Mixed Electoral Systems and Electoral System Effects

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Mixed Electoral Systems and Electoral System Effects Electoral Studies 23 (2004) 575–599 www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud Mixed electoral systems and electoral system effects: controlled comparison and cross- national analysis Robert G. Moser a,Ã, EthanScheiner b,c a University of Texas at Austin, Austin, TX 78712, USA b Stanford University, Stanford, CA, USA c University of California at Davis, Davis, CA 95616, USA Abstract Utilizing data from 15 countries that employ mixed electoral systems, we provide a cross- national analysis of the defining elements and potentially constraining effects of such sys- tems. Using district level election results, we examine the effects of the proportional rep- resentation (PR) and single-member district (SMD) tiers of mixed systems separately and in combination. We also test the effects on electoral outcomes of different components of mixed systems such as linked tiers, ratio of SMD to PR seats, and majority versus plurality rules in the SMD tier. Our findings suggest that, despite claims of a ‘‘contamination effect’’ between the two tiers, in countries with developed party systems, PR and SMD electoral arrange- ments tend to approximate their expected effects even when used in combination in mixed systems. We also find that particular institutional characteristics within mixed systems have a substantial constraining effect on the number of significant political parties. However, the nature of the party system itself, in particular the extent to which its parties are institutiona- lized, also plays a very important role in shaping the degree to which constraining effects are truly felt. # 2003 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Keywords: Mixed electoral systems; Electoral system effects; Duverger’s law; Party institutionalization à Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-512-232-7278; fax: +1-512-471-1068. E-mail address: [email protected] (R.G. Moser). 0261-3794/$ - see front matter # 2003 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/S0261-3794(03)00056-8 576 R.G. Moser, E. Scheiner / Electoral Studies 23 (2004) 575–599 1. Introduction Mixed electoral systems, defined here as electoral systems that provide voters two votes for the legislature—one for a party list in a proportional representation (PR) tier and one for a candidate in a single-member district (SMD) tier—have emerged as a major alternative to strictly PR or SMD systems. This paper provides an analytical dissection of mixed electoral systems. Using district level data from 15 countries, we offer a comparative analysis of the effects of PR and SMD elec- toral arrangements when used simultaneously in mixed systems. Our approach offers several contributions to the growing literature on mixed electoral systems: first, we examine the effects of mixed systems in the widest var- iety of cases to date. Our dataset includes established democracies and new democ- racies from Europe, post-communist states, and Latin American countries, with systems that range from the long-standing institutionalized parties of Germany to the nearly inchoate party systems of Soviet successor states. Our study also pro- vides the most complete analysis we have found of the effects of different insti- tutional variations of mixed electoral systems, such as the impact of linked versus unlinked tiers. Finally, unlike many such cross-national studies of mixed systems, we use district level data to test relationships between electoral arrangements and party configurations, since theories of electoral system effects apply most directly to this level of analysis. With our data, we are able to analyze the independent influence of PR and SMD rules whencombinedinmixed electoral systems. The separate votes cast inthe PR and SMD portions of the balloting offer scholars an opportunity for ‘‘controlled comparison’’: mixed electoral systems represent a social laboratory in which effects of different types of electoral systems can be studied in isolation from influences of the social context such as social cleavages, socioeconomic development, or culture. Such an approach not only produces fresh insights on the effects of PR and SMD elections; but also explores the extent to which ‘‘contamination’’—the presence of PR balloting altering SMD politics and SMD balloting affecting PR—shapes the effects of electoral rules inmixed systems (see HerronandNishikawa, 2001; Cox and Schoppa, 2002). We find that PR and SMD electoral arrangements tend to approximate their expected effects evenwhenused incombinationif party systems are well developed. Our central findings focus on the factors that constrain the number of significant candidates and political parties. We find that particular institutional features within mixed systems—such as mechanisms linking the two tiers—constrain such numbers, but electoral institutional features are not alone in their constraining effects. We argue that the nature of the party system itself, in particular the extent to which a country’s party system is institutionalized, also plays a critical role in shaping the degree to which electoral system constraining effects are truly felt. Con- straining effects commonly attributed to electoral systems are much more likely at a certain level of party institutionalization. R.G. Moser, E. Scheiner / Electoral Studies 23 (2004) 575–599 577 2. Duverger’s law and its limits The electoral system literature is based onthree central Duvergerianpremises: PR systems tend to produce multi-party systems; two-ballot majoritarian systems promote multiple parties aligned into two camps; and plurality systems promote bipartism (Duverger, 1986, p. 70). Subsequent scholarship has better specified the nature of all these relationships. District magnitude (the number of representatives elected from each district) seems to be the decisive influence on multipartism and disproportionality in the translation of votes to seats. Low magnitudes, especially SMDs, have a powerful constraining effect on the number of parties and produce high disproportionality. High magnitudes allow (but do not cause) greater proliferation of parties and pro- duce less disproportionality (Taagepera and Shugart, 1989; Lijphart, 1994). The constraining effect of electoral systems seems to reside most directly at the district level rather than at the national level (Sartori, 1986, pp. 54–55; Cox, 1997). Cox (1997) explicates the limits of Duvergerianequilibria. District level strategic voting (and, by implication, strategic entry and departure by elites) requires certain conditions regarding actors’ motivations, preferences, time horizons, and avail- ability of accurate information. Plurality SMD elections may not reduce the vote for minor parties if any of the following holds: voters who are not short-term instrumentally rational; a lack of public information about voter preferences and vote intentions (and, hence, insufficient sense about which candidates are ‘‘out of the running’’); widespread certainty regarding likely winners; and the presence of many voters who strongly prefer their first choice and, thus, are nearly indifferent to other choices (Cox, 1997, p. 79). Even if conditions are favorable for establishing two-candidate races at the dis- trict level, bipartism projection to the national level is not assured. Projection depends on parties’ ability to unite prominent elites in single nationwide party organizations. If this is not accomplished, the two candidates produced in district level plurality elections may belong to many different parties across the country. Cox cites institutional factors, most notably the direct election of a powerful national executive, as the primary forces behind such nationalization (Cox, 1997, pp. 182–193). The pre-conditions for strategic behavior at the district level and projection of bipartism to the national level are particularly problematic during the initial elec- tions in new democracies, especially cases with little democratic tradition. The absence of previous electoral experience and accurate polling information may deny voters and elites the information necessary to behave strategically. The lack of well-established parties undermines the ability of voters and elites to behave strategically, as well as project to the national level constraining effects that occur at the district level. Where parties are new and weak, party ID among voters may be absent, so the main voting cues voters are left with involve the personal char- acteristics of candidates and patronage. In many new democracies, party organi- zations tend to be transitory, with parties continually entering and leaving the political arena (usually in step with the clout of their party leaders), thereby pro- 578 R.G. Moser, E. Scheiner / Electoral Studies 23 (2004) 575–599 viding little continuity between electoral periods. In such democracies, voters find it hard to cultivate lasting party preferences, leaving most uncommitted to any party. As we discuss below, party institutionalization has major consequences for elec- toral systems’ interaction with party systems. It would be a mistake to assume that institutionaleffects foundinestablished democracies will be replicated inthe very different context of new democracies in East Europe, Eurasia, and Latin America. Through our controlled comparison of PR and SMD tiers of mixed sys- tems in both consolidated and unconsolidated democracies, we can investigate the extent to which the level of party institutionalization conditions electoral system effects. Regarding specific effects of mixed electoral systems, Cox and Schoppa (2002) and HerronandNishikawa (2001) each argue cogently that there will be
Recommended publications
  • The Case for Electoral Reform: a Mixed Member Proportional System
    1 The Case for Electoral Reform: A Mixed Member Proportional System for Canada Brief by Stephen Phillips, Ph.D. Instructor, Department of Political Science, Langara College Vancouver, BC 6 October 2016 2 Summary: In this brief, I urge Parliament to replace our current Single-Member Plurality (SMP) system chiefly because of its tendency to distort the voting intentions of citizens in federal elections and, in particular, to magnify regional differences in the country. I recommend that SMP be replaced by a system of proportional representation, preferably a Mixed Member Proportional system (MMP) similar to that used in New Zealand and the Federal Republic of Germany. I contend that Parliament has the constitutional authority to enact an MMP system under Section 44 of the Constitution Act 1982; as such, it does not require the formal approval of the provinces. Finally, I argue that a national referendum on replacing the current SMP voting system is neither necessary nor desirable. However, to lend it political legitimacy, the adoption of a new electoral system should only be undertaken with the support of MPs from two or more parties that together won over 50% of the votes cast in the last federal election. Introduction Canada’s single-member plurality (SMP) electoral system is fatally flawed. It distorts the true will of Canadian voters, it magnifies regional differences in the country, and it vests excessive political power in the hands of manufactured majority governments, typically elected on a plurality of 40% or less of the popular vote. The adoption of a voting system based on proportional representation would not only address these problems but also improve the quality of democratic government and politics in general.
    [Show full text]
  • An Electoral System Fit for Today? More to Be Done
    HOUSE OF LORDS Select Committee on the Electoral Registration and Administration Act 2013 Report of Session 2019–21 An electoral system fit for today? More to be done Ordered to be printed 22 June 2020 and published 8 July 2020 Published by the Authority of the House of Lords HL Paper 83 Select Committee on the Electoral Registration and Administration Act 2013 The Select Committee on the Electoral Registration and Administration Act 2013 was appointed by the House of Lords on 13 June 2019 “to consider post-legislative scrutiny of the Electoral Registration and Administration Act 2013”. Membership The Members of the Select Committee on the Electoral Registration and Administration Act 2013 were: Baroness Adams of Craigielea (from 15 July 2019) Baroness Mallalieu Lord Campbell-Savours Lord Morris of Aberavon (until 14 July 2019) Lord Dykes Baroness Pidding Baroness Eaton Lord Shutt of Greetland (Chairman) Lord Hayward Baroness Suttie Lord Janvrin Lord Wills Lord Lexden Declaration of interests See Appendix 1. A full list of Members’ interests can be found in the Register of Lords’ Interests: http://www.parliament.uk/mps-lords-and-offices/standards-and-interests/register-of-lords- interests Publications All publications of the Committee are available at: https://committees.parliament.uk/committee/405/electoral-registration-and-administration-act- 2013-committee/publications/ Parliament Live Live coverage of debates and public sessions of the Committee’s meetings are available at: http://www.parliamentlive.tv Further information Further information about the House of Lords and its Committees, including guidance to witnesses, details of current inquiries and forthcoming meetings is available at: http://www.parliament.uk/business/lords Committee staff The staff who worked on this Committee were Simon Keal (Clerk), Katie Barraclough (Policy Analyst) and Breda Twomey (Committee Assistant).
    [Show full text]
  • Who Gains from Apparentments Under D'hondt?
    CIS Working Paper No 48, 2009 Published by the Center for Comparative and International Studies (ETH Zurich and University of Zurich) Who gains from apparentments under D’Hondt? Dr. Daniel Bochsler University of Zurich Universität Zürich Who gains from apparentments under D’Hondt? Daniel Bochsler post-doctoral research fellow Center for Comparative and International Studies Universität Zürich Seilergraben 53 CH-8001 Zürich Switzerland Centre for the Study of Imperfections in Democracies Central European University Nador utca 9 H-1051 Budapest Hungary [email protected] phone: +41 44 634 50 28 http://www.bochsler.eu Acknowledgements I am in dept to Sebastian Maier, Friedrich Pukelsheim, Peter Leutgäb, Hanspeter Kriesi, and Alex Fischer, who provided very insightful comments on earlier versions of this paper. Manuscript Who gains from apparentments under D’Hondt? Apparentments – or coalitions of several electoral lists – are a widely neglected aspect of the study of proportional electoral systems. This paper proposes a formal model that explains the benefits political parties derive from apparentments, based on their alliance strategies and relative size. In doing so, it reveals that apparentments are most beneficial for highly fractionalised political blocs. However, it also emerges that large parties stand to gain much more from apparentments than small parties do. Because of this, small parties are likely to join in apparentments with other small parties, excluding large parties where possible. These arguments are tested empirically, using a new dataset from the Swiss national parliamentary elections covering a period from 1995 to 2007. Keywords: Electoral systems; apparentments; mechanical effect; PR; D’Hondt. Apparentments, a neglected feature of electoral systems Seat allocation rules in proportional representation (PR) systems have been subject to widespread political debate, and one particularly under-analysed subject in this area is list apparentments.
    [Show full text]
  • A Canadian Model of Proportional Representation by Robert S. Ring A
    Proportional-first-past-the-post: A Canadian model of Proportional Representation by Robert S. Ring A thesis submitted to the School of Graduate Studies in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts Department of Political Science Memorial University St. John’s, Newfoundland and Labrador May 2014 ii Abstract For more than a decade a majority of Canadians have consistently supported the idea of proportional representation when asked, yet all attempts at electoral reform thus far have failed. Even though a majority of Canadians support proportional representation, a majority also report they are satisfied with the current electoral system (even indicating support for both in the same survey). The author seeks to reconcile these potentially conflicting desires by designing a uniquely Canadian electoral system that keeps the positive and familiar features of first-past-the- post while creating a proportional election result. The author touches on the theory of representative democracy and its relationship with proportional representation before delving into the mechanics of electoral systems. He surveys some of the major electoral system proposals and options for Canada before finally presenting his made-in-Canada solution that he believes stands a better chance at gaining approval from Canadians than past proposals. iii Acknowledgements First of foremost, I would like to express my sincerest gratitude to my brilliant supervisor, Dr. Amanda Bittner, whose continuous guidance, support, and advice over the past few years has been invaluable. I am especially grateful to you for encouraging me to pursue my Master’s and write about my electoral system idea.
    [Show full text]
  • Election Calendars: Key Dates to Remember. 2020 Congressional Primary Calendar
    Election Calendars: Key Dates to Remember. 2020 Congressional Primary Calendar January February March April May June July August September October November December Primaries Election Day Congressional Primaries Major-party Major-party State Date State Date filing deadline filing deadline Alabama Mar. 3 Nov. 8, 2019 South Carolina Jun. 9 Mar. 30 Arkansas Mar. 3 Nov. 11, 2019 Virginia Jun. 9 Mar. 26 California Mar. 3 Dec. 6, 2019 New York Jun. 23 Apr. 2 North Carolina Mar. 3 Dec. 20, 2019 Utah Jun. 23 Mar. 19 Texas Mar. 3 Dec. 9, 2019 Colorado Jun. 30 Mar. 17 Mississippi Mar. 10 Jan. 15 Oklahoma Jun. 30 Apr. 10 Ohio Mar. 17 Dec. 18, 2019 Arizona Aug. 4 Apr. 6 Illinois Mar. 17 Dec. 2, 2019 Kansas Aug. 4 Jun. 1 Maryland Apr. 28 Feb. 5 Michigan Aug. 4 Apr. 21 Pennsylvania Apr. 28 Feb. 18 Missouri Aug. 4 Mar. 31 Indiana May 5 Feb. 7 Washington Aug. 4 May 15 Nebraska May 12 Feb. 18 (incumbents); Tennessee Aug. 6 Apr. 2 Mar. 2 (non-incumbents) Hawaii Aug. 8 Jun. 2 West Virginia May 12 Jan. 25 Connecticut Aug. 11 Jun. 9 Georgia May 19 Mar. 6 Minnesota Aug. 11 Jun. 2 Idaho May 19 Mar. 13 Vermont Aug. 11 May 28 Kentucky May 19 Jan. 28 Wisconsin Aug. 11 Jun. 1 Oregon May 19 Mar. 10 Alaska Aug. 18 Jun. 1 Iowa Jun. 2 Mar. 13 Florida Aug. 18 Apr. 24 Montana Jun. 2 Mar. 9 Wyoming Aug. 18 May 29 New Jersey Jun. 2 Mar. 30 New Sept. 8 Jun.
    [Show full text]
  • Legislature by Lot: Envisioning Sortition Within a Bicameral System
    PASXXX10.1177/0032329218789886Politics & SocietyGastil and Wright 789886research-article2018 Special Issue Article Politics & Society 2018, Vol. 46(3) 303 –330 Legislature by Lot: Envisioning © The Author(s) 2018 Article reuse guidelines: Sortition within a Bicameral sagepub.com/journals-permissions https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329218789886DOI: 10.1177/0032329218789886 System* journals.sagepub.com/home/pas John Gastil Pennsylvania State University Erik Olin Wright University of Wisconsin–Madison Abstract In this article, we review the intrinsic democratic flaws in electoral representation, lay out a set of principles that should guide the construction of a sortition chamber, and argue for the virtue of a bicameral system that combines sortition and elections. We show how sortition could prove inclusive, give citizens greater control of the political agenda, and make their participation more deliberative and influential. We consider various design challenges, such as the sampling method, legislative training, and deliberative procedures. We explain why pairing sortition with an elected chamber could enhance its virtues while dampening its potential vices. In our conclusion, we identify ideal settings for experimenting with sortition. Keywords bicameral legislatures, deliberation, democratic theory, elections, minipublics, participation, political equality, sortition Corresponding Author: John Gastil, Department of Communication Arts & Sciences, Pennsylvania State University, 232 Sparks Bldg., University Park, PA 16802, USA. Email: [email protected] *This special issue of Politics & Society titled “Legislature by Lot: Transformative Designs for Deliberative Governance” features a preface, an introductory anchor essay and postscript, and six articles that were presented as part of a workshop held at the University of Wisconsin–Madison, September 2017, organized by John Gastil and Erik Olin Wright.
    [Show full text]
  • Ronald Reagan, Louisiana, and the 1980 Presidential Election Matthew Ad Vid Caillet Louisiana State University and Agricultural and Mechanical College
    Louisiana State University LSU Digital Commons LSU Master's Theses Graduate School 2011 "Are you better off "; Ronald Reagan, Louisiana, and the 1980 Presidential election Matthew aD vid Caillet Louisiana State University and Agricultural and Mechanical College Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.lsu.edu/gradschool_theses Part of the History Commons Recommended Citation Caillet, Matthew David, ""Are you better off"; Ronald Reagan, Louisiana, and the 1980 Presidential election" (2011). LSU Master's Theses. 2956. https://digitalcommons.lsu.edu/gradschool_theses/2956 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at LSU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in LSU Master's Theses by an authorized graduate school editor of LSU Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ―ARE YOU BETTER OFF‖; RONALD REAGAN, LOUISIANA, AND THE 1980 PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION A Thesis Submitted to the Graduate Faculty of the Louisiana State University and Agricultural and Mechanical College in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts in The Department of History By Matthew David Caillet B.A. and B.S., Louisiana State University, 2009 May 2011 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I am indebted to many people for the completion of this thesis. Particularly, I cannot express how thankful I am for the guidance and assistance I received from my major professor, Dr. David Culbert, in researching, drafting, and editing my thesis. I would also like to thank Dr. Wayne Parent and Dr. Alecia Long for having agreed to serve on my thesis committee and for their suggestions and input, as well.
    [Show full text]
  • Single Transferable Vote Resists Strategic Voting
    Single Transferable Vote Resists Strategic Voting John J. Bartholdi, III School of Industrial and Systems Engineering Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, GA 30332 James B. Orlin Sloan School of Management Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA 02139 November 13, 1990; revised April 4, 2003 Abstract We give evidence that Single Tranferable Vote (STV) is computation- ally resistant to manipulation: It is NP-complete to determine whether there exists a (possibly insincere) preference that will elect a favored can- didate, even in an election for a single seat. Thus strategic voting under STV is qualitatively more difficult than under other commonly-used vot- ing schemes. Furthermore, this resistance to manipulation is inherent to STV and does not depend on hopeful extraneous assumptions like the presumed difficulty of learning the preferences of the other voters. We also prove that it is NP-complete to recognize when an STV elec- tion violates monotonicity. This suggests that non-monotonicity in STV elections might be perceived as less threatening since it is in effect “hid- den” and hard to exploit for strategic advantage. 1 1 Strategic voting For strategic voting the fundamental problem for any would-be manipulator is to decide what preference to claim. We will show that this modest task can be impractically difficult under the voting scheme known as Single Transferable Vote (STV). Furthermore this difficulty pertains even in the ideal situation in which the manipulator knows the preferences of all other voters and knows that they will vote their complete and sincere preferences. Thus STV is apparently unique among voting schemes in actual use today in that it is computationally resistant to manipulation.
    [Show full text]
  • Appendix A: Electoral Rules
    Appendix A: Electoral Rules Table A.1 Electoral Rules for Italy’s Lower House, 1948–present Time Period 1948–1993 1993–2005 2005–present Plurality PR with seat Valle d’Aosta “Overseas” Tier PR Tier bonus national tier SMD Constituencies No. of seats / 6301 / 32 475/475 155/26 617/1 1/1 12/4 districts Election rule PR2 Plurality PR3 PR with seat Plurality PR (FPTP) bonus4 (FPTP) District Size 1–54 1 1–11 617 1 1–6 (mean = 20) (mean = 6) (mean = 4) Note that the acronym FPTP refers to First Past the Post plurality electoral system. 1The number of seats became 630 after the 1962 constitutional reform. Note the period of office is always 5 years or less if the parliament is dissolved. 2Imperiali quota and LR; preferential vote; threshold: one quota and 300,000 votes at national level. 3Hare Quota and LR; closed list; threshold: 4% of valid votes at national level. 4Hare Quota and LR; closed list; thresholds: 4% for lists running independently; 10% for coalitions; 2% for lists joining a pre-electoral coalition, except for the best loser. Ballot structure • Under the PR system (1948–1993), each voter cast one vote for a party list and could express a variable number of preferential votes among candidates of that list. • Under the MMM system (1993–2005), each voter received two separate ballots (the plurality ballot and the PR one) and cast two votes: one for an individual candidate in a single-member district; one for a party in a multi-member PR district. • Under the PR-with-seat-bonus system (2005–present), each voter cast one vote for a party list.
    [Show full text]
  • Presidential Commission on the Supreme Court of the United States
    Presidential Commission on the Supreme Court of the United States The Contemporary Debate over Supreme Court Reform: Origins and Perspectives Written Statement of Nikolas Bowie Assistant Professor of Law, Harvard Law School June 30, 2021 Co-Chair Rodriguez, Co-Chair Bauer, and members of the Commission, thank you for inviting me to testify. You have asked for my opinion about the causes of the current public debate over reforming the Supreme Court of the United States, the competing arguments for and against reform at this time, and how the commission should evaluate those arguments. The cause of the current public debate over reforming the Supreme Court is longstanding: Americans rightfully hold democracy as our highest political ideal, yet the Supreme Court is an antidemocratic institution. The primary source of concern is judicial review, or the power of the Court to decline to enforce a federal law when a majority of the justices disagree with a majority of Congress about the law’s constitutionality. I will focus on two arguments for reforming the Supreme Court, both of which object to the antidemocratic nature of judicial review. First, as a matter of historical practice, the Court has wielded an antidemocratic influence on American law, one that has undermined federal attempts to eliminate hierarchies of race, wealth, and status. Second, as a matter of political theory, the Court’s exercise of judicial review undermines the value that distinguishes democracy as an ideal form of government: its pursuit of political equality. Both arguments compete with counterarguments that judicial review is necessary to preserve the political equality of so-called discrete and insular minorities.
    [Show full text]
  • Improving the Top-Two Primary for Congressional and State Races
    Towards a More Perfect Election: Improving the Top-Two Primary for Congressional and State Races CHENWEI ZHANG* I. INTRODUCTION .............................................................................. 615 1I. B ACKGROUN D ................................................................................ 620 A. An Overview of the Law RegardingPrimaries ....................... 620 1. Types of Primaries............................................................ 620 2. Supreme Court JurisprudenceRegarding Political Partiesand Primaries....................................................... 622 B. The Evolution of the Top-Two Primary.................................. 624 1. A laska................................................................................ 62 5 2. L ouisiana .......................................................................... 625 3. California ......................................................................... 626 4. Washington ............................. ... 627 5. O regon ........................................... ................................... 630 I1. THE PROS AND CONS OF Top-Two PRIMARIES .............................. 630 A . P ros ......................................................................................... 63 1 1. ModeratingEffects ............................................................ 631 2. Increasing Voter Turnout................................................... 633 B . C ons ....................................................................................... 633
    [Show full text]
  • Documentation
    HOUSE BILL NO. 1 ENROLLED TABLE OF CONTENTS SCHEDULE 01 - EXECUTIVE DEPARTMENT ..................................13 01-100 Executive Office ...........................................13 Administrative ..........................................13 Governor's Office of Coastal Activities .......................14 01-101 Office of Indian Affairs ......................................14 01-102 Office of the Inspector General ................................15 01-103 Mental Health Advocacy Service ..............................15 01-106 Louisiana Tax Commission ...................................16 01-107 Division of Administration ...................................17 Executive Administration ..................................17 Community Development Block Grant .......................17 Auxiliary Account .......................................18 01-109 Coastal Protection & Restoration Authority ......................19 01-111 Governor's Office of Homeland Security and Emergency Preparedness .........................................20 01-112 Department of Military Affairs ................................22 Military Affairs Program ..................................22 Education Program .......................................23 Auxiliary Account .......................................23 01-116 Louisiana Public Defender Board ..............................24 01-124 Louisiana Stadium and Exposition District .......................25 01-129 Louisiana Commission on Law Enforcement and the Administration of Criminal Justice ........................26
    [Show full text]