A Simple Model of Levies: Implications for

Harmonization

Jin-Hyuk Kim

Abstract

This paper analyzes optimal copyright levies in a representative consumer model

and derives welfare implications for harmonization of levy rates. When the policymak-

ers place enough weight on the interests of collecting societies, harmonization could

lead to a reduction in social welfare. When countries are asymmetric, the country

with a larger proportion of foreign consumption and more ine¢ cient system loses

more from harmonization. A calibration exercise using European data shows that har-

monization would increase aggregate welfare. In some countries, both consumers and

policymakers are better o¤; however, in others, policymakers are worse o¤ although

consumers would gain from harmonization. (JEL F42, O34, O52)

Keywords: copyright levies; international harmonization

Department of Economics, University of Colorado at Boulder. E-mail: [email protected].

1 1 Introduction

A copyright levy, also called as a private copying levy, is a special tax that is charged on

various copying equipment and blank media that consumers use to produce copies for private

use and for non-commercial purposes. The levy systems were introduced in many European

countries under the EU Directive on the harmonisation of certain aspects of copyright and

related rights in the information society (2001/29/EC).1 However, there is no European- wide levy system, but each Member States sets di¤erent levy rates to the same recording equipment and media. In all instances, the levies are set and administered by copyright collecting societies acting on behalf of rights holders.2 This process has often prompted heated national debates over the appropriate level of levies.

On the other hand, national variation in the size of levies distorts the single market, and the European Commission has attempted to harmonize copyright levies. The initiative launched by Charlie McCreevy, the Internal Markets Commissioner for the EU, in 2006 to harmonize levies was, however, aborted after political pressure from France. Press reports say that McCreevy was forced to back down by Commission President, who was indirectly pressured by French collecting societies and by the French government allegedly because income from the levies is used to …nance cultural events and projects (Mallinder 2008; Nie- mann 2010). Since then, the variation in levies remains considerable. For instance, in 2010

1 The Directive, in particular Article 5.2(b), allows Member States to introduce a variety of private copying exceptions and to provide for fair compensation for rightholders for the use made of their protected works. 22 out of the 27 Member States have implemented the exception accompanied by a levy system. In Ireland and the UK, private copying exceptions other than the time-shifting of broadcasts are not authorised, whereas in Malta, Greece, and Luxembourg, private copying exceptions were legislated into a law but no levy system has been introduced or enforced. 2 For instance, rightholders in foreign countries receive their dues via their local collecting society under the series of bilateral reciprocal agreements that each collecting society has with its sister societies in other countries.

2 the levy on a CD varies from e0.35 in France to e0.03 in Switzerland.

Collecting societies seem to wield in‡uence by lobbying at the national and supranational level. Levy rates have been increasing, and legislations to cut levies have been deterred.

Levies are often considered as a source of revenue for collecting societies as well as for rightholders. In particular, collective societies, before distributing the collected levies to domestic or foreign rightholders, often deduct a part of the collections to fund a variety of social and cultural programs for national artists from festivals to pension funds.

The proportion of deductions are set by the national laws, which vary across countries.

That is, cultural funds are a matter of national policy with little cross-border e¤ects, so the deductions are set by each country’spolicymaker even if the levy were harmonized.

This paper builds a simple model to capture some of the salient features of copyright levy system. Based on the premise of the Directive that private copying causes economic harm to the rightholders, the model assumes that the levies can substitute in for the lower income that would result under private copying. Following Johnson (1985), the focus is on the long run, and I assume that the supply of creative goods would depend positively on the amount of creator’sremuneration. In addition, the e¢ ciency loss associated with commodity taxation is captured with an increasing function of levy rate, and the national policymakers are assumed to maximize the weighted sum of a representative consumer’s utility and the size of cultural funds re‡ecting the collecting societies’in‡uence on them.

The basic …ndings are intuitive. The levy rate chosen by the policymaker is always positive because of the market failure. Deduction for cultural funds is provided only when the policymaker places a su¢ ciently large weight on the interests of collecting societies.

At the interior solution, the levy rate increases with the collecting society’s in‡uence and

3 decreases with the marginal cost of taxation. An increase in consumer’s marginal utility reduces the size of cultural funds, but the levy rate remains the same. This basic model is then extended to a two-country setting to investigate the e¤ects of harmonization of levy rates across countries, where the two countries are linked through leakages and injections of levy collections that are distributed to foreign rightholders after deductions.

As is well known in the literature on macroeconomic policy coordination, harmoniza- tion of levies would internalize the spillovers across countries. This can be seen clearly in a symmetric country case, where the harmonized levy would be higher relative to the non- cooperative level. However, under the in‡uence of collecting societies, this means that the levy is even higher, so that both countries could be made worse o¤ after harmonization.

When countries are asymmetric, the country with a larger share of foreign consumption and more ine¢ ciency from commodity taxation would see its levy increase due to harmoniza- tion, and thus would be made worse o¤. Therefore, in the real world, where countries are heterogeneous, the aggregate welfare e¤ects could be ambiguous.

To assess how well the model explains the real world and what predictions it yields regarding the harmonization e¤orts, I calibrate the above model using available data on how the levies were distributed to domestic and foreign rights holders, respectively, and for the social and cultural purposes in ten European countries. The estimated policymaker’s weight on the size of cultural funds is three times larger than the weight on a representative consumer, from which each countries’ine¢ ciency parameter is backed out. The harmonized levy rate is calculated by maximizing the aggregate utility of the policymakers using both equal weight as well as the actual number of votes in the European Council. Given this, the size of cultural funds are determined by each policymaker.

4 This exercise reveals that while the harmonization increases the aggregate social welfare, which is de…ned as the sum of each country’sconsumer welfare including any e¢ ciency loss but excluding the policymaker’s weight on cultural funds, there is a considerable variation across countries. For instance, Germany and Spain gain the most from the harmonization and their policymakers are also made better o¤ with harmonized levies. However, in some countries, like France and Austria, the policymakers are made worse o¤ and thus may oppose to harmonization initiatives despite that their consumer welfare would increase moderately.

Another …nding is that a fewer number of policymakers would be made worse o¤ by the harmonization if the countries’voting rights were equally distributed.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 brie‡y discusses the rele- vant literature. Section 3 lays out the basic model and characterizes the equilibrium. Section

4 extends the model to a two-country setting and analyzes the implications of harmoniza- tion both for symmetric and asymmetric countries. Section 5 calibrates the model using data from ten European countries and calculates the welfare consequences of counterfactual, harmonized levies. Section 6 concludes.

2 Literature Review

Economists have taken an interest in the copying and copyright issues with the advances of copying technologies. The two most thoroughly investigated issues appear to be the short- run pricing e¤ect and the optimal level of copyright protection.3 Recently, researchers have

3 See, for example, Novos and Waldman (1984) and Liebowitz (1985). The literature has developed well beyond these seminal papers, which I do not attempt to survey here. See Peitz and Waelbroeck (2006) and Towse et al. (2008) for recent surveys.

5 begun to examine the issue of hardware taxation or copyright levies. For instance, Chen and Png (2003) show that it is socially optimal to charge a levy on copying media rather than to impose a …ne on infringing users. In Gayer and Shy (2003), the optimal levy rate is positive when piracy endangers the existence of creative industry which has a high …xed cost. Kinokuni (2005) adds that the optimal levy rate could be positive because if the levy is too low, then creators may adopt copy-protection technology.

The strength of this short-run framework is its micro-foundation of pro…t-maximizing behavior for a given copyrighted good, whereas long-run analysis that addresses the supply response has been generally lacking in these models. An important exception is Johnson

(1985), who captures the supply response in the long run with a simple reduced form equation that is an increasing function of the pro…t.4 He then performs social welfare calculation based on his model and …nds that the optimal levy can be a large fraction (68 percent) of the market price of the originals because the long-run bene…t exceeds the short-run cost. This paper contributes to the long-run assessment of the copyright levy system that takes into account the in‡uence of collecting societies on the policymakers.5

This paper is also related to the literature on international policy coordination. The traditional approach is to model interacting governments as optimizing agents who choose policy instruments. Not surprisingly, the basic …nding is that, in models of international spillovers, coordination can lead to an e¢ ciency gain. In some instances, however, policy

4 Another strand of literature examines the supply response to changes in copyright terms, where recent empirical evidence suggests that the current copyright term may be excessive (see, e.g., Boldrin and Levine 2009; Png and Wang 2009). 5 Huang and Png (2010) empirically …nd some evidence that levies are in‡uenced by both content produc- ers’slobbying and the median consumer’spreference. More speci…cally, the odds of having a levy system are higher in countries where consumers’ethical costs are lower, which is consistent with lobbying equilibrium. However, when interacted with a measure of democracy, the odds are lower with lower ethical costs, which is an evidence that levies are also in‡uenced by consumers’preferences.

6 coordination can be counterproductive.6 In investigating incentives to harmonize intellectual protection through international treaties, Scotchmer (2004) shows that harmoniza- tion can improve upon tendencies to underprovide unilateral protection due to out‡ow of pro…ts, but it is not an e¢ cient solution when unilateral protection is su¢ cient for incentives or public sponsorship is the most e¢ cient way to fund R&D.

This paper shows another channel through which policy coordination may reduce welfare.

That is, when the policymaker maximizes his own objective function that weighs more heav- ily on lobbying group than social welfare, coordination which internalizes foreign spillovers could move government policy in the direction of reducing social welfare. When countries are asymmetric and policies are strategic substitutes, Casella (1992) shows that not all cooper- ative equilibria will dominate noncooperative solution, in particular, from the point of view of smaller or weaker countries. This general intuition holds in this paper, too. Moreover, calibration results seem consistent with Casella’s argument that the weaker countries need more than proportional weight in common policy-making.

3 The Model

Consider a society, which is populated by a unit measure of identical consumers who have quasi-linear preferences on consumption of copyrighted goods and a numeraire. I assume that due to an easy access to copying technology and the prohibitive cost of monitoring

6 A well-known case is that when policymakers face time-inconsistency problems, coordination eliminates competition between policymakers, who then become more opportunistic ex post and adopt a policy that reduces the representative citizen’swelfare (Rogo¤ 1985).

7 private copying, the measure of consumers who purchase the originals is zero in equilibrium.7

That is, market failure occurs and no copyrighted goods will be supplied without e¤ective

copyright protection because of its public good nature. Thus, the government has to tax the

sale of copying equipment and/or blank media as a second-best solution. The government

also determines how much to deduct from the levy collections for cultural funds.

These funds are spent on hosting various cultural and social events as well as supporting

welfare programs for authors and artists. I assume that the number of authors and artists

is …nite, hence measure zero, so that the spent on cultural funds do not contribute to the

social welfare, which in this model is the same as consumer welfare. This is a simplifying

assumption, but on the other hand, the use of such deductions has not been well understood

due to the closed nature of the collecting society’s businesses. Moreover, recently, some

collecting societies have been charged with fraudulently siphoning o¤ funds destined for

artists. Let  and  denote the size of the levy and cultural deductions per consumer.

After deduction, levy proceeds are distributed to the rightholders as private copying

remuneration, which stimulates the long-run supply. I assume a simple linear production

technology, l =  , where l is the supply of creative goods.8 Assume that the consumer’s utility function u(l) satis…es the Inada conditions. The levies also create the usual deadweight loss associated with commodity taxation, which is captured by a continuous convex function

(), where 0() > 0, (0) = 0, and 0(0) = 0. The cultural funds as well as the levies are

7 Note that it is due to the nature of representative consumer model that an individual chooses to copy rather than buy the original although he knows that all the other individuals would act in the same way. Assuming heterogeneous copying costs, which leads to a non-zero fraction of the consumers buying the original goods, does not have a substantive implication in this paper. Thus, I abtract from the issue of whether private copying levy is necessary at all. 8 This is in fact not a crucial assumption because to satisfy the second-order condition, it su¢ ces to assume that the consumer’sutility, u(l), is concave in  and . That is, production technology may exhibit decreasing or moderately increasing returns to scale as long as utility from consumption is su¢ ciently concave.

8 administered by collecting societies, and as monopoly entities in many European countries, they have been successful in in‡uencing the policymakers through lobbying.

Following the literature on bureaucracy (e.g., Niskanen 1968), I assume that the col- lecting societies maximize their discretionary budget (i.e., cultural funds), . On the other hand, the policymaker’sobjective function can be drawn from the literature on lobbying. For instance, Grossman and Helpman (1994) focus on truthful equilibrium of a model in which the government policymaker maximizes a weighted sum of social welfare and campaign con- tributions and the lobbying group is willing to contribute up to the maximum bene…t they derive from the policy. Thus, I assume that the policymaker maximizes a weighted sum of social welfare and the size of cultural funds, which collecting societies are willing to pay:

max u( )  () +  (1) ;

s.t.  0,  0,  ,    where  < is the weight attached to the interests of the collecting societies. 1

An interior solution ( ; ) of the above maximization problem is characterized by the following two …rst-order conditions:

 = 1 + 0( ) (2)

 = u0(  ). (3)

From equation (2), it follows that the rate of copying levy,  , depends on the marginal costs of commodity taxation, 0(), and the weight policymaker places on the size of cultural

9 funds, . However, the following proposition shows that if the weight placed on cultural funds is relatively low, then the policymaker does not provide any cultural funds ( = 0) although the levy rate is always positive (  > 0). The intuitive reason for this is that unless  is larger than the cost of raising public funds, the policymaker would rather reduce both the levy rate and cultural funds to bene…t consumers than set aside any cultural funds. The following propositions characterize the policymaker’s optimal choice ( ; ) and show comparative statics results. All proofs are collected in the Appendix.

Proposition 1. There exists a value  > 1 such that the following characterizes domestic policy.

(i) For  ,   > 0 and  = 0, where u0( ) = 1 + 0( ) and u0( ) = . 

(ii) For  > ,   > 0 and   >  > 0, where  = 1 + 0( ) and u0(  ) = .

(iii) Both   and  are continuous functions of .

 Proposition 2. Let i denote the threshold value when i0 () and ui0 () are indexed by i = A; B.

(i) For  ,   does not depend on ; for  > , both   and  increase in .     (ii) If A0 () > B0 (), then,  A <  B for any ; A < B for  > B, where A > B.   (iii) If u0 () > u0 (), then,   >   for  < A and   =   for  A;  <  for A B A B A B  A B     > B, where A > B.

Figure 1 depicts how the policymaker chooses the levy rate   when   and  > ,  respectively. In Figure 1.(a), the policymaker equates the marginal cost of raising public

10 funds, 1 + 0(), with the marginal social bene…t, u0( ). On the other hand, in Figure

1.(b), the policymaker equates the marginal social cost with his private marginal bene…t

from providing the cultural funds, . That is, when  is su¢ ciently high, social welfare is

at a suboptimal level because the policymaker substitutes social marginal bene…t with his

private marginal bene…t although there is no distortion on the cost of raising public funds,

that is, 1 + 0().

This accords well with the …ndings in Proposition 2. For instance, in 2.(i), the e¤ect of

an increase in  is to increase both   and  when the policymaker places su¢ cient weight

on cultural funds. In 2.(iii), an increase in the consumer’smarginal utility does not lead to a

higher rate of   when  is su¢ ciently high, although the policymaker responds by reducing

the size of cultural deduction before distributing remuneration. On the other hand, 2.(ii)

says that the policymaker always responds to an increase in the marginal cost of taxation

by both decreasing the levy rate and, where applicable, reducing the size of cultural funds.

The implication for social welfare is straightforward. The policymaker’sobjective func-

tion coincides with social welfare when  = 0. Proposition 1 says that the policymaker

behaves as if he maximizes the social welfare as long as  . That is,   does not depend  on  and  = 0, which indeed maximize the social welfare. However, when  is greater than

,   starts to exceed the socially optimal level, which creates an e¢ ciency loss. Moreover, a positive  starts to get transferred to collecting societies, so it further decreases consumers’ welfare. Therefore, an increase in  beyond  causes social welfare to decrease.

11 4 Harmonization

Consider two countries, i = 1; 2, each with a unit measure of identical consumers as speci…ed in the previous Section. These two countries are linked together by the fact that some fraction, 0 < i < 1, of the consumption of creative goods in country i are imports from country j = i. Hence, of the levy collection in country i ‡ows out of country i to the 6 i rightholders in country j. On the other hand, cultural funds are used to sponsor domestic programs only and hence are not transferred to the other country. In a noncooperative policy- setting game, domestic policies ( i, i) are chosen by the policymakers in each country i, who maximize the following objective function:

max u((1 i) i i + j j)  i ( i) + i. (4)  i;i

9 In the following, I assume an interior solution ( i > 0, i > 0) for both countries. Then, the noncooperative solution is characterized by the following …rst-order conditions:

(1 ) = 1 + 0( ), i = 1; 2, (5) i i

 = u0((1 )   +  j), i = 1; 2, j = i. (6) i i i j 6

From (5), it follows that  i <  , where   is the levy rate chosen in autarky. In a cooperative policy-setting context, on the other hand, the same levy rate,  h, has to be chosen to maximize the sum of the two policymakers’ objective functions. That is, the

9 Considering the corner solution does not bring any technical innovation to the following analysis, but it only changes the strict welfare comparison to "at least as good as" statement.

12 two countries have equal weight in a global policy-making body.10 However, it is assumed that the size of cultural funds are still set by the national policymakers. This is because, say, in Europe sponsoring cultural activities would have little Internal Market relevance.11

Note that since cultural activities do not have cross-border spillover e¤ects, the policymakers

h h h choose ( , 1 , 2 ) simultaneously:

max u((1 1) 1 + 2)  () + 1 (7) ;1;2

+u((1 ) 2 + )  () + 2. 2 1

It is straightforward to show that international policy coordination restores the levy rates

h to the level policymakers would have chosen without spillovers, that is,  =  .

The following result may seem counterintuitive, but it can be explained by the fact that policymakers tend to choose too high a levy rate when they place a su¢ ciently large weight on cultural funds. Levy rates are lower in the noncooperative regime than in the cooperative case because some fraction of levy collection ‡ows out of the country. However, the previous Section establishes that a larger  means a lower domestic welfare, holding other factors constant. By internalizing the externalities, policy coordination increases the levy rate, which reduces social welfare. Even if the corner solution is considered, harmonization cannot increase social welfare in the symmetric country case.

10 The fact that the population as well as decision weight of the two countries are the same does not have substantive qualitative implications for the results that follow. Both assumptions will be relaxed in the next Section when the model is brought to the data. 11 This is similar to the reason why “it would be hard to understand that the Commission would set a cap on, say, an obligation for certain types of companies to dedicate part of their pro…ts to R&D that was established by a Member State’s legislation” (European Grouping of Societies of Authors and Composers 2008).

13 The level of social welfare in the noncooperative and cooperative equilibria is de…ned as

h h h h h h SW  = ui((1 )  +  )   i( ) and SW = ui((1 )  +  )  i( ) i i i i j j i i i i i j h for i = 1; 2, and let SWi = SW SW  denote the welfare change in country i from i i harmonization.

Proposition 3. Let SWi denote the level of social welfare in country i when i is indexed by i.

(i) If the two countries are identical in all respects, then SW1 = SW2 < 0.

(ii) If the two countries are identical except 1 > 2, then SW1 < SW2 < 0.

Proposition 3.(ii) says that, when countries are asymmetric in terms of foreign depen- dence, both countries are still worse o¤ under harmonized levy system; however, the country with less foreign dependence (i = 2) su¤ers less than the other country (i = 1) does. The rea-

h son is as follows. Since  i is determined by equation (5), 1 > 2 > 0 implies  1 <  2 <  , which means that to harmonize the levy rate, country 1 has to increase the levy rate more than country 2 has to. Thus, the social welfare loss, de…ned as the area below the social marginal cost of raising additional public funds, 1 + 0(), is larger in country 1 than in country 2. This area is illustrated in Figure 2.

One might wonder why the size of remuneration distribution net of cultural deduction does not change after harmonization of levy rates. The intuitive reason is that when the policymaker sets the domestic policy i, he will transfer funds to collecting societies until consumers’marginal utility equals the policymaker’sprivate marginal bene…t, . This means that any level change in domestic levy rate as well as net in‡ow (or out‡ow) of levy collections

14 between countries are completely absorbed by changes in cultural funds. Therefore, as long

as consumers’utility functions are the same across countries, there is no secondary e¤ect on

consumer surplus through adjustments in i.

The next result considers two di¤erent types of asymmetry between countries. Proposi-

tion 4.(i) says that when the marginal social cost of raising public fund is smaller in country

2 than in country 1, all other things equal, country 2 is better o¤ than country 1 under har- monized levy system, both in absolute and relative terms. That is, country 2 either su¤ers less from increased levy or in fact gains from reduced levy rate. The intuition here is that absent any international spillover, the harmonized levy rate is determined by the average of

h the two social marginal cost functions, which means  1 <  <  2. This force holds even in the presence of payment externality, hence the result.

Proposition 4. Let SWi denote the level of social welfare in country i when i0 () and ui0 () are indexed by i.

(i) If the two countries are identical except 10 () > 20 (), then SW1 < 0 and SW1 <

SW2.

(ii) If the two countries are identical except u0 () = u0 (), then SW1 = SW2 < 0. 1 6 2

Proposition 4.(ii) adds that there are no welfare implications with regard to the shape of consumers’ utility function. The logic is similar to the above. That is, because the domestic policymaker can completely undo the e¤ects of harmonization on consumer surplus by adjusting the size of cultural funds, the net remuneration to domestic rightholders after any deductions and additions remains the same yielding the same amount of surplus. The

15 results in Proposition 4.(i) and 4.(ii) are illustrated in Figures 3 and 4, respectively. The

above Propositions imply that welfare implications of harmonization could be quite complex

when the two countries di¤er in more than one respect.

5 Calibration Exercise

In this Section, I estimate the welfare consequences of harmonized levy system by …tting

real world data to the model and calculating counterfactual, harmonized levy rate for ten

European countries. This exercise is intended to only illustrate how the model can be

applied to actual data; hence, caution needs to be exercised when interpreting the results

of this exercise. Here the key identifying assumption is that the levy rates,  i, are mainly determined by variations in foreign dependence and the cost of raising public funds across countries. This means that I hold constant the policymakers’weight on cultural funds and the consumers’utility function across countries.12

The dataset comprises all European countries for which the following data is available: levy rate on CD-R, size of cultural deduction, share of foreign distribution after deduction (see

Table 1). Due to paucity of data, only 10 countries satisfy this requirement, and especially I was able to obtain the data on cultural deduction and foreign share of each country only for

2004.13 Annual data on copyright levies are made available by the Dutch Private Copying

12 The …rst part of this assumption may be justi…ed by the fact that there are lobbying activities at both national and supranational level, such as in the European Union or World Intellectual Property Organization, by national collecting societies and their umbrella organization. The second part of the assumption is simplifying. 13 The original data is provided by European Grouping of Societies of Authors and Composers (GESAC), which represents 34 of the main collective copyright management societies in the European Union, Nor- way, and Switzerland, and the table is contained in the European Commission’s First Call for Comments, “Copyright Levies in a Converging World”in 2006.

16 Society through international surveys.14 Levy rates as well as populations are based on 2005 data. These do not vary substantially across years, so the following results should not be very sensitive to the particular year chosen here.

The overview of the calibration strategy is as follows. I …rst assume two functional forms

i 2 to estimate a structural model: u(l) = ln l and i( i) = 2  i . From the …rst-order conditions,

this yields  i as a function of i, i, and . I also derive a regression equation (which will follow shortly) that relates  i to i. From the regression of this equation, parameter  is

identi…ed and estimated (which is roughly 3). Using the estimated value of , parameter

i can be recovered from the expression for  i. With these estimated values, I calculate

h h counterfactual, harmonized levy rate  and the size of cultural funds i as predicted by

h h the model in the previous Section. Social welfare is then evaluated at ( i; i) and ( ; i )

together with those estimated parameter values, which allows welfare comparison between

the two cases.

In the noncooperative setting, the policymakers’objective function is as follows:

 i  i i  i 2 max ln (1 i) i + j ( ) , (8)  i;i 2  

where j = ( j=i j jj)=i represents the in‡ow of foreign levy collections to domestic 6 P rightholders adjusted by the total population (i) in each country i and j. Additionally,

1 is a scale factor which means that the average consumer consumes unit of blank CDs in

a year, and i is the size of cultural funds divided by the population. Assuming an interior

14 See Png and Wang (2009) for an analysis using this panel data. The reason why other types of copyright levies (e.g., on MP3 players) are not used in the following analysis is that, …rst, those levy rates vary widely with the speci…cations of the devices; second, the levies are modelled in this paper as marginal costs rather than a …xed cost, so levy on blank CD is more suitable for this analysis.

17 solution, the two …rst-order conditions are

1 i 1   = + i i , (9) 1 i 2  i i + j 1 = . (10) 1 i  i i + j

Rearranging (10) yields

(1 ) i = + i j. (11) i 

The foreign in‡ow, j, is not observed in the dataset, but the term j might be quite small. This is because most of foreign consumption in European countries are due to rights holders in the USA or UK (which are not in the dataset) rather than from each other. Given the cultural di¤erences between the sample countries, this may be a plausible assumption.

Moreover, there is an o¤setting e¤ect. Because collecting societies deduct a small portion of levy collections as administration fees, i could underestimate the size of all deductions prior to redistribution. If one believes that either these two forces roughly o¤set each other or there are other enough random factors, then I can specify the regression equation as follows:

(1 ) i = + i + "i, (12) i  the estimate of which yields,

(1 ) i = :1074 + :3189 i, i

(:028) (:162) where robust standard errors are in the parentheses and the coe¢ cients are signi…cant at

18 the 1- and 10-percent level, respectively. By taking the ratio of the two coe¢ cient, the point

estimate of parameter  is :3189 2:9693. :1074 ' Combining (9) and (10) yields

((1 i) 1)  i = . (13) i

Since  i, i, , and estimates are known, i can be calculated for each country i.

In the cooperative setting, the policymakers maximize a weighted sum of each policy- makers’ utility function multiplied by the decision weight, wi, attached to each country i = 1; : : : ; n. Again, ignoring the j term, it is straightforward to show that the following two …rst-order conditions hold:

1 i 1   w i = 0, (14) i  h h 2 (1 i) i ! i X 1 = . (15) (1 )  h h i i

Using (14) and (15), harmonized levy rate and the size of cultural funds can be calculated as follows.

 si(1 ) 1  h = i i , (16) 1 s  P i i i  h 1 h = max (1P ) ; 0 , (17) i f i  g

where si = wi= i wi is the country i’sshare of the decision rights.

P 1 In the …rst scenario, countries have equal decision power, si = n , in setting the har-

19 monized levy rate. The …rst two columns in Table 2 show the counterfactual, harmonized

levy rate and each countries’(per capita) size of cultural funds implied by the model. The

harmonized levy rate is around e0:12 per CD, and the model also predicts that in most

countries (except in the case of Latvia) cultural funds will not be provided under harmo-

nized levy system. The next two columns compare the individual social welfare evaluated at

h h h ( ; ) and ( ;  ). The signs of SWi = SW SW  indicate that in seven out of the i i i i i ten countries, social welfare increases at the national level, whereas it decreases in the other

three countries.

On the other hand, the last three columns calculate and compare the national policymak-

ers’private utility before and after the harmonization. The policymaker’sutility is denoted

as DMi, and it includes an additional term, i, to account for the collecting societies’in-

h ‡uence. The signs of DMi = DM DM  indicate that …ve out of the ten countries’ i i policymakers stand to lose from the harmonization. In particular, there are con‡icts of in- terests in the sense that in Austria, Denmark, and France, policymakers would lose whereas consumers gain under harmonized levy system. This is mainly because in most countries, the levy rate will fall after harmonization and policymakers can no longer support for cultural funds.

In the second scenario, countries have unequal decision power. Speci…cally, I use the number of each countries’votes in the European Council to calculate their decision power, si. The results of the same exercise are presented in Table 3. Here the model predicts that the harmonized levy rate will be even lower, at around e0:09 per CD, and no country will be able to sponsor cultural funds from the levy collection. In …ve out of the ten countries, social welfare increases, and only three countries’policymakers will support for the reform.

20 Again, in Austria and France, policymakers stand to lose despite the gains to be achieved in terms of social welfare. This seems consistent with the anecdotal evidence discussed earlier.

Table 4 summarizes the welfare implications under these two scenarios. Changes in the individual social welfare are multiplied by the population size of each country, and these are added up to calculate the changes in the aggregate social welfare across the ten coun- tries. Note, however, changes in the policymakers’utilities are added up without weighting.

First, with equal decision power, this calibration exercise shows that aggregate social welfare increases as well as the aggregate measure of the policymakers’ utilities. Therefore, with appropriate side transfers among the policymakers, the ten countries should be able to har- monize the levy rate. In doing so, countries like Spain, Germany, and France would bene…t the most.

On the other hand, with unequal decision power, the model predicts that the aggregate social welfare still increases but to a lesser degree than before. Importantly, the change in the aggregate measure of the policymakers’utilities are now negative, meaning that even with side transfers the policymakers would not be able to agree among themselves on the reform proposal. This may explain why the e¤orts to harmonize the levy rate by the European

Commission failed to succeed. In terms of aggregate social welfare, Germany and Spain would gain the most, but policymakers in other countries would lose. In particular, French policymaker would lose the most despite the moderate, predicted increase in the social welfare.

21 6 Conclusion

Private copying exception and levy compensation for all its practical purposes have taken on growing importance in the digital age. For instance, Canada began collecting levies in 2000, where the levy can be as high as 90 percent of CD prices and millions of dollars have been distributed to rights holders, and other countries are considering levy systems. One of the controversies, however, regarding the levy system is that the levies vary signi…cantly across countries. Notwithstanding international treaties to harmonize intellectual property rights, this phenomenon remains a puzzle. To my knowledge, this paper is the …rst to develop a tractable model and quantify the bene…ts and losses from harmonization of copyright levies.

The theoretical model is based on a familiar public good provision model with cross- border spillovers and in particular allows the policymaker’sutility to depend on his concern for cultural funds (or, alternatively, transfers from collecting societies). Analysis of the model

…nds that the levy rate could be too high from social welfare perspective when the policy- maker places enough weight on cultural funds. Because international policy coordination internalizes cross-border externalities, the basic force under harmonization is to increase the levy rate, and this can reduce social welfare. However, when countries are asymmetric, this becomes much more complex due to interactions between various components of the model.

Calibration of a version of the model yields predictions that seem to be consistent with how the European Commission’sinitiative to harmonize the levies failed due to disagreement from some Member States. That is, aggregate social welfare would increase, but some policymakers are made worse o¤ because they can no longer sponsor cultural funds for collecting societies. Another …nding is that the policymakers collectively do better when the

22 decision weights are equally distributed, so the reform can be adopted with side transfers.

While these results seem to accord well with some facts, this study is by no means exhaustive, and other issues should be taken into account when drawing policy conclusions regarding the levy systems.

References

[1] Boldrin, Michele, and David Levine (2009). "Market Size and Intellectual Property

Protection." International Economic Review 50(3): 855–881.

[2] Casella, Alessandra (1992). "Participation in a Currency Union." American Economic

Review 82(4): 847–863.

[3] Chen, Yeh-Ning, and Ivan Png (2003). "Information Goods Pricing and Copyright En-

forcement: Welfare Analysis." Information Systems Research 14(1): 107–123.

[4] European Grouping of Societies of Authors and Composers (2008). Response to the

Second Call for Comments, “Fair Compensation for Acts of Private Copying.”

[5] Gayer, Amit, and Oz Shy (2003). "Copyright Protection and Hardware Taxation." In-

formation Economics and Policy 15: 467–483.

[6] Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman (1994). "Protection for Sale." American Eco-

nomic Review 84(4): 833–850.

23 [7] Huang, Ke-Wei, and Ivan Png (2010). "Who Makes the Law? Political Economy Analy-

sis and Evidence from Copyright Levies." Working Paper, National University of Sin-

gapore.

[8] Johnson, William (1985). "The Economics of Copying." Journal of Political Economy

93(1): 158–174.

[9] Kinokuni, Hiroshi (2005). "Compensation for Copying and Bargaining." Information

Economics and Policy 17: 349–364.

[10] Liebowitz, Stan (1985). "Copying and Indirect Appropriability: Photocopying of Jour-

nals." Journal of Political Economy 93(5): 945–957.

[11] Mallinder, Lorraine (2008). "Electronics Industry to Continue Subsidies of Artists."

European Voice, 21 February 2008. (Web. 13 March 2011.)

[12] Niemann, Fabian (2010). "The Online Market: Breaking the Copyright Levies Dead-

lock." Ericsson Business Review, 30 April 2010 (Web. 13 March 2011.)

[13] Niskanen, William (1968). "The Peculiar Economics of Bureaucracy." American Eco-

nomic Review 58(2): 293–305.

[14] Novos, Ian, and Michael Waldman (1984). "The E¤ects of Increased Copyright Protec-

tion: An Analytic Approach." Journal of Political Economy 92(2): 236–246.

[15] Peitz, Martin, and Patrick Waelbroeck (2006). "Piracy of Digital Products: A Critical

Review of the Theoretical Literature." Information Economics and Policy 18(4): 449–

476.

24 [16] Png, Ivan, and Qiu-hongWang (2009). "Copyright Law and the Supply of Creative

Work: Evidence from the Movies." Working Paper, National University of Singapore.

[17] Rogo¤, Kenneth (1985). "Can International Monetary Policy Cooperation Be Counter-

productive?" Journal of International Economics 18(3-4): 199–217.

[18] Scotchmer, Suzanne (2004). "The Political Economy of Intellectual Property Treaties."

Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 20(2): 415–437.

[19] Towse, Ruth, Christian Handke, and Paul Stepan (2008). "The Economics of Copyright

Law: A Stocktake of the Literature." Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues

5(1): 1–22.

7 Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1. It is straightforward to check that the columns of the Jacobian of the constraints are independent, and thus the constraint quali…cation condition holds at any solution candidate. Form a Lagrangian and derive the full set of …rst-order conditions as follows:

L(; ; 1; 2; 3) = u( )  () +  + 1( ) + 2() + 3(); (18)

u0( ) 1 0() + 1 + 2 = 0;

u0( ) +  1 + 3 = 0;

1( ) = 0; 1 0;   0;  

25 2 = 0; 2 0;  0;  

3 = 0; 3 0;  0:  

i)  =  ,   = 0,  = 0. Then, 1 + 2 = 1 + 0(0) u0(0) < 0. This is a contradiction.

ii)  =  ,   > 0,  > 0. Since 3 = 0, 1 =  u0(0) < 0. This is a contradiction.

iii)  <  ,   > 0,  = 0. Since 1 = 2 = 0, u0( ) = 1 + 0( ) and 3 = u0( ) .   Because 3 0, the condition holds if u0( ) . Let  = u0( ). Then,  = 1 + 0( ) > 1  

because   > 0. The next case shows that if  < ,  = 0 at the optimum. 6

iv)  <  ,   > 0,  > 0. Since 1 = 2 = 3 = 0, u0(  ) = 1 + 0( ) and

u0(  ) = . Combining the two, 0( ) =  1. For  > 0, it must be  > u0( ) =

1 + 0( ) =  > 1 because   > 0. There are no other solution candidates.

It is straightforward to check that Berge’s theorem of the maximum applies, and thus

the solution ( ; ) is upper hemicontinuous. Since u00(l) < 0 and 00() > 0, the solution is

single-valued, hence, continuous. 

Proof of Proposition 2. (i) Suppose  . Then,   is determined by u0( ) = 1 + 0( ) 

and hence independent of . For  > 1,   is determined by 0( ) =  1. By totally

@  @  di¤erentiating both sides, 00( ) = 1. Since 00 > 0, > 0. Also, u0(  ) =  holds @ @

@  @ true, where u00( ) < 0. By totalling di¤erentiating both sides, u00(  ) = 1. @ @   Thus, @ = @  1 > 0. @ @ u00   (ii) De…ne A = u0( A) = 1 + A0 ( A) and B = u0( B) = 1 + B0 ( B). It can be    readily shown that A < B and A > B. Thus, if  B,   = A < B =   . If  A B    B <  A, by 2.(i),   = A < B <   , and also  = 0 <  . If A < , since  A B A B

1 + 0 (  ) =  = 1 + 0 (  ),   <   ; from u0(   ) =  = u0(   ),  <  . A A B B A B A A B B A B

26   (iii) De…ne A = uA0 ( A) = 1 + 0( A) and B = uB0 ( B) = 1 + 0( B). It can be readily      shown that A > B and A > B. Thus, if  B,   = A > B =   . If B <  < A, by  A B  2.(i),  A = A and since 1 + 0( B ) =  < A = 1 + 0( A), A >  B . Also, A = 0 < B . If  A , 1 + 0(  ) =  = 1 + 0(  ), thus   =   ; from u0 (   ) =  = u0 (   ),  A B A B A A A B B B

A < B . 

Proof of Proposition 3. It is straightforward to show that   is characterized by (1 ) = i i h 1 + 0( i) in the noncooperative equilibrium and by  = 1 + 0( ) in the cooperative

equilibrium.

h (i) Since 1 = 2 > 0, it follows that  1 =  2 =   <  . Substituting into the

…rst-order conditions, u0(  ) =  = u0(  ). Since u0is a one-to-one function, 1 2

 =  = . Then, SW  = SW  = u(  )   ( ). Similarly, it holds that 1 2 1 2 h h h h h h h h h u0(  ) =  = u0(  ), so that  =  =  . Therefore,    =   , and 1 1 1 2 h h h h h h h h SW = SW = u(  )  ( ). SW1 = SW2 =   + ( )  ( ) < 0. 1 2 h (ii) In the noncooperative equilibrium, since 1 > 2 > 0, it follows that  1 <  2 <  .

From the …rst-order conditions, u0((1 )  +  ) =  = u0((1 )  +  ). Since 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 1

u0is a one-to-one function, (1 )  +   = (1 )  +  . Then, SW  SW  = 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 h h   + ( )   ( ) > 0. In a similar fashion, it can be shown that SW SW = 0. 2 2 1 1 1 2 h h h h h h Finally, since u0((1 )  +  ) = , SW SW  =   + ( )  ( ) < 0, 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 it follows that SW1 < SW2 < 0. 

Proof of Proposition 4. (i) It is straightforward to show that  i is characterized by

(1 ) = 1 + 0 ( ) in the noncooperative equilibrium. Since, 0 () > 0 (),   <  . It i i 1 2 1 2 also satis…es u0((1 )   +  ) =  = u0((1 )   +  ), where u0 is an injection. 1 1 2 2 2 1

27 Thus, SW  SW  =   +( )   ( ) > 0. On the other hand, in the cooperative case, 1 2 2 2 1 1 h h h  is determined by  = 1 + 10 ( )=2 + 20 ( )=2. Since 10 () > 20 (), it can be shown that

h h h h h  >  . It still holds that u0((1 )  +  ) = . Then, SW SW  =   + ( ) 1 1 1 1 1 1 h h h h h h  ( ) < 0 because   <  . SW2 SW1 = 1( ) 2( ) + SW SW  > 0, 1 1 2 h h where the last inequality holds because 1( ) > 2( ).

(ii) It is straightforward to show that   is characterized by (1 ) = 1 + 0( ) in the i i h h noncooperative equilibrium, and  is characterized by  = 1+0( ) in the cooperative case.

h h h Hence,   =   =   <  . Using the …rst-order conditions, u0 (  ) =  = u0 (  ) and 1 2 1 1 1 1 h h h h u0 (  ) =  = u0 (  ), where u0 is an injection. Then, SW SW  =   +( )  2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 h h h h h ( ) < 0. Also, SW1 SW2 = u1(  ) u1(  ) u2(  )+u2(  ) = 0. 1 1 2 2 

28 Figure 1: Policymaker’sChoice in a Single Country

Figure 2: Welfare Losses from Harmonization ( 1 > 2)

29 Figure 3: Welfare Loss and Gain from Harmonization (10 > 20 )

Figure 4: Welfare Losses from Harmonization (u0 = u0 ) 1 6 2

30 Table. 1: Dataset of 10 European Countries

31 Table. 2: Harmonization with Equal Weight

32 Table. 3: Harmonization with Voting Weight

33 Table. 4: Summary of Welfare Implications

34