Re-Imagining Fashion As an Ecosystem of Commons1

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Re-Imagining Fashion As an Ecosystem of Commons1 David Bollier David Bollier is an American activist, scholar, and blogger who is focused on the commons as a new paradigm for re-imagining economics, politics, and culture. He pursues this work as Director of the Reinventing the Commons Program at the Schumacher Center for a New Economics [www.centerforneweconomics.org] (Massachusetts, US), and as Cofounder of the Commons Strategies Group, [www.commonsstrategies.org] an international advocacy project. Bollier is the author of many books, including Think Like a Commoner [www.thinklikeacommoner.com] (2014); Patterns of Commoning (2015) [www.patternsofcommoningorg] and The Wealth of the Commons (2012), [www.wealthofthecommons.org] both with co-editor Silke Helfrich; and the forthcoming Free, Fair and Alive: The Insurgent Power of the Commons, co-authored with Helfrich. Bollier lives in Amherst, Massachusetts. Tags: Commons / Cooperation / Enclosure / fashion / Internet / Market capitalism Link: http://apria.artez.nl/re-imagining-fashion-as-an-ecosystem-of-commons/ Re-imagining Fashion as an Ecosystem of Commons1 Many players in the global fashion world are increasingly concerned about problematic industry norms and practices—from energy-intensive supply chains and abusive labour practices to transgressive marketing and elitist sensibilities. Is it possible to imagine a more humane and eco- responsible fashion system? This paper describes how diverse commoners around the world are pioneering creative, post-capitalist forms of provisioning, peer governance, and social practice. The principles of commoning—autonomous ‘world-making’ of provisioning and peer governance from within market/state polities—may hold some answers in helping to imagine a new ecosystem of commons for fashion design, provisioning, and distribution. The Commons as a Social System, Not Unowned Resources One general way to understand the commons is as everything that we inherit or create together, which we must pass on, undiminished, to future generations. Our common wealth consists of countless resources that we share such as public lands, state-funded research, the atmosphere, the oceans, the airwaves used by broadcasters. Historically, the state has been the self-styled trustee of such resources—a task it has not performed very conscientiously or faithfully. In truth, the commons is not simply a collection of shared resources. It must be understood as a social and political system for managing that shared wealth, with an emphasis on self-governance, fairness, and sustainability. The commons consists of resources plus the social system for managing them plus the specific rules, social practices, institutions, and traditions used to manage the resources. The commons is an integrated social system for provisioning and peer governance—one that focuses on inclusiveness, fairness, basic needs, and stewardship of shared wealth. If you mention ‘the commons’ to someone today, the first idea that usually comes to mind is ‘the tragedy of the commons’. That idea was launched by biologist Garrett Hardin in the journal Science in a now-famous essay published in 1968. Hardin asked readers to imagine a pasture in which no individual farmer has a rational incentive to hold back his use of it. He declared that each individual farmer would put as many sheep on the pasture as possible because no individual has a rational 1 This essay is derived from remarks made by David Bollier, Director of the Reinventing the Commons Project, at Schumacher Center for a New Economics, to the Fashion Colloquium: Searching for the New Luxury, a conference held in Arnhem, Netherlands, on 31 May and 1 June 2018. 60 incentive to hold back. By this logic, Hardin declared, the pasture will inevitably be destroyed through over-exploitation: the tragedy of the commons. Over the past two generations, economists and conservative ideologues embraced the ‘tragedy parable’ as a powerful way to denigrate the collective management of resources, especially by government. Hardin’s narrative also proved useful as a way to champion private property rights, so-called free markets, and deregulation. Even though the term ‘the commons’ became widely associated with the idea of the word ‘tragedy’, the irony is that Hardin was not really describing a commons. He was describing an open-access regime in which there are no rules for managing a resource, no boundaries around it, and, indeed, no community. The scenario he was describing—in which free riders can appropriate or damage resources at will—is more accurately a description of unfettered markets in which everyone does whatever s/he wants. You might say Hardin was describing the tragedy of the market. The late Professor Elinor Ostrom of Indiana University powerfully rebutted the whole ‘tragedy of the commons’ fable in her landmark 1990 book, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. This book and hundreds of case studies by Ostrom and her colleagues showed that it is entirely possible for communities to manage forests, fisheries, farmland, irrigation water, wild game, and other natural resources as commons, without over-exploiting them. Her research and that of many scholars that she assembled into the International Association for the Study of Commons2 demonstrated this through hundreds of empirical studies. One might ask, how, then, is the over-exploitation of resources avoided? The short answer is, people talk to each other. They negotiate rules for working out their differences. People who live near each other or work together have strong incentives to cooperate. They are entirely capable of self-organizing systems that can identify and punish free riders, develop a shared community ethic and norms, and in other ways protect their shared wealth. This is not always easy and it is certainly not automatic, but it is an historic tradition in the human species. An estimated two billion people around the world depend on natural resources managed as commons for their everyday survival. Most economists ignore this reality, however, because their very language and terms of analysis privilege the market economy—the world of exchange-value, not use-value. Adam Smith’s writings about markets are most notable for providing a moral justification for market activity, sanitizing the vices of greed and envy as ‘self-interest’ that ultimately benefits the public good via the Invisible Hand. He redefined the very idea of ‘the economy’ by ignoring self-provisioning that takes place outside of conventional circles of money and market exchange. Ostrom’s great achievement was in demonstrating how much value and stable management actually occurs through commons. She won the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2009—the first woman to win the award—by documenting and theorizing about cooperation, sharing, trust, and other nonmarket behaviours that most conventional economists neglect as ‘exogenous variables’. Its epistemological model quite literally can’t make sense of such social behaviours because, by the terms of the model, they are ‘irrational’. For economists, market transactions are the main event, and anything that cannot be priced is not taken very seriously. No wonder the commons and its social behaviours are culturally invisible! Market Enclosure as a Scourge of our Time One of the reasons that the commons discourse is being resurrected today is to make the commons more visible—but also to highlight the idea of ‘enclosure’. Enclosure consists of the privatization and 2 Originally, the International Association for the Study of Common Property. 61 commodification of shared wealth by corporations, often in collusion with governments. It can be seen in countless attempts by market players to appropriate for themselves such shared resources as land, water, seeds, genetic information, cultural works, information, public spaces, and much else. Across the world, timber companies are seizing great swaths of forests and wilderness that belong to the people, many of whom have tended the forests for generations. Big Pharma is privately patenting valuable drug research for which taxpayers have paid billions of dollars. Enclosure can be seen in corporate ‘partnerships’ with universities that privatize research funded by the public. Most recently, we have seen fierce attempts by telecom and cable companies to seize control over access to the Internet in order to convert that great commons into a closed marketplace. Enclosures amount to a massive theft and dispossession of common wealth for private gain. It is typically portrayed as ‘progress’—the idea that private investment and marketization will improve societies. But in fact, the relentless expansion of market activity is often a profound dispossession of people’s shared wealth. It is not just a taking of resources but the destruction of community identities and cultures based on sharing. It is an erasure from memory that certain traditions and ways of life are possible. People who have been victimized by investors, corporations, and market growth are increasingly fighting back, however. They seek to reclaim what is theirs and re-establish the communities of commoning that once flourished. For example, indigenous peoples are trying to preserve their ethnobotanical knowledge from the biopiracy of big pharmaceutical and ag-biotech companies. Subsistence farmers are trying to protect their right to share seeds. Fishers are trying to protect their livelihoods from industrial harvesting. Many Latin Americans are fighting the neo-extractivist agenda of multinational
Recommended publications
  • Tragedy of the Commons : Th
    tragedy of the commons : The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_T000193&pr... tragedy of the commons Elinor Ostrom From The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition, 2008 Edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume Abstract ‘The tragedy of the commons’ arises when it is difficult and costly to exclude potential users from common-pool resources that yield finite flows of benefits, as a result of which those resources will be exhausted by rational, utility-maximizing individuals rather than conserved for the benefit of all. Pessimism about the possibility of users voluntarily cooperating to prevent overuse has led to widespread central control of common-pool resources. But such control has itself frequently resulted in resource overuse. In practice, especially where they can communicate, users often develop rules that limit resource use and conserve resources. Keywords collective action; common-pool resources; common property; free rider problem; Hardin, G.; open-access resources; private property; social dilemmas; state property; tragedy of the commons Article The term ‘the tragedy of the commons’ was first introduced by Garrett Hardin (1968) in an important article in Science. Hardin asked us to envision a pasture ‘open to all’ in which each herder received large benefits from selling his or her own animals while facing only small costs of overgrazing. When the number of animals exceeds the capacity of the pasture, each herder is still motivated to add more animals since the herder receives all of the proceeds from the sale of animals and only a partial share of the cost of overgrazing.
    [Show full text]
  • Lifeboat Ethics: the Case Against Helping the Poor
    Lifeboat Ethics: the Case Against Helping the Poor by Garrett Hardin, Psychology Today, September 1974 Environmentalists use the metaphor of the earth as a "spaceship" in trying to persuade countries, industries and people to stop wasting and polluting our natural resources. Since we all share life on this planet, they argue, no single person or institution has the right to destroy, waste, or use more than a fair share of its resources. But does everyone on earth have an equal right to an equal share of its resources? The spaceship metaphor can be dangerous when used by misguided idealists to justify suicidal policies for sharing our resources through uncontrolled immigration and foreign aid. In their enthusiastic but unrealistic generosity, they confuse the ethics of a spaceship with those of a lifeboat. A true spaceship would have to be under the control of a captain, since no ship could possibly survive if its course were determined by committee. Spaceship Earth certainly has no captain; the United Nations is merely a toothless tiger, with little power to enforce any policy upon its bickering members. If we divide the world crudely into rich nations and poor nations, two thirds of them are desperately poor, and only one third comparatively rich, with the United States the wealthiest of all. Metaphorically each rich nation can be seen as a lifeboat full of comparatively rich people. In the ocean outside each lifeboat swim the poor of the world, who would like to get in, or at least to share some of the wealth. What should the lifeboat passengers do? First, we must recognize the limited capacity of any lifeboat.
    [Show full text]
  • Exclusivity and the Construction of Intellectual Property Markets
    The Fable of the Commons: Exclusivity and the Construction of Intellectual Property Markets Shubha Ghosh* TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ................................................................................... 857 I. LOOKING BEYOND THE COMMONS: TURNING HIGH TRAGEDY INTO LOW DRAMA .................................................................... 860 A. The Fable of the Commons................................................. 861 B. Governing the Commons Through the Goals of Distributive Justice ............................................................ 864 II. THE DIMENSIONS OF DISTRIBUTIVE JUSTICE.............................. 870 A. Creators ............................................................................ 871 B. Creators and Users............................................................ 876 C. Intergenerational Justice.................................................... 879 III. DISTRIBUTIVE JUSTICE IN PRACTICE .......................................... 880 A. Fair Use: Allocating Surplus Among Creators and Users .. 881 B. Secondary Liability: Spanning Generational Divides......... 883 C. Antitrust: Natural and Cultural Monopolies and the Limits of Exclusivity in the Marketplace ............................ 886 D. Traditional Knowledge: Expanding Canons and the Global Marketplace ........................................................... 888 CONCLUSION....................................................................................... 889 * Professor of Law, Southern Methodist University, Dedman School
    [Show full text]
  • Joseph Henry Vogel* of the “Study on Domestic Measures” by Margo A
    Peer Review by Joseph Henry Vogel* of the “Study on Domestic Measures” by Margo A. Bagley et al with reference to “Combined Study on Traceability and Databases” by Fabian Rohden et al and “Study on Concept and Scope” by Wael Houssen et al (cc) 2019. Joseph Henry Vogel 29 November 2019, Department of Economics, University of Puerto Rico-Río Piedras [email protected] Key messages: • Can one analyze domestic measures on a term which is (1) undefined, (2) deemed not appropriate, (3) unused in science and (4) universally absent in national legislation? The cart is out of sight of the horse. The inclusive approach--examining whatever DSI could possibly mean---has rendered the study leaden. Frank discussion is needed regarding the cart and the horse. Non-rational behavior is germane to frankness. • Enclose quotations around the first usage of any big idea, thereby signaling that a literature exists. “Bounded openness” and “natural information” are not enclosed or duly attributed in the narrative. The etymology of “digital sequence information” is also absent. Its genesis in “digital biopiracy” sheds light on a modality of ABS that is fair, equitable and efficient. • Whenever possible, difficult-to-locate references should be complemented by similar open- access references. The publications cited on the economics of information and bounded openness are not the most accessible that exist. Preamble: Non-conducive to peer review is the template format. Copyediting may require numbered lines to locate errors in punctuation, spelling and grammar; peer reviews do not. Critique requires narrative. This review is the second in a trilogy that addresses foundational flaws in Decision 14/20.
    [Show full text]
  • Epistemological Implications of the Tragedy of the Commons
    BUSSECON REVIEW OF SOCIAL SCIENCE 1(1) (2019) 01-05 BUSSECON REVIEW OF SOCIAL SCIENCES BRSS VOL 1 NO 1 ISSN: 2687-2285 Available online at www.bussecon.com Journal homepage: https://www.bussecon.com/ojs/index.php/brss Epistemological implications of the tragedy of the commons Doaa M. Salmana*, Nadine Kamelb a Professor of Economics and Finance, Head of economics department, Associate Dean , October University for Modern Sciences and Arts, Egypt bOctober University for Modern Sciences and Arts, Egypt A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T Article history: This paper defines and examines the Garett Hardin’s concept of the Tragedy of the Commons. First, an Received 15 March 19 introductory to the concept is presented along with an extensive critique on Hardin’s 1968 impactful Received in revised form 17 June 19 publication. Second, although the tragedy of the commons belies in the field of environmental economics, Accepted 27 June 19 an extensive research is conducted on how the concept has naturally extended to other cornerstones such as Philosophy, Ethics & Morality, and human behaviour. The objective of this paper is to not see whether the concept is dubbed correct or erroneous, but rather urge readers to take a collective stand regardless of the Keywords: universal validity of the concept and shed some serious insight on the hazards of climate change and pursuit Tragedy of the commons of self-interest. Environmental degradation JEL Classification: O13 O140 © 2019 Bussecon International Academy. Hosting by Bussecon International. All rights reserved.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economics of Information, Studiously Ignored in the Nagoya Protocol on Access to Genetic Resources and Benefit Sharing
    Law Environment and Development JournalLEAD THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION, STUDIOUSLY IGNORED IN THE NAGOYA PROTOCOL ON ACCESS TO GENETIC RESOURCES AND BENEFIT SHARING Joseph Henry Vogel, Nora Álvarez-Berríos, Norberto Quiñones-Vilches, Jeiger L. Medina-Muñiz, Dionisio Pérez-Montes, Arelis I. Arocho-Montes, Nicole Val-Merniz, Ricardo Fuentes-Ramírez, Gabriel Marrero-Girona, Emmanuel Valcárcel Mercado, Julio Santiago-Ríos ARTICLE VOLUME 7/1 LEAD Journal (Law, Environment and Development Journal) is a peer-reviewed academic publication based in New Delhi and London and jointly managed by the School of Law, School of Oriental and African Studies (SOAS) - University of London and the International Environmental Law Research Centre (IELRC). LEAD is published at www.lead-journal.org ISSN 1746-5893 The Managing Editor, LEAD Journal, c/o International Environmental Law Research Centre (IELRC), International Environment House II, 1F, 7 Chemin de Balexert, 1219 Châtelaine-Geneva, Switzerland, Tel/fax: + 41 (0)22 79 72 623, [email protected] ARTICLE THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION, STUDIOUSLY IGNORED IN THE NAGOYA PROTOCOL ON ACCESS TO GENETIC RESOURCES AND BENEFIT SHARING Joseph Henry Vogel*, Nora Álvarez-Berríos, Norberto Quiñones-Vilches, Jeiger L. Medina-Muñiz, Dionisio Pérez-Montes, Arelis I. Arocho-Montes, Nicole Val-Merniz, Ricardo Fuentes-Ramírez, Gabriel Marrero-Girona, Emmanuel Valcárcel Mercado, Julio Santiago-Ríos This document can be cited as Joseph Henry Vogel et al., ‘The Economics of Information, Studiously Ignored in the Nagoya Protocol on Access to Genetic Resources and Benefit Sharing’, 7/1 Law, Environment and Development Journal (2011), p. 52, available at http://www.lead-journal.org/content/11052.pdf Joseph Henry Vogel, Professor of Economics, University of Puerto Rico-Río Piedras (UPR-RP), PO Box 9021833 San Juan, PR, 00902-1833 USA.
    [Show full text]
  • Before the Tragedy of the Commons: Early Modern Economic Considerations of the Public Use of Natural Resources
    409 Before the Tragedy of the Commons: Early Modern Economic Considerations of the Public Use of Natural Resources Nathaniel Wolloch* This article distinguishes between the precise legal and economic approach to the commons used by Hardin and many other modern commentators, and the broader post-Hardinian concept utilized in environmentally-oriented discussions and aiming to limit the use of the commons for the sake of preservation. Particularly in the latter case, it is claimed, any notion of the tragedy of the commons is distinctly a modern twentieth-century one, and was foreign to the early modern and even nineteenth-century outlooks. This was true of the early modern mercantilists, and also of classical political economists such as Adam Smith and even, surprisingly, Malthus, as well as of Jevons and his neoclassical discussion aimed at maximizing the long-term use of Britain’s coal reserves. One intellectual who did recognize the problematic possibility of leaving some tracts of land in their pristine condition to answer humanity’s need for a spiritual connection with nature was J. S. Mill, but even he regarded this as in essence almost a utopian ideal. The notion of the tragedy of the commons in its broader sense is therefore a distinctly modern one. Was there a concept of the tragedy of the commons before William Forster Lloyd in 1833, the precedent noted by Garrett Hardin himself?1 If we mean by this an exact concept akin to the modern recognition that population pressure leads to the irrevocable depletion and even destruction of irreplaceable natural resources, then the answer by and large is negative.
    [Show full text]
  • Politics of Political Economy: Revisiting Elinor Ostrom and Garrett Hardin
    POLITICS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY: REVISITING ELINOR OSTROM AND GARRETT HARDIN Will Parsley TC 660H Plan II Honors Program The University of Texas at Austin November 29, 2016 __________________________________________ Dr. Alexandra K. Wettlaufer French and Italian, Plan II Honors Supervising Professor __________________________________________ Joseph Bailey Jr. Plan II Honors Second Reader ABSTRACT Author: Will Parsley Title: Politics of Political Economy: Revisiting Elinor Ostrom and Garrett Hardin Supervising Professors: Dr. Alexandra K. Wettlaufer and Joseph Bailey Jr. The goal of this thesis is to provide perspective on Prof. Elinor Ostrom’s (d. 2012) challenges and achievements in the field of Political Economy. Her works, chiefly Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions of Collective Action published in 1990, are emblematic of a consensus change in the lens through which policy makers, economists, and everyday human beings view management of shared natural resources. Elinor “Lin” Ostrom’s thinking typifies that of the model 21st-century political economist: combining creative vision with dogged empirical research to address wholly new and distinctly modern sets of problems. Professor Ostrom tackled problems such as wildlife preservation, urban water management, and fishery conservation among others. Despite receiving the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2009, her body of work on institutions for collective action is often undercut by its unearned reputation as a direct rebuttal to Garrett Hardin’s controversial essay “The Tragedy of the Commons,” published in 1968. However, Ostrom's work stands alone. A clear-eyed review of political economics reveals the triumph of her indomitable conviction in her method over barriers created by gender- prejudice. 2 Introduction Political Economy is young academic field that features creative combinations of economics, political science, and ecology to solve humankind’s oldest resource problems.
    [Show full text]
  • Property in Land
    Article Property in Land Robert C. Ellicksont CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ............................................. 1317 I. THE CASE FOR INDIVIDUAL OWNERSHIP OF LAND .................. 1322 A. Three Simple Land Regimes .............................. 1323 B. Small Events: The Relative Ease of MonitoringBoundaries ........ 1327 1. The Genius of Individual Land Ownership ................ 1327 2. Technologiesfor Marking, Defending, and Proving Boundaries . 1328 C. Medium Events: A Simple Way to Promote Cooperative Relations ... 1330 II. THE ADVANTAGES OF GROUP OWNERSHIP OF LAND .................. 1332 A. When Returns Increase with Parcel Size ..................... 1332 1. Efficient Boundaries ................................. 1332 2. Large Events ..................................... 1334 B. Three Pioneer Settlements ............................... 1335 1. Jamestown ........................................ 1336 2. Plymouth .......................................... 1338 3. Salt Lake City ...................................... 1339 t Walter E. Meyer Professor of Property and Urban Law, Yale Law School. I thank participants in workshops at the Harvard, University of Toronto, and Yale Law Schools for comments on a preliminary draft. I am especially indebted to Betsy Clark, Jim Coleman, Rob Daines, Harold Demsetz, Henry Hansmann, Jim Krier, Tony Kronman, John Langbein, Eric Rasmusen, Roberta Romano, Richard Ross, David Schmidtz, Peter Schuck, Jim Scott, Steve Shavell, Paul Stephan, Ed Zelinsky, and, as always, Carol Rose. Simon Frankel, Robin Kelsey,
    [Show full text]
  • An Introduction to Ostrom's Eight Principles for Sustainable
    An Introduction to Ostrom’s Eight Principles for Sustainable Governance of Common-Pool Resources as a Possible Framework for Sustainable Governance of Space T. Chow, Secure World Foundation, [email protected] B. Weeden, Secure World Foundation, [email protected] Abstract This paper outlines the “tragedy of the commons,” reviews Nobel Prize Winner1 Elinor Ostrom’s principles for sustainable governance of common-pool resources (CPR), and relates both to outer space. Ostrom’s principles were distilled from decades of studies on dozens of CPR situations. They capture the best practices of CPRs that have been used sustainably for decades or even centuries, thus avoiding the famous “tragedy of the commons” without relying on privatization or a “Leviathan” authority. When viewed in the context of space sustainability and governance, these principles highlight some long- standing challenges and emerging issues. Over the past few years, achieving the long-term sustainability of space activities has become a central goal for many, both at the national and international level. However, while more policymakers and stakeholders are recognizing the importance of space sustainability, none have spelled out an effective governance strategy, and accompanying policies, for accomplishing it. This paper concludes that Ostrom’s principles can potentially inform those ongoing policy initiatives and highlight specific areas on which to focus initial space sustainability efforts. Introduction Over the last few years, the goal of space sustainability has become increasingly important within the field of space policy. Although many have long recognized the importance of outer space for national and international security and global business, there is a growing realization that the ability to use space for its benefits on Earth is not guaranteed forever.
    [Show full text]
  • Open Access Commons
    Open Access and Information Commons1 Yochai Benkler Open access commons are family of institutional arrangements that are far more pervasive in modern complex economies than is usually recognized in the economic literature. Core resources necessary for communications, innovation, trade, transportation, and energy are managed on the basis of symmetric use privileges open to all, deploying nondiscriminatory allocation based on queuing where congestion occurs, rather than on exclusive proprietary control used to achieve price clearance. Highways, roads and sidewalks, navigable waterways, and open squares are central to intercity and urban commerce. The public domain in knowledge, data, information, and culture forms the foundation of innovation, markets, and creativity. Open standards, the core Internet protocols, unlicensed wireless spectrum, and the privately-created open access commons in Free and Open Source Software (FOSS) runs most Internet infrastructure. More ambiguously, common carriage and public utilities that characterize basic infrastructures for energy and wired communications exhibit full or partial characteristics of open access commons. The defining characteristic of open access commons, by comparison to property, whether individual or collective, is their utilization of (a) symmetric use privileges for (b) an open, undefined set of users in the general public, rather than (a’) asymmetric exclusive control rights located in the hands of (b’) an individual legal entity or defined group (club) use, and (c) their primary reliance on queuing and some form of governance-based allocation, rather than (c)’ price-cleared models, for congestion-clearance and management. Far from being necessarily less efficient or unsustainable, for substantial classes of resources we have observed many critical resources migrating from provisioning based on a reasonably well-developed market in private exclusive rights to open access commons.
    [Show full text]
  • Examining the Tragedy of the Commons Dilemma: Looking at the New Hampshire Fishing Industry
    University of New Hampshire University of New Hampshire Scholars' Repository Honors Theses and Capstones Student Scholarship Spring 2019 Examining the Tragedy of the Commons Dilemma: Looking at the New Hampshire Fishing Industry Peter A. Brown Follow this and additional works at: https://scholars.unh.edu/honors Part of the Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, and the Taxation Commons Recommended Citation Brown, Peter A., "Examining the Tragedy of the Commons Dilemma: Looking at the New Hampshire Fishing Industry" (2019). Honors Theses and Capstones. 439. https://scholars.unh.edu/honors/439 This Senior Honors Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Scholarship at University of New Hampshire Scholars' Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Honors Theses and Capstones by an authorized administrator of University of New Hampshire Scholars' Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS: FISHING IN NH 0 2019 Examining the Tragedy of the Commons Dilemma: Looking at the New Hampshire Fishing Industry By Peter Brown Faculty Advisor: John Tommasi UNDERGRADUATE HONORS THESIS UNIVERSITY OF NEW HAMPSHIRE 1 Table of Contents Abstract……………………………………………………………………………………………2 Literature Review………………………………………………………………………………….2 Research Topic…………………………………………………………………………………….7 Data and Methodology…………………………………………………………………………….7 Model……………………………………………………………………………………………...8 Results……………………………………………………………………………………………..8 Interpretation………………………………………………………………………………………9
    [Show full text]