fiscal D ue to ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 0.2 1.1 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.7 0.5 0.0 0.6 0.1 0.0 –0.1 –0.1 –0.6 –0.2 –0.6 –0.9 –0.5 Baseline ussia, Sweden, and Switzerland. R ussia, Sweden, R epublic of etherlands, N etherlands, ustria ussian Federation eal Trade Balance Change in the R eal Trade Brazil R epublic of China, People’s France Germany Greece India Ireland Italy Japan Korea, A Belgium N etherlands R Spain Sweden Switzerland KingdomUnited Portugal United States United average PPP weighted Simple average The assumption for the scenarios is an increase in government spending by 0.5 percent in 2011 and 2012. The sample of surplus The in 2011 and 2012. 0.5 percent spending by in government is an increase the scenarios assumption for The TABLE 6.12 TABLE Source: I M F staff estimates. Source: parity. power purchasing PPP: N ote: a 186 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

impact on the peripheral countries remains contained to an improvement of 0.1–0.2 percentage points. Only Belgium is likely to experience an improvement in the trade balance by close to ½ percentage point. The reason for the low impact is that most of the correction in the trade bal- ance is brought about by domestic policies, since none of the peripheral countries is highly interlinked in trade terms with the core countries that have surpluses. Additionally, the absence of an impetus from the United States or the United Kingdom in this scenario explains the low impact on Ireland.

CONCLUSION In a world of unsynchronized fiscal spending patterns across countries and nor- mal interest rate levels, spillovers from fiscal policies across countries are likely to be limited. However, since 2009 the fiscal patterns across most developed coun- tries have been largely synchronized. While the magnitude varies, in most coun- tries the fiscal expansion of 2009 and 2010 is set to be followed by fiscal consoli- dation in 2011, 2012, and beyond. At the same time, the interest rates remain low, while the output gaps have not closed yet in many advanced economies. In such an economic environment, fiscal multipliers are likely to be above the usual levels, and a synchronized and significant swing in fiscal policy from expansion to consolidation is likely to magnify the role of spillovers from fiscal policy across countries. We find that even in this setting, aggregate negative spillovers to other coun- tries are likely to be contained in 2011–12. Despite potentially sizeable domestic effects from consolidation, we find that the cumulative impact on GDP over the two years (2011 and 2012) is not likely to exceed 0.3 percentage points on a PPP- weighted basis and ½ percentage points on simple-average basis under the various assumptions on fiscal multipliers and import elasticities. While the absolute size of spillovers varies depending on the measure of fiscal stance, size of multipliers, and imports elasticities, average spillovers are invariably small compared to the size of the impact of domestic fiscal policy. Nevertheless, the average masks differences across countries. For small and open European economies such as Belgium, Netherlands, and Austria, spillovers are important. In contrast, the coordinated exit from fiscal stimulus will have a limited direct effect on European peripheral countries, since they are relatively closed, with the notable exception of Ireland. While the latter could benefit from external support, such support would require contributions from the major economies, including the United States and the United Kingdom—both coun- tries where fiscal relaxation is not currently in the cards. Changes in the German fiscal plan alone would have a very limited impact on the European periphery. Under the baseline scenario, projected fiscal change for 2011 and 2012 will help reduce external imbalances. However, the effects over these two years are likely to be relatively small. While a stronger fiscal expansion in surplus countries could reduce the respective countries’ surpluses, the “leakages” tend not to go to

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 187 the peripheral countries. Therefore, most of the correction in the peripheral coun- tries’ trade balances will have to be brought about by domestic consolidation in these countries. Consequently, the bad news is that the countries in need cannot rely much on other countries’ fiscal policies to stimulate their growth in the short run. The good news, however, is that ambitious consolidation plans in the European peripheral countries will have only limited repercussions for much of the rest of the world.

REFERENCES Almunia, Miguel, Agustín S. Bénétrix, Barry Eichengreen, Kevin H. O’Rourke, and Gisela Rua, 2009, “From Great Depression to Great Credit Crisis: Similarities, Differences and Lessons,” NBER Working Paper No. 15524 (Nov.) (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Auerbach, Alan J., and Yuriy Gorodnichenko, 2010 “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy,” NBER Working Paper No. 16311 (Aug.) (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Beetsma, Roel, Massimo Giuliodori, and Franc Klaassen, 2006. “Trade Spill-overs of Fiscal Policy in the European Union: A Panel Analysis,” Economic Policy, CEPR, CES, MSH, Vol. 21, No. 48, pp 639–87. Bénassy-Quéré, Agnès and Jacopo Cimadomo, 2006, “Changing Patterns of Domestic and Cross-Border Fiscal Policy Multipliers in Europe and the U.S.” CEPII No. 2006–24 (Dec.). Blanchard, Olivier, Carlo Cottarelli, Antonio Spilimbergo and Steven Symansky, 2009, “Fiscal Policy for the Crisis,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 7130 (London: Centre for Economic and Policy Research). Blanchard, Olivier, and Roberto Perotti, 2002, “An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, No. 4 (Nov.), pp. 1329–68. Canova, Fabio, and Evi Papa, 2007 “Price Differentials in Monetary Unions: The Role of Fiscal Shocks,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 117 (March), pp. 713–37. Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo, 2009. ”When Is the Government Spending Multiplier Large?,” NBER Working Paper No. 15394 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Cogan, John F., Tobias Cwik, John B. Taylor, and Volker Wieland, 2009, “New Keynesian versus Old Keynesian Government Spending Multipliers,” NBER Working Paper No. 14782 (March) (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Corsetti, Giancarlo, André Meier and Gernot J. Müller, 2010a. “Cross-Border Spillovers from Fiscal Stimulus,” International Journal of Central Banking, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 5–37 (March). ———, 2010b, “What Determines Government Spending Multipliers,” Unpublished manu- script. Cwik, Tobias, and Volker Wieland, 2009. ”Keynesian Government Spending Multipliers and Spillovers in the Euro Area,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 7389 (London: Centre for Economic and Policy Research). Girouard, Nathalie, and Christophe André, 2005, “Measuring Cyclically-Adjusted Budget Balances for OECD Countries,” OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 434 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Gros, D., and A. Hobza, 2001, “Fiscal Policy Spillovers in the Euro Area. Where Are They?”, CEPS Working Document No.176 (Brussels: Centre for European Policy Studies). IMF, 2010, “Recovery, Risk and Rebalancing,” World Economic Outlook (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 188 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

———, 2011, “Slowing Growth, Rising Risks,” World Economic Outlook, Chapter 4 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Kee, Hiau Loo, Alessandro Nicita, and Marcelo Olarreaga, 2008. “Import Demand Elasticities and Trade Distortions,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 90, No. 4, pp. 666–82. Leibovici, Fernando, and Michael E. Waugh, 2011 “International Trade and Intertemporal Substitution,” Working paper, New York University. OECD, 2009, “The Effectiveness and Scope of Fiscal Stimulus,” OECD Economic Outlook Interim Report (March) (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Romer, Christina D., and David H. Romer, 2010 “The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: Estimates Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks,” American Economic Review, Vol. 100 (June 2010), pp. 763–801. Schindler, Martin, Antonio Spilimbergo, and Steve Symansky, 2009, “Fiscal Multipliers,” IMF Staff Position Note No. SPN/09/11 (May) (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Tagkalakis, Athanasios, 2008, “The Effects of Fiscal Policy on Consumption in Recessions and Expansions,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 92 (2008), pp.1486–1508.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 189 0.00 0.00 –0.09 –0.10 –0.05 –0.19 –0.07 –0.04 –0.13 –0.05 –0.23 –0.10 –0.16 –0.03 –0.03 –0.16 –0.13 –0.10 –0.13 –0.07 –0.24 Elasticities 1.10 0.98 1.00 1.10 0.94 1.06 1.15 0.99 1.00 0.89 0.90 0.77 1.14 1.16 0.77 0.99 0.88 1.00 0.99 0.90 0.94 Revenue Expenditure 1.14 (1.63) 1.37 (1.86) 1.07 (1.56) 1.14 (1.63) Import elasticity M ultipliers (Higher values in, baseline multipliers brackets) Expenditure multiplier larreaga (2008); and I M F staff calculations. icita and O larreaga Revenue multiplier Revenue Current year year Previous Current year year Previous 0.2 (0.29) 0.3 (0.52) 0.4 (0.52) 0.6 (0.79) 1.3 (1.79) 0.22 (0.3) 0.45 (0.66) 0.49 (0.6) 0.83 (1.02) 1.15 (1.64) 0.22 (0.31) 0.42 (0.64) 0.56 (0.67) 0.82 (1.01) 1.12 (1.61) 0.25 (0.34) 0.4 (0.62) 0.4 (0.52) 0.65 (0.84) 1.13 (1.62) 0.18 (0.27) 0.48 (0.69) 0.35 (0.47) 0.74 (0.93) 1.11 (1.6) 0.23 (0.31) 0.45 (0.67) 0.6 (0.72) 1 (1.19) 0.23 (0.31) 0.49 (0.7) 0.45 (0.57) 0.84 (1.03) 1.09 (1.58) 0.18 (0.27) 0.48 (0.69) 0.35 (0.47) 0.74 (0.93) 1.1 (1.59) 0.35 (0.44) 0.74 (0.95) 0.4 (0.51) 0.8 (1) 0.16 (0.24) 0.32 (0.54) 0.58 (0.69) 0.96 (1.15) 1.14 (1.63) 0.2 (0.29) 0.4 (0.62) 0.4 (0.51) 0.8 (1) 0.22 (0.31) 0.42 (0.64) 0.56 (0.67) 0.82 (1.01) 1.34 (1.83) 0.22 (0.31) 0.42 (0.64) 0.56 (0.67) 0.82 (1.01) 1.33 (1.82) 0.22 (0.31)0.1 (0.18) 0.42 (0.64) 0.28 (0.49) 0.56 (0.67) 0.34 (0.46) 0.82 (1.01) 0.76 (0.95) 1.1 (1.59) 1.07 (1.56) 0.22 (0.31) 0.42 (0.64) 0.56 (0.67) 0.82 (1.01) 1.12 (1.61) 0.2 (0.29) 0.3 (0.52) 0.7 (0.82) 1.1 (1.29) 1.14 (1.63) 0.22 (0.31) 0.42 (0.64) 0.56 (0.67) 0.82 (1.01) 1.13 (1.62) 0.18 (0.27) 0.48 (0.69) 0.35 (0.47) 0.74 (0.93) 1.05 (1.54) 0.35 (0.44) 0.74 (0.95) 0.4 (0.51) 0.8 (1) 0.2 (0.29) 0.6 (0.82) 0.7 (0.82) 1.1 (1.29) 1.08 (1.57) ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution R epublic of evelopment (2010); Kee, N (2010); Kee, and D evelopment Cooperation Economic for O rganisation ultipliers and Elasticities by Country, Baseline Country, M ultipliers and Elasticities by ssumptions on Fiscal verage ustria A A United States United United KingdomUnited Switzerland Sweden Spain R ussian Federation Portugal Korea, Korea, N etherlands Japan Italy Ireland India Greece Germany France China Brazil Belgium A APPENDIX TABLE 6A.1 TABLE Sources: Sources: 190 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

TABLE 6A.2

Impact of a 1 Percent of GDP Reduction in Fiscal Spending on Growth After Two Years, Baseline Multipliers (Percent)

From: Austria Belgium Brazil China France Germany Greece India Ireland Italy Japan To: Austria –1.10 –0.01 –0.01 –0.02 –0.03 –0.16 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.05 –0.01 Belgium –0.01 –0.75 0.00 –0.02 –0.12 –0.12 0.00 –0.02 0.00 –0.04 –0.01 Brazil 0.00 0.00 –0.82 –0.02 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 China 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.82 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.04 France 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –1.11 –0.05 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.03 –0.01 Germany –0.02 –0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.03 –0.81 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 Greece 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.82 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 India 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.82 0.00 0.00 –0.01 Ireland 0.00 –0.04 –0.01 –0.02 –0.04 –0.05 0.00 –0.01 –0.81 –0.03 –0.04 Italy –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.03 –0.03 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.97 –0.01 Japan 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.81 Korea, 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.14 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.02 0.00 –0.01 –0.05 Republic of Netherlands –0.01 –0.03 0.00 –0.01 –0.05 –0.11 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.03 –0.01 Portugal 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.03 –0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 Russian 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 –0.03 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 Federation Spain 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.04 –0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 Sweden 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.03 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 Switzerland –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.03 –0.06 0.00 –0.03 0.00 –0.02 –0.02 United 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 Kingdom United States 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01

PPP –0.01 –0.01 –0.04 –0.18 –0.05 –0.06 0.00 –0.07 0.00 –0.04 –0.08 weighted average

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 191

TABLE 6A.2 (continued)

Impact of a 1 Percent of GDP Reduction in Fiscal Spending on Growth After Two Years, Baseline Multipliers (Percent) Korea, Republic Russian United United Inward of Netherlands Portugal Federation Spain Sweden Switzerland Kingdom States Total Spillovers

–0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.02 –0.02 –0.04 –1.53 –0.43 0.00 –0.04 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.01 –0.01 –0.03 –0.04 –1.26 –0.51 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.89 –0.07 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.07 –1.03 –0.21 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.03 –1.34 –0.23 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.03 –1.04 –0.22 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.86 –0.05 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.90 –0.08 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 –0.01 –0.03 –0.01 –0.01 –0.06 –0.14 –1.33 –0.52 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.02 –1.15 –0.18 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.88 –0.08 –0.82 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.07 –1.17 –0.34

0.00 –0.76 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.01 –0.01 –0.03 –0.03 –1.13 –0.37 0.00 –0.01 –0.84 0.00 –0.05 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –1.01 –0.16 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.82 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.98 –0.16

0.00 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –1.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –1.17 –0.17 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.74 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.88 –0.14 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.74 –0.01 –0.03 –1.00 –0.26 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.65 –0.02 –0.77 –0.12

0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.60 –0.63 –0.03

–0.03 –0.02 0.00 –0.04 –0.03 –0.01 –0.01 –0.03 –0.20 –0.91 –0.14

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 192 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

TABLE 6A.3

Cumulative Growth Impact of Actual Consolidation in 2011–2012, Cyclically-Adjusted Fiscal Measure, Baseline Multipliers (Percent)

From: Austria Belgium Brazil China France Germany Greece India Ireland Italy Japan

To: Austria –0.52 –0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.04 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 0.00 –0.08 0.00 Belgium 0.00 –0.69 0.00 –0.02 –0.15 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 –0.01 –0.06 0.00 Brazil 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 China 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.79 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 0.00 France 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –1.41 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.04 0.00 Germany –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.04 0.03 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.04 0.00 Greece 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –3.54 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 India 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.58 0.00 –0.01 0.00 Ireland 0.00 –0.04 0.00 –0.02 –0.06 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –1.20 –0.04 0.00 Italy 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.04 0.00 –0.02 0.00 0.00 –1.56 0.00 Japan 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 Korea, Republic of 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.13 –0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 0.00 Netherlands 0.00 –0.03 0.00 –0.01 –0.06 0.00 –0.02 0.00 –0.01 –0.05 0.00 Portugal 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 Russian Federation 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 Spain 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.05 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.03 0.00 Sweden 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 Switzerland –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.03 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 –0.04 0.00 United Kingdom 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 0.00 United States 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

PPP weighted 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.17 –0.07 0.00 0.00 –0.05 –0.01 –0.06 0.00 average

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 193

TABLE 6A.3 (continued)

Cumulative Growth Impact of Actual Consolidation in 2011–2012, Cyclically-Adjusted Fiscal Measure, Baseline Multipliers (Percent) Korea, Republic Russian United United of Netherlands Portugal Federation Spain Sweden Switzerland Kingdom States Total Domestic Spillovers

–0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.04 0.01 0.00 –0.05 –0.04 –0.85 –0.52 –0.34 0.00 –0.06 –0.01 –0.01 –0.07 0.01 0.00 –0.11 –0.04 –1.25 –0.69 –0.57 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.09 –0.01 –0.07 –0.02 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.07 –0.97 –0.79 –0.18 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.07 0.01 0.00 –0.05 –0.03 –1.67 –1.41 –0.27 –0.01 –0.02 –0.01 –0.01 –0.04 0.01 0.00 –0.04 –0.03 –0.24 0.03 –0.27 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –3.59 –3.54 –0.05 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.66 –0.58 –0.08 –0.01 –0.03 –0.01 –0.01 –0.09 0.01 0.00 –0.20 –0.15 –1.85 –1.20 –0.66 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.04 0.00 0.00 –0.03 –0.02 –1.76 –1.56 –0.20 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.10 –0.02 –0.08 –0.87 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.07 –1.16 –0.87 –0.30 0.00 –1.10 –0.01 –0.01 –0.06 0.01 0.00 –0.09 –0.03 –1.46 –1.10 –0.36 0.00 –0.01 –2.53 0.00 –0.16 0.00 0.00 –0.03 –0.01 –2.81 –2.53 –0.27 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 –0.66 –0.02 0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.02 –0.80 –0.66 –0.14 0.00 –0.01 –0.04 0.00 –3.09 0.00 0.00 –0.04 –0.01 –3.30 –3.09 –0.21 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.02 1.05 0.00 –0.04 –0.02 0.90 1.05 –0.15 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.03 0.00 –0.15 –0.03 –0.03 –0.38 –0.15 –0.23 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 0.00 –1.95 –0.02 –2.07 –1.95 –0.12 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.59 –0.62 –0.59 –0.03

–0.03 –0.02 –0.01 –0.03 –0.09 0.01 0.00 –0.10 –0.19 –0.86 –0.73 –0.13

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 194 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

TABLE 6A.4

Cumulative Growth Impact of Actual Consolidation in 2011–2012, Headline Fiscal Measure in Ratios, Baseline Multipliers (Percent) Korea, Republic From: Austria Belgium Brazil China France Germany Greece India Ireland Italy Japan of

To: Austria –0.82 –0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.05 –0.18 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.09 –0.02 –0.01 Belgium –0.01 –0.92 0.00 –0.02 –0.17 –0.13 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.07 –0.01 –0.01 Brazil 0.00 0.00 –0.23 –0.02 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 China 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.74 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.05 –0.02 France 0.00 –0.02 0.00 –0.01 –1.58 –0.05 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.05 –0.01 –0.01 Germany –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.05 –0.90 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.04 –0.01 –0.01 Greece 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –2.71 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 0.00 India 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.62 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 Ireland 0.00 –0.05 0.00 –0.02 –0.07 –0.06 –0.01 0.00 –1.31 –0.05 –0.04 –0.01 Italy 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.04 –0.04 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –1.73 –0.01 0.00 Japan 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.89 –0.01 Korea, 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.13 –0.01 –0.02 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.06 –1.07 Republic of Netherlands –0.01 –0.04 0.00 –0.01 –0.07 –0.13 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.05 –0.01 –0.01 Portugal 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.04 –0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 0.00 Russian 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.02 –0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.03 –0.01 –0.01 Federation Spain 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.06 –0.03 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.04 –0.01 0.00 Sweden 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 0.00 Switzerland –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.04 –0.06 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 –0.04 –0.02 –0.01 United 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.02 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 Kingdom United States 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00

PPP –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.16 –0.08 –0.07 0.00 –0.05 –0.01 –0.07 –0.09 –0.04 weighted average

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 195

TABLE 6A.4 (continued)

Cumulative Growth Impact of Actual Consolidation in 2011–2012, Headline Fiscal Measure in Ratios, Baseline Multipliers (Percent)

Russian United United Inward Netherlands Portugal Federation Spain Sweden Switzerland Kingdom States Total Domestic Spillovers

–0.01 –0.01 –0.02 –0.04 0.00 –0.01 –0.05 –0.06 –1.4 –0.8 –0.59 –0.06 –0.01 –0.01 –0.08 –0.01 0.00 –0.11 –0.06 –1.7 –0.9 –0.79 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.3 –0.2 –0.10 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.11 –1.0 –0.7 –0.29 –0.01 –0.01 –0.01 –0.07 0.00 0.00 –0.05 –0.04 –2.0 –1.6 –0.37 –0.02 0.00 –0.01 –0.04 0.00 0.00 –0.05 –0.04 –1.2 –0.9 –0.33 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 –2.8 –2.7 –0.08 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.03 –0.7 –0.6 –0.11 –0.02 –0.01 –0.01 –0.09 0.00 0.00 –0.21 –0.22 –2.2 –1.3 –0.88 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.05 0.00 0.00 –0.03 –0.04 –2.0 –1.7 –0.28 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.03 –1.0 –0.9 –0.10 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.10 –1.5 –1.1 –0.40

–1.08 –0.01 –0.01 –0.06 –0.01 0.00 –0.09 –0.04 –1.6 –1.1 –0.57 –0.01 –2.02 0.00 –0.17 0.00 0.00 –0.03 –0.02 –2.4 –2.0 –0.33 –0.01 0.00 –1.06 –0.02 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.03 –1.3 –1.1 –0.21

–0.01 –0.03 –0.01 –3.17 0.00 0.00 –0.04 –0.02 –3.4 –3.2 –0.26 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.38 0.00 –0.04 –0.03 –0.6 –0.4 –0.21 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.03 0.00 –0.24 –0.03 –0.05 –0.6 –0.2 –0.35 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 0.00 –2.10 –0.04 –2.3 –2.1 –0.17

0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.91 –1.0 –0.9 –0.04

–0.02 –0.01 –0.05 –0.10 0.00 0.00 –0.11 –0.30 –1.19 –1.0 –0.19

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 196 Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?

TABLE 6A.5

Cumulative Growth Impact of Actual Consolidation in 2011–2012, Headline Real Fiscal Measure, Baseline Multipliers (Percent)

From: Austria Belgium Brazil China France Germany Greece India Ireland Italy Japan To: Austria 0.12 0.00 0.01 0.04 –0.01 –0.13 –0.02 0.02 0.00 –0.06 –0.01 Belgium 0.00 –0.43 0.01 0.03 –0.04 –0.10 –0.02 0.04 0.00 –0.04 –0.01 Brazil 0.00 0.00 1.28 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 China 0.00 0.00 0.01 1.28 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.02 0.00 –0.01 –0.03 France 0.00 –0.01 0.01 0.02 –0.35 –0.04 –0.01 0.01 0.00 –0.03 –0.01 Germany 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.03 –0.01 –0.65 –0.01 0.01 0.00 –0.03 –0.01 Greece 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –3.81 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 India 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.57 0.00 0.00 –0.01 Ireland 0.00 –0.02 0.01 0.03 –0.02 –0.04 –0.01 0.01 –0.75 –0.03 –0.03 Italy 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.02 –0.01 –0.03 –0.02 0.01 0.00 –1.13 –0.01 Japan 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.04 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.64 Korea, Republic of 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.22 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 0.04 0.00 –0.01 –0.04 Netherlands 0.00 –0.02 0.00 0.02 –0.02 –0.09 –0.02 0.01 –0.01 –0.03 –0.01 Portugal 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.01 –0.01 –0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 Russian Federation 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 Spain 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.01 –0.01 –0.02 –0.01 0.01 0.00 –0.02 0.00 Sweden 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.00 –0.02 0.00 0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 Switzerland 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.02 –0.01 –0.04 –0.01 0.06 0.00 –0.03 –0.01 United Kingdom 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.01 –0.01 –0.01 0.00 United States 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01

PPP weighted 0.00 0.00 0.06 0.28 –0.02 –0.05 0.00 0.14 0.00 –0.05 –0.06 average

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova and Weber 197

TABLE 6A.5 (continued)

Cumulative Growth Impact of Actual Consolidation in 2011–2012, Headline Real Fiscal Measure, Baseline Multipliers (Percent) Korea, Republic Russian United United Inward of Netherlands Portugal Federation Spain Sweden Switzerland Kingdom States Total Spillovers

0.00 –0.01 –0.01 0.03 –0.04 0.01 0.00 –0.04 –0.01 –0.1 –0.23 0.00 –0.02 –0.01 0.02 –0.08 0.01 0.00 –0.08 –0.01 –0.7 –0.32 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 1.3 0.01 –0.01 0.00 0.00 0.02 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.02 –0.02 1.2 –0.07 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.01 –0.07 0.00 0.00 –0.04 –0.01 –0.5 –0.18 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 0.02 –0.04 0.01 0.00 –0.03 –0.01 –0.7 –0.08 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 –3.8 –0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 1.6 –0.01 0.00 –0.01 –0.01 0.01 –0.09 0.01 0.00 –0.16 –0.05 –1.1 –0.40 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.02 –0.05 0.00 0.00 –0.03 –0.01 –1.2 –0.10 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.6 0.03 –0.35 0.00 0.00 0.02 –0.01 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.02 –0.2 0.17 0.00 –0.38 –0.01 0.01 –0.06 0.01 0.00 –0.07 –0.01 –0.7 –0.28 0.00 0.00 –2.50 0.00 –0.17 0.00 0.00 –0.02 0.00 –2.7 –0.22 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.73 –0.02 0.00 0.00 –0.01 0.00 1.7 –0.05 0.00 0.00 –0.04 0.01 –3.16 0.00 0.00 –0.03 0.00 –3.3 –0.12 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 –0.02 0.73 0.00 –0.03 0.00 0.7 –0.06 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 –0.03 0.00 0.13 –0.02 –0.01 0.1 –0.07 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 –0.02 0.00 0.00 –1.57 –0.01 –1.6 –0.06 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 –0.01 –0.17 –0.2 –0.00

–0.01 –0.01 –0.01 0.08 –0.10 0.01 0.00 –0.08 –0.05 0.1 –0.04

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, and Direction of Trade Statistics; and IMF staff estimates. Note: PPP: purchasing power parity.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution This page intentionally left blank

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CHAPTER 7 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Difference?

ANNA IVANOVA

The discussion of global and regional imbalances has put the spotlight on a possible link between current accounts and structural policies. Drawing on standard empirical current account models, the paper finds that the commonly recommended structural factors cannot explain the widening of imbalances prior to the 2008–09 crisis. That said, structural factors do help explain some part of long-standing cross-country differ- ences in the current account levels. In particular, countries with stricter credit market regulation, higher taxes on businesses, lower minimum wage (in particular, in slow- growing economies), and generous unemployment benefits tend to have higher current account balances than others.

INTRODUCTION Although the relationship between global current account imbalances and the financial crisis of 2008–09 is far from obvious, concern remains that such imbal- ances are a continuing source of global instability and a threat to a sustainable recovery (Blanchard and Milesi-Ferretti 2009). The seriousness with which the imbalances are viewed is reflected in the far-reaching actions that have been pro- posed to limit them, including a suggestion for imposing quantitative targets on the current account balances.1 Underlying these proposals is the premise that some sizeable fraction of both the surpluses and the deficits represents

The author is grateful for invaluable support and guidance from Ashoka Mody. She also thanks Fabian Bornhorst for allowing her to use some of his analysis. The chapter has benefited from the insightful comments by participants at several workshops at the Germany in an Interconnected World Economy conference organized by the Federal Ministry of Finance of Germany, with particular thanks to the discussant, Carsten-Patrick Meier; “Preventing and Correcting Macro Economic Imbalances in the Euro Area” co-organized by the Central Bank of the Netherlands and the IMF; and the IMF internal group on macroeconomic imbalances in Europe. Special thanks also go to Akito Matsumoto for help- ful discussions. Susan Becker provided valuable research assistance. 1 See, for example, the proposal by U.S. Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner to the meeting of G-20 ministers in South Korea in 2010 (http://graphics8.nytimes.com/packages/pdf/10222010geithnerletter. pdf). 199

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 200 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

“distortions.” In other words, where the current account balance is the outcome of an “optimal” allocation of resources (“good imbalance”), it is not a problem; but the imbalances that result from policy distortions or externalities are “bad.” Since distortions are undesirable even from the country perspective, their mitiga- tion by policy action is twice blessed, since this also scales back the threat from global instability. In this paper, I empirically examine the contribution of structural factors—the presumed locus of the distortions—to current account imbalances. While the analysis covers an extended period, 1975–2009, I use the results to interpret developments during the last phase of the sample period. It was in those years that the unprecedented global expansion and exuberance were accompanied by widen- ing imbalances. I conclude that a significant fraction of the imbalances in the run-up to the crisis reflected the global cycle. Yet, since much policy attention has been focused on possible structural causes and remedies, the bulk of the paper is devoted to assessing the link between structural policies and the current account. I apply these findings in particular to Germany, where the current account sur- plus surged to 7.5 percent of GDP in 2007. In practice, the specific distortions at the root of imbalances remain a matter of some speculation, with competing explanations for the observed behavior of the current account. For example, high current account surpluses due to low investment may reflect a variety of factors, including lack of competition in the financial sector, high corporate taxation, or expectations of low potential growth. More seriously, the same package of structural policies is at times prescribed to both surplus and deficit countries. That package often includes deregulation of product, services, and credit markets, reduction in employment protections, removal of rigidities in the labor market, and taxation. While these policies may be good for many reasons, their impact on the current account is not clear a priori. Structural policies, which may influence productivity growth and/or access to credit, could impact both savings and investment decisions. The variety of channels and the complex interactions between them make the issue an empirical one, a perspective that I adopt. For a panel of 106 advanced, emerging, and developing countries, I estimate an equation to determine the correlates of the current account balance, using five- year non-overlapping averages. As is standard practice, to represent the intertem- poral consumption and investment decisions underlying the current account, I include such control variables as income growth and level, population age struc- ture, fiscal balance, initial net foreign asset position, and the degree of financial integration. In line with other recent studies, I find that these standard determi- nants of the current account did not evolve significantly during the final years of the global exuberance and so cannot be used to explain the emergence of global imbalances. I then add a number of variables representing structural factors. Even more so than the standard variables, structural factors changed little over time or changed in the same direction in both surplus and deficit countries. Therefore, these factors can explain very little of the emergence of imbalances prior to the crisis.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 201

I infer from these findings that the emergence of imbalances was likely linked to cyclical factors. Germany, in particular, was able to benefit from the global increase in demand for technology-intensive goods, in the production of which Germany has a comparative advantage. However, the “windfall” profits of German firms due to their export success did not immediately translate into an increase in domestic investment, since German firms apparently viewed the boom as temporary, and the German growth potential remained low. As a further consideration, I ask if structural policies, while not directly influ- ential, may have helped shape the response of the current account to the standard variables. The evidence presented in this paper suggests that even in their role as absorbers or amplifiers of changes in fundamentals, structural factors account for only a small fraction of the imbalances. To be clear, even if they are not candidates for explaining the rise in imbal- ances, some structural factors do have a meaningful correlation with the current account balance and so can explain longstanding differences in the current account balances across countries. Even these findings need to be qualified, however, as they are often not robust across country samples and time periods, with some com- monly recommended policies increasing and some reducing the current account balance. With these caveats, the empirical results suggest that lower business taxa- tion, credit market regulation,2 and unemployment benefits can reduce the current account surplus. Consistent with earlier studies, I find that a lower minimum wage and less strict employment protection, often recommended for making the labor market “more flexible,” are associated with larger current account surpluses. In the application to Germany, this would imply that the minimum wage would have to be raised and employment protection strengthened to reduce the current account surplus, although this may not be desirable since a higher minimum wage and stricter employment protection might also raise unemployment. These findings’ relevance to Germany is therefore unclear. However, in some of Europe’s periph- eral economies, reducing minimum wage and lowering employment protection could contribute to reducing their current account deficits. The empirical evidence therefore points to select structural measures that would need to be tailored to particular countries, rather than a package of broad structural policies for addressing imbalances. For Germany, these results suggest that lower taxes on businesses, further reduction in the gross unemployment replacement rate, and a smaller public share in the banking system3 could reduce the surplus. Altogether, however, the impact on the German current account surplus will likely be modest.

2 The measure of credit market regulation employed in this paper includes four components measur- ing the degree of public ownership of the banking system, control of interest rates, percentage of credit extended to private sector, and competition from foreign banks. 3 Germany scores well on all of the subcomponents of the index of credit market regulation except the degree of public ownership of the banking system due to the large presence of publicly owned banks (Landesbanken and Sparkassen).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 202 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

LITERATURE REVIEW The relationship between structural policies and the current account remains an open one. The literature agrees that fundamentals such as income per capita, demographics, fiscal policy, and other traditional factors are important determi- nants of the current account. But beyond that, while several recent studies point to imbalances in the run-up to the 2008–09 crisis as “excessive” compared to the fundamentals, the role of structural factors in the emergence of these imbalances remains an open question. The overall impact of the commonly recommended package of structural policies—such as liberalization of product, services and credit markets, reduction in employment protection, removal of other labor mar- ket rigidities, and reduction in business taxation—remains unclear. Chinn and Prasad (2003), Abiad, Leigh and Mody (2009), Jaumotte and Sodsriwiboon (2010), and Lane and Milessi-Ferretti (2011) find that current account balances are largely driven by such fundamentals as relative per-capita income, fiscal stance, demographics, oil prices, the initial net foreign assets posi- tion, and the degree of financial integration conditional on income level. The studies find a positive and significant relationship between relative income per capita and the current account, possibly capturing the fact that capital flows from rich countries to poor countries, where there are higher growth “catching up” opportunities. The current account balances are also found to be relatively large where the fiscal balances are relatively large, suggesting that private sector savings provide only a partial Ricardian offset to changes in public savings (the coefficient is often found to be less than one). Higher old and young dependency ratios are associated with lower current account balances, since relatively higher dependency ratios are associated with the lower aggregate savings. However, the expected change in the old dependency ratio has a positive association with the current account, since countries that age rapidly are saving more. For oil producers, the current account is positively related to the oil balance, which captures fluctuations in the oil price. The litera- ture also finds that the current account is positively associated with the initial net foreign assets position. While it is somewhat counterintuitive, this finding likely reflects the fact that the net foreign assets position is generating net investment income, which is part of the current account. Financial integration is also found to facilitate access to capital for poor countries; hence, poorer countries tend to have lower current account balances at a given state of financial integration. Some studies also find that among developing countries, the degree of trade openness is negatively associated with the current account balance. Chinn, Eichengreen, and Ito (2011) also find weak evidence that countries with more developed financial markets have weaker current accounts, but their results are not robust. While a substantial body of literature exists on the link between current accounts and macroeconomic fundamentals, the literature on the link between structural policies and the current account is scarce and inconclusive. Following is a summary of the recent studies, which should allow one to view this chapter in proper perspective.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 203

Kennedy and Sløk (2005) conclude that current account imbalances are struc- tural in nature because they deviate from the current accounts projected under unchanged fiscal policies, unchanged real exchange rates, and monetary policy aimed at closing the output gap in the medium term. They also find that cycli- cally adjusted current accounts are correlated with the potential growth, although this correlation is largely driven by cross-country differences. On the other hand, they do not find a robust link between specific structural policies and the current account in their reduced-form pooled time series and cross-country regressions, which they conducted on a sample of 14 OECD countries. However, there is some evidence that more open product and financial markets are associated with weaker current accounts. The other variables under investigation included indica- tors of labor market regulation, foreign direct investment (FDI) restrictiveness, financial market development (stock market capitalization), and labor market performance (trend participation rate and non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment, or NAIRU). Nevertheless, they encourage policymakers to undertake structural policies because a faster growing economy will improve wel- fare, though it may or may not reduce imbalances. Kerdrain, Koske and Wanner (2010) estimate reduced-form regressions in a large panel of 117 advanced, emerging, and developing countries to assess the impact of structural policies on savings, investment, and the current account. They conclude that structural policies may influence savings, investment, and the current account, not only through their impact on macroeconomic conditions such as productivity growth or public revenues and expenditures but also directly. In particular, social spending, notably spending on health care, is associated with lower savings rates, possibly due to lower precautionary savings, and with a lower current account. Stricter employment protection is associated with lower savings rates, if unemployment benefits are low, as well as higher investment rates, per- haps due to a greater substitution of capital for labor, leading to lower current account balances. Product market liberalization is found to temporarily boost investment, though direct impact on the current account could not be detected. Financial market deregulation may lower the savings rate, although only in less developed countries, and again the direct impact on the current account could not be detected. While the Kerdrain, Koske and Wanner (2010) study is rather comprehensive, their regression includes country-specific fixed effects, which may absorb some of the cross-country variation in the current account, possibly related to the structural variables, which do not change significantly over time. Also, some of their other variables, such as user cost of capital and productivity growth, might reflect struc- tural conditions. As a result, their study does not allow one to fully answer the ques- tion of the individual impact of various structural policies on the current account. Kerdrain, Koske, and Wanner (2010) find little evidence that structural poli- cies affect the speed of adjustment of the current account to the equilibrium. In contrast, Ju and Wei (2007) provide evidence that rigid labor markets reduce the speed of adjustment of the current account to the long-run equilibrium. The lat- ter authors use a two-step approach: first, they estimate a speed of convergence of

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 204 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

the current account ratio to the steady state for each country separately, using a vector-error correction model, and second, they relate the speed of convergence to the degree of labor market rigidity in a cross-section of countries. However, large economies, such as the United States, Japan, and Germany, are excluded from this analysis, because the authors suggest that the current accounts in large economies could behave systematically differently due to the importance of not only their domestic labor market flexibility but also foreign labor market flexibility. Jaumotte and Sodsriwiboon (2010) estimate pooled current account regres- sions with traditional determinants as controls in a smaller sample of 49 advanced and emerging economies to test for the importance of the European Monetary Union and the potential impact of policies. They find that financial liberalization and higher minimum wage lower the current account, while no direct link could be detected between the level of employment protection or the level of unemploy- ment benefits and the current account. In an econometric study covering 100 advanced, emerging, and developing countries for the period 2001–09 (annual data), Bayoumi, Vamvakidis, and Vitek (2010) find that countries with more (less) credit market regulation have higher (lower) current account balances while controlling for traditional fundamentals.4 Berger and Nitsch (2010) investigate the link between employment protection and product market regulation and the bilateral trade balances as a fraction of total bilateral trade in a sample of 18 European countries over a long time horizon (1948 through 2008). They find that countries with less flexible labor and product markets exhibit systematically lower bilateral trade surpluses than others. A recent body of literature also identifies imbalances in the period preceding the crisis as “excessive” compared to fundamentals. These studies including Barnes, Lawson, and Radziwill (2010), who estimate current account regression with traditional factors in a sample of 25 OECD countries; Lane and Milessi- Ferretti (2011), in a sample of 65 advanced and emerging economies; and Chinn, Eichengreen, and Ito (2011), in a sample of 109 industrial and developing coun- tries. Barnes, Lawson, and Radziwill (2010) and Chinn, Eichengreen, and Ito (2011) find some evidence that such excesses could partly be explained by hous- ing investment, real housing appreciation, and stock market performance. However, large residuals remain, in particular, for the United States and China. Lane and Milessi-Ferretti (2011) conclude that the countries with the largest excesses before the 2008–09 crisis have experienced the largest corrections there- after, and also find that the adjustment in deficit countries has been achieved primarily through demand compression rather than expenditure switching. They further conclude that the high output costs that have been associated with the rapid current-account corrections provide support for research that assesses whether current account deficits during good times might partly reflect

4 Bayoumi, Vamvakidis, and Vitek (2010) employ an index of credit market regulation constructed by the Fraser Institute, which is also utilized in this paper (see Appendix for details).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 205 distortions that fail to internalize the risk of a subsequent sudden stop. It is not clear, however, what exactly these distortions are. Finally, theoretical literature (see, for example, Vogel 2011) suggests that while structural policies that mainly target supply-side weaknesses may help regain competitiveness in economies with competitiveness problems in the short run, in the longer run this effect is offset by the income effect as imports rise. Consequently, the lasting long-term rebalancing of external accounts also requires the correction of demand imbalances. The current paper contributes to the existing empirical literature in the follow- ing three dimensions. First, it attempts to shed some light of the role of struc- tural policies in the emergence of imbalances in the run-up to the 2008–09 financial crisis. Second, it assesses the direct impact of a commonly recommended package of structural policies on the current account in a large sample of advanced, emerging, and developing countries while controlling for traditional macroeconomic fundamentals. Third, it assesses the potential size of the current account reduction due to these policies in Germany, which has come under a spotlight due to its large current account surplus. While the results in this paper support some of the earlier findings, they point to the lack of robustness of many results in determining the level of the current account. Moreover, the paper emphasizes the muted role of structural factors in causing the growth of imbalances just prior to the recent crisis. For Germany, the paper offers some policy directions for change but cautions that the quantitative effects may be small.

BASELINE MODEL This section introduces the results of the baseline econometric model. The base- line model is estimated using a random effects model in a sample of 106 advanced, emerging, and developing countries. It includes traditional fundamen- tals, which were found to be important current account determinants in the earlier literature. As a robustness check, an Ordinary Least Squares OLS model with cluster robust standard errors (not including fixed effects) is also estimated and yields similar results. The current account is averaged over five-year non- overlapping periods spanning the period of 1975–2009, since the goal is to iden- tify the determinants of the medium term or so to speak “structural current account.” Many of the explanatory variables enter as deviations from the PPP- weighted sample average in a given period, which captures the fact that current accounts are determined by the countries’ positions relative to their trading part- ners. Data sources are described in the Appendix. The baseline model (Table 7A.1)5 largely confirms the findings in the litera- ture. Higher relative income per capita, fiscal balance, and initial net foreign assets position as well as higher oil prices for oil producers are associated with the

5 Tables 7A.1 through 7A.6 may be found at the end of this chapter.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 206 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

higher current account balances.6 Countries with relatively high current depen- dency ratios have lower current account balances, as the elderly tend to draw on savings more. However, countries with the higher expected increases in the dependency ratio, capturing the speed of aging, are found to have higher current account surpluses. The regression also includes the degree of financial integration, measured by the sum of foreign assets and liabilities in percent of GDP and the interaction of the financial integration with the GDP per capita growth in the previous period (column 2). The link between financial integration and the current account works more robustly through growth than through the income level. In particu- lar, it reduces the current account balance in the countries with higher previous- period growth. However, high-growth countries also tend to be poorer countries, so this finding is consistent with that in Abiad, Leigh and Mody (2009). The model presented in this chapter does not include any crisis dummies, unlike some of the earlier studies. The reason is that the goal is to explain the developments in the current account with the known set of factors, including structural policies, while the dummies could capture some of the effects without identifying the policies and factors behind the crisis. The relationship between the fundamentals and the current account balance in the sample of OECD countries is somewhat different (Tables 7A.1, 7A.2, 7A.4, and 7A.5, columns 1 and 2). The relationship between the current account and income per capita, fiscal balance, the ratio of net foreign assets to GDP, old dependency ratio, an increase in the old dependency ratio, and the interaction of financial integration and past growth remains broadly unchanged in the OECD sample, although in some cases the coefficients become insignificant. In contrast, the coefficient on the young dependency ratio becomes positive and significant. While this result appears counterintuitive, it is consistent with the findings of Kerdrain, Koske, and Wanner (2010) as well as Barnes, Lawson and Radziwill (2010). It could perhaps be explained by the fact that richer OECD countries can afford to save more for future generations, for example for education purposes. The degree of trade openness also appears to matter more in a sample of OECD countries; in particular, the higher the trade openness the higher is the current account surplus, perhaps reflecting the fact that richer countries that are also more open tend to export capital to the poorer countries. The baseline model generates a fairly good fit, especially for advanced coun- tries, explaining about 35 percent of the variation in the current account bal- ances in the sample. The model explains cross-country variation better than time-series variation, with the between R-square of 0.5 (Figures 7.1a and 7.1b).

6 Although some of the variables, e.g. financial integration, openness, and oil price, may be nonsta- tionary, the residuals from the baseline regression estimated on annual data are found to be stationary using an augmented Dickey-Fuller test, though they exhibit serial correlation. Therefore, the results of the random effects model were estimated using standard errors robust for heteroscedasticity and serial correlation.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 207

0.3

0.2

0.1

0

–0.1

–0.2

–0.3

Actual current account to GDP –0.4

–0.5 –0.1 –0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 Fitted Current Account to GDP

Figure 7.1a Actual and Fitted Current Account to GDP, Advanced Economies

0.3

0.2

0.1

0

–0.1

–0.2

–0.3 Actual current account to GDP –0.4

–0.5 –0.15 –0.1 –0.05 0 0.05 0.1

Fitted Current Account to GDP

Figure 7.1b Actual and Fitted Current Account to GDP, Other Countries Sources: Annual Macroeconomic Database of the European Commission (AMECO); World Economic Outlook data- base; and IMF staff estimates.

Nonetheless, the residuals from the current account regression largely mirror the imbalances that emerged in mid-2000. The “fundamentals” therefore did not evolve to generate the imbalances. This is the case even when accounting for the potential impact of the financial integration and trade openness. The fact that imbalances widened across the globe suggests that some global forces were at work, although country-specific factors probably determined the direction of change in the current accounts (Figures 7.2a and 7.2b).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 208 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

10 China Germany 8 Japan Spain 6 United States 4 2 0 –2 –4 –6 –8 –10 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Year indicates the beginning of the 5-year period

Figure 7.2a Current Account Balance, Germany and Four Large Economies, 1975–2005 (Five-year averages, percent of GDP)

10 China Germany 8 Japan Spain 6 United States 4 2 0 –2 –4 –6 –8 –10 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Year indicates the beginning of the 5-year period

Figure 7.2b Residuals from the Baseline Model, Germany and Four Large Economies, 1975–2005 (Five-year averages, percent of GDP) Sources: Annual Macroeconomic Database of the European Commission (AMECO); IMF, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff estimates.

STRUCTURAL POLICIES AND THE CURRENT ACCOUNT This section introduces structural policies such as regulation, taxation, and the level of minimum wage and unemployment benefits, and discuss the results of the estimation when these factors are added to the baseline regression as five-year averages. With respect to the emergence of imbalances, two distinct possibilities emerge regarding what role structural policies could have played. First, structural policies on their own could have directly impacted the current accounts. For example, a high level of business taxation may have reduced investment incentives, leading

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 209

4.5 Japan 4.0 United States Germany 3.5 Spain 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007

Figure 7.3a Employment Protection, Germany and Three Selected Countries, 1989–2007

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3 China Japan United States 0.2 Germany Spain 0.1

0.0 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004

Figure 7.3b Gross Unemployment Replacement Rate, Germany and Four Selected Countries, 1980–2004

12

10

8

6

4 China Japan 2 United States Germany Spain 0 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006

Figure 7.3c Credit Market Regulation, Germany and Four Selected Countries, 1985–2006

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 210 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

6

5

4

3

2 United States Japan 1 Spain Germany

0 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007

Figure 7.3d Regulation in Electricity/Transport/Communication, Germany and Three Selected Countries, 1980–2007 Sources: Aleksynska and Schindler (2011); Fraser Institute; and Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.

to lower investment and higher current account balances. Second, structural policies could have shaped the response of the current account to changes in macroeconomic fundamentals and shocks, including global shocks. But even if structural policies did not play a major role in the emergence of imbalances in any way, they might help explain the differences in the levels of the current accounts across the globe. In that case, they could also be used as a tool for reducing imbal- ances. These three possibilities are investigated below. First, I note that many structural indictors either did not change substantially over time, in particular during the period of the emergence of global imbalances, or if they did, often changed in the same direction for the surplus and deficit countries (Figures 7.3a-d).7 China is the notable exception, where its credit market was substantially deregulated in 2005 and there was a substantial increase in the ratio of minimum to mean wages in 2002. However, given the earlier findings in the literature on the impact of the financial liberalization and the minimum wage, one could expect both of these changes to reduce China’s current account surplus. So it is unlikely that structural factors on their own can explain the emergence of imbalances. Second, I augment baseline regressions with the structural indicators that vary over time 8 (see Table 7A.1 for the full sample and Table 7A.4 for an OECD

7 In Germany, the 2004 Hartz IV reform reduced unemployment benefits and social transfers and increased the flexibility of temporary employment. The subcomponent of the employment protection indicator, which measures protection of temporary employment, did decline, but the overall index increased. 8 Some of the variables to replace the missing values were interpolated, as some of these variables are not available on an annual basis. I also extrapolated the values of some structural variables to 2009, since for this year many of the structural variables were not available. The index of employment pro- tection is available only for OECD countries, but there are subcomponents of this indicator, such as advance notice period and severance pay after nine months, available for a broader set of countries in (Aleksynska and Schindler, 2011). I constructed an employment protection index for a broader set using an out-of-sample forecast from the regression of the employment protection index on advance notice period and severance pay after nine months.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 211 sample). Generally, the results do not indicate a robust relationship between the current account and structural policies, although in some specifications in the full sample the coefficient on the unemployment gross replacement ratio is positive and significant, while that on the ratio of the minimum-to-mean wage and employment protection indicator is negative and significant. No significant asso- ciation is found for OECD countries, although the sample there is rather small. The positive association between the current account and the gross unemploy- ment replacement rate could reflect the fact that generous unemployment systems might contribute to higher unemployment rates by reducing incentives to seek new jobs (Bassani and Duval 2006, Vandenberg 2010). In such an environment, the unemployment rate and the probability of becoming unemployed are higher, which could lead to higher precautionary savings by households. However, there might be a counteracting impact as high unemployment benefits provide higher income in the event of job loss. However, to have a negative impact on the current account-to-GDP-ratio, this higher income would have to lead to an increase in the marginal propensity to consume. The results suggest that the latter effect has not been important historically.9 The negative association between the ratio of the minimum wage to the mean wage and the current account is consistent with earlier findings and may reflect the fact that higher minimum wage may lead to higher labor costs and, therefore, hurt competitiveness. This, in principle, could work through both savings and investment channels. Higher labor costs may reduce corporate profitability and savings. However, higher labor costs may also encourage companies to substitute capital for labor, when the latter is expensive. Finally, higher employment protection is associated with a lower current account, which is consistent with the findings in the literature that higher employment protection reduces savings and increases investment. Higher employment protection raises implicit and explicit labor costs, so the impact can be similar to that of the minimum wage. Not surprisingly, the residuals from the regression where three of the struc- tural variables are included (unemployment gross replacement rate, ratio of the minimum-to-mean wage, and employment protection index) continue to mirror the imbalances (Figure 7A.2). Hence, structural factors on their own did not evolve to generate the imbalances either. While structural policies may not have contributed directly to the emergence of imbalances, they may have helped shape the response of the current account to macroeconomic shocks and changes in the fundamentals. In other words, struc- tural factors might have played a role as macroeconomic shock absorbers or amplifiers. This hypothesis is tested by analyzing the interaction of structural factors with the more dynamic fundamentals.

9 At the time of the financial crisis, however, the impact of the reduction in unemployment benefits may have been different from that observed historically, since the level of unemployment may be largely a reflection of lower demand for labor rather than lower labor supply. Hence, the finding on unemployment benefits should be interpreted in the medium-term context.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 212 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

10 Japan United States 8 Germany 6 Spain 4 2 0 −2 −4 −6 −8 −10 1990 1995 2000 2005

Year indicates the beginning of the 5-year period

Figure 7.4 Residuals from the Model with Structural Variables, Germany and Three Selected Countries, 1990–2005 (Five-year averages, percent of GDP) Source: IMF staff estimates.

LONG-STANDING STRUCTURAL DIFFERENCES AND THE CURRENT ACCOUNT The long-standing differences in the levels of structural variables on the figures above are striking. They reflect not only policy differences but also differences in institutional arrangements and social norms. As such, these factors could have been important in explaining the long-standing cross-country differences in the current accounts. To test this hypothesis, given a rather small sample size, all structural variables over all available years were averaged to construct a structural indicator for each country that captures that country’s long-term structural characteristic. The relationship between the current account and these structural variables, which do not vary over time, are investigated, while controlling for fundamentals as before (see Tables 7A.1 and 7A.2 for the global sample; Table 7A.4 for the OECD sample). In most cases, structural variables enter as deviations from a PPP GDP-weighted sample mean to capture the relative standing of a country compared to its trading partners. This formulation essentially allows us to test whether structural factors help explain country-specific fixed effects. The results are summarized in Table 7.1. The most robust result is for the ratio of the minimum-to-mean wage, which has a negative sign and is significant in almost all specifications. The positive impact of the unemployment gross replacement rate is also fairly robust. However, the impact of other structural indicators is not robust across two different sam- ples. Moreover, some commonly recommended policies would increase the cur- rent account while others would reduce it. In particular, lower business taxation, less credit market regulation, and lower unemployment benefits can reduce the current account surplus. However, lower minimum wage and employment

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 213 o o o o o N N N N N Yes significant Statistically Largely Yes Largely Largely Yes Largely n n n p p p p p Countries D EC O assets and lower previous period growth previous assets and lower o Impact on the current account Impact on the current account N Yes period growth the higher previous Yes Yes Yes the higher initial value of net foreign significant strengthened by Possibly Direction Advanced, Emerging, and Developing Economies and Developing Emerging, Advanced, OECD Sample Statistically Largely Largely ll Countries and ll Countries A n n p p p NA NA NA NA NA NA ccount, ccount, Direction A eforms on Current on Current eforms ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution R SE the current account account SE the current A E UCE the current account account UCE the current R D C E N R F staff estimates. M eregulation of professional services of professional eregulation eregulation in retail trade in retail eregulation eregulation of the credit market of the credit eregulation educing the ratio of minimum wage to mean wage educing the ratio of minimum wage to protection educing employment educing taxes (profit, labor and other business taxes) and labor and other business taxes) (profit, educing taxes rate replacement gross educing Unemployment Impact of Selected Structural R R balance D R tax payments for simplifying procedures R D I that could Structural reforms balance D Product market deregulation Product Structural reforms that could that could Structural reforms TABLE 7.1 TABLE Source: I Source: 214 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

protection, often recommended for making the labor market “more flexible,” are associated with larger current account surpluses. The two new indicators that become significant in the overall sample when structural variables enter as averages over time are corporate income tax rate/ indicator of doing business paying taxes10 and credit market regulation (the higher value of this index means less regulation). Countries with a long-standing tradition of relatively high business taxes are found to have, on average, higher current account balances. This could reflect the fact that higher corporate taxa- tion reduces investment incentives and so may raise the current account bal- ance.11 The credit market regulation index, which is constructed by the Fraser Institute, includes several components, namely: the degree of public ownership of the banking system, control of interest rates, percentage of credit extended to the private sector, and competition from foreign banks. For example, in the case of Germany this index indicates strict regulation largely on account of the high public ownership of the banking system. The results suggest that stricter credit market “regulation” raises the current account. Stricter credit market regulation can work through both savings and investment channels. In particular, the lack of access to credit may constrain investment. However, lack of access to credit may also encourage household and corporate savings. Given that the index cap- tures a broader set of components than just credit extended to the private sector, the results could indicate that it is the broader effectiveness and efficiency of the banking sector that affects the current account. To be clear, though, these relationships are not evident in the OECD sample. The indicators of the degree of regulation in product and services markets, which are available only for OECD countries, generally are not significantly associated with the current account. The results for the OECD sample, however, should be interpreted with caution due to a relatively small number of observations. Following Chinn and Ito (2007) and Abiad, Leigh, and Mody (2009), as a robustness check two additional financial measures were included, namely the degree of financial development measured by the ratio of private credit to GDP and the measure of capital account openness constructed in Chinn and Ito (2008). Unlike Chinn and Ito (2007), however, I included a measure of financial development at the start of the period rather than the five-year period average to mitigate the potential endogeneity problem, since financial development is mea- sured by the ratio of private credit to GDP. Both financial development and capital account openness were not significant when included on their own. However, similarly to Abiad, Leigh and Mody (2009), I find that fast growing countries (typically, these are poorer countries), which a have higher degree of capital account openness, also have lower current account balances, which could

10 This variable captures the amount and administrative burden of paying taxes and contributions for a medium-size company; it is a rank of a country among all countries. 11 There is evidence from firm-level data that lower corporate tax rates or higher depreciation allow- ances are associated with higher investment (e.g., Vartia, 2008; Schwellnus and Arnold, 2008).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 215 be interpreted as greater capital account openness helping the inflow of capital to poorer countries. The inclusion of these variables does not alter the conclusions for other struc- tural variables with the exception of the credit market regulation variable, the coefficient on which becomes insignificant. While in principle, credit market regulation and the degree of capital account openness are conceptually different, they appear to capture similar aspects of the availability of credit. For simplicity of exposition, capital account openness is not included in the tables, but the result on credit market regulation should be treated with caution in this light. Overall, empirical evidence points to select structural measures, rather than a broad and diffuse package of structural policies, for addressing imbalances. Moreover, there may be a trade-off between reducing the current account imbal- ance and achieving other policy objectives, so the choice of the policy instruments should not be based purely on their impact on the current account.

INTERACTION OF STRUCTURAL FACTORS AND FUNDAMENTALS This section investigates whether long-standing structural differences may have shaped the response of the current account to changes in fundamentals. To this end, I augment regressions in Table 7A.112 with the interaction terms of the structural variables averaged over time with the fundamentals. Due to a substantial reduction in the degrees of freedom with the inclusion of the interac- tion terms, I experimented with the groups of variables both separately and together and chose the variables that turned out to be significant based on a set of these regressions. The results are summarized in Table 7A.5.13 The evidence of the indirect impact of structural policies on the current account is inconclusive, since most of the findings, with the exception of the interaction of the minimum-to-mean ratio and the previous period growth, are not robust across specifications. The most robust finding is that the negative impact of the minimum-to-mean wage ratio on the current account is stronger in countries that experience rapid income growth. This finding could be consistent with the interpretation that a higher minimum wage increases labor cost and reduces companies’ savings or forces them to substitute capital for labor. Higher labor costs in the fast growing countries may provide stronger incentives for com- panies to substitute capital for labor, leading to higher investment and a lower current account balance. This finding also suggests that the relationship between the minimum wage and the current account may be stronger for less developed countries, which tend to have higher rates of growth.

12 Tables 7A.1 through 7A.6 are located in the appendix to this chapter. 13 The analysis included various interaction terms, but the table reports only a subset of the results. In particular, no robust link between the interaction of credit market regulation/demographics and the current account could be established, although some theoretical research (Coeurdacier, Guibaud, and Jin, 2012) suggests that such interaction may be important.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 216 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

The impact of the gross unemployment replacement rate depends on the ini- tial net foreign assets position and the previous period’s per capita income growth. In particular, the positive impact of the unemployment benefits on the current account may be reduced in countries that experience rapid income growth. This finding would be consistent with the explanation that high unemployment ben- efits increase the rate of unemployment and the probability of becoming unem- ployed, which in turn lead to higher precautionary savings, since such a probability would be reduced in an environment of rapid income growth. The finding that the positive impact of unemployment benefits on the current account is strength- ened in countries with a high initial net-foreign-assets position is difficult to interpret; it could be related to the fact that the net-foreign-asset position might capture the persistence of the current account beyond the factor-income contri- bution. Nonetheless, the residuals from the regression with interaction terms (Table 7A.5, column 2; and Figure 7.5) track the imbalances, though they are closer to zero than in the baseline model for all countries except Japan. So even as absorb- ers or amplifiers of changes in the fundamentals, the commonly evoked struc- tural policies cannot account for the emergence of imbalances. There might be other important structural differences in the economies of the surplus and deficit countries, not necessarily representing policy distortions, which translated global shocks into the differing responses of the current accounts. In addition, the emergence of imbalances coincided with the global cyclical upswing and a rapid expansion of world trade; cyclical factors have therefore likely played a role. The correlation of the “excess imbalances” with the housing investment/housing real price as well as with the performance of the stock market found in the literature provide further support to this proposition. A further investigation into the role of structural policies and broader structural factors in the impact of cyclical shocks on the current account may therefore be warranted.

10 8 China Japan 6 United States Germany Spain 4 2 0 –2 –4 –6 –8 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Year indicates the beginning of the 5-year period

Figure 7.5 Residuals from the Model with Structural Variables Interacted with Fundamentals, Germany and Four Selected Countries, 1975–2005 (Five-year averages, percent of GDP) Source: IMF staff estimates.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 217

IMPLICATIONS FOR GERMANY This section analyzes what the empirical findings imply for a country like Germany, where the current account surplus reached a historical high of 7.5 percent in 2007. The improvement in the current account in Germany was driven by an improvement in Germany’s trade balance on goods and coincided with the expansion of global trade. Germany’s trade surplus has been consis- tently positive over the past half-century. Its export competitiveness derives from a comparative advantage in a large number of specialized product variet- ies. Germany was able to hold its market share when other European countries lost it.14 (Figures 7.6 and 7.7) While Germany has increased both exports to and imports from Europe as part of increased trade integration, its imports are increasingly tilted toward products produced most cost-effectively by China.15 (Figures 7.8a and 7.8b) Thus, while German exports have remained largely unaffected by the competition from Asia and Eastern Europe, much of the rest of Europe was affected. European imbal- ances therefore largely reflect the loss of competitiveness of other countries. While German exports have been performing strongly for a good reason, it is somewhat puzzling why imports did not catch up. A look at domestic demand

Germany’s competitive advantage arises from specialized product varieties.

12 CHN 10 DEU USA 8

6 ITA 4 JPN FRA

product varieties NLD KOR ESP 2 MYS IND POL World market share in specialized World IRL PRT 0 GRC 0 100 200 300 400 500 Number of specialized product varieties

Figure 7.6 Specialized Products Varieties and World Market Share, Selected Countries. Sources: See footnote 14; UN Comtrade Database; and staff estimates. Note: Computed with Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) 4 level trade data for 2007.

14 The charts on competitiveness and imports were provided by Fabian Bornhorst as part of the joint column on VOXEU, which can be found at http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/6873. 15 In view of East Asia’s deep and extensive industrial division of labor, China’s exports to Germany include export value added from other countries.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 218 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

Germany’s export growth is mainly due to growth in world trade, not increas- ing market share. 500 Increased market share World trade effect 400

300

200

100

0

–100

Italy India China Korea Spain Japan Poland Greece France Ireland Portugal Germany Malaysia

Netherlands United States

Figure 7.7 Contribution of World Trade Growth and Changes in Market Share to Export Increases, 15 Selected Countries Sources: UN Comtrade Database; and IMF staff estimates. Note: Increase in exports 2001–08, as percent of exports in 2001, decomposed into the effect of world trade growth and that of increased market share. Computed with Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) 4 level trade data.

The share of imports from China has grown rapidly from a low base.

Rest of the World 28%

European Union United States 60% 9% China 3%

Figure 7.8a Origin of German Imports, 2000 Source: UN Comtrade Database.

suggests that while all sectors contributed to increased current account surplus, the largest contributor was German corporate sector (Figure 7.9), which did not match a substantial increase in profits with increased investment despite the latter being consistently low. Germany’s corporate investment remained low compared

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 219

Rest of the World 27%

European United States Union 3% 56%

China 14%

Figure 7.8b Growth of Germany’s Imports, by Region 2000–2009 Source: UN Comtrade Database.

German investment has been low compared to EU peers even after accounting for outward foreign direct investment.

25 EU Germany 23

21

19

17

15

13

11

9 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009

Figure 7.9 Combined Domestic Corporate Investment (Gross) and Outward FDI , Germany and European Union (EU), 1999–2009 (Percent of GDP) Sources: Eurostat; and Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development. to European peers, even accounting for foreign direct investment (FDI) outflows. The reluctance to invest domestically reflects long-standing low returns to invest- ment in Germany, but pinning down particular policy distortions that could hold back investment is difficult. One possible explanation, consistent with the find- ings for the German labor market in the years preceding the 2008–09 crisis (Burda and Hunt, 2011), is manufacturing employers’ lack of confidence that the boom would last. The estimated potential growth in Germany remained low (close to 1 percent) during those years, and the companies chose to save a

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 220 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

TABLE 7.2 Germany: Potential Impact of the Selected Structural Reforms on the Current Account Change in the current account in percent of GDP Credit Market Deregulation to OECD average –0.5 Reduction in taxes and simplification of tax procedures to US rank –0.3 Reduction in gross unemployment replacement ratio to OECD average –0.4 Total –1.2

Source: IMF staff estimates.

substantial portion of the “windfall profits” while increasing investment only slowly.16 Nonetheless, the results of the estimation would suggest that in application to Germany, lower taxes on businesses, further reduction in the gross unemploy- ment replacement rate, and a smaller public share in the banking system could help reduce the surplus, albeit only moderately. Despite a comprehensive reform of the corporate income tax in 2008, the combined federal and local corporate tax rates in Germany remain above the OECD average. German unemployment benefits also remain rather generous. Public sector banks occupy an important place in the German system, more so than in other advanced economies. These banks have implicit government back- ing and low profitability. The package of measures, which includes scaling down the public provisioning of banking services, reducing unemployment benefits in the direction of the OECD average, and reducing and simplifying business taxes to move Germany to the U.S. rank in the ’s “Doing Business” indica- tor could reduce the surplus by about 1.25 percent of GDP. Reduction in taxes and unemployment benefits, however, should be undertaken in a way that does not jeopardize long-term fiscal sustainability goals.

CONCLUSION This chapter reported on my econometric investigation into the possible links between the current account balance and the commonly recommended package of structural policies, including financial regulation, tax policy, and labor market flexibility. I find little evidence that this set of policies contributed substantially to the emergence of global imbalances. The large imbalances likely reflected mainly a booming world economy. Moreover, while the structural factors might have helped shape the response of the current account to macroeconomic shocks and fundamentals, even in their role as shock absorbers/amplifiers those factors only partially account for the emergence of imbalances.

16 In addition, overall low private investment in the 2000s reflected a prolonged period of normaliza- tion in housing construction following the reunification boom and restructuring in the commercial real estate construction.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 221

Nonetheless, structural policies do help explain long-standing cross-country differences in the current account levels. While the results are not always robust, there is evidence that stricter credit market regulation—encompassing the degree of public ownership of the banking system, interest rate controls, percentage of credit extended to the private sector, and competition from foreign banks—is associated with a higher current account balance. Countries with higher taxes on businesses, generous unemployment benefits, lower minimum wage, and less strict employment protection also tend to have higher current account balances than others. To the extent that less developed countries tend to experience higher rates of growth, lowering the minimum wage is likely to be more effective in reducing the current account deficits of these countries than of advanced coun- tries. Some of the commonly proposed structural policies would reduce—while others would increase—the current account balance. These findings point to select structural measures tailored to the specific country circumstances, rather than a package of broad and diffuse structural policies, for addressing imbalances. It is also important to keep in mind that current account balance is not the only objective of policy makers, and the design of a policy package should take other objectives into account. For example, some of the policies that could lower the current account may increase inequality, which could be undesirable from the social point of view. In relation to Germany, which experienced a large increase in the current account surplus in mid-2000, these findings imply that the most promising ave- nues for Germany to pursue in reducing its current account surplus through structural policies is to lower the tax burden, liberalize the banking system to allow greater private sector participation, and reduce unemployment benefits. However, altogether, the impact of these structural policies on the surplus will likely be modest, so a broader strategy for raising potential growth and raising domestic consumption and investment in the medium term will be essential.

REFERENCES Abiad, A., D. Leigh, and A. Mody, 2009, “Finance and Convergence,” Economic Policy (April). Aleksynska, M., and M. Schindler, 2011, “Labor Market Regulations in Low-, Middle-, and High-Income Countries: A New Panel Database,” IMF Working Paper No. 11/154 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Barnes, S., J. Lawson, and A. Radziwill, 2010, “Current Account Imbalances in the Euro Area: A Comparative Perspective,” OECD Working Paper No. 826 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Bassani, A., and R. Duval, 2006, “Employment Patterns in OECD Countries: Reassessing the Role of Policies and Institutions,” OECD Social Employment and Migration Working Paper No.35 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Bayoumi, T., T. Oni, A. Vamvakidis, and F. Vitek, 2010, “How Far Do Differences in Financial Regulation Drive Global Imbalances?,” Mimeo (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Berger H., and V. Nitsch, 2010, “The Euro’s Effect on Trade Imbalances,” IMF Working Paper No. 10/226 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 222 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

Blanchard, O., and G. M. Milesi-Ferretti, 2009, “Global Imbalances: In Midstream?,” IMF SPN/09/29 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Burda, M.C., and J. Hunt, 2011, “What Explains the German Labor Market Miracle in the Great Recession,” NBER Working Paper No. 17187 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Chinn, M.D., B. Eichengreen, and H. Ito, 2011, “A Forensic Analysis of Global Imbalances,” La Follette School Working Paper No. 2011-007 (Madison, Wisconsin: University of Wisconsin). Chinn, M.D., and H. Ito, 2007, “Current Account Balances, Financial Development, and Institutions: Assaying the World ‘Savings Glut’,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 26, No. 4, pp. 546–69. ———, 2008, “A New Measure of Financial Openness,” Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis, Vol. 10, No. 3 (September), pp. 309–22. Chinn, M.D., and Prasad, E.S., 2003, “Medium-Term Determinants of Current Accounts in Industrial and Developing Countries: an Empirical Exploration,” NBER Working Paper No. 7581(Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Coeurdacier, N., S. Guibaud, and K. Jin, 2012, “Credit Constraints and Growth in a Global Economy,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 9109, available at http://www.cepr.org/pubs/new- dps/dplist.asp?dpno=9109. Jaumotte, F., and P. Sodsriwiboon, 2010, “Current Account Imbalances in the Southern Euro Area, IMF Working Paper No. 10/139 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Ju, J., and S.-J. Wei, 2007, “Current Account Adjustment: Some New Theory and Evidence,” NBER Working Paper No. 13388 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Kennedy, M., and T. Sløk, 2005, “Are Structural Reforms the Answer to Global Current Account Imbalances?,” OECD Economic Studies No. 41, 2005/2 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Kerdrain, C., I. Koske, and I. Wanner, 2010, “The Impact of Structural Policies on Savings, Investment and Current Accounts,” OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 815 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Lane, P., and G.M. Milessi-Ferretti, 2011, “External Adjustment and the Global Crisis,” IMF Working Paper No. 11/197 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Schwellnus, C., and J.M. Arnold, 2008, “Do Corporate Taxes Reduce Productivity and Investment at the Firm Level? Cross-Country Evidence from the Amadeus Dataset,” OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 641 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Vandenberg, P., 2010, “Impact of Labor Market Institutions on Unemployment: Results from a Global Panel,” ADB Economics Working Paper No. 219 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Vartia, L., 2008, “How Do Taxes Affect Investment and Productivity? An Industry-level Analysis of OECD Countries,” OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 656 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Vogel, L., 2011, “Structural Reforms and External Rebalancing in the Euro Area: A Model- Based Analysis,” European Commission Economic Paper No. 443 (July) (Brussels: European Commission).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 223

APPENDIX Data Description The analysis included a sample of 106 advanced, emerging, and developing coun- tries with populations exceeding one million. The OECD sample included 27 countries. The new EU member states are included starting from the year 1994 to avoid structural breaks. Most of the traditional variables determining the cur- rent account were computed following Abiad, Leigh, and Mody (2009). The current account as a ratio to GDP was taken from the Annual Macroeconomic Database (AMECO) of the European Commission’s Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs (http://ec.europa.eu/economy_ finance/indicators_en.htm) where available, and from the IMF’s World Economic Outlook (WEO) database in other cases. Income per capita is real PPP GDP per capita in 2005 constant prices with 1996 reference year from Penn World Tables 7.3 up to year 2007 (http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu). The rest of the years were extrapolated using per capita real GDP growth from the WEO database. Fiscal balance as a share of GDP was computed as general government net lending/ borrowing from the WEO database where available, otherwise general govern- ment overall fiscal balance was used from the same database. Net foreign assets as a ratio to GDP were computed as foreign assets minus foreign liabilities divided by GDP. All the variables are from the External Wealth of Nations (1970–2007) database, which can be downloaded from http://www.philiplane.org/EWN.html. Financial integration was computed as the sum of foreign assets and foreign lia- bilities divided by GDP from the same data source. Old (young) dependency ratios were computed using the data from the World Development Indicators (WDI) database. The old (young) dependency ratio was defined as the ratio of the population aged above 64 (below 15) relative to the population aged 15–64. The increase in the old dependency ratio was computed over the five-year period (see below) to capture the underlying demographic trend. Trade openness is calculated as the sum of exports and imports divided by GDP; it is obtained from the Penn World Tables 7.3 database (‘openc’/100). Oil price is taken from IMF’s WEO database. Several macroeconomic variables (current account to GDP ratio, GDP per capita growth, fiscal balance, oil price) were averaged over the 5-year non-overlapping periods, namely, 1975–79, 1980–84, 1985–89, 1990–94, 1995–99, 2000–04, and 2005–09. Other variables were included as of the year preceding the beginning of the five-year period, e.g. 2004 for the period 2005–09. Many of the variables were also included as the deviations from the PPP-weighted sample average (growth, fiscal balance, young and old dependency ratios) while real GDP per capita was computed as the ratio to the U.S. real GDP per capita in a given year. Credit market regulation is obtained from the Fraser Institute (http://www. freetheworld.com/) and comprises an index consisting of four components, mea- suring the degree of public ownership of the banking system, control of interest rates, percentage of credit extended to the private sector, and competition from foreign banks. The index ranges between zero and 10 with the higher values implying less regulation.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 224 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

The gross unemployment replacement rate is obtained from Aleksynska and Schindler (2011) and is the average of the gross unemployment replacement rates over two years of unemployment. The ratio of minimum wage to mean wage is taken from the same database. Employment protection indicator for OECD countries was obtained from the OECD database (http://www.oecd.org). For other countries, employment protection index was constructed as an out-of sample forecast from the regression of the OECD employment protection index on the measures of the stipu- lated advance notice period (in months) and severance pay after nine months (in months), which were obtained from Aleksynska and Schindler (2011). For OECD countries, central government corporate income tax rates were obtained from the OECD database. The corporate income tax rate comprises the basic central government statutory (flat or top marginal) corporate income tax rate, measured gross of a deduction if any for sub-central tax. The corporate income tax rate for other countries was obtained from the IMF Fiscal Affairs Corporate Income Tax rate database. The indicator of doing business paying taxes is a country’s rank among 183 countries based on the indicator that combines measures of the level of taxes and mandatory contributions that a medium-size company must pay in a given year with the measures of the administrative burden of paying taxes and contributions. The data is available at http://www.doingbusi- ness.org/rankings. Labor tax wedge for OECD countries is a total tax wedge of the average earner from the OECD database. It is computed as a combined central and sub-central government income tax plus employee and employer social security contribution taxes and expressed as a percentage of labor costs, defined as gross wage earnings plus employer social security contributions. The tax wedge is also adjusted for cash transfers. The indicators of product market regulation, regulation in energy transport and communication as well as regulation in professional ser- vices and retail trade are available only for OECD from the OECD database. The indicators of product market regulation are a comprehensive and interna- tionally comparable set of indicators that measure the degree to which policies promote or inhibit competition in areas of the product market. This indicator is available only for a subset of years, namely 1998, 2003, and 2008. When struc- tural variables were included as time-varying, the values for available years were assigned to the corresponding five-year periods. The OECD indicator of regula- tion in energy, transport and communications (ETCR) summarizes regulatory provisions in seven sectors: telecoms, electricity, gas, post, rail, air passenger transport, and road freight. While this indicator is not as broad as that of product market regulation, it is available as longer time-series, namely, annual data for the period 1975–2007 with gaps for some countries. The data in available years were attributed to the five-year periods. The indicator of regulation in professional services covers entry and conduct regulation in the legal, accounting, engineering, and architectural professions. The indicator of regulation in retail trade covers barriers to entry, operational restrictions, and price controls in retail distribution. Both of these indicators are available for the years 1996, 2003, and 2008 and in econometric analysis the data for available years were assigned to the corresponding five-year periods.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ivanova 225 ) (9) continued ( 1975–2009 (8) 1975–2009 verages over Five Year Year Five over verages A (7) 1975–2009 (6) 1975–2009 (5) 1975–2009 (4) 1975–2009 obust Standard Errors, Structural Variables are are Variables Structural Errors, obust Standard R (3) [–1.45] [–0.63] [–1.04] [–1.16] [–0.88] [–1.16] –0.0025 –0.0010 –0.0018 –0.0020 –0.0017 –0.0020 1975–2009 odel with M (2) [1.61] [1.73] [1.44] [1.71] [0.28] [–0.69] [0.28] [0.38] 0.0034 0.0035* 0.0031 0.0032* 0.0004 –0.0010 0.0004 0.0009 [–2.53] [–3.59] [–3.44] [–3.46] [–0.77] [–1.49] [–0.77] [–2.04] –0.0010** –0.0013*** –0.0011*** –0.0011*** –0.0003 –0.0005 –0.0003 –0.0010** 1975–2009 (1) [2.26] [3.28] [2.62] [2.61][2.29] [2.05] [2.07] [2.21] [2.09] [2.15] [2.73] [2.21] [1.42] [1.45] [0.89] [1.88] [0.89] [2.10] [2.91] [2.54] [2.19] [2.02] [0.96] [3.37] [2.28] [3.37] [3.35] [4.49] [4.36][4.56] [4.33] [4.42] [3.01] [3.73] [2.55] [2.42] [1.18] [2.84] [0.47] [1.13] [1.18] [0.21] [1.26] [1.13] [1.45] [–0.25] [1.03] [1.18][–0.54] [0.34][–0.82] [–0.67] [1.09] [–1.12] [–0.88] [1.09] [–0.64] [–0.43] [1.25] [–0.23] [1.25] [1.09] [0.25] [2.33] [1.41] [0.41] [2.08] [1.17] [2.33] [0.41] [0.31] [1.19] [–3.73] [–3.93] [–4.15] [–3.64] [–1.29] [0.20] [0.29] [0.20] [–2.09] –0.0002 0.0010 0.0012 0.0003–0.0138 0.0011–0.0080 –0.0177 0.0016 –0.0117 –0.0253 –0.0079 –0.0116 0.0020 –0.0033 0.0354 0.0016 0.0022 0.0699** 0.0022 0.0899** 0.0046 0.0699** 0.0146 0.0110 0.0046 0.0152 0.0146** 0.0197*** 0.0194*** 0.0253*** 0.0248** 0.0229** 0.0282**0.0005** 0.0229** 0.0004** 0.0005** 0.0196 0.0006*** 0.0003 0.0001 0.0003* 0.0001 0.0004** 0.0247*** 0.0236*** 0.0265***0.3853*** 0.0211*** 0.3782*** 0.0176** 0.3790*** 0.0107 0.1882** 0.2325*** 0.0047 0.1328 0.0107 0.0219 0.0083 0.1328 0.1450 1975–2009 andom Effects –0.3226*** –0.3400*** –0.3744*** –0.3810*** –0.1273 0.0191 0.0373 0.0191 –0.2631** R e c ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution il producer O b b,d c,d P c,d D a,b b,d c,d b P D b ccount and Structural Policies: and Structuralccount Policies: A P per capita D ld dependency ratio et foreign assets to G assets to et foreign Current Current Sample Total Periods, O integration Financial Fiscal balance to G to balance Fiscal openness Trade Increase in the old dependency 5 years ratio over 0.7330*** oil price* Contemporaneous 0.6511** 0.6117** 0.5964** 0.2593 0.6761*** 0.8173** 0.6761*** 1.0855*** Dependent variable=current account to GDP account to Dependent variable=current average) (5-year of G Log Credit market regulation Credit Financial integration*Previous period growth integration*Previous Financial Previous period growth Previous N Young dependency ratio Young TABLE 7A.1 TABLE 226 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence? (9) 1975–2009 (8) 1975–2009 verages over Five Year Year Five over verages A leksynska & Schindler, 2010). leksynska & Schindler, (7) A [–2.06] [–0.82] –0.0125** –0.0053 1975–2009 ession of the employment protection index on protection ession of the employment (6) [–1.31] [–1.92] [–1.31] [–1.23] –0.0169 –0.0271* –0.0169 –0.0194 1975–2009 (5) [0.78] [0.40] [–0.86] [0.40] 0.0002 0.0002 –0.0004 0.0002 1975–2009 emerging and developing countries ( countries and developing emerging r period. (4) [2.12] [1.49] [0.89] [1.79] [0.89] [1.60] 0.0572** 0.0421 0.0314 0.0816* 0.0314 0.0709 1975–2009 obust Standard Errors, Structural Variables are are Variables Structural Errors, obust Standard R (3) 1975–2009 odel with M (2) 1975–2009 (1) 1975–2009 andom Effects R ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution c,d escription for data sources. escription for D c,d,g ata c,d D c,d,f ) employment protection index was used. For a broader sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast from the regr from sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast a broader For index was used. protection employment P-weighted sample average. P-weighted D D EC O ccount and Structural Policies: and Structuralccount Policies: continued ( A countries countries F staff estimates, see F staff estimates, D M EC advance notice period and severance pay after 9 months. The latter two indicators are available for a large sample of advanced, a large for available are indicators two latter The after 9 months. pay period and severance notice advance O bservations 548 548 501 371 242 153 124 153 172 umber of countries 106 106 101 77 65 48 48 48 59 atio of minimum wage to mean wage atio of minimum wage to Current Current Sample Total Periods, eviation from a PPP G eviation from eviation from US level in a given year. in a given US level eviation from t the beginning of the period, for example for a 5-year period covering 2005–2009, 2004 value was used. period covering a 5-year example for for of the period, t the beginning Dependent variable=current account to GDP account to Dependent variable=current average) (5-year rate replacement Gross Corporate income tax rate income Corporate R Employment protection index protection Employment O N A D D

For For Financial Integration is one year before the beginning of a given 5-year period; growth is the average over the previous 5-yea the previous over is the average period; growth 5-year of a given the beginning before is one year Integration Financial

5-year period average. 5-year Gross replacement rate is the average over 2 years of unemployment. 2 years over is the average rate replacement Gross TABLE 7A.1 TABLE Source: I Source: a b c d e f g Ivanova 227 ) (9) continued continued ( 1995–2009 (8) 1975–1994 verages over the over verages A (7) 1975–2009 (6) 1975–2009 (5) 1975–2009 (4) 1975–2009 obust Standard Errors, Structural Variables are are Variables Structural Errors, obust Standard R (3) 1975–2009 odel with M (2) [2.73] [2.65] [2.16] [2.50] [2.80] [2.12] [1.15] [1.79] 0.0971*** 0.0998*** 0.0929** 0.0945** 0.1130*** 0.1007** 0.0511 0.1128* 1975–2009 (1) [2.06] [2.48] [2.38] [2.16] [2.15] [2.11] [2.08] [0.08] [1.83] [2.37] [2.13] [2.22] [3.13] [3.14] [2.92] [2.82] [1.90] [2.95] [1.17] [1.31] [1.35] [1.31] [1.31] [1.45][1.60] [1.51] [1.64] [0.26] [1.54] [–0.35] [0.72] [0.67] [0.98] [1.14] [1.23] [–0.09] [4.83] [3.58][4.58] [3.42][3.34] [2.90] [3.01] [2.47] [3.02] [3.00] [2.29] [2.39] [3.49] [2.49] [2.38] [3.65] [2.40] [2.31] [1.50] [3.11] [2.32] [2.99] [3.18] [2.23] [1.53] [1.59] [3.33] 0.0012 0.0014 0.0015 0.0016 0.0016 0.0017 0.00180.0034 0.0009 0.0032 –0.0009 0.0030 0.0016 0.0015 0.0023 0.0027 0.0098 –0.0002 [–0.80][–0.48] [–0.79] [0.25] [–0.66] [–0.88] [0.81] [–0.86] [1.00] [–0.76] [1.01] [–0.81] [0.63] [1.69] [0.52] [1.49] [–1.17] [1.06] [–2.16] [–3.11] [–2.70] [–2.29] [–2.58] [–3.07] [–2.81] [–0.04] [–1.44] [–4.07] [–4.46] [–4.39] [–4.93] [–4.92][–2.81] [–4.94] [–4.10] [–5.00] [–4.00] [–0.10] [–2.37] [–3.39] [–2.36] [–2.63] [–2.69] [0.33] [–1.35] –0.0211–0.0056 –0.0193 –0.0170 0.0032 –0.0236 0.0100 –0.0232 0.0114 –0.0191 0.0117 –0.0203 0.0080 0.0647* 0.0064 0.1191 –0.0169 0.0155 0.0004** 0.0005** 0.0005** 0.0005** 0.0005** 0.0005** 0.0005** 0.0000 0.0004* 0.0264*** 0.0205*** 0.0206***0.3941*** 0.0157*** 0.3123***0.0211*** 0.0158*** 0.3369*** 0.0187*** 0.0194** 0.3202** 0.0191*** 0.0193** 0.3201** 0.0130 0.0228** 0.2954** 0.0263*** 0.0226** 0.2925** 0.0277*** 0.1979** 0.0283*** 0.2683 0.0209 0.0611*** –0.0047** –0.0081*** –0.0080*** –0.0059** –0.0059*** –0.0070*** –0.0067*** –0.0001 –0.0088 1975–2009 andom Effects –0.3481*** –0.3966*** –0.4024*** –0.4652*** –0.4657*** –0.4644*** –0.4671*** –0.0167 –0.4961*** –0.0011*** –0.0013*** –0.0014*** –0.0013** –0.0013** –0.0013*** –0.0014*** 0.0012 –0.0006 R e c ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution il producer O b b,d d,f P c,d d,f,g D a,b b,d c,d b P D b ccount and Structural Policies: and Structuralccount Policies: A P per capita D ld dependency ratio et foreign assets to G assets to et foreign Current Current Sample Total Whole Period, Financial integration Financial Trade openness Trade Increase in the old dependency 5 years ratio over 0.6131** oil price* Contemporaneous 0.6208** 0.6741** 1.0845*** 1.0905*** 0.9556*** 0.9197*** 0.6809* 1.6603*** Gross replacement rate replacement Gross Fiscal balance to G to balance Fiscal period growth integration*Previous Financial Dependent variable=current account to GDP account to Dependent variable=current average) (5-year of G Log Young dependency ratio Young market regulation Credit Previous period growth Previous N O TABLE 7A.2 TABLE 228 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence? (9) 1995–2009 (8) 1975–1994 verages over the over verages A leksynska & Schindler, 2010). leksynska & Schindler, (7) A 1975–2009 ession of the employment protection index on protection ession of the employment (6) [1.82] [1.76] 0.0001* 0.0001* 1975–2009 (5) [–0.07] [–0.71] –0.0004 –0.0048 1975–2009 emerging and developing countries ( countries and developing emerging r period. (4) [–2.42] [–2.48] [–1.89] [–1.88] [–0.69] [–1.99] –0.0400** –0.0399** –0.0325* –0.0328* –0.0122 –0.0669** 1975–2009 obust Standard Errors, Structural Variables are are Variables Structural Errors, obust Standard R (3) [0.90] [2.15] [2.53] [0.54] [–0.67] 0.0005 0.0014** 0.0014** 0.0003 –0.0007 1975–2009 odel with M (2) 1975–2009 (1) 1975–2009 andom Effects R ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution d,f f escription for data sources. escription for D d,f,h ata d,f D ) employment protection index was used. For a broader sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast from the regr from sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast a broader For index was used. protection employment P-weighted sample average. sample average. P-weighted D D EC O ccount and Structural Policies: and Structuralccount Policies: continued ( A countries countries F staff estimates. See F staff estimates. D M EC advance notice period and severance pay after 9 months. The latter two indicators are available for a large sample of advanced, a large for available are indicators two latter The after 9 months. pay period and severance notice advance O bservations 532 426 400 323 323 349 349 114 118 oing business paying taxes rank taxes oing business paying umber of countries 101 78 73 60 60 65 65 43 59 atio of minimum wage to mean wage atio of minimum wage to Current Current Sample Total Whole Period, eviation from a PPP G eviation from eviation from US level in a given year. in a given US level eviation from t the beginning of the period, for example for a 5-year period covering 2005–2009, 2004 value was used. period covering a 5-year example for for of the period, t the beginning Dependent variable=current account to GDP account to Dependent variable=current average) (5-year tax rate income Corporate R Employment protection index protection Employment D O N A D D

Gross replacement rate is the average over 2 years of unemployment. 2 years over is the average rate replacement Gross For For Financial Integration is one year before the beginning of a given 5-year period; growth is the average over the previous 5-yea the previous over is the average period; growth 5-year of a given the beginning before is one year Integration Financial

5-year period average. 5-year Structural variable are country averages over all available years in a given period. in a given years all available Structural country over variable are averages TABLE 7A.2 TABLE Source: I Source: a b c d e f g h Ivanova 229 ) (9) continued continued ( 1995–2009 (8) 1975–1994 (7) 1975–2009 verages over the Whole Period, Whole Period, the over verages A (6) 1975–2009 (5) 1975–2009 (4) 1975–2009 (3) 1975–2009 obust Standard Errors, Structural Variables are are Variables Structural Errors, obust Standard R (2) [2.46] [2.30] [2.01] [2.46] [2.81] [2.00] [1.18] [1.70] 0.0789** 0.0760** 0.0768** 0.0798** 0.0955*** 0.0837* 0.0492 0.1009* 1975–2009 (1) [2.10] [3.29] [3.30] [2.57] [2.59] [2.41] [2.33] [0.43] [2.01] [1.16] [1.27] [1.50] [2.41] [2.41] [2.15] [1.98] [1.25] [2.71] [4.51] [2.90][4.31] [2.58][5.72] [3.34] [2.16] [4.47] [3.44] [2.09] [4.26] [2.62] [2.87] [4.16] [2.61] [3.07] [4.03] [2.55][2.95] [1.35] [4.78] [2.55] [2.69] [2.31] [4.74] [1.80] [2.71] [2.70] [1.59] [1.74] [3.47] [1.68] [1.91] [2.03] [1.50] [0.78] [1.72] [1.48] [1.43] [1.45] [1.44] [1.72] [1.79] [0.26] [–0.12] [–2.04] [–3.04] [–2.57] [–2.21] [–2.51] [–3.05] [–2.76] [–0.32] [–1.39] [–0.76][–0.54] [–1.03] [–0.01] [–0.88] [0.35] [–1.19] [–1.17] [0.48] [–1.16] [0.49] [–1.21] [0.43] [1.33] [0.29] [0.57] [–1.44] [1.67] [–3.35] [–4.19] [–3.91] [–5.12] [–5.13][–4.21] [–5.22] [–5.29] [–5.24] [–5.40] [–0.31] [–3.05] [–4.48] [–3.05] [–3.57] [–3.58] [0.26] [–2.15] 0.0017* 0.0016 0.0015 0.0018 0.0018 0.0020* 0.0021* 0.0009 –0.0003 –0.0204–0.0061 –0.0238 –0.0002 –0.0216 –0.0318 0.0042 –0.0313 0.0057 –0.0281 0.0060 –0.0294 0.0051 0.0502 0.0034 0.0442 –0.0184 0.0207 0.0005** 0.0006*** 0.0006*** 0.0005** 0.0005** 0.0005** 0.0005** 0.0002 0.0005** LS with Cluster LS with Cluster 0.0215*** 0.0149*** 0.0143**0.3643*** 0.0113** 0.3084***0.0339*** 0.0111** 0.3418*** 0.0347*** 0.0146*** 0.3219** 0.0354*** 0.0153*** 0.3222** 0.0383*** 0.0113 0.0386*** 0.2965** 0.0431*** 0.0202** 0.2910** 0.0429*** 0.1589* 0.0338***0.0061*** 0.0661*** 0.2666 0.0047*** 0.0048*** 0.0044* 0.0043* 0.0050* 0.0054** 0.0122 0.0027 –0.0039** –0.0069*** –0.0066** –0.0050** –0.0052** –0.0064*** –0.0061*** –0.0006 –0.0082 1975–2009 –0.3061*** –0.3373*** –0.3240*** –0.4374*** –0.4378*** –0.4487*** –0.4504*** –0.0533 –0.6214*** –0.0016*** –0.0015*** –0.0016*** –0.0017*** –0.0017*** –0.0018*** –0.0018*** 0.0009 –0.0014** O e c ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution il producer O b b,d d,f P c,d d,f,g D a,b b,d c,d b P D b ccount and Structural Policies: and Structuralccount Policies: A P per capita D ld dependency ratio et foreign assets to G assets to et foreign Current Current Sample Total Gross replacement rate replacement Gross Financial integration Financial Trade openness Trade Increase in the old dependency 5 years ratio over oil price* Contemporaneous 0.3301 0.4243 0.4938 0.8303** 0.8340** 0.7158** 0.6772* 0.4677 1.5275*** Dependent variable=current account to GDP account to Dependent variable=current average) (5-year of G Log Previous period growth Previous N O period growth integration*Previous Financial Young dependency ratio Young market regulation Credit Fiscal balance to G to balance Fiscal TABLE 7A.3 TABLE 230 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence? (9) 1995–2009 (8) 1975–1994 leksynska & Schindler, 2010). leksynska & Schindler, (7) A 1975–2009 verages over the Whole Period, Whole Period, the over verages A ession of the employment protection index on protection ession of the employment (6) [1.74] [1.68] 0.0001* 0.0001* 1975–2009 (5) [–0.19] [–0.70] –0.0010 –0.0043 1975–2009 emerging and developing countries ( countries and developing emerging r period. (4) [–2.30] [–2.36] [–1.80] [–1.81] [–0.53] [–2.13] –0.0348** –0.0344** –0.0287* –0.0293* –0.0089 –0.0684** 1975–2009 (3) [1.23] [1.75] [2.00] [0.36] [–0.52] 0.0006 0.0010* 0.0010* 0.0002 –0.0005 1975–2009 obust Standard Errors, Structural Variables are are Variables Structural Errors, obust Standard R (2) 1975–2009 (1) LS with Cluster LS with Cluster 1975–2009 O ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution d,f f escription for data sources. escription for D d,f,h ata d,f D ) employment protection index was used. For a broader sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast from the regr from sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast a broader For index was used. protection employment P-weighted sample average. P-weighted D D EC O ccount and Structural Policies: and Structuralccount Policies: continued ( A countries countries F staff estimates. See F staff estimates. D M LS: ordinary least squares standard linear regression procedure. linear regression LS: ordinary standard least squares EC O advance notice period and severance pay after 9 months. The latter two indicators are available for a large sample of advanced, a large for available are indicators two latter The after 9 months. pay period and severance notice advance O bservations 532 426 400 323 323 349 349 114 118 oing business paying taxes rank taxes oing business paying atio of minimum wage to mean wage atio of minimum wage to -squared 0.371 0.399 0.401 0.368 0.368 0.363 0.361 0.311 0.549 Current Current Sample Total eviation from a PPP G eviation from eviation from US level in a given year. in a given US level eviation from t the beginning of the period, for example for a 5-year period covering 2005-2009, 2004 value was used. period covering a 5-year example for for of the period, t the beginning Dependent variable=current account to GDP account to Dependent variable=current average) (5-year tax rate income Corporate R Employment protection index protection Employment D O R ote: ote: A D D

Gross replacement rate is the average over 2 years of unemployment. 2 years over is the average rate replacement Gross For For Financial Integration is one year before the beginning of a given 5-year period; growth is the average over the previous 5-yea the previous over is the average period; growth 5-year of a given the beginning before is one year Integration Financial

5-year period average. 5-year Structural variable are country averages over all available years in a given period. in a given years all available Structural country over variable are averages TABLE 7A.3 TABLE Source: I Source: N a b c d e f g h Ivanova 231 ) (8) continued continued ( 1975–2009 (7) 1975–2009 verages over Five Year Year Five over verages A (6) 1975–2009 (5) 1975–2009 (4) [0.32] [–0.16] [–0.46] [0.46] [0.83] 0.0090 –0.0043 –0.0128 0.0282 0.0384 1975–2009 (3) [0.09] [0.15] [–0.73] [–0.69] [0.27] [0.20] 0.0002 0.0004 –0.0027 –0.0020 0.0016 0.0014 1975–2009 obust Standard Errors, Structural Variables are are Variables Structural Errors, obust Standard R (2) [0.08] [0.06] [–0.22] [–0.23] [–1.49] [–2.28] [–1.10] 0.0002 0.0001 –0.0004 –0.0004 –0.0017 –0.0029** –0.0018 [–2.07] [–1.98] [–1.97] [–1.59] [–1.35] [–2.04] [–3.81] –0.0008** –0.0008** –0.0007** –0.0006 –0.0004 –0.0007** –0.0010*** 1975–2009 odel with M (1) [1.41][0.05] [1.35] [–0.47] [1.33] [–0.46] [1.50] [–0.27][0.94] [1.31] [–0.28] [0.81] [2.32] [0.66] [0.80] [3.96] [0.40] [0.34] [5.90] [–0.55] [0.45] [0.64] [1.61] [0.53] [2.05] [2.28][2.21] [2.12] [2.16] [1.94] [2.16][2.14] [2.29] [2.24] [1.98] [0.89] [2.70] [1.88] [0.80] [1.66] [2.76] [0.92] [0.69] [2.33] [0.67] [1.94] [1.61] [1.21] [1.95][1.97] [2.18] [1.76] [2.00] [1.76] [2.71] [1.89] [3.44] [1.85] [2.96] [4.05] [3.61] [4.00] [3.36] [4.19] 0.02910.0055 0.0307 –0.0562 0.0304 –0.0588 0.0348 –0.0376 0.03100.0002 –0.0430 0.0311** 0.0002 0.0862 0.0530*** 0.0002 0.0692*** 0.0525 0.0001 –0.1104 0.0001 0.0001 0.0002 0.0001 [–1.09] [–0.21] [–0.27] [–0.31] [–0.97] [0.37] [0.56] [0.70] 0.0261* 0.0295** 0.0295** 0.0346*** 0.0420*** 0.0380*** 0.0527*** 0.0534*** –0.0021 –0.0005 –0.0005 –0.0007 –0.0022 0.0006 0.0012 0.0015 0.0372** 0.0401** 0.0402**0.2813** 0.0384* 0.2814** 0.0444** 0.2796** 0.2928** 0.01270.1513** 0.3608*** 0.1422** 0.0140 0.3052* 0.1447* 0.0207 0.1279 0.1843*** 0.1483** 0.1275 0.0994* 0.1431 0.1367 1975–2009 andom Effects R e c ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution il producer O b b,d c,d P c,d c,d,f D a,b b,d c,d b P Sample D D b EC ccount and Structural Policies: and Structuralccount Policies: O A P per capita D ld dependency ratio et foreign assets to G assets to et foreign Current Current Periods, O dependency ratio Young integration Financial Previous period growth Previous N openness Trade Fiscal balance to G to balance Fiscal Credit market regulation Credit Financial integration*Previous period growth integration*Previous Financial Gross replacement rate replacement Gross Dependent variable=current account to GDP (5-year average) GDP (5-year account to Dependent variable=current of G Log Increase in the old dependency 5 years ratio over oil price* Contemporaneous 0.5264** 0.4982* 0.4958* 0.5353* 0.5232* 0.9795*** 1.5232*** 1.6074*** TABLE 7A.4 TABLE 232 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence? (8) [0.72] 0.0048 1975–2009 (7) [–0.39] [–1.14] –0.0041 –0.0121 1975–2009 verages over Five Year Year Five over verages A leksynska & Schindler, 2010). leksynska & Schindler, (6) A [0.77] [–0.09] [–1.25] 0.0192 –0.0020 –0.0271 1975–2009 ession of the employment protection index on protection ession of the employment (5) [0.61] [0.90] [0.52] [0.07] 0.0003 0.0006 0.0005 0.0001 1975–2009 (4) emerging and developing countries ( countries and developing emerging 1975–2009 r period. (3) 1975–2009 obust Standard Errors, Structural Variables are are Variables Structural Errors, obust Standard R (2) 1975–2009 odel with M (1) 1975–2009 andom Effects R c,4 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution c,d escription for data sources. escription for D c,d,g ata c,d D ) employment protection index was used. For a broader sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast from the regr from sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast a broader For index was used. protection employment P-weighted sample average. sample average. P-weighted D D Sample EC D O EC ccount and Structural Policies: and Structuralccount Policies: continued O ( A countries countries F staff estimates. See F staff estimates. D M EC advance notice period and severance pay after 9 months. The latter two indicators are available for a large sample of advanced, a large for available are indicators two latter The after 9 months. pay period and severance notice advance O bservations 160 160 160 148 142 97 68 66 umber of countries 27 27 27 26 26 19 19 19 atio of minimum wage to mean wage atio of minimum wage to egulation in energy transportegulation in energy and communication Current Current Periods, eviation from a PPP G eviation from eviation from US level in a given year. in a given US level eviation from t the beginning of the period, for example for a 5-year period covering 2005–2009, 2004 value was used. period covering a 5-year example for for of the period, t the beginning Dependent variable=current account to GDP (5-year average) GDP (5-year account to Dependent variable=current tax rate income Corporate R Employment protection index protection Employment R O N A D D

For For Financial Integration is one year before the beginning of a given 5-year period; growth is the average over the previous 5-yea the previous over is the average period; growth 5-year of a given the beginning before is one year Integration Financial

5-year period average. 5-year Gross replacement rate is the average over 2 years of unemployment. 2 years over is the average rate replacement Gross TABLE 7A.4 TABLE Source: I Source: a b c d e f g Ivanova 233 ) (11) continued continued ( 1975–2009 (10) 1975–2009 verages over the Whole the over verages A (9) 1975–2009 (8) 1975–2009 (7) 1975–2009 (6) 1975–2009 (5) obust Standard Errors, Structural Variables are are Variables Structural Errors, obust Standard R 1975–2009 (4) odel with 1975–2009 M (3) [–0.63] [0.99] [1.18] [0.81] [1.24] [1.41] [1.38] –0.0004 0.0011 0.0012 0.0006 0.0008 0.0011 0.0011 1975–2009 andom Effects R (2) [0.81] [0.79] [0.58] [1.95] [2.00] [1.87] [2.01] [2.00] [2.27] [1.82] 0.0367 0.0360 0.0226 0.0804* 0.0821** 0.0785* 0.0808** 0.0821** 0.0823** 0.0777* 1975–2009 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution (1) [1.67] [1.30] [1.33] [0.62] [0.30] [0.71] [1.16] [0.76] [0.71] [0.67] [0.65] [1.34] [1.44] [1.30] [4.42][0.81] [4.82][0.06] [0.78] [5.29] [–0.03] [0.78] [4.49] [–0.11] [0.66] [4.57] [–0.99] [0.53] [–1.41] [5.29] [0.25] [–1.42] [5.74] [0.94] [–1.03] [5.44] [–1.07] [1.08] [–1.42] [0.25] [–1.21] [0.99] [–1.06] [0.65] [2.13] [1.98][1.96] [1.94][2.10] [2.08] [0.59][1.75] [2.38] [2.08] [0.48] [1.65] [2.29] [1.41] [0.51] [1.64] [2.88] [1.96] [0.72] [2.00] [3.11] [2.14] [0.65] [1.89] [2.89] [1.87] [0.51] [1.94] [3.55] [1.45] [0.55] [2.22] [3.36] [2.14] [0.59] [2.14] [2.89] [1.80] [1.94] [3.61] [1.69] [2.09] [3.41] [2.07] 0.0302 0.0330 0.0310 0.0612*** 0.0641***0.0002 0.0666*** 0.00020.0001 0.0665*** 0.0712*** –0.0001 0.0001 0.0666*** –0.0002 0.0001 0.0728*** –0.0014 0.0720*** 0.0001 –0.0017 0.0000 –0.0018 0.0002 –0.0015 0.0002 –0.0015 0.0000 –0.0018 –0.0015 0.0002 –0.0014 0.0001 [–1.88] [–1.84] [–1.55] [–3.05] [–3.28] [–3.57] [–2.94] [–2.97] [–3.57] [–3.21] [–2.72] [–0.23] [–0.42] [–0.46][–0.47] [0.08] [–0.72] [–0.70] [0.16] [–1.77] [0.10] [–1.73] [0.19] [–1.69] [0.31][–0.02] [–2.64] [0.10] [0.10] [–3.07] [0.33] [–1.69] [0.20] [0.30] [–2.83] [–0.06] [–3.62] [–0.67] [–0.44] [–0.16] [–0.22] [–0.44] [–1.03] [–0.72] 0.0407* 0.0302 0.0314 0.0168 0.0089 0.0185 0.0227 0.0153 0.0185 0.0133 0.0113 0.4963* 0.4769* 0.4774 0.7237** 0.7191* 0.7086* 1.0304** 0.9610** 0.7086* 0.9749** 0.9351** –0.0005 –0.0010 –0.0012–0.0606 0.0002 –0.0893 0.0004 –0.0911 –0.2026* 0.0002 –0.2107* 0.0005 –0.2047* 0.0007 –0.3575*** –0.4064*** 0.0002–0.0001 –0.2047* 0.0007 –0.3607*** 0.0006 –0.3429*** 0.0007 0.0013 –0.0003 –0.0039 –0.0032 –0.0011 –0.0012 –0.0032 –0.0044 –0.0031 0.2807** 0.2643** 0.2612*0.1438** 0.08930.0299** 0.1384** 0.0321** 0.0746 0.1435** 0.0321** 0.0557 0.0795 0.0373*** 0.0612* 0.1092 0.0377*** 0.0719** 0.0378*** 0.0971 0.0385*** 0.0503* 0.0795 0.0323*** 0.0389 0.0717 0.0378*** 0.0719** 0.0360*** 0.0831 0.0465* 0.0388*** 0.0491* –0.0008* –0.0007* –0.0006 –0.0009*** –0.0009*** –0.0010*** –0.0012*** –0.0013*** –0.0010*** –0.0012*** –0.0011*** 1975–2009 il O d,f b b,d d,f P c,d d,f,7 D a,b b,d c,d Sample b P D D b ccount and Structural Policies: and Structuralccount Policies: EC e A O P per capita c D ld dependency ratio et foreign assets to G assets to et foreign Current Current Period, Previous period growth Previous Credit market regulation Credit Corporate income tax rate income Corporate Dependent variable=current Dependent variable=current average) GDP (5-year account to of G Log O integration Financial integration*Previous Financial period growth N openness Trade in the old Expected increase dependency ratio oil price* Contemporaneous producer Fiscal balance to G to balance Fiscal dependency ratio Young rate replacement Gross TABLE 7A.5 TABLE 234 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence? (11) 1975–2009 (10) 1975–2009 verages over the Whole the over verages A (9) 1975–2009 leksynska & Schindler, 2010). leksynska & Schindler, A (8) ession of the employment protection index on advance index on advance protection ession of the employment [1.43] 0.0097 1975–2009 (7) [1.15] [0.97][0.41][0.83] [0.64] [1.40] [1.41] [0.50] 0.0007 0.00060.00200.0139 0.0029 0.0007 0.0006 0.0021 [–1.08] [–0.67] [–0.55] –0.0058 –0.0041 –0.0029 1975–2009 g and developing countries ( countries g and developing r period. (6) [0.26] [0.26] 0.0000 0.0000 1975–2009 (5) [–1.72] [–1.48] [–2.06] [–2.43] [–1.48] [–2.02] [–2.04] obust Standard Errors, Structural Variables are are Variables Structural Errors, obust Standard –0.0121* –0.0123 –0.0126** –0.0150** –0.0123 –0.0134** –0.0134** R 1975–2009 (4) [–3.00] [–3.42] [–2.96] [–3.99] [–4.70] [–2.96] [–3.83] [–4.15] odel with –0.0386*** –0.0468*** –0.0483*** –0.0649*** –0.0658*** –0.0483*** –0.0507*** –0.0511*** 1975–2009 M (3) 1975–2009 andom Effects R (2) 1975–2009 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution (1) 1975–2009 escription for data sources. escription for D f d,f ata D d,f,h ) d,f employment protection index was used. For a broader sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast from the regr from sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast a broader For index was used. protection employment d,f P-weighted sample average. sample average. P-weighted D D EC Sample d,f O D d,f ccount and Structural Policies: and Structuralccount Policies: EC continued ( A O countries countries F staff estimates. See F staff estimates. D M d,f EC notice period and severance pay after 9 months. The latter two indicators are available for a large sample of advanced, emergin sample of advanced, a large for available are indicators two latter The after 9 months. pay period and severance notice O bservations 160 157 157 115 115 115 115 115 115 115 115 oing business paying taxes rank taxes oing business paying umber of countries 27 26 26 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 atio of minimum wage to mean atio of minimum wage to egulation in retail trade egulation in retail egulation in energy transportegulation in energy egulation in professional services egulation in professional Current Current Period, eviation from a PPP G eviation from eviation from US level in a given year. in a given US level eviation from t the beginning of the period, for example for a 5-year period covering 2005–2009, 2004 value was used. period covering a 5-year example for for of the period, t the beginning D Dependent variable=current Dependent variable=current average) GDP (5-year account to R wage O N R and communication R market regulation Product R Labor tax wedge Employment protection index protection Employment A D D

Gross replacement rate is the average over 2 years of unemployment. 2 years over is the average rate replacement Gross For For Financial Integration is one year before the beginning of a given 5-year period; growth is the average over the previous 5-yea the previous over is the average period; growth 5-year of a given the beginning before is one year Integration Financial

5-year period average. 5-year Structural variable are country averages over all available years in a given period. in a given years all available Structural country over variable are averages TABLE 7A.5 TABLE a b c d e f g h Source: I Source: Ivanova 235 ) (5) continued continued ( 1995–2009 (4) 1975–1994 (3) 1975–2009 obust Standard Errors, Structural Errors, obust Standard R (2) odel with 1975–2010 M (1) [2.53] [3.17][2.43][2.41] [2.74] [2.17] [2.26] [2.55] [1.45] [5.44] [2.07] [1.81][2.26] [2.19] [1.69] [1.84] [5.03] [2.39][2.38] [–0.63] [3.12] [1.69] [4.41] [0.81] [3.91] [0.60] [0.96] [1.24][0.73] [0.49][3.16] [0.75] [–1.60] [2.98][0.90] [0.45] [3.29] [1.12] [–1.00] [0.96] [2.37] [0.51] [2.48] [1.16] [–1.14] [2.81] [1.72] [2.10] [0.39] [–0.53] 0.0011 0.0011 0.00160.0083 0.0012 0.0078 –0.0037 0.0020 0.0050 0.0048 –0.0171 0.0018 0.0102 0.0099 –0.0020 [–0.89] [–0.50] [–1.04] [1.22] [0.80] [–2.16][–2.34] [–1.37] [–2.58] [–3.35] [–3.11] [0.03] [–0.34] [–0.21] [–2.79] [–4.86] [–5.33] [–5.21] [–0.14] [–3.48] –0.0238 –0.0133 –0.0265 0.0463 0.0566 0.0130** 0.0169***0.3104** 0.0134***0.0237** 0.3107** 0.0111 0.0293** 0.2846** 0.0424*** 0.0200** 0.1732* 0.0268** 0.2735* 0.0005** 0.0769*** 0.0004* 0.0005**0.0843** –0.0002 0.1608*** 0.0004* 0.1275*** 0.0385 0.1962*** 0.0015*** 0.0011* 0.0011** 0.0003 –0.0004 –0.0013**–0.0053** –0.0007 –0.0110*** –0.0014*** –0.0059*** 0.0001 –0.0008 –0.0001 –0.0105*** 1975–2009 –0.4416*** –0.4878*** –0.4353*** –0.0229 –0.4896*** andom Effects R e c ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution il producer O d,f b b,d d,f P c,d d,f,g D a,b b,d c,d b P verages over the Whole Period, Total Sample Total Whole Period, the over verages D A b ccount and Structural Policies (interaction with fundamentals): (interaction with and Structuralccount Policies A P per capita D ld dependency ratio et foreign assets to G assets to et foreign Variables are are Variables Current Current Dependent variable=current account to GDP (5-year average) GDP (5-year account to Dependent variable=current of G Log Previous period growth Previous N O integration Financial tax rate income Corporate Trade openness Trade Credit market regulation Credit rate replacement Gross Fiscal balance to G to balance Fiscal Increase in the old dependency 5 years ratio over oil price* Contemporaneous period growth integration*Previous Financial 1.0614*** 1.0954*** 1.0508*** 0.8079** 1.5315** Young dependency ratio Young TABLE 7A.6 TABLE 236 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence? (5) 1995–2009 (4) 1975–1994 leksynska & Schindler, 2010). leksynska & Schindler, A (3) [4.66] [0.86] [2.44] ession of the employment protection index on protection ession of the employment 0.2037*** 0.0632 0.2415** 1975–2009 obust Standard Errors, Structural Errors, obust Standard R (2) odel with [1.30] 0.0130 1975–2010 M emerging and developing countries ( countries and developing emerging s used. r period. (1) 60 60 60 44 59 323 323 323 116 118 [1.26] [1.96] [0.57] [0.72] 0.0003 0.0004** 0.0001 0.0003 [–0.07][–0.30] [–1.32][–1.43] [–0.62][–0.19] [0.30] [–2.17] [–0.03] [–1.21] [–2.05] [–2.26] [–2.24] [–2.75] [–2.01] [–3.37] [–2.66] [–3.43] [–2.07] [–1.98] –0.0004–0.0002 –0.0089–0.0145 –0.0027 0.0018–0.0003 –0.0166** –0.0002 –0.0115 –0.0257** –0.0119** –0.0110** –0.0136*** –0.0199** 1975–2009 –0.0495*** –0.0462*** –0.0460*** –0.0388** –0.0565** andom Effects R c,d,f b,d,f c,d,f,h c,d,f c,d,f b,d,f,g P c,d,f,g D ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution b,d,f,g d,f escription for data sources. escription for D d,f,h ata D et foreign assets to G assets to et foreign N ) employment protection index was used. For a broader sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast from the regr from sample an index was constructed as an out-of-sample forecast a broader For index was used. protection employment P-weighted sample average. sample average. P-weighted D verages over the Whole Period, Total Sample Total Whole Period, the over verages D EC A O egulation*Previous period growth egulation*Previous R ccount and Structural Policies (interaction with fundamentals): (interaction with and Structuralccount Policies continued ( A arket countries countries F staff estimates. See F staff estimates. M D M EC advance notice period and severance pay after 9 months. The latter two indicators are available for a large sample of advanced, a large for available are indicators two latter The after 9 months. pay period and severance notice advance O bservations umber of countries atio of minimum wage to mean wage atio of minimum wage to atio of minimum wage to mean wage*Financial integration mean wage*Financial atio of minimum wage to atio of minimum wage to mean wage*Previous period growth mean wage*Previous atio of minimum wage to Variables are are Variables Current Current eviation from a PPP G eviation from eviation from US level in a given year. in a given US level eviation from Dependent variable=current account to GDP (5-year average) GDP (5-year account to Dependent variable=current R rate* replacement Gross Gross replacement rate*Trade openness rate*Trade replacement Gross Crerdit Crerdit period growth rate*Previous replacement Gross period growth tax rate*Previous income Corporate R Employment protection index*Previous period growth index*Previous protection Employment R O N Employment protection index protection Employment D D Fundamentals are included as of the beginning of the period, for example for a 5-year period covering 2005–2009, 2004 value wa period covering a 5-year example for for of the period, included as of the beginning are Fundamentals

Gross replacement rate is the average over 2 years of unemployment. 2 years over is the average rate replacement Gross For For Financial Integration is one year before the beginning of a given 5-year period; growth is the average over the previous 5-yea the previous over is the average period; growth 5-year of a given the beginning before is one year Integration Financial

Fundamentals are included as 5-year period averages. included as 5-year are Fundamentals Structural variable are country averages over all available years in a given period. in a given years all available Structural country over variable are averages TABLE 7A.6 TABLE Source: I Source: a b c d e f g h Ivanova 237 NA OECD Average escription for more detailed information. more escription for D ata D France SpainFrance Japan Germany facto floor may be higher as wages are set by collective bargaining bargaining collective set by be higher as wages are facto floor may a es but the series ended in 2005. The table presents unemployment net unemployment table presents The es but the series ended in 2005. combined corporate income tax rate, including sub-central tax rates, which provides a including sub-central which provides tax rate, income tax rates, corporate combined United United States leksynska Schindler (2011). See and A countries up to 2008. up to countries D EC year O 20082009 7.7 392008 9.2 55 34 9.32005 66 30 0.3 8.9 61 40 0.5 8.2 54 30 0.2 9.0 60 26 0.4 56 0.0 0.3 Latest Latest available available ); Business Indicators; and D EC O evelopment ( evelopment D c ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution d b ate R ate R ean Wage M egulation 2008 0.2 2.5 2.5 1.9 3.0 2.2 a R eplacement eplacement R rganisation for Economic Co-operation Economic for and rganisation O egulation etail Trade 2008 2.6 3.1 2.7 2.4 2.4 2.4 R R arket regulation 2008 0.8 1.5 1.0 1.1 1.3 1.4 inimum Wage inimum Wage to arket M M M better assessment of the actual on corporations. better tax burden agreements and enforceable by law. by and enforceable agreements replacement ratio for a single person, no children, at 100 percent of average wage, which is available for for which is available wage, of average at 100 percent a single person, no children, ratio for replacement oing business rank on paying taxesoing business rank on paying 2009 54 55 86 115 80 verage Labor Tax Wedge (single earner w/o children at 100 percent of average wage) of average at 100 percent (single earner w/o children Wedge Tax Labor verage 2009 29 49 38 29 51 36 atio of egulation in Energy Transport and CommunicationTransport egulation in Energy 2007 1.8 2.2 1.6 2.2 1.1 2.1 egulation in Professional Servicesegulation in Professional egulation in 2008 1.1 2.1 2.1 1.5 2.9 2.0 Structural in Comparison Indicators: Germany Employment Protection Protection Employment R R Credit Credit Unemployment Gross Gross Unemployment R R D Combined Corporate Income Tax Tax Income Corporate Combined A Product The regression included federal corporate income tax rate, which was available for a wide set of countries. The table presents The a wide set of countries. for which was available tax rate, income corporate included federal regression The While Germany has no minimum wage in most sectors except for construction workers, electrical workers and some others, the de electrical and some others, workers construction workers, for has no minimum wage in most sectors except While Germany Higher value means less regulated. For the United States the index declined from 8.9 to 7.7 between 2007 and 2008. 7.7 between 8.9 to the index declined from States the United For Higher value means less regulated. The regression included a two-year average unemployment gross replacement ratio, which was available for a wide set of countri for which was available ratio, replacement gross unemployment average included a two-year regression The TABLE 7A.7 TABLE Sources: Fraser Institute; Fraser Sources: a b c d 238 Current Account Imbalances: Can Structural Policies Make a Diff erence?

EU and Germany: Corporate Savings EU and Germany: Corporate Investment (Net, percent of GDP) (Net, percent of GDP) 5 5 European Union European Union 4 Germany 4 Germany

3 3 2 2 1

1 0

−1 0 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

EU and Germany: Household Savings EU and Germany: Household Investment (Net, percent of GDP) (Net, percent of GDP) 8.0 4 European Union 7.5 European Union 7.0 Germany Germany 3 6.5 6.0 5.5 2 5.0 4.5 1 4.0 3.5 3.0 0 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

EU and Germany: Government Savings EU and Germany: Government Investment (Net, percent of GDP) (Net, percent of GDP) 2 1.2 European Union 1 Germany European Union 0.8 Germany 0

−1 0.4 −2

−3 0.0 −4

−5 −0.4 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Figure 7A.1 Germany and EU: Savings and Investment by Sector, 1999–2009 Source: Eurostat.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CHAPTER 8 Discussion

Comment on Chapters 2 and 3

MALTE HÜBNER

Martin Schindler’s chapter (Chapter 2) addresses a highly relevant topic. Two years ago, the German Council of Economic Experts (GCEE), along with many others, was very concerned that the crisis could have an adverse impact on long-term growth. The concern was that financing costs would rise and remain high over a sustained period, slowing down growth and increasing long- term unemployment. Another concern was that rushed policy responses could harm potential growth (GCEE, 2009). It is therefore reassuring to read Martin Schindler with two years of development behind us. He finds that potential output in Germany has remained almost unaffected by the financial crisis. This, he concludes, is the consequence of the specific nature of the shock that Germany faced: a temporary drop in external demand. I fully agree with this analysis. Before taking a closer look at Schindler’s results, it is important to note, as he does, that potential output can be measured by a variety of methods, each with its strengths and weaknesses. He is rightly concerned about univariate approach- es, which can mislead, especially in times of drastic change. However, it is impor- tant to assess the robustness of findings from any particular approach. This is what I do here. To check the plausibility of the results, I am going to compare his results with the GCEE’s estimations, which I carried out with a production func- tion approach (GCEE, 2011). For the period from 2005 to 2011, the GCEE’s production function approach leads to results very similar to Schindler’s. There are small differences between both estimates, but they are natural, given that the results have been obtained with different methods (Figure 8.1a). But importantly, there is little indication of a decline in potential growth relative to the precrisis average. For the medium term, Schindler is a little bit more optimistic than the GCEE. It is interesting to briefly consider why this is the case. Consider the decomposition of the GCEE’s potential growth projection (Figure 8.1b). The GCEE expects a negative contribution to potential growth from the labor force from 2014 onwards, with the dampening of the labor contribution due

Malte Hübner is an economist at the German Council of Economic Experts. 239

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 240 Discussion

3.0 IMF estimate GCEE estimate

2.0

1.0

0.0 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016

−1.0

Figure 8.1a Potential Growth (In percent)

3.0 Hours worked Capital stock Total factor productivity

2.0

1.0

0.0 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015

−1.0

Figure 8.1b Contributions to Growth (GCEE estimates, 2010, percent) Sources: German Council of Economic Experts (GCEE); and IMF staff calculations.

to ageing and shrinking of the population already evident in prior years. This estimate already relies on fairly optimistic assumptions, for instance that unemployment can decrease further without causing an acceleration in infla- tion and that net migration inflows will add 200,000 persons per year to the workforce. The slightly higher potential growth rates in Schindler’s estimate are thus most likely caused by other determinants of potential output, such as faster capital accumulation or a rise in total factor productivity growth. Both developments are plausible. For instance, it is conceivable that Germans are

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Discussion 241 beginning to channel savings, which previously fueled housing price bubbles in the European periphery, into domestic investments, thus increasing the pace of capital accumulation. The GCEE’s findings also reinforce Schindler’s conclusion that medium-term growth prospects for Germany are moderate at best, despite the stability of poten- tial output during the crisis. Should total factor productivity continue to grow at the average rate of the last decade, potential growth in the medium-term may only range from 0.8 to 1.2 percentage points per year (GCEE, 2011). It is there- fore important to bring the issue of productivity growth back on the agenda. Chapter 3 in this volume, by Helene Poirson, does exactly this. Poirson shows that productivity growth in Germany declined relative to the United States between 1995 and 2004, reflecting faster capital accumulation and more rapid TFP growth in the United States. The period of strong TFP growth in the United States was correlated with high levels of investment in ICT, where- as slow TFP growth in Germany coincided with relatively modest investment in ICT, suggesting that lack of ICT investment caused the meager productivity performance in Germany. However, there is always the problem of separating correlation from causa- tion. Possibly, firms in the United States were more productive in the first place, and more productive firms simply invested more in ICT. Moreover, since 2005, there was a resurgence in productivity growth in Germany’s market sec- tor without a corresponding increase in ICT investment, as Poirson discusses. Of course, TFP growth after 2005 might have been driven by cyclical factors, but overall, the developments after 2005 suggest a cautious interpretation of the data. The reference to the link between ICT adoption and productivity growth reflects state-of-the-art thinking about the reasons for the poor productivity per- formance in Europe as compared with the United States. Putting aside the issue of how firmly this link is established, Poirson makes some important suggestions about how to foster ICT adoption in Germany. I see this as the main innovation in Poirson’s approach. I find the proposal to foster ICT adoption by public procurement most inter- esting. However, I am skeptical. The link between government procurement of ICT and ICT adoption in the private sector does not strike me as firmly estab- lished. I do agree, however, that public demand might generate economies of scale that would foster ICT adoption in the private sector. There is always the question of why the market on its own should not be able to adopt technologies that are produced with economies of scale. My main con- cern with using public procurement to foster ICT adoption is that it may invite ICT producers to rent-seeking activities. The government might be persuaded to procure ICT products by claiming that this might benefit ICT adoption in the private sector. For this reason, I would be careful about setting objectives other than enhancing public sector productivity when deciding on the level of public sector investment in ICT.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 242 Discussion

Improving Germany’s education would be an alternative way to foster ICT adoption. A substantial literature provides evidence that high-skilled workers facili- tate ICT adoption (see Doms et al. 1997 for an analysis at the macro level and Arvanitis, 2005; Bresnahan, Brynjolfsson, and Hitt, 2002; Fabiani, Schivardi, and Trento, 2005 for the firm-level). Currently, demographic trends are beginning to cause the German workforce to shrink. This process will accelerate once the baby- boomers reach retirement age. Even if improving educational outcomes in Germany failed to foster ICT adoption, this strategy would help to offset part of the impact of a declining workforce on potential growth by raising labor productivity.

Comment on Chapter 4

WERNER EICHHORST

MAIN ARGUMENTS Martin Schindler provides a consistent analysis of the German employment response to the 2008–09 global economic crisis. He demonstrates that the moder- ate impact of the crisis on the German labor market can be explained by the propitious nature of existing institutions, discretionary action, and the type of external shock experienced. He refers to five main explanatory elements: • First, prior labor market reforms adopted in the early to mid-2000s, in particular the Hartz package, contributed to reducing unemployment in Germany both with respect to measured open unemployment and struc- tural unemployment. One can therefore argue that the institutional envi- ronment of the German labor market has become more employment- friendly during the past decade. Schindler infers that the Hartz IV reform has been the most crucial factor, since it merged unemployment assistance with social assistance and reinforced activation policies for the long-term unemployed so that the likelihood of the unemployed (re)entering the labor market increased as incentives to take up paid work were boosted. • Second, automatic stabilizers helped stabilize employment at the core of the German labor market, namely in export-oriented manufacturing (Eichhorst et al. 2010; Möller, 2010). German manufacturers were most heavily hit by the crisis, which affected them mainly through a trade shock, with foreign orders declining steeply in late 2008 and early 2009. However, work-time adjustments meant that they were able to protect their skilled workforce without having to resort to major redundancies. On the one hand, work- time accounts, which had run into surplus due to the full utilization of

Werner Eichhorst is Deputy Director of Labor Policy at IZA, Bonn.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Discussion 243

production capacities during the boom phase between 2007 and 2008, facilitated a phase of shorter actual weekly working hours. On the other hand, employers were able to rely on the long-established short-time work allowance, which provides workers with a partial replacement of pay losses for hours not worked amounting to at least 60 percent of net hourly pay. However, without further policy changes, employers would have encoun- tered major non-wage labor costs in social security contributions to be paid for hours not worked. • Third, as a response to this and in order to encourage the take-up of short- time work instead of dismissing workers, the short-time work allowance was made more attractive in late 2008 and early 2009. On the one hand, the maximum duration was increased from six months to 24 months on a tem- porary basis. On the other hand, and most importantly, employers’ social security contributions were paid by the unemployment insurance fund if training was provided to short-time workers or if short-time work lasted for more than six months. This considerably lowered employers’ costs of using short-time work. • Fourth, German manufacturing employers acted very cautiously during the crisis. Past experience had taught them that dismissing skilled workers dur- ing a temporary downturn can lead to severe skill shortages when demand recovers. This is particularly true in situations of imminent demographic change, which result in smaller cohorts of young workers entering the labor market. In fact, there is evidence that those sectors where firms had experi- enced difficulties in recruiting before the crisis were most affected by the crisis, and employers were most reluctant to dismiss workers at short notice (Möller, 2010). • Fifth, and finally, the existing institutional repertoire tallied well with the character of the shock that hit Germany. It was possible to cope with a temporary external shock, which predominantly affected manufacturing, through strong reliance on work-time flexibility in the form of working- time accounts and subsidized short-time work. Had the shock not been so temporary—and had it then spread into other sectors—unemployment would probably have risen more dramatically.

SOME QUALIFYING FACTORS In general, the arguments put forward by Schindler are essentially consistent with the consensual interpretation of Germany’s most recent ‘employment miracle.’ However, some qualifications are necessary. First, the effect of the Hartz IV reform on the German unemployment rate is highly plausible, and in fact there is some evidence in favor of this. Nonetheless, empirical research has not been totally conclusive on this issue, since it is very difficult to determine the effect of Hartz IV in the context of a number of simultaneous labor market changes, in particular a far-reaching liberalization of nonstandard employment, lifting most

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 244 Discussion

TABLE 8.1 The German Labor Market from 2008–2011 2011 (medium IAB 2008 2009 2010 scenario) Real GDP, percent 1 –4.7 3.6 2.4 Hours worked, percent 1.2 –3.1 2.9 1.7 - Full-time 1 –4 2.8 1.7 - Part-time 2.6 1.2 3.4 1.8 Total employment, percent 1.4 –0.1 0.5 0.9 Total employment, 1,000 40,216 40,171 40,438 40,841 Employees covered by social insurance, percent 2.1 0 1.2 1.6 Unemployment, 1,000 3,268 3,414 3,238 2,927 Unemployment rate, percent 7.8 8.1 7.7 7

Source: Fuchs et al., 2011.

restrictions on the use of temporary agency work. So it seems more appropriate to attribute the downward trend in unemployment to the full Hartz package, the related ‘Agenda 2010’ reforms, and the parallel growth of sectors with highly flex- ible wages in the absence of collective agreements or binding minimum wages. Second, the moderate upward deviation from the stable downward trend of the unemployment rate experienced during the crisis does not put into question the general structural improvement of the German labor market due to institu- tional change. More than other countries, Germany succeeded in avoiding a massive increase in unemployment and was able to return to the downward path of unemployment in 2010. In fact, the German labor market turned out to be more resilient than expected by most observers. As Table 8.1 shows, the recession did not result in significant unemployment and, moreover, it was not followed by jobless growth but by robust job creation.

A CLOSER LOOK AT THE GERMAN LABOR MARKET When analyzing the German labor market in more depth, one can see that it was characterized not only by stable unemployment during the crisis but also by stable and growing total employment. Taking a sectoral perspective (Table 8.2), there were in fact some marginal employment losses in manufacturing. However, robust job creation in most other sectors led to stable employment figures even in 2009 and continued growth in 2010. In particular, the private services sector (especially transport and hospitality) and public employment (e.g., education, health and social services) continued to grow during 2009 and 2010. However, the strong expansion of business services was partly driven by a massive increase in agency work contracts—a sector where significant job cuts had been imple- mented in the first phase of the crisis. Therefore, the general picture of stable overall employment and a resilient labor market tends to hide important differ- ences in sectoral employment dynamics.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Discussion 245

TABLE 8.2 Sectoral Employment Patterns Percentage change Sector (Employment in thousands) Feb-09 Feb-10 Feb-11 2009–2011 Mining, Energy, Water 546 544 544 –0.4 Total Manufacturing 6,490 6,237 6,331 –2.5 Construction 1,493 1,489 1,544 3.4 Wholesale and Retail Trade, Repairs 4,044 4,002 4,073 0.7 Transport and Logistics 1,399 1,378 1,428 2.1 Hotels and Restaurants 779 788 809 3.9 Information and Communication 834 826 842 1 Finance and Insurance 1,007 1,005 1,003 –0.4 Business Services 3,361 3,415 3,707 10.3 Of which: Temporary Work 533 560 738 38.5 Public Administration, Social Security 1,684 1,706 1,704 1.2 Education 1,067 1,105 1,100 3.1 Health and Social Services 3,339 3,464 3,574 7 Other Services, Private Households 1,070 1,082 1,073 0.3 Total 27,307 27,230 27,929 2.3

Sources: Bundesagentur für Arbeit; and author’s calculations

In fact, differential growth in some sectors and occupations contributes to an ever more prominent dualization of the German labor market (Eichhorst and Marx, 2011). This also applies to manufacturing, where internal flexibility was not the only channel of adjustment and external flexibility was equally important. While working-time accounts and subsidized short-time work stabilized the core workforce, there were significant job losses at the margin, in particular among less skilled blue-collar workers carrying out routine operative tasks. After the Hartz reforms, which had deregulated temporary agency work and established collec- tively agreed wages below those of direct employees of manufacturers, many labor- ers and machine operators were employed as agency workers. They were made redundant at the outset of the crisis (and rehired later on when demand picked up again), thereby taking a disproportionate share of employment risks. A similar phenomenon was observed with respect to fixed-term contracts in manufacturing. Between 2008 and 2009, a large share of these contracts were neither renewed nor transformed into permanent jobs (Hohendanner, 2010). In fact, due to this pat- tern, manufacturing companies now have smaller core workforces than in the past. This part of the labor force shows growing average tenure as long-term employ- ment is emphasized — but at the same time there is a larger marginal segment of routine jobs where skills shortages do not seem to matter (Figures 8.2 and 8.3).

SUMMARY AND POLICY CONCLUSIONS Germany seems to have found a solution to short-term fluctuations in demand. This solution is not perfect, but it proved to be quite effective during the recent economic crisis, since the existing institutional repertoire was suited to the tempo- rary, export- and manufacturing-centered nature of the crisis and required only minor adjustment. Furthermore, the German labor market benefited not only

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 246 Discussion

1,600,000 Stock, East Stock, West 1,400,000 Notifications

1,200,000 2009: About 4 percent of all employees, 11 percent in 1,000,000 manufacturing, 20 percent in car making, about 350,000 FTE 800,000 (would be 1 PP unemployment rate)

600,000

400,000

200,000

0 Nov.10 Apr. 08 Apr. July 08 Apr. 09 Apr. July 09 Apr. 10 Apr. July 10 Oct. 08 Oct. 09 Oct. 10 Jan. 08 May 08 Jan. 09 May 09 Jan. 10 May 10 Nov. 08 Nov. Nov. 09 Nov. Feb. 08 Feb. 09 Feb. 10 Dec. 08 Aug. 08 Dec. 09 Aug. 09 Dec. 10 Aug. 10 Sep. 10 June 08 June 09 June 10 Sept. 08 Sept. 09 March 08 March 09 March 10 Figure 8.2 Short Time Work in Germany Source: Bundesagentur fuer Arbeit. Note: FTE: full time equivalents; PP: percentage point

Employment loss and recovery of 900,000 about 250,000 agency workers Actual values 800,000 Six month moving average 700,000 (Actual values) 600,000

500,000

400,000

300,000

200,000

100,000

0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Figure 8.3 Temporary Agency Work in Germany Sources: Bundesagentur fuer Arbeit; and author calculations.

from fairly stable employment in manufacturing but also from robust employment growth in the private and public service sectors. This ongoing sectoral shift implies a growing variety of job types and a wider dispersion of working conditions and wages across occupations. Policymakers face a new set of challenges, which are probably harder to tackle than mere fine-tuning of existing policy schemes. From a policy perspective, the German experience demonstrates two themes. On the one hand, automatic stabilizers are important for promoting internal flex- ibility as a (limited) alternative to external flexibility, that is, dismissals. Flexible work-time agreements and publicly subsidized short-time work schemes can help avoid major job losses in the skilled core workforce if, and only if, economic

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Discussion 247 shocks are temporary. On the other hand, the German case is also characterized by a specific function of the second tier of employment, consisting of fixed-term contracts and temporary agency work, which helps buffer the core against major short-term adjustment of the number of jobs. Nevertheless, the more volatile forms of employment at the margin of the labor market create new challenges regarding employment stability and promotion as well as social protection. This calls for the recalibration of employment protection and unemployment benefits, in particular better coverage by unemployment insurance.

Comment on Chapter 5

FELIX HÜFNER

Hélène Poirson and Sebastian Weber’s chapter is important in the German con- text from an analytical as well as policy perspective. Analytically, it challenges the conventional wisdom that German growth is an important driver of other coun- tries’ (especially European) economies, by showing that growth spillovers from Germany, despite the size of the German economy, are actually smaller than those originating in other large economies. This obviously bears an important policy message, namely that increased fiscal spending in Germany is less effective in stimulating growth abroad than is often assumed. This point was underlined in Chapter 6. At a time of increasing divergences in Europe, these findings are an important contribution to the debate. The study presented in Chapter 5 estimates a VAR for 14 European countries plus Canada, Japan and the United States. One of its key findings is that the German economy is more sensitive to external shocks than are other countries: the sensitivity is particularly notable to shocks originating in the United States and Asia. In contrast, outward spillovers from Germany to other countries are estimated to be less than half the size of spillovers of other large economies. However, the spillovers from Germany to some smaller euro area countries that have tight trade links, such as Austria and the Netherlands, are large, not least because these smaller countries are integrated into the supply chains of German companies. Among the larger economies, spillovers are significant only to Italy. Importantly, however, spillovers to the peripheral countries like Greece, Ireland, and Portugal are much smaller than, for example, spillovers to these countries emanating from France. Overall, the finding is that Germany acts as a conduit of international shocks to other countries, rather than being an independent source of spillovers. In line with these results is the fact that identified third-country effects matter less for Germany than for other countries in the sample, showing that Germany is more directly affected by foreign shocks.

Felix Hüfner was senior economist on the Germany desk in the OECD Economics Department at the time of writing. The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the OECD or its member countries.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 248 Discussion

An innovative feature of the paper is the analysis of the time-variation of spill- over effects by splitting the sample and testing for a differing impact during the financial crisis of 2008–09. Spillovers from Germany are found to have been broadly stable during the period from 1993 to 2010 compared with the full sample that starts in 1975. This is a surprising result given the increase in trade integration, not least in Europe, and the increase in FDI-driven supply chain links during the past two decades. Shock transmission is generally found to increase during the 2008–09 crisis period for most countries, although this is less the case for Germany.

ACCOUNTING FOR GDP SIZE DIFFERENCES AND OPENNESS When interpreting the estimated responses, it needs to be kept in mind that the impulses are not adjusted for GDP size. Thus, a one-percent growth shock origi- nating from the United States is more likely to have a growth effect on other countries than a one-percent shock from Germany. Indeed, the authors report in a chart showing GDP size with outward spillovers that both are correlated. Adjusting the spillover estimates for the size-difference throughout the paper would make the German results even more outstanding, since even without such an adjustment the estimation results show a larger effect for shocks emanating from countries smaller than Germany, such as the United Kingdom or France. At the same time, this last result might partly reflect the sample composition, which lacks some eastern European countries with which Germany has tight supply-chain links.

INTERPRETATION OF THE CRISIS DUMMY The VAR specifications include a dummy for 2008:Q4 and 2009:Q1, aiming to gauge any amplification effects in crisis times. Estimation results including the dummy show much lower spillover effects—often only half of the response yielded in estimations without the dummy—suggesting substantial amplification effects (even though this is less the case for Germany). To the extent that such a dummy captures, for example, spillovers of crisis in the domestic banking system or the housing market, say in the United States or Spain, to other countries, its size seems large. It would be interesting to identify in more detail what is driving the crisis amplification result; one factor worth exploring is the role of the break- down of trade financing following the insolvency of Lehman Brothers (Cheung and Guichard, 2009). Including the crisis dummy into the authors’ framework for identifying the trade channel could shed more light on this issue.1 Similarly,

1 In addition to including a crisis dummy, an interesting exploration would be to test whether the importance of the trade channel has changed over time by identifying its importance for the split sample. This would probably help to better understand the result that the trade channel is less impor- tant for the transmission of shocks originating in the euro area relative to those coming from non-euro area countries. At first glance, this finding is surprising, given the tight trade integration within the area.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Discussion 249 it would be interesting to have a discussion on why Germany had no higher spillovers during the crisis, while other countries’ had a high amplification during the crisis, and on how this finding might affect the authors’ claim that Germany acts as a conduit for external shocks to other countries.

RECENT LACK OF DOMESTIC DEMAND IN GERMANY When interpreting the results of the study, one has to keep in mind the particular growth performance of Germany over most of the past decade, which was char- acterized by a lack of domestic demand and significant growth contributions from foreign demand. For example, real total domestic demand grew by an annual average of just 0.75 percent since 1999, compared to an (un-weighted) average of close to 2 percent for the G-7 countries (excluding Germany). Keeping in mind the role of domestic demand in the size of spillovers, as identified by the authors, the lower spillovers from Germany in the more recent period may just reflect the particular growth composition in Germany during the period (between 1975 and 1992, annual average growth in German real total domestic demand was equal to the un-weighted G-7 average). While the lack of domestic demand also reflects structural factors (OECD, 2010a), many forecasters expect a cyclical increase in domestic demand in Germany over the coming years, so spillovers might turn out to be higher going forward.

LIMITED PICK-UP IN SPILLOVERS At the same time, trade linkages in the euro area, at least between the large mem- ber countries, are smaller than often presumed, limiting the upside potential for German spillovers at least through trade. Exports to Germany account for at most 3 percent of GDP in the large euro area countries, while for the smaller, more integrated neighbouring countries the share amounts to more than 10 percent (Table 8.3). Therefore, even if the projected increase in domestic demand in

TABLE 8.3 Trade Linkages Between Germany and Euro Area Countries (Percent) Exports to Germany… …as a share of total exports …as a share of GDP France 13 3 Italy 11 3 Spain 8 2 Greece 4 1 Ireland 9 9 Austria 22 12 Netherlands 15 12 Slovakia 17 14

Source: Author’s calculations.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 250 Discussion

0.40

0.35

0.30

0.25

0.20

0.15 Germany

0.10 Import propensity of domestic demand 0.05

0.0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Import propensity of exports

Figure 8.4 Estimated Import Propensities Source: Long-run marginal import propensities as estimated in Pain, N. et al. (2005), “The New International Trade Model,” Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development Economics Department Working Paper No. 440. Germany materializes, increased imports are unlikely to exert large effects on the other major euro area countries. This hypothesis is supported by the fact that import propensities out of domestic demand are estimated to be relatively low in Germany, again limiting the outward growth effects of any domestic stimulus (Figure 8.4). However, import propensities for exports are much higher, again supporting the chapter’s finding that Germany acts as a conduit to other countries of changes in external demand for its goods.

OTHER CHANNELS THAT COULD BE AT WORK The authors’ finding that the trade channel accounts for at most 30 percent of spillovers among large euro area countries opens up the questions of which other channels can account for the remaining part of the spillovers and whether growth may spill over through channels that are not captured by the chosen approach (as indicated by the increased correlation of Germany’s growth rate with that of the rest of the euro area the authors report). Two candidates for growth transmission within the euro area over and above the trade channel are the financial channel and the monetary policy channel (OECD, 2010b). One indicator for the importance of the financial channel for the transmis- sion of shocks is the size of a country’s banking sector claims on other countries. These claims have increased substantially over the past decade; for example,

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Discussion 251

10 25 9 Germany on Spain 8 20 Spain on Germany 7 6 15 5 4 10 3 Percent of Spanish GDP

Percent of German GDP 2 5 1 0 0 1999:Q4 2000:Q2 2000:Q4 2001:Q2 2001:Q4 2002:Q2 2002:Q4 2003:Q2 2003:Q4 2004:Q2 2004:Q4 2005:Q2 2005:Q4 2006:Q2 2006:Q4 2007:Q2 2007:Q4 2008:Q2 2008:Q4 2009:Q2 2009:Q4 Figure 8.5 Consolidated Banking Claims between Germany and Spain (Percent of GDP) Source: Bank for International Settlements, Consolidated Banking Statistics database and Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Economic Outlook database. claims by German banks on Spanish banks have increased from around 5 per- cent of Spanish GDP in 2002 to close to 20 percent by 2008, while the claims of Spanish banks on German banks have remained fairly stable in terms of German GDP over the same period (Figure 8.5). German surplus savings, originating not least through the lack of domestic investment, were thus partly channelled to Spain, supporting domestic demand there, not least in the resi- dential investment sector. It is worth noting that this channel works in both directions, with negative spillovers from Spain affecting German growth during and after the crisis; this may be one explanation behind the significant spillovers from Spain to Germany (the second largest after the United States in the more recent period) identified by the authors, notably in the more recent period and the crisis. The mechanics of monetary policy in the monetary union are another avenue of growth transmission. According to this channel, slow growth in Germany dur- ing most parts of the last decade kept monetary conditions looser than they otherwise would have been (as monetary policy is set on the basis of data for the euro area average). Given Germany’s weight in the euro area average, slow growth in Germany translated via lower interest rates to higher growth elsewhere. Thus, this channel provides an indirect growth spillover from Germany to other coun- tries in the euro area, however with lower growth in Germany leading to higher growth elsewhere (Figure 8.6). The framework applied by the authors might not be able to directly capture both the financial and the monetary policy channel, since it focuses solely on GDP growth rates. One possible, though likely imperfect, identification would be to include (residential) investment growth as an additional variable into the VAR. This would allow for the identification of an ‘investment channel’

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 252 Discussion

1 Germany 0

−1

−2

−3

−4

Interest rate gap −5

−6

−7

−8 01234567 Annual real GDP growth

Figure 8.6 Monetary Conditions and Real GDP Growth in the Euro Area (Average 1999–2007) Sources: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and author’s calculations.

(in analogy to the inclusion of export growth, which the authors apply to iden- tify the trade channel), which is the most likely way in which differences in financial conditions are transmitted across countries.

Comment on Chapter 7

CARSTEN-PATRICK MEIER

MOTIVATION AND FINDINGS Anna Ivanova’s chapter looks at an important topic. Current account imbalances are widely suspected to be related to the global financial crisis of 2008–09 as well as to the ensuing debt crisis in Europe. Although the question is still open whether those imbalances have to be regarded as one of their causes or rather as one of their early symptoms, they are at the heart of the policy debate. In par- ticular, the significant increase in Germany’s current account surplus in the aggre- gate and vis-à-vis most of the other Euro area countries over the past decade has renewed the interest in understanding the factors behind the current account surge and, at the same time, to identify possible cures. This is the starting point of the chapter, which looks at the structural—as opposed to the cyclical—determinants of the German current account surplus

Dr. Carsten Patrick Meier is founder and Managing Director of Kiel Economics.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Discussion 253 and proposes policy measures that could help to reduce it. The basis of its policy prescriptions is an econometric study of the current account movements of a total of 106 advanced, emerging, and developing countries over the years from 1970 to 2009 and their likely determinants. The analysis is conducted within a random-effects panel framework that uses five-year averages of variables in an attempt to filter out cyclical forces. The conclusion is that while structural factors such as taxes, labor market, and product market regulations do not play a sig- nificant role in the emergence of large current account positions over the last decade, they may in some cases explain part of the differences in the current account positions of the countries in the sample. In particular, for some subsets of countries it is found that the current account is likely to be more positive the higher the corporate income tax rate, the stricter the credit market regulation, and the higher the gross replacement rate. Consequently, the tentative policy prescription of the paper for Germany is to lower the replacement rate, the cor- porate income tax rate, and regulation of the banking sector (which in the discus- sion is identified with reduced public ownership of banks) in order to reduce its current account surplus.

SOME QUARRELS The paper’s empirical findings and the policy prescriptions derived for Germany raise questions. With respect to the empirical analysis, what strikes me most is the lack of robustness in the findings across different country samples. To be sure, the paper emphasizes this lack of robustness several times and concludes that “the impact of these structural reforms on the surplus will likely be mod- est….” Importantly, none of the three structural determinants that the policy prescriptions for Germany are to address turn out to be significant when the sample is restricted to the OECD countries. Evidently, there is a structural dif- ference in the sample; the parameters of the panel model for the non-OECD countries are significantly different from the parameters for the OECD coun- tries. Given this difference, it is difficult to draw conclusions from the full- sample analysis, especially for the OECD countries, to which Germany belongs. But even if one accepts the econometric results despite their somewhat shaky statistical grounding, they look rather puzzling. This is especially the case for the gross replacement rate, which turns out to have a positive sign in the regression results. According to standard labor market theory (e. g. Layard, Nickell, and Jackmann, 2005), a higher replacement rate—in a manner similar to a higher minimum wage and higher unemployment protection—should increase the res- ervation wage, thus raising overall wages and unit labor costs and leading to a loss of price competitiveness, which should ultimately dampen exports and stimulate imports. The sign should, therefore, be negative. While the paper presents some economic reasoning for this counterintuitive result, the most likely explanation is that the statistical result is driven by the high amount of collinearity of the

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 254 Discussion

three labor market indicators used: replacement rate, minimum wage, and employment protection index. Indeed, countries that have high replacement rates often also feature high employment protection and minimum wages. A simple remedy for the empirical strategy would be to aggregate the three indica- tors into one overall indicator of “worker protection.” When the result with respect to the replacement rate is applied to Germany, it becomes even more puzzling. According to the econometric finding of a positive relationship between this indicator and the current account surplus, the signifi- cant reduction in unemployment benefits and social assistance from 2004 onwards mentioned in the paper should have reduced Germany’s current account surplus in the second half of the last decade. Instead, the German current account surplus increased at an accelerated pace until the global financial crisis took hold. This lack of dynamic correspondence in the case of Germany also applies to the second determinant identified in the paper. While the estimated positive association between the corporate income tax rate and the current account sur- plus seems plausible—since, everything else being equal, higher corporation taxes mean lower investment and thus higher capital exports—it is again tricky to find the pattern for Germany that is suggested by the regression results. Indeed, cor- porate income taxes were lowered substantially in 2000—two years before the German current account surplus started to take off. Finally, there is the conclusion that stricter banking regulation is a factor that contributes to Germany’s current account surplus. Again, the economic rationale that tighter credit resulting from a lack of competition in the banking sector low- ers investment and increases the current account surplus seems plausible. However, it is hard to see that Germany, with its 2,000 independent banks, suf- fers from a lack of competition in the banking sector. While most of the savings banks that make up one-third of the banks are not held by private entities but by the local communities, they cannot simply be counted as belonging to the state and therefore hampering competition. Indeed, in the past it has sometimes been argued that the German banking sector is over-competitive, resulting in low mar- gins and relatively low capitalized banks. Moreover, the banking sector has been deregulated substantially over the past 15 years, notably with the elimination of the public guarantee obligation for the state-owned Landesbanken enforced by European Union law in 2005. In the case of Germany, neither the level of bank- ing regulation nor its dynamics lend themselves readily to confirm the positive relationship between strict banking regulation and the current account as sup- posed by the regression results.

NEED FOR POLICY MEASURES Given my difficulties with the three factors mentioned above, the main conclu- sion I draw from the empirical analysis is that structural factors do not play much of a role in the current account in most countries, at least not in the advanced countries. In my view, current accounts are largely cyclical phenomena. The cycle

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Discussion 255 driving them may have a longer duration than the conventional four to five years—a fact that casts some doubt on the validity of taking simple five-year averages for cyclical adjustment—but it remains a cycle. Typically, this cycle reflects the longer-term adjustment of the economies in question to external shocks. The German current account is a case in point. After unification, it turned negative as government deficits widened, investment in housing soared, and price competiveness was eroded by sharp wage hikes. It went back into positive terri- tory in the second half of the 1990s when investment in housing slowed down and fiscal deficits declined. However, until 2001, the trade account was never more than 1.5 percent of GDP, thanks partly due to the hike in consumption and in business investment spurred by the tech-bubble, which happened to be par- ticularly pronounced in Germany. It was only after the effects of the European Monetary Union began to take hold that trade and current account surpluses widened significantly. While the common monetary policy was too strict for Germany, it was too lax for the economies at the European periphery, which were already stimulated heavily by the decline in long-term interest rates brought about by monetary union. As a consequence, consumption and investment boomed and wage growth accelerated in those countries while the German economy was dampened, leading to widening current account imbalances between the two regions of the euro area. The comprehensive tax, social security, and labor market reforms implemented in Germany between 2000 and 2005 enhanced this pro- cess. Intended to stop the rise of unemployment and fiscal deficits, the reforms not only depressed private consumption temporarily, but also lowered workers’ reservation wage and thus improved the price competitiveness of German firms, not least vis-à-vis its competitors from the rest of the Euro area. Today, the macroeconomic setting looks completely different. The German economy has recovered quickly from the global financial crisis, thanks mainly to the long-term effects of the reforms. Employment continues to rise and unem- ployment is falling. Most other advanced countries have not come out of the crisis as well as Germany has. In the rest of the euro area, unemployment has risen sharply and capacity utilization is well below normal levels. However, adjustment is already visible. Not only have European periphery countries, such as Ireland and Spain, managed to improve their current accounts, the German trade surplus has also declined from its peak of 8.5 percent at the end of 2007 to about 5 per- cent at the end of 2011. On the domestic side, we now have interest rates that are too low for the German economy while they are too high for most of the rest of the euro area countries, a fact that is enhanced by the debt crisis. A small con- struction boom is already building up in Germany as property prices have risen in real terms in 2011—for the first time in a decade. At the same time, with the unemployment rate heading for 6.5 percent in 2012, 5.5 percentage points lower than in 2005, labor shortages have become an important concern for many firms, and wage pressure is rising. At Kiel Economics, we expect unit labor costs to increase significantly in Germany over the coming years while unit labor costs in the rest of the euro area are set to stagnate or even

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 256 Discussion

fall as a consequence of high unemployment and, possibly, labor market reforms. Inflation is therefore set to accelerate in Germany, while it is likely to remain moderate in the rest of the euro area. This process will eventually erode German price competitiveness and will further reduce the German trade surplus— completely without the help of structural policies.

REFERENCES Arvanitis, S., 2005, “Computerization, Workplace Organization, Skilled Labour and Firm Productivity: Evidence for the Swiss Business Sector,” Economics of Innovation and New Technology, Vol. 14, No. 4, pp. 225–49. Bresnahan, T. E. Brynjolfsson, and L.M. Hitt, 2002, “Information Technology, Workplace Organization, and the Demand for Skilled Labour: Firm Level Evidence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, No. 1, pp. 339–76. Cheung, C., and S. Guichard, 2009, “Understanding the World Trade Collapse,” OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 729 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Doms, M., Dunne, T., Koske, T., 1997, “Workers, Wages and Technology,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 1, pp. 253–90. Eichhorst, Werner, Mathias Dolis, Paul Marx, Andreas Peichl, Stefan Ederer and Thomas Leoni, 2010, The Role of Social Protection as an Economic Stabiliser: Lessons from the Current Crisis, Report based on a study conducted for the European Parliament, IZA Research Report 31, Bonn: IZA. Eichhorst, Werner, and Paul Marx, 2011, “Reforming German Labour Market Institutions, Journal of European Social Policy, Vol. 21, No. 1, pp. 73–87. Fabiani, S., F. Schivardi, S. Trento, 2005, “ICT Adoption in Italian Manufacturing: Firm Level Evidence,” Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 14, No. 2, pp. 225–49. Fuchs, Johann, M. Hummel, S. Klinger, E. Spitznagel, S. Wanger, E. Weber, and G. Zika, 2011, “Rekorde und Risiken: neue Arbeitsmarktprognose,” IAB Kurzbericht 7/2011. GCEE, 2009, “Die Zukunft nicht aufs Spiel setzen,” Wiesbaden. ———, 2010, “Chancen für einen stabilen Aufschwung,” Wiesbaden. ———, 2011, “Herausforderungen des demografischen Wandels,” Wiesbaden. Hohendanner, Christian, 2010, “Unsichere Zeiten, unsichere Verträge? : Befristete Arbeitsverträge zwischen Auf- und Abschwung, IAB-Kurzbericht,” 14/2010. Ivanova, A., and S. Weber, 2011, “Do Fiscal Spillovers Matter?”, IMF Working Paper No. 11/211 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). Layard, Richard, Stephen Nickell, and Richard Jackmann, 2005, “Unemployment: Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market,” 2nd edition (Oxford: Oxford University Press). Möller, Joachim, 2010, “The German Labor Market Response in the World Recession: De-Mystifying a Miracle,” Zeitschrift für Arbeitsmarktforschung, Vol. 42, No. 4, pp. 325–36. OECD, 2010a, Economic Surveys: Germany (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). ———, 2010b, Economic Surveys: Euro Area (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution About the Contributors

Fabian Bornhorst Fabian Bornhorst is an economist in the European Department of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and works on the surveillance teams for Germany and the euro area. Previously he worked in the Fiscal Affairs and African departments of the IMF and was an economist in the Ministry of Finance in Namibia as a fellow of the Overseas Development Institute (ODI). He has pub- lished papers on fiscal policy, natural resource related tax revenue, and public investment and growth. He obtained his Ph.D. in economics from the European University Institute (Italy) and holds master’s degrees in economics from University College London (U.K.) and the Freie Universität Berlin (Germany).

Werner Eichhorst Werner Eichhorst studied sociology, political science, psychology, and public policy and administration at the universities of Tübingen and Konstanz (Germany), where he graduated as Diplom-Verwaltungswissenschaftler in 1995. He received his Ph.D. from the University of Konstanz in 1998. From 1999 to 2004 he was project director at the Bertelsmann Foundation, a private think tank in Germany, where he was responsible for comparative analyses of the German labor market and related policy areas. After working with the Institute for Employment Research (IAB) from 2004 to 2005, he joined the Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) as research associate in July 2005, becoming a senior research associate there in February 2006 and deputy director of labor policy in April 2007. His main research area is the comparative analysis of labor market institutions and performance as well as the political economy of labor market reform strategies.

Malte Hübner Malte Hübner is an economist at the German Council of Economic Experts, where he is responsible for macroeconomic analysis and energy policy. Before joining the staff of the Council, he conducted theoretical and empirical research in the area of fiscal federalism. He obtained his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Mannheim (Germany) in 2009 and holds a master’s degree in com- puter science from the Universität des Saarlandes (Germany).

Felix Hüfner Felix Hüfner is deputy director in the Global Macroeconomic Analysis Department at the Institute of International Finance (IIF), where he is responsible for the IIF’s

257

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 258 About the Contributors

global macroeconomic forecasting work, its monthly Global Economic Monitor publication, and its report on Capital Flows to Emerging Economies. Before coming to the IIF in 2012, he was senior economist and head of the Germany/Slovak Republic desk at the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). He also worked as an economist for the Bundesbank, the European Central Bank (ECB) and the Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW) and was a bank apprentice at Deutsche Bank. He received a B.A. from the University of Cologne (Germany), a master’s degree in economics from the University of Munich, and a Ph.D. from the University of Würzburg (Germany). He passed all three levels of the CFA program.

Anna Ivanova Anna Ivanova is a senior economist in the European Department of the IMF and works on the surveillance team for Germany. Previously she worked as an economist in the Fiscal Affairs, Middle East, and Central Asia departments of the IMF and as a physicist at the Institute of Nuclear Problems in Belarus. She has published a series of papers in the areas of fiscal policy, the role of international financial institutions, and growth. She obtained her Ph.D. in economics from the University of Wisconsin-Madison (USA), a master’s degree in economic development from Vanderbilt University (USA), and a master’s degree in nuclear physics from the Belarussian State University (Belarus).

Christian Kastrop Christian Kastrop is deputy director-general of the Economics Department and director of the Public Finance, Macroeconomics, and Research Directorate of the German Federal Ministry of Finance. He has been director of the European Economic and Monetary Union Directorate and director of the International and Financial and Monetary Policy Directorate. He is chairman of the OECD Senior Budgetary Officials (SBO) Network on Performance and Results. From 2008 to 2009, he chaired the EU Economic Policy Committee (ECOFIN-EPC), of which he was vice-chairman from 2005 to 2008. He is a lecturer at the Free University of Berlin at the Hertie School of Governance, a policy fellow of the Cologne Institute of Public Finance, and a State Member for Germany at BRUEGEL, a think-tank located in Brussels. After starting his career as an assistant researcher and lecturer in economics at the University of Cologne, he joined the Federal Ministry of Finance in 1989, where he held various positions, including chief press officer, director of the Press and Communication Division in the Minister’s Office, and director of the Fiscal Policy Division. He holds a master’s degree and a Ph.D. in economics from the University of Cologne, after studies in economics, psychology, medieval philosophy, and methodology of science at Cologne and at Harvard University (USA).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution About the Contributors 259

Carsten-Patrick Meier Carsten Patrick Meier is founder and managing director of Kiel Economics, a macroeconomic and risk management consultancy. He studied economics in Göttingen and Kiel (Germany) and obtained his Ph.D. under Prof. Dr. Juergen B. Donges. Between 1998 and 2008 he led the research groups on the German business cycle and, later, on risks in the banking sector at the Kiel Institute for the World Economy. He is the author of numerous articles on the business cycle, capital markets, and banks, as well as on economic modeling and forecasting.

Ashoka Mody Ashoka Mody was deputy director in the IMF’s European and then Research Department when this book was written. He is now Charles and Marie Robertson visiting professor in International Economic Policy at Princeton University. He worked for many years at the World Bank and has also been a visiting professor at the University of Pennsylvania’s Wharton School (USA). His academic research, motivated by and drawing closely on his policy responsibilities, has recently focused on international finance and domestic political economy.

Hélène Poirson Hélène Poirson is senior economist in the European Department at the International Monetary Fund (IMF), where she is responsible for financial sector surveillance for France. Previously, she worked on the surveillance teams for France and Germany, and held positions in the Research, Asia and Pacific, and Finance Departments. Before joining the IMF in 1999, she was economist at the Observatoire Francais des Conjonctures Economiques (OFCE), a private think- tank. She has published a range of policy and research papers, especially in the areas of economic growth, exchange rate and monetary policy issues, and capital markets issues. Her most recent research focuses on bank-level spillovers within and from the euro area. She holds a Ph.D. in economics from DELTA, École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales (France) and a MSc in mathematics from Ecole Polytechnique (France). She is a CFA charterholder.

Martin Schindler Martin Schindler is a senior economist at the Joint Vienna Institute (JVI), on leave from the IMF. He is also a policy fellow at the Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). At the JVI, he directs and contributes to capacity building and training activities for public sector officials in Central, Eastern and Southeastern Europe, mostly on policies for macroeconomic management and financial stabil- ity. At the IMF, he most recently worked on the surveillance teams for Germany and the euro area. He has published on a range of topics in macroeconomics and

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 260 About the Contributors

international finance, and his work has appeared in the Journal of Monetary Economics, the Journal of International Economics, and the Journal of International Money and Finance, among other outlets. He holds a Diplom-Kaufmann degree from the Universität des Saarlandes and a Ph.D. in economics from the University of Pennsylvania (USA).

Sebastian Weber Sebastian Weber currently works as an economist at the IMF, where he has held positions in the European and African departments. He has written policy papers and articles on labor markets, monetary policy, and international macro and finance. His current research agenda focuses on the role of domestic institutions for the transmission of shocks. He has been a consultant for the OECD and the World Bank. He holds a Ph.D. and a master’s degree in international economics from the Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies in Geneva (Switzerland) and studied politics and economics at the University of Cape Town (South Africa) and the University of Hamburg (Germany), where he obtained a B.Sc. (Hons.) in economics.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Index

[Page numbers followed by b, f, n, or t refer to boxed text, figures, footnotes, or tables, respectively.]

A trade patterns, 110 Access to capital Beveridge curve, 91, 92f current account balance dynamics and, Brazil, 162, 172 199, 200, 202, 214–215 future challenges and opportunities, 10 C initial public off erings in Germany and, 71 Canada obstacles to technology investment in generation and transmission of spillover Europe, 57 eff ects, 121, 127, 128, 129, 153 See also Credit market regulation international fi nancial linkages, 112 Agriculture sector, projected output gaps, responses to U.S. growth shocks, 102 45f Capital account openness, 214–215 Asian economies China future challenges for Germany’s growth, credit market deregulation, 210 2, 10 current account surpluses of 2000s, 16 Germany’s integration with, in early domestic investment patterns, 16 2000s, 13 European trade, 2, 111 global competition, 15–16, 217 generation and transmission of shocks, See also specifi c Asian nation 100, 111, 162, 170, 184 Austria German exports to, 15, 22–23, 22f fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, German imports from, 217, 218f 150, 174, 176, 180, 182 as global competitor, 28 generation and transmission of wage patterns and trends, 210 spillovers, 124, 126, 127, 129, 162, Cloud computing, 72 186, 247 Collective bargaining agreements, 24, 89b growth spillover eff ects, 121, 122 Consolidation, fi scal post-World War II growth, 5 spillover eff ects of synchronization of, Automatic stabilization, 21n, 157, 158, 149–150, 151, 186 172, 242, 246 See also Fiscal spillover eff ects on recovery Corporate investment, 218–219, 219f B Corporate profi ts, 7, 16, 218–219 Banking. See Financial sector Credit market regulation Baseline econometric modeling, 205, current account imbalances and, 200, 206–207 201, 204, 209f, 214, 215, 221, 254 Belgium Germany’s, 201n fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, 150, measures of, 201n, 214, 223 165, 170, 174, 176, 180, 184, 186 Current account balances generation and transmission of current literature on, 202–205 spillovers, 121, 124, 126, 127, 129, cyclical sources of current imbalances, 162, 186 16, 201, 216, 254–255

261

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 262 Index

data sources, 223 Hartz reforms and, 255 economic signifi cance of, 252 post-World War II recovery, 4, 7 eff ect of long-standing structural spillover eff ects and, 25, 99, 105, 249 packages, 212–215, 225–234t U.S., 3 eff ect of structural factors on Domestic investment and savings fundamental determinants of, 201, causes of low investment in Germany, 210, 211, 215, 216f, 235–237t 16, 201 fi ndings from baseline econometric in current account balance dynamics, modeling, 205–206 203 fundamental determinants of, 200, 202, future economic growth and, 49 206–207 Germany’s current account imbalances Germany’s current surplus, 1, 2, 16, 31, and, 16, 201, 202, 218–219 200, 201, 217, 218f, 255 during Germany’s reemergence period in Germany’s reemergence (2004–08), (2004–08), 16 1, 10, 14–16, 201 Great Recession eff ects, 19 in Germany’s slowdown period (1960s– obstacles to, in Germany, 57, 69–72, 2004), 7, 8f 219–220 imbalances prior to Great Recession, population aging and, 29–30 199, 200, 204–205 productivity lags related to investment implications for recovery from fi nancial lags in ICT, 49 crisis, 199 sectoral diff erences in Europe and modeling methodology, 200, 205–207, Germany, 238f 252–254 sources of current global account rationale for mitigation of distortions imbalances, 200 in, 199–200 strategies for reducing imbalances, 16, 201, 217–221, 220t E structural factors in dynamics of, ECB, 26 202–204, 208–210, 253–256 Economic growth in Germany, 4f, 76t structural sources of current imbalances, employment patterns and, 78–79 16, 199, 200, 201, 202, 220–221 future challenges, 1, 2–3, 27–30, 38, unifi cation eff ects, 7, 255 50, 255–256 U.S. economy, 3 Great Recession eff ects, 1, 19–23, 20f, See also Target 2 system 21f, 22f, 38, 90, 239 intensive growth, 7 international comparisons, 2, 3 D phases of, 1–2, 3, 31 Demographics. See Population aging post-World War II period (1940s–60s), Distribution services, 67–68 3–5, 6f, 30–31 Domestic demand and consumption projections, 239–241, 240f course of Great Recession, 21, 23f reemergence period (2004–08), 9–13, current account balances of 2000s and 31 16 reunifi cation eff ects, 1, 2, 7 employment patterns and, 16, 17f, 23, slowdown period (1960s-2000s), 5–9, 23f 55 future challenges for growth, 2–3 sources of, 61, 62f, 64t, 240f Germany as global engine of growth See also Exports, Germany’s; Potential and, 25 GDP growth correlations, 127–129, 128t Educational investments, 242

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Index 263

Employment patterns obstacles to technology investments, 57, cyclical patterns in Germany, 78, 69–72 80–84, 86f perceptions of Germany’s international defi nition of potential GDP, 38–39 role and responsibilities, 2, 10, domestic demand and consumption 25–26, 31 patterns and, 16, 17f, 23, 23f post-World War II recovery, 4–5 future challenges for Germany, 31, 49 productivity growth patterns, 55, 56–57 Great Recession outcomes, 20, 21f, recent wage rises, 11, 11f 43–44, 77, 80–84, 81f, 82f, 84f, 244, sectoral savings and investment 244t, 245, 245t behavior, 238f international comparison, 43f, 79f, 80, 82f sensitivity to external shocks, 115–116, intersectoral diff erences in fi nancial 243 crisis outcomes, 244, 245t in slowdown period (1960s–2000), post-World War II recovery, 4–5, 5–6, 6f 16–17, 17f sources of current account imbalances, replacement rate, 201, 209f, 211, 212, 14–16 216, 220, 224, 253–254 sources of growth spillovers, 97, 102– services sector, 66b 103, 112–114, 115–118, 130–131, in slowdown period (1960s–2000s), 7, 247 78–79 spillover eff ects of decline in German unifi cation eff ects, 7 spending, 160–162, 161t work-time adjustments in response to strategies for productivity improvement, fi nancial crisis, 12, 24, 83–84, 84f, 73 92, 242–243, 246–247 transmission of spillover eff ects, 102, See also Labor market, Germany; Wages 124, 126, 127 and income See also Target 2 system; specifi c country Employment protection legislation, 7, 24, European Monetary Union 90, 90n, 254 fi scal policy spillovers, 243 current account balance dynamics and, generation and transmission of shocks, 209f, 211, 212–214 102, 115, 130 data sources, 224 sensitivity to U.S. shocks, 116–118 See also Hartz reforms spillover risks, 110–112, 110t Europe, Germany and trade channel transmission of chocks, determinants of productivity 126, 127f performance, 58b trade patterns, 110–111, 110t evidence of spillover eff ects in recovery, See also Europe, Germany and; specifi c 97–98 country export growth in 2000s, 13–16, 13f, European Recovery Program, 4 14f, 217, 217f Exchange rates fi scal policy spillover eff ects, 25–26, in current account balance dynamics, 152, 166, 182 203 Germany as regional locomotive of synchronized fi scal consolidation eff ects growth, 2, 25 on recovery, 149 Hartz-like labor reforms of 1990s, Exports, Germany’s 12–13, 24 future challenges, 2–3 investment patterns preceding fi nancial Great Recession as export shock, 24, crisis, 219f 36–38, 89–90, 239 labor unit labor cost evolution (1990– Great Recession eff ects, 19, 22–23, 22f, 2010), 9f 36, 242

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 264 Index

international comparison of growth in future prospects, 186–187 2000s, 14f, 217, 217f growth impact of coordinated post-World War II growth, 1, 2, 4, 4t, 5 relaxation, 182, 183t product specialization, 13, 13f, 28 growth outcomes, 170, 171t, 172f in reemergence period (2004–08), 10, impact of spending reductions, 159– 13–16, 13f, 14f 166, 164t, 165f, 166f, 190–191t signifi cance of, in Germany economy, 1, limitations, 25–26 35–36, 36f, 36n outcomes of 2011–12 consolidation in slowdown period (1960s–2000s), plans, 166–180, 169t, 170f, 192– 7, 8f 197t source of Germany’s current account trade balance outcomes, 182–186, 184t, surplus, 217, 218f 185t use of real revenues and expenditures in F simulation, 174–179 Financial integration Foreign direct investment current account balance dynamics and, current account balance dynamics and, 202, 206, 223 203 spillover transmission and, 1–3, 102, domestic corporate investment and, 219f 110 spillover eff ects, 100 Financial sector France cross-border spillover risk, 110, 111t, 112 generation and transmission of shocks, 97, German bank claims on foreign banks, 98–99, 113–114, 121, 122, 124, 127, 250–251, 251f 129, 130, 142–143f, 162, 170, 247 linkage to current account balance, 203, German trade with, 15 204 Great Recession impact in, 19 mechanisms of spillover transmission, sensitivity to external shocks, 113, 103–104, 110, 111t, 112, 130 116–118, 126, 153 policy strategies for reducing global current account imbalances, 201 G in post-World War II recovery, 5 GDP. See Gross domestic product productivity, 67–68 German Council of Economic Experts, public share of, 201, 220, 221 growth projections of, 239, 241 response to Great Recession onset, Germany 20–21 banking sector competitiveness, 254 Finland, 121, 122, 127, 129 credit market regulation, 214 Fiscal spillover eff ects on recovery current account surplus, 200, 201, 217 analytical methodology, 150–151, current economy, 255 155–159 economic resilience, 1, 2, 19, 30–31 automatic stabilization eff ects, 172–174 explanations for recovery from Great concerns, 149–150 Recession, 1–2, 20–24, 31, 35, 93b, current expectations, 149 239, 255 data sources, 159 fi scal policy spillover eff ects, 150–151, eff ect of increased consolidation, 160, 166–180, 182–184 180–182 generation and transmission of eff ects of higher multipliers and import spillovers, 97, 98, 99, 112–113, elasticities, 150, 154, 179–180, 181f, 116–118, 121, 122, 129, 130–131, 189t 140–141f within Europe, 103 investment patterns in Reemergence fi ndings from literature, 151–155 period, 16, 201

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Index 265

obstacles to investment, 57, 69–72, lessons from German experience, 93, 219–220 245–246 sensitivity to external shocks, 115–116 outcomes in Germany, 19–20, 35, 38, strategies for reducing current account 50, 90, 254 imbalances, 201, 217–221, 220, outcomes in U.S., 80 220t, 221 output declines, 19–20, 20f, 35 tax system, 220 projected outcomes in potential GDP, transmission of shocks, 115–116 39–40, 43–46 unemployment benefi ts in, 220 protective factors in German labor See also Domestic demand and market, 35, 77, 90–92, 93b, 242– consumption; Domestic investment 243, 245–247, 255 and savings; Economic growth Target 2 balances, 26, 26f, 27f in Germany; Europe, Germany trade outcomes, 2, 19, 22–23, 22f and; Labor market, Germany’s; See also Fiscal spillover eff ects on Manufacturing sector, Germany’s; recovery; Spillover eff ects in recovery Productivity, Germany’s; Service Greece sector, Germany’s fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, 184 Globalization generation of spillover eff ects, 122, 127, competition and trade during Germany’s 128, 160, 247 reemergence period (2004–08), 12–13 growth spillover eff ects, 122 future challenges for Germany’s sensitivity to external shocks, 113–114, manufacturing sector, 10 115, 124, 160, 166, 172, 176 Germany as transmitter of global trade Gross domestic product impulses, 25 adjusting spillover eff ects for size of, 248 Germany’s economic slowdown of Gross domestic product (GDP) 1970s/80s and, 7 adjusting spillover eff ects for size of, 248 Germany’s labor reforms in 2000s and, external and domestic demand and, 12–13 127–129, 128t, 129f Germany’s post-World War II economic in Germany’s slowdown period (1960s– performance, 1, 2 2000), 5, 7 perceptions of Germany’s roles and Great Recession eff ects, 19, 20f, 34, 36, responsibilities, 10, 25–26, 31 37, 37f, 38, 80 See also Fiscal spillover eff ects on recovery; growth composition in Germany and Spillover eff ects in recovery; Trade U.S., 62f Great Recession (2008–09), 1 growth expectation in 1990s and early capital fl ows in eurozone, 26 2000s, 8–9, 9f employment outcomes in Germany, 12, growth spillovers in crisis and recovery, 20, 21f, 23f, 24, 44, 77, 80–84, 81f, 118–123, 118t, 119–120f 82f, 84f, 244, 245, 245t international comparison of growth, explanations for Germany’s recovery, 14f, 36f, 37f 1–2, 20–24, 31, 35, 93b, 239, 255 per hour worked and per capita GDP, as export shock for Germany, 24, 60f, 76t 36–38, 89–90, 239 post-World War II per capita, 6f Germany’s institutional and policy unifi cation eff ects, 7 responses to, 23–24, 88 volatility of Germany’s, 2, 3, 17–18, 18f global current account imbalances and, See also Economic growth in Germany; 199, 204–205 Potential GDP international comparison of Group of Seven, 118–121 employment outcomes, 82f Group of Twenty, 20–21

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 266 Index

H See also Information and Hartz reforms, 11–13, 24, 49, 49n, 77, communications technology 80, 85–88, 92, 93b, 96, 210n, 242, Insolvency law, 71 243–244, 245, 255 Interest rates as mechanism of spillover transmission, I 103 ICT. See Information and communications recent patterns, 18, 19f technology risk aversion and, 18 Immigration policies, 7, 49, 49n synchronized fi scal consolidation eff ects Imports, Germany’s on recovery, 149–150, 186 international comparison of growth in International Monetary Fund Article IV 2000s, 15f, 219f consultations with Germany, 3 post-World War II patterns, 4, 4t Ireland, 11 source of current account surplus, 217, fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, 150, 218–219 160, 162, 167–170, 174, 176, 180, 184 sources, 15, 15f, 217, 218f generation of spillover eff ects, 115, 122, transmission of spillover eff ects, 249–250 127, 160, 247 India, 162 sensitivity to external shocks, 113–114, Infl ation 126, 165, 166 future challenges for Germany, 255–256 Italy, 5, 12, 24 projected outcomes of Great Recession, generation of spillover eff ects, 98, 113– 44–45, 46f 114, 121, 122, 123, 124, 127, 130, Information and communications 144–145f, 162, 170, 247 technology sensitivity to external shocks, 113, education of workforce for, 242 116–118, 126 future challenges and opportunities, 10, 55, 72 J German investments, 61, 68–69 Japan, 2, 3 Germany’s infrastructure, 59, 69 current account surpluses of 2000s, 16 Internet access, 69, 69f, 71 domestic investment patterns, 16 obstacles to investment in Germany and European trade, 111, 112 Europe, 57, 69–72 generation of spillovers, 97, 98–99, 101, private sector productivity, 65, 65f, 66b, 102, 111, 112, 113, 115, 121, 122, 124, 67 127, 129, 130, 135–137f, 162, 184 productivity lags related to investment as global competitor, 28 lags in, 49, 55, 57, 58b, 59, 60–62, Great Recession eff ects, 19 63–64, 66, 70, 241 interest rate historical patterns, 19f productivity patterns, 56 manufacturing sector, 10, 11f public procurement, 10, 71, 241 output volatility, 17, 18f as source of productivity growth, 56, population aging, 28, 28f, 29f 56b, 70b, 72–73, 241 stock market volatility, 18f strategies for productivity improvement, 73 K Innovation and technological advancement Knowledge economy determinants of productivity, 58b Germany’s current status, 55 future challenges and opportunities, 10 measures of, 60 in Germany’s slowdown period sources of, 61–62 (1960s–2000), 7 U.S. growth, 66b patent applications, international See also Information and comparison of, 59f communications technology

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Index 267

Korea future challenges of global competition, fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, 184 1, 2, 10, 27–28 as global competitor, 28 growth in reemergence period transmission of spillover eff ects, 162, 176 (2004–08), 10 Kurzarbeit, 23–24, 88, 93 growth trends, 66b international comparison of importance L of, 11f Labor market, Germany’s investment behavior, 218–220 Beveridge curve, 91, 92f post-World War II (to 1960s) recovery, current account balance dynamics and, 1, 4–5, 10 203–204, 215–216, 253–254 productivity patterns, 55, 56, 59, current supply, 90–91 66–67 demographic challenges, 2, 28–30 projected output gaps, 44, 45f educational preparation, 242 responses to onset of fi nancial crisis, future challenges for Germany, 31, 49, 242–243 92–93, 239–241, 255–256 as source of economic resilience, 1 Hartz reforms of 2000s, 11–13, 77, 80, as source of Germany’s economic 85–88, 92, 93b, 96, 242, 243–244, resilience, 28, 30–31 245, 255 Marshall Plan, 4 human capital factors in productivity, Mexico, 102 58b, 63n Minimum wage levels human capital in service sector, 70b current account imbalances and, 199, implications of population aging trends, 201, 204, 210, 211, 212–214, 215, 30, 30f 221 institutional and policy responses to Great data sources, 224 Recession, 23–24, 35, 88, 242–243 Monetary policy post-World War II period, 4–5 in current account balance dynamics, protective factors mediating fi nancial 203 crisis, 23–24, 35, 77, 90–92, 93b, transmission of spillover eff ects, 242–243, 245–247 251–252 in reemergence period (2004–08), 9f, See also Exchange rates 10–13 rigidity, 203–204 N signifi cance of experiences in 1990s and Netherlands 2000s, 77–78 fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, in slowdown period (1960s–2000s), 7, 150, 170, 176, 180, 182 8–9, 78–80 trade patterns, 110 strategies for reducing current account transmission of spillover eff ects to, imbalances, 201, 220 121, 122, 124, 127, 129, 162, unit labor cost evolution (1990–2010), 186, 247 9f See also Employment patterns; O Productivity, Germany’s; Wages and Oil shocks of 1970s, 1, 7, 31 income Okun’s law, 81–83, 83b Organisation for Economic Co-Operation M and Development countries Manufacturing sector, Germany’s current account balance dynamics, 206, eff ects of Great Recession, 245 212, 214, 253 employment patterns preceding fi scal policy spillover eff ects in, 153 fi nancial crisis, 242–243 ICT infrastructure, 59, 68–69

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 268 Index

P measurement challenges, 57n Population aging patterns and trends, 55, 67f current account balance dynamics and, policy recommendations to improve, 73 202, 206 post-World War II recovery, 55, 60 data sources, 223 private versus public services economy, future challenges, 2, 28–30, 242 62–64 implications for labor market, 2, 30, 30f projections, 241 international comparison of trends, 28f, signifi cance of, in future growth, 50 29f U.S. productivity versus, 58–64, 60f, savings and consumption behavior and, 60t, 61t, 64t, 65–68, 65f, 66b, 66t, 29–30 68t, 241 Portugal See also Total factor productivity fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, 184 Public procurement sensitivity to external shocks, 113–114, cautions in, 241 124, 166, 172 in current account balance dynamics, transmission of spillover eff ects, 122, 203 127, 128, 160, 247 of ICT services, 71, 241 Potential GDP defi nition, 38–39 R future concerns, 38, 47, 50 Regulatory environment German unifi cation eff ects, 39 current account imbalances and, 200, labor market outcomes of Great 201, 203, 204, 210f Recession, 43–44 data sources, 224 modeling methodology and data insolvency law, 71 sources, 41–42, 41t, 52–53, 239 technology investment in Europe and, output gap modeling, 41, 42, 42f, 44, 57, 71–72 44f See also Credit market regulation output measurement, 39, 41 Risk aversion, 17–18 per capita, 50f Russia projected outcomes in growth fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, 184 accounting model, 47–49, 239–241 transmission of spillover eff ects, 162 projected outcomes of Great Recession, 35, 38, 39–40, 43–46 S transmission of growth shocks to, 37, Service sector, Germany’s 41–42 future challenges and opportunities, Productivity, Germany’s 2–3, 10 cyclical factors in recent growth, 62 government procurement for public data sources, 57 good, 10 determinants of, 58–59, 60–62 growth of, 10, 66b future challenges and opportunities, 10 human capital supply, 70b growth in reemergence period (2004– productivity patterns, 55, 56–57, 59, 08), 10 65f, 67–68, 68t ICT investment and growth in, 10, projected output gaps, 45f 49, 55, 56, 56b, 57, 58b, 59, 60–62, U.S. service economy and, 3 63–64, 66, 70, 70b, 72–73 SoFFin, 21, 21n international comparison, 55, 56–57, Spain, 97, 99 57n, 59f domestic and foreign growth spillovers, intersectoral diff erences, 10, 55, 56–57, 118–121 59, 64–72, 66t fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, 184

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Index 269

generation and transmission of shocks, Stock markets 97, 99, 113, 115, 118n, 121, 124, initial public off erings in Germany, 71 127, 128, 129, 130, 146–147f, 162, mechanism of spillover transmission, 170 103 German bank claims on banks in, volatility, 18, 18f 250–251, 251f Structural vector autoregression modeling, sensitivity to external shocks, 113, 97, 98 116–118, 172 Sweden Spillover eff ects in recovery fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, 184 adjusting for GDP size, 248 transmission of spillover eff ects, 122, cross-border linkages, 109–112 127, 129, 172 current understanding of spillover Switzerland dynamics, 100–105 fi scal consolidation spillover eff ects, domestic and foreign contributions, 182, 184 118–123 transmission of spillover eff ects to, 122, domestic demand and, 99, 249–250 124, 126, 127, 172, 174 evidence for, 97–98, 99f fi ndings from vector autoregression T modeling, 98–99, 104–105, Target 2 system, 25 130–131, 248–249 capital fl ow patterns, 26, 26f, 27f German fi scal policy as regional in Great Recession, 26, 26f, 27f stimulus, 25–26 Tax systems inward growth spillovers, to Germany, current account imbalances and, 199, 115–118, 247 200, 201, 212, 214, 220, 221, 254 mechanisms of transmission, 25, 101, current German, 220 103, 107–109, 123, 130, data sources, 224 250–252 obstacles to ICT growth, 69 modeling methodology, 97, 98, 100, spillover eff ects of fi scal policy, 152, 104, 105–109, 123, 123n, 126, 153–154 129n, 248, 251–252 Total factor productivity nonstandard channels, 113 European performance, 58–59, 58b outward growth spillovers, from future challenges and opportunities, 72 Germany, 112–115, 247 human factors in, 58b, 63n possible sources of growth, 97, 130 international comparison, 49f, 241 research needs, 99–100, 131, intersectoral diff erence, 57 248–249 patterns in Germany, 57, 241 role of Germany in, 25, 99, 130–131 policy recommendations to improve, 73 size of, 101–102, 126–129, 133t projected potential growth in Germany, synchronized fi scal consolidation and, 35, 47–48, 48f, 49–50 149–150 signifi cance of, in productivity growth, third-country eff ects, 123–126, 124f, 58, 61–62, 67–68 125f, 247 sources of, 241 through Target 2 system, 26 Trade time-variation, 248 current account balance dynamics and, trade channels in, 249–251 206 transmission of one-percent growth export patterns, 110t shocks, 102, 134–147f generation of spillovers from, 25, 103, Stimulus spending in response to Great 109–112, 123–126, 128f, 129, 129f, Recession, 20–21, 22f, 152 130

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 270 Index

Great Recession eff ects, 36 Great Recession impact in, 19, 80 growth correlations, 127–129, 128t, growth projections, 38, 45–46, 46f, 47 129f growth rates, 76t spillover eff ects of fi scal consolidation, interest rate historical patterns, 19f 182–186, 184t, 185t labor market outcomes of Great spillover eff ects of spending decline in Recession, 44 Germany, 159–166, 164t, 165f, 166f labor market structural characteristics, transmission of spillover eff ects, 249– 80 251 manufacturing sector, 11f unifi cation eff ects, 7, 8f output volatility, 17, 18f See also Exports, Germany’s; Imports, population aging, 28f, 29f Germany’s potential GDP patterns, 39–40, 46, 47f private versus public services economy U productivity, 62–64 Unemployment benefi ts productivity growth patterns, 49, 55, 56– current account balances and, 201, 203, 57, 56b, 58–64, 60f, 60t, 61t, 64t, 241 204, 211, 212, 216 sectoral diff erences in productivity, 66t current German, 220 sensitivity to external shocks, 121, 153 in Germany’s slowdown period (1970s), services sector growth, 66b 7 services sector productivity, 65f Hartz reforms, 12, 85 sources of productivity growth, 58–59 Unifi cation of West and East Germany, 1, stock market volatility, 18f 2, 7, 31, 39, 79, 255 United Kingdom V European trade, 111 Vector autoregression modeling, 97, 98, generation of spillover eff ects, 113, 101, 104, 248 115, 116, 121, 122, 123, 127, 128, 138–139f, 162, 170, 172 W Great Recession impact in, 19 Wages and income insolvency laws, 71 determinants of current account United States, 6 balance, 202, 206 economic challenges and opportunities, future challenges for Germany, 31 3 post-World War II recovery, 5 European trade, 111 in recent years, 10–11 future of ICT, 72 in reemergence period (2004–08), generation of spillovers from, 97, 98– 10–13, 11f, 12f 99, 101, 102, 103, 110, 111, 112, in slowdown period (2004–08), 7, 8, 79 114–115, 116, 121, 122, 124, 127, See also Minimum wage levels 128, 130, 134f, 153–154, 162, 170, Work-sharing and work-time adjustment 174, 247 schemes, 12, 24, 83–84, 84f, 92, as global competitor, 28 242–243, 246–247

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution