Exchange Rate Regimes, Globalization, Financial Crises, and Monetary Policy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Exchange Rate Regimes, Globalization, Financial Crises, and Monetary Policy A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Bordo, Michael D. Article Exchange rate regimes, globalization, financial crises, and monetary policy NBER Reporter Online Provided in Cooperation with: National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, Mass. Suggested Citation: Bordo, Michael D. (2006) : Exchange rate regimes, globalization, financial crises, and monetary policy, NBER Reporter Online, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, MA, Iss. Winter 2006/07, pp. 10-13 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/61885 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Research Summaries Exchange Rate Regimes, Globalization, Financial Crises, and Monetary Policy Michael D. Bordo* My research in the past decade has con- Today while advanced countries can market that mitigated these effects involved centrated largely on four related themes successfully float, emergers who are less significant start-up costs, while the impor- that I discuss in this article: Exchange Rate financially mature and must borrow abroad tance of scale suggests that network exter- Regimes, Globalization, Financial Crises, in advanced country currencies are afraid to nalities and liquidity were pivotal in the and Monetary Policy. float, for the same reason as their nineteenth emergence of overseas markets in domestic century forbearers were. To obtain access to currency debt.5 Exchange Rate Regimes foreign capital, they may need a hard peg to The limiting case of a fixed exchange the core country currencies. In my paper with rate regime is a monetary union. My study As discussed in the Fall 999 NBER Marc Flandreau the key distinction between of the history of monetary unions (MUs) Reporter, much of my earlier work focused core and periphery countries, both then with Lars Jonung 6—based on the exam- on the gold standard and related mone- and now, is financial maturity, evidenced in ples of the United States, Germany, and tary regimes. A series of papers with Finn the ability to issue international securities Italy — suggests that the success of MUs Kydland, Ronald MacDonald, and Hugh denominated in domestic currency3 (or the of the past has been intimately linked with Rockoff emphasized the importance of absence of “original sin”, a phrase coined by both fiscal and political unification. The credible commitment mechanisms in the Eichengreen and Haussman (999)4). implementation of EMU was largely driven design of monetary regimes, focusing on the However, a case study by Chris Meissner, by the political will of elites and its ultimate gold standard. My recent work extends this Angela Redish, and myself of the debt history success may also depend upon the political approach. of several former colonies of Great Britain will of the citizenship. The choice of exchange rate regimes, (the United States, Canada, Australia, New between fixed and floating exchange rates, Zealand, and South Africa), who had largely Globalization evolved considerably in the past hundred overcome the problem of original sin by the years.2 Before 94, advanced countries third quarter of the twentieth century, finds Globalization—the integration of adhered to gold while periphery countries that sound fiscal institutions, high credibility goods, labor, and capital markets — has been either emulated the advanced countries or of the monetary regimes, and good financial one of the dominant issues in the past sev- floated. Some peripheral countries were development are not sufficient to completely eral decades. The present era of globaliza- especially vulnerable to financial crises and break free from original sin. Conversely, tion was preceded by an earlier era in the late debt default, in large part because of their poor performance in these policy realms is nineteenth century — from 870 to World extensive external debt obligations denomi- not, for the most part, a necessary condition War I. Globalization in historical perspec- nated in core country currencies. This left for Original Sin. The factor we emphasize tive was the subject of a recent NBER con- them with the difficult choice of floating for the common progress toward borrowing ference volume, edited with Alan Taylor but restricting external borrowing or devot- in domestic currencies across the five coun- and Jeffrey Williamson. The articles in the ing considerable resources to maintaining an tries is the presence of shocks, such as wars, book covered many aspects of the globaliza- extra hard peg. massive economic disruption, and the emer- tion experience, including the integration gence of global markets. The differences in of markets, growth convergence, inequal- *Bordo is a Research Associate in the NBER’s evolution between the United States and ity, financial development, the transmission Programs on Monetary Economics and the the Dominions we attribute to differences in of shocks, and the political economy of the Development of the American Economy. size, the role of a key currency, which charac- backlash in the interwar period that ended He is also a Professor of Economics at terized the United States and not the others, the first era of globalization. Rutgers University. During 200–7, he and to membership in the British Empire. My research with Barry Eichengreen is the Pitt Professor of Economic History The importance of major shocks suggests and Douglas Irwin7 focused on a compari- at Cambridge University and a Fellow at that the establishment of a domestic bond son of the record of financial and commer- Kings College Cambridge. 10 NBER Reporter Winter 2006/7 cial globalization in the two eras of global- policies. One possible determinant of cri- 973–98, with countries in the same region ization.8 The empirical evidence we survey ses in emerging countries is the presence of not receiving assistance, suggests that the suggests that, while in some respects the original sin. real performance of the former group was financial integration of the pre-94 era My work with Chris Meissner finds, in possibly worse than the latter. Similar results remains unsurpassed, in other respects both eras of globalization, an increased prob- are obtained after adjusting for self-selection today’s financial markets are even more ability that emerging countries with original bias and counterfactual policies7. closely integrated than those in the past. sin experienced debt, currency, and bank- The difference today is that new informa- ing crises. Furthermore, crises were more Monetary Policy tion-generating-and-processing technolo- likely to be a problem for middle-income gies have reduced the market-segmenting emerging countries that were less financially Economic history has long provided effects of asymmetric information. In con- developed. In the first era of globalization, a useful laboratory for the practitioners of sequence, the range of financial claims that countries like Italy, Portugal, Argentina and monetary policy. My research in the area has are traded internationally has broadened. Brazil were more crisis-prone than Australia, focused on deflation and monetary policy While in the past entities (governments, Canada, Denmark, and Sweden. and asset prices. railroads, and mining companies) with tan- Another part of this research program Deflation in historical perspective gible and therefore relatively transparent focuses on the transmission of financial cri- assets were predominant, now international ses. Antu P. Murshid and I (2000)2 pres- The return in the 990s to an environ- investors transact freely in a much broader ent evidence from weekly data on sovereign ment of low inflation has raised the spec- range of securities. bond prices and interest rates for episodes of ter in the United States of deflation and the We also find that the commercial inte- financial turbulence from 880 to 997. We collapse of prices such as occurred in the gration before World War I was more lim- find little evidence for contagion, defined 930s. My work with Angela Redish focuses ited. Given that integration today is even as an incidence in bilateral cross-market on the deflationary experience of 870–96 more pervasive than a hundred years ago, it correlations, adjusted for heteroscedastic- during the pre-94 classical gold standard is surprising that trade tensions and finan- ity. However, we do find evidence sugges- period. That episode has resonance for today cial instability have not been worse in recent
Recommended publications
  • A Model of Bimetallism
    Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Model of Bimetallism François R. Velde and Warren E. Weber Working Paper 588 August 1998 ABSTRACT Bimetallism has been the subject of considerable debate: Was it a viable monetary system? Was it a de- sirable system? In our model, the (exogenous and stochastic) amount of each metal can be split between monetary uses to satisfy a cash-in-advance constraint, and nonmonetary uses in which the stock of un- coined metal yields utility. The ratio of the monies in the cash-in-advance constraint is endogenous. Bi- metallism is feasible: we find a continuum of steady states (in the certainty case) indexed by the constant exchange rate of the monies; we also prove existence for a range of fixed exchange rates in the stochastic version. Bimetallism does not appear desirable on a welfare basis: among steady states, we prove that welfare under monometallism is higher than under any bimetallic equilibrium. We compute welfare and the variance of the price level under a variety of regimes (bimetallism, monometallism with and without trade money) and find that bimetallism can significantly stabilize the price level, depending on the covari- ance between the shocks to the supplies of metals. Keywords: bimetallism, monometallism, double standard, commodity money *Velde, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago; Weber, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and University of Minne- sota. We thank without implicating Marc Flandreau, Ed Green, Angela Redish, and Tom Sargent. The views ex- pressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Fed- eral Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, or the Federal Reserve System.
    [Show full text]
  • WHY DID the BANK of in Financial Markets and Monetary Economics
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHY DIDTHEBANK OF CANADA EMERGE IN 1935? Michael Bordo Angela Redish Working Paper No. 2079 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 November 1986 The research reported here is part of the NBER's research program in Financial Markets and Monetary Economics. Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Paper #2079 November 1986 Why Did the Bank of Canada Emerge in 1935? ABSTRACT Three possible explanations for the emergence of the Canadian central bank in 1935 are examined: that it reflected the need of competitive banking systems for a lender of the last resort; that it was necessary to anchor the unregulated Canadian monetary system after the abandonment of the gold standard in 1929; and that it was a response to political rather than purely economic pressures. Evidence from a variety of sources (contemporary statements to a Royal Comission, the correspondence of chartered bankers, newspaper reports, academic writings and the estimation of time series econometric models) rejects the first two hypotheses and supports the third. Michael D. Bordo Angela Redish Department of Economics Department of Economics College of Business Administration University of British Columbia University of South CArolina Vancouver, B.C. V6T lY2 Columbia, SC 29208 Canada Why Did the Bank of Canada Emeroe in 1935? Michael D. Bordo and Angela Redish Three possible explanations for the emergence of the Canadian central bank in 1935 are examined: that it reflected the need of competitive banking systems for a lender of last resort; that it was necessary to anchor the unregulated Canadian monetary system after the abandonment of the gold standard in 1929; and that it was a response to political rather than purely economic pressures.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation, Productivity Shocks and Gold: Evidence from the 1880-1914 Period
    Deflation, Productivity Shocks and Gold: Evidence from the 1880-1914 period Michael D. Bordo NBER and Rutgers University John Landon-Lane Rutgers University Angela Redish University of British Columbia Abstract In this paper, we examine the issue of deflation from a historical perspective. We focus on the price level and growth experiences at the four dominant countries on the gold standard, in the period 1880-1913: the United States, the United Kingdom, France and Germany. We distinguish between good deflation (driven by positive aggregate supply shocks) and bad deflation (driven by negative aggregate demand shocks). We use an empirical Blanchard-Quah model which decomposes the behavior of prices, output, and the money stock in the impact of three structural shocks (a world price level shock, a domestic supply shock, a domestic demand shock). Our key finding is that the European economies were essentially classic in the sense that money was neutral and output was mainly supply driven. In the United States, however, we observe both good and bad deflation. JEL: Money, Economic History, 1880-1913. Keywords: Deflation, Gold Standard, Demand, Supply Shocks. The authors wish to thank participants at the CNEH conference and at the Money/macro seminar at Carleton University and Tulane University, for comments, and Jake Wong for research assistance. Michael D. Bordo, Department of Economics, New Jersey Hall, 75 Hamilton Street, Rutgers University. New Brunswick NJ 08901. (732) – 932 – 7069/7416. [email protected] Introduction The return to an environment of low inflation in most countries in the past decade has sparked renewed interest in the subject of deflation since its possibility is only a recession away.
    [Show full text]
  • Draft. Do Not Cite. April 4, 2005 Deflation, Productivity Shocks And
    Draft. Do not cite. April 4, 2005 Deflation, Productivity Shocks and Gold: Evidence from the 1880-1914 period Michael D. Bordo NBER and Rutgers University John Landon-Lane Rutgers University Angela Redish University of British Columbia Paper prepared for seminar at Carleton University, and the conference of the Canadian Network in Economic History, Kingston, ON, April 2005. All comments appreciated. Introduction The return to an environment of low inflation in most countries in the past decade has sparked renewed interest in the subject of deflation since its possibility is only a recession away. The recent deflationary experiences of Japan, China, Hong Kong, Switzerland and other countries led to concern in 2003 by policymakers at the Federal Reserve, the ECB and elsewhere that it could happen to them. They feared the possibility of prolonged stagnation as experienced by Japan or even worse a deflationary spiral that would lead to the conditions of the 1930s Great Depression (Bordo and Filardo, 2004). In this paper we examine the issue from an historical perspective. We focus on the experience of deflation in the late nineteenth century when most of the countries of the world adhered to the classical gold standard. The period 1880-1914 was characterized by two decades of secular deflation followed by two decades of secular inflation. The price level experience of the pre 1914 period has considerable resonance for today’s environment. Several elements are salient. First deflation pre 1914 was quite low as has been the case recently. In the U.S. the GNP deflator declined by an average of 1% to 1.5 % per year from 1880-1896.
    [Show full text]
  • When Did the Dollar Overtake Sterling As the Leading International Currency? Evidence from the Bond Markets
    WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 1433 / MAY 2012 WHEN DID THE DOLLAR OVERTAKE STERLING AS THE LEADING INTERNATIONAL CURRENCY? EVIDENCE FROM THE BOND MARKETS by Livia Chitu, Barry Eichengreen and Arnaud Mehl In 2012 all ECB publications feature a motif taken from the €50 banknote. NOTE: This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily refl ect those of the ECB. Acknowledgements The authors are grateful to Thierry Bracke, Marc Flandreau, Kristin Forbes, Norbert Gaillard, Christopher Meissner, Angela Redish and Roland Straub for helpful discussions. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily refl ect those of the ECB or the Eurosystem. Livia Chițu at European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany; e-mail: [email protected] Barry Eichengreen at University of California, 603 Evans Hall, Berkeley, 94720 California, USA; e-mail: [email protected] Arnaud Mehl at European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany; e-mail: [email protected] © European Central Bank, 2012 Address Kaiserstrasse 29, 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19, 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Internet http://www.ecb.europa.eu Fax +49 69 1344 6000 All rights reserved. ISSN 1725-2806 (online) Any reproduction, publication and reprint in the form of a different publication, whether printed or produced electronically, in whole or in part, is permitted only with the explicit written authorisation of the ECB or the authors.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation Edited by Richard C
    Cambridge University Press 978-0-521-83799-6 — Deflation Edited by Richard C. K. Burdekin , Pierre L. Siklos Frontmatter More Information DEFLATION Until recently, fears of deflation seemed nothing more than a relic of the Great Depression. However, beginning in the 1990s, persistently falling consumer prices emerged in Japan, China, and elsewhere. Deflation is also a distinct possibility in some of the major euro area economies, especially Germany, and became a concern of the U.S. Federal Reserve in 2003. Deflation may be worse than inflation, not only because the real burden of debt rises but also because firms would confront rising real wages in a world where nominal wage rigidity prevails. This volume explores some key themes regarding deflation including: (i) how economic agents and policy makers have responded to de- flation; (ii) the links between monetary policy, goods price movements, and asset price movements; (iii) the impact of deflation under different monetary policy and exchange rate regimes; and (iv) stock market reactions to deflation. Richard C. K. Burdekin is Jonathan B. Lovelace Professor of Economics at Claremont McKenna College, Claremont, California. His areas of interest include monetary and financial economics, Chinese economic reforms, and inflation and deflation. Professor Burdekin has published four books: Budget Deficits and Economic Performance (with Farrokh K. Langdana), Confidence, Credibility and Macroeconomic Policy (with Farrokh K. Langdana), Distributional Conflict and Inflation (with Paul Burkett), and Establish- ing Monetary Stability in Emerging Market Economies (edited with Thomas D. Willett, Richard J. Sweeney, and Clas Wihlborg). He has also authored more than forty refereed journal articles that have been published in the American Economic Review; the Jour- nal of Economic History; the Journal of International Money and Finance; the Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking; and the Review of Economics and Statistics, among other leading publications.
    [Show full text]
  • Should We Worry About Deflation? Prevention and Cure
    Should We Worry about Deflation? * Prevention and Cure 2003 McKenna Lecture on International Trade and Economics; Perspective on the Economy Willem H. Buiter** *** European Bank for Reconstruction and Development NBER and CEPR * Lecture given at Claremont McKenna College, on November 24, 2003. ** The views and opinions expressed are those of the author and not necessarily those of the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. *** © Willem H. Buiter 2003, 2004. Abstract After an absence of almost half a century, the spectre of deflation is once again haunting the corridors of central banks and finance ministries in the industrial world. While preventing or combating deflation poses some unique difficulties not present in preventing or combating inflation, deflation can be prevented and, if it has taken hold, can be overcome, using conventional instruments of monetary and fiscal policy. These include changes in the short nominal interest rate (when the zero bound constraint is not binding), the intentional depreciation of the external value of the currency, open market purchases of government securities and monetary financing of government deficits caused by expansionary tax cuts, increases in transfers or higher public spending on goods and services. Base money-financed tax cuts or transfer payments – the mundane version of Friedman’s helicopter drop of money – will (almost) always boost aggregate demand, but require coordination of monetary and fiscal policy. Unconventional monetary and fiscal measures are also available. These include open market purchases of private and foreign securities, negative nominal interest rates (through a carry tax on currency) and temporary tax measures aimed at shifting private consumption from the future to the present, by tilting the intertemporal terms of trade.
    [Show full text]
  • Phony Deflation Worries
    Phony Deflation Worries Charles W. Calomiris1 Columbia University Shadow Open Market Committee Meeting New York, New York November 3, 2014 1 This paper was prepared for presentation at the November 3, 2014 meeting of the Shadow Open Market Committee. I thank Mickey Levy for helpful suggestions. These days deflation risk is a concern that many central bankers, pundits, and journalists voice regularly.2 Concern may be the wrong word; it might be better called an obsession. Central bankers – we are told – must battle deflation risk today at all costs because deflation slows growth, and may cause recessions and financial system collapses. I agree with the view that the Fed should be targeting an announced long-run rate of inflation (my preference would be 1%, but I am almost as happy with the Fed’s chosen 2% target). And so, I agree that monetary policy should seek to avoid sustained deflation or very low inflation as part of its inflation targeting commitment. But that is not the same as believing that a short-run deviation from 2% inflation to 3%, 1%, 0%, or -1% – especially if it were a consequence of actions that better ensured adherence to the long-run 2% target – would pose a severe economic risk. In particular, given the significant inflation risk associated with exiting from the Fed’s QE3 policy, beginning to scale back the Fed’s portfolio of long-maturity mortgage-backed securities and government bonds would be appropriate. That would limit medium-term inflation risk, despite the fact that it might result in a near-term rate of inflation that is slightly less than 2%.
    [Show full text]
  • Money, Inflation, and Output: a Quantity-Theoretic Introduction
    Money, Inflation, and Output: A Quantity-Theoretic Introduction Jon´ Steinsson∗ University of California, Berkeley July 4, 2021 An amazing variety of items have been used as money throughout history. For many centuries, cowrie shells where a dominant form of money in large parts of Asia and Africa. In Icelandic (my mother tongue), the word for money is the same as the word for sheep (“fe”)´ because sheep were used as a medium of exchange for centuries. Similarly, the English word “pecuniary” comes from the Latin word “pecus,” which means cattle. Tobacco and beaver skins (among other objects) were used as money in the British colonies of North America in the 17th and 18th cen- turies. The most common form of money over the past millenium has probably been coins made of gold, silver, copper, and sometimes other metals. More recently, paper money, bank deposits, and other types of ledger entries have become the dominate form of money in much of the world. Most people are used to the monetary system employed in their own society, and may not give it much thought on a day-to-day basis. But the monetary system used in one society can strike people in other societies as puzzling and even illogi- cal. Take, for example, the Micronesian island of Yap. It’s unusual monetary system was described in The Island of Stone Money by anthropologist Henry Furness (1910) as well as by Friedman (1992, ch. 1). The medium of exchange on Yap was called fei. Furness describes fei as “large, solid, thick, stone wheels, ranging in diameter from a foot to twelve feet, having in the center a hole varying in size with the di- ameter of the stone, wherein a pole may be inserted sufficiently large and strong to ∗I would like to thanks Amanda Awadey for excellent research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • I. Introduction
    CENTRAL BANKS : PAST , PRESENT , FUTURE * ANGELA REDISH I. INTRODUCTION The current European financial crisis has under- lined the critical importance of the design of cen- tral banks for monetary, financial and economic stability; and, in particular, it has raised questions about the functionality of a central bank indepen- dent of a sovereign fiscal power. But the relation- ship between the state and the central bank is not only at issue in Europe. In the United States, the question of how separate the Federal Reserve Sys- tem and the federal government should be is also more frequently heard in policy discussions than it has been for many decades. This paper looks at the question of central bank mandate and design in a larger historical context with the goal of under- standing the rationale for the design of the Euro- pean Central Bank (ECB), and also of developing a better understanding of how central banks will evolve over the next few decades. *University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Over the centuries, central banks have played four Canada. broad roles in the economy: fiscal support, financial E-mail: [email protected]. stability support, monetary support and macroeco- Paper prepared for the nomic support. Let me say a few words about each Conference on Monetary before looking at some case studies. Central banks History, Banco de la República, Bogotá, can provide revenue or fiscal support for their gov- Colombia. ernment in a variety of ways. The use of the power ENSAYOS SO B RE POLÍTICA ECONÓMICA, VOL . 30, NÚ M . 67, EDICIÓN ES P E C IAL HISTORIA DE LA B AN C A C ENTRAL 15 to coin/print money to produce revenue for the sovereign, of course, long predates central banking and the debate over the legitimacy of such use is an equally old one.
    [Show full text]
  • David Dodge: 70 Years of Central Banking in Canada (Central Bank
    David Dodge: 70 years of central banking in Canada Remarks by Mr David Dodge, Governor of the Bank of Canada, to the Canadian Economics Association, Hamilton, Ontario, 27 May 2005. * * * It gives me great pleasure to be here today with you, and to chair this special conference session celebrating the 70th anniversary of the Bank of Canada. The Bank opened its doors on 11 March 1935, at the height of the Great Depression, and immediately faced enormous challenges. In meeting those challenges, the new Bank of Canada drew on the experience of other, established central banks. It received valuable guidance in functions such as the issuance of bank notes, managing foreign exchange reserves, and promoting financial stability. However, such guidance did not prove to be much of an advantage in what has become the main function of the Bank of Canada - monetary policy. Up to the time that the Bank was founded, monetary policy had been subject to the tight discipline of the gold standard - a topic that Angela Redish has explored in her work. That discipline severely limited the authorities' room to manoeuvre. The notion that countries, acting through their central banks, might actually try to stabilize macroeconomic activity within their borders is a relatively new one. As a consequence, over the past 70 years, the Bank of Canada and other central banks have had to learn by doing - by experimenting and gradually refining the art and science of monetary policy implementation. We have received a great deal of help in this effort from the academic community, including the people here today.
    [Show full text]
  • Is Deflation Depressing? Evidence from the Classical Gold Standard
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IS DEFLATION DEPRESSING? EVIDENCE FROM THE CLASSICAL GOLD STANDARD Michael D. Bordo Angela Redish Working Paper 9520 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9520 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 February 2003 The authors would like to thank Pierre St. Amant, Ramdane Djoudad and participants at the Claremont conference on Deflation, as well as at seminars at Carleton University, Queen’s University, the University of Colorado and the University of Western Ontario for very useful comments. The views expressed herein are those of the author and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. ©2003 by Michael Bordo and Anglea Redish. All rights reserved. Short sections of text not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit including ©notice, is given to the source. Is deflation depressing? Evidence from the Classical Gold Standard Michael Bordo and Angela Redish NBER Working Paper No. 9520 February 2003 JEL No. E31, N11 ABSTRACT We distinguish between good and bad deflations. In the former case, falling prices may be caused by aggregate supply (possibly driven by technology advances) increasing more rapidly than aggregate demand. In the latter case, declines in aggregate demand outpace any expansion in aggregate supply. This was the experience in the Great Depression (1929-33), the recession of 1919-21, and may be the case in Japan today. In this paper we focus on the price level and growth experience of the United States and Canada, 1870-1913. Both countries adhered to the international gold standard.
    [Show full text]