54 March 2007

VARIETIES WITHIN CAPITALISM? THE MODERNISATION OF FRENCH AND ITALIAN SAVINGS BANKS, 1980-2000 PERSPECTIVES

VARIETIES WITHIN CAPITALISM? THE MODERNISATION OF FRENCH AND ITALIAN SAVINGS BANKS, 1980-2000

Olivier Butzbach Faculty of Political Science Second University of Naples Via del Setificio, 15 Complesso Monumentale Belvedere San Leucio 81020 Caserta (CE) E-mail: [email protected] Acknowledgments

This study draws on my doctoral dissertation; my thanks, therefore, go first of all to my doctoral thesis advisor, Martin Rhodes, who helped me focus and asked me the right questions throughout my research and writing. My thanks also go to the other three members of my doctoral jury: Colin Crouch, Richard Deeg and Adriano Giannola, who provided me with precious comments in the last phase of the writing process. I also thank all my interviewees, whom I cannot list here, and all of those who, at various stages, have facilitated my research. In particular, I wish to thank, in France, Valérie Delumeau and Jean-Philippe Goethals and the staff at: the Caisse d’Epargne de Picardie, the Caisse d’Epargne de Provences Alpes Corse, the Fédération Nationale des Caisses d’Epargne and the Caisse Nationale des Caisses d’Epargne; in Italy, the Associazione fra le Casse di Risparmio Italiane, Mrs. Giacchetti and the Associazione Bancaria Italiana.

I further wish to express my gratitude to my Italian friends and colleagues, in particular Adriano Giannola and Giuseppe Pennisi who have honoured me with their trust and given me, at various stages of my doctoral life, very valuable support and opened for me the doors to the University.

Last but not least, I wish to thank Mita and Nicolas for their continuous support and their resistance to “doctoral fatigue”.

This study has been published by ESBG (European Savings Banks Group) in the framework of the first Savings Banks Academic Award. The objective of the Savings Banks Academic Award is to stimulate comparative research projects on the rich historical heritage of the European savings banks and to propose solutions for the future.

The findings, interpretations and conclusions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the views of ESBG (European Savings Banks Group or WSBI (World Savings Banks Institute). ESBG nor WSBI guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The material in this publication is copyrighted.

ESBG – The European voice of savings and retail banks.

4 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

The world of finance has changed rapidly over the past two decades: heightened competition, financial globalisation, technological innovations, regulatory changes… European savings banks, which constitute a pillar of European political economies, have had to adjust.

French and Italian savings banks have been all the more exposed to change as they formerly belonged to a very specific kind of financial system characterised by heavy state intervention and regulation; and as such state-administered credit systems have been completely dismantled during the 1980s. Savings banks in both countries faced, therefore, a dramatically altered environment to which they had to adjust in order to survive.

This research, building on a case study approach, aims at uncovering the process of change in the savings banks sector in France and Italy; and at identifying the factors of change in each country. According to the literature on comparative political economy, adjustment patterns (of firms or national economic systems) are shaped by existing institutions. Institutional specificities, which are path-dependent over time, determine the peculiar outcome of change in each country; and while convergence is the outcome of market forces, divergence reflects the operation of “rigid” national institutions. The research question addressed here concerns, therefore, both the direction of change and its causes. In other words, what explains French and Italian savings banks’ apparent different trajectories in front of common pressures to adjust?

Findings show simultaneous convergence and divergence forces at play within French and Italian savings banks’ adjustment processes. French savings banks have become a nationally integrated cooperative banking group, while Italian savings banks have either merged with other banks to form nationally integrated commercial banking groups, or formed alliances at the regional or local level.

5 On the business side, the evidence is even less linear: savings banks in both countries have demonstrated a suprising ability to innovate (at the level of products or markets), while maintaining strong positions in their traditional activities. Findings suggest, therefore, the presence of a multi- layered process of change, where institutions both determine and are determined by the strategies pursued by top management.

6 VARIETIES WITHIN CAPITALISM? THE MODERNISATION OF FRENCH AND ITALIAN SAVINGS BANKS, 1980-2000

Table of Contents

Acknowledgments 4

Executive summary 5

Introduction 9

1. Factors and directions of change in European banking 17

2. Organisational and institutional change in national financial systems 39

3. The role of savings banks in the European economies in the XXth century: the cases of France and Italy 53

4. The unravelling of state administered credit systems and their impact on banking 93

5. The regulatory normalisation of savings banks 141

6. The changing boundaries of coordination: savings banks’ corporate restructuring and sector organisation 169

7. Changes in savings banks’ corporate governance 199

8. Changes in savings banks’ corporate strategies 219

9. Conclusions 251

Bibliography 263

7 8 INTRODUCTION

1. The research puzzle: European savings banks’ adjustment to radical shifts in their environment

Savings banks fill both an important and peculiar space in the history of European financial systems. In fact, savings banks can be considered as trademarks of the economies of Germany, Belgium, Spain, France, Italy and the Netherlands, since they are intricately linked to those countries’ industrial and financial development, and because they exhibit strength and financial power rarely seen elsewhere.

The first savings banks were created in the early to mid XIXth century in the UK and Germany as deposit banks catering for the low income earning populations, who were then ignored by other credit institutions. Along the years, the savings banks movement spread throughout Europe and savings banks expanded their activities on the asset side, through lending both to individuals and small firms – considered too risky by large national banks - and through financing public investments via the holding of government securities.

Initially, savings banks were mostly local, private, non-profit banks often organised in strong sector associations at the local, regional and national level – epitomised by the German model of “giro” associations. Most savings banks were originally set up by local power-holders and institutions linked to the church or to the rising elites of the new industrial society. Their non- profit nature meant that, in contrast to commercial banks, they did not have to make profits or pay dividends. In fact, savings banks carried out an explicit redistributive mission, giving part of their yearly revenues to the poor or to the local economy. Hence savings banks’ profound rooting in local economies and communities.

9 Savings banks usually benefited from a protective legal status that allowed them to exert their mission as public goods providers without being confronted to the same market pressures faced by commercial banks. In Germany, for instance, the Sparkassen used to enjoy unlimited state guarantees that enabled them to secure the highest possible credit rating (which recurrently raised the concerns of for-profit competitors and European regulators).

Most European savings banks retained their specific organisational and governance features throughout the XXth century. Today, they are still powerful actors in the banking sector in France, Germany, Italy, Norway, Belgium, Spain, Austria, Portugal, and Sweden. Their local rooting and ownership, the trust they built over the years among depositors, the occasional protection and regulatory advantages provided to them by the state enabled savings banks to reap and keep, until today, high market shares in the deposit (and in some cases the lending) market in the nine countries mentioned above.

More precisely, in 2002 European savings banks represented, on average, 25% of housing loans in their home country, 23% in lending to firms and households, and held 19.6% of total assets in the banking market; on the liability side, they held around one third of total deposits1. In Spain, the 46 Cajas held, as of December 2002, 46% of banking loans and 47% of deposits. And these market shares have been growing over the past ten years. In 2000, French savings banks “weighed” 36.6% of total lending to households (commercial banks held a 44% market share in this segment), against 27.4% in 1995; more generally, cooperative banks increased their shares in deposits, up to 59.7% of the market in 20002. In Italy, (former3) savings banks held in 2003 a 27% market share for deposits, and a 17% market share for lending. In Germany, the non- profit sector is even more dominant; in 2002 75% of deposits were at Sparkassen or at Deutsche Genossenschaftsbank, the lead institution of the co-operative banking sector.

1 Data from the European Savings Banks Group’s 2003 Annual Report. The data refer to the eight countries mentioned above plus 15 other European countries – all members of the ESBG. 2 Source: Banque de France, CECEI, 2000 Report. 3 As will be precised later on, all of Italy’s savings banks have lost their specific legal status during the 1990s. Many of them have merged or been acquired by commercial banking groups.

10 And its hegemony does not seem to be questioned by the failed mergers between and , and then between Dresdner and Commerzbank. Savings banks are also important actors when compared internationally. In 1999 the French Caisse d’Épargne ranked 39th among the world’s largest banks, with 1,012 billion dollars in assets4.

Savings banks’ resilience is all the more surprising as European financial systems have been exposed to strong pressures to change since the late 1970s. Such changes have led to much more market-oriented financial systems, thus giving private, for-profit banks a premium when compared to non-profit banks such as savings banks. Indeed, as mentioned above, the savings banks philosophy is opposed to the free-market view. As Revell put it in the late 1980s, “the conflict is between the free market philosophy, with its single goal of profit maximisation, and the philosophy of the savings banks in all countries, which attaches value to the economic welfare of a particular locality, to social works for the benefit of the inhabitants of that locality, and co-operation rather than conflict and competition between individual savings banks.” (Revell 1989: p.1.)

Thus the first issue tackled by this research presents itself: how have savings banks successfully adjusted to exogenous changes that were a priori unfavourable to their specific business profile? In other words, as the Institute of European Finance put it in a 1999 report: “how might those savings banks survive?” (IEF, 1999) Indeed, successful adjustment can be measured on the basis of the survival of a business organisation in an adverse environment (tight selection). Of course, survival here means conservation of the organisation's business identity (core activities, structure, objectives). Survival, therefore, does not preclude transformation; but to “successfully adjust” a firm should maintain, in a changed environment, the core elements that characterised its business model in the previous environment. In our cases, legal and corporate statuses could change, therefore; as long as savings banks remain distinguishable from other types of banks, they will have adjusted in a successful way.

4 Source: The Banker, July 1999.

11 The issue is all the more relevant in those countries where changes have been more severe, i.e. France and Italy. These two countries were long characterised (at least since the late 1920s) by extensive state intervention in the economy, and especially in the credit system – giving birth to what has been known as a “state-administered credit system” in France and other countries (see Zysman 1983; Loriaux, 1991; and Loriaux et. al, 1997), a category that could include Italy, too (as will be argued in chapter 4)5. In both countries, savings banks were a key component of state-administered credit, especially on the liability side: in short, they collected savings that were in turn channelled to fund public investment predominantly through government securities. In exchange for taking part in administered credit, savings banks received regulatory protection against competition, which, until the late 1970s, prevented savings banks’ business homologation with, and takeover from commercial banks.

Therefore, French and Italian savings banks faced a radically altered business environment in the 1980s and 1990s. Not only did they face changes common to all European countries: technological innovation, changes in clients’ behaviour, increased competition by banks and non- bank financial institutions and markets, European regulation. In addition, French and Italian savings banks also had to cope with the unraveling of state-administered credit in both countries, starting in the late 1970s. They seem, however, to have adjusted successfully: as mentioned above, French and Italian savings banks have (at least until the early 2000s) maintained high market shares in the savings and deposit markets (the same market share of 27.3% in 1997 for both countries) and in some segments of the credit market as well (while savings banks lending represented 18% of all bank lending in Italy in 1997, that proportion fell to 5% for France – but in market segments such as lending to local governments or households, French savings banks did perform well)6.

Yet this adjustment has taken, it seems, two radically different paths: in France, savings banks have gradually tightened their organisational and business ties to form a united banking group present on all segments of the credit market, following a series of top-down impulses from regulators and top management.

5 In his seminal 1983 work, Zysman proposed a three-fold categorisation of national financial systems, based on the main provider of financial services and products to firms and households: market-based systems (such as the UK and the US), bank-based systems (Germany, Japan), and state-administered credit systems (such as France). 6 Numbers are from the Institute of European Finance’s 1998 report on the future of European savings banks (IEF 1999).

12 In addition, the French caisses d’épargne have been granted a cooperative status by law-makers. In Italy, savings banks have become joint-stock companies and have disappeared as a distinct category; and the adjustment paths differ from one savings bank to another – a process of differentiation closely associated with territorial differences. Adjustment paths here refer to the twenty-year long changes experienced by savings banks with respect to: (i) legal and corporate status,; (ii) corporate ownership and governance; (iii) inter-firm relationships and organisation; (iv) market and product strategy.

Hence our two research questions: First, how have savings banks successfully adjusted to a priori adverse changes in their environment? Secondly, what can explain the different adjustment paths taken by French and Italian savings banks, given similar points of departure and similar pressures to change?7

2. The implications of changes in French and Italian savings banks

Finance and banking have for a long time played a central role in defining the peculiar characteristics of national economies. Financial systems, in particular, are associated with specific patterns of economic and industrial development and business-government relationships. In countries such as France and Italy, for instance, governments have historically used their leverage over the credit system to direct savings to industrial investment.

Moreover, capital accumulation is often associated with financial intermediation as a driver for economic development. The credit system allows transforming “dormant capital” into productive capital, thus unleashing the forces of economic growth and development. Some economic historians, such as Richard Sylla, further argue that not only did financial revolution precede the industrial revolution; it actually prepared it (Sylla, 2000). Yet other scholars have found that the market- government nexus at the heart of modern European economic development heavily relied on finance, and in particular intermediated finance (Zysman 1983).

7 This study builds therefore on a “most similar cases” comparative strategy, which will be further discussed in chapter 1.

13 In addition, recent works in comparative political economy, inspired by new institutionalism, assign finance and financial institutions a key role in the maintenance of a country’s distinctive path of economic development. In particular, Hall and Soskice identified finance as one of five key institutions (the other ones are: corporate governance, industrial relations, the role of state and the skill production system) that together shape national “varieties of capitalism” (Hall and Soskice 2001). Indeed, as argued in the book’s introductory chapter, national financial systems represent an attractive field of inquiry for comparativists, since they are seen as the segment of the economy most exposed to globalisation, and, therefore, to convergence pressures (for a similar argument see Cerny, 1989, Loriaux, 1991, Story and Walter, 1996).

Concretely, this means that, for instance, having locally rooted networks of cooperative banks that own shares in local businesses will permit small firms to rely on a stable source for long-term finance – without having to resort to large cash flows, equity creation or market finance for their investments. This specific financial configuration is, in turn, linked to specific performance targets (long-term versus short-term; stable growth versus cost-cutting, etc.) and specific organisational forms and labour- management relations that, together, characterise a country’s political economy. Finance, therefore, lies at the heart of national capitalism. More importantly for this research, banking (or intermediated finance) lies at the heart of European varieties of capitalism. In his seminal work, Gerschenkron showed indeed how intermediated finance was a characteristic of late development and XXth century capitalism (Gerschenkron 1963).

Given the central role of finance in modern capitalism, understanding changes in finance and banking is instrumental to understanding changes in national capitalism as a whole. As Zysman has argued, “by knowing the financial system one can predict the nature of the process of adjustment” (Zysman, 1983). This has two implications for researchers. First, changes in financial structures and functioning are likely to have an important impact on the rest of the economy. Specifically, banking concentration, dis-intermediation and financial market de-segmentation are likely to affect (i) the range of instruments, services and products offered to corporate and individual customers and (ii) the conditions under which firms and households have access to such services and products. In fact, firms often voice their concerns over changing financing conditions by banks and financial intermediaries.

14 For instance, the recent conclusion of the “Basle II agreement”, led by the Bank for International Settlements, which modifies the way banks calculate their risk ratios, led to strong opposition from Italy’s small and medium firms’ business associations, fearing that this would further hinder their access to banking loans.

Secondly, changes in finance and banking are likely to epitomise changes in the political economy as a whole. Banks were among the first companies to be nationalised by the French government in 1981-1982. Similarly, the privatisation of Italian banks in the early 1990s constituted the first step towards a massive shift from public to private ownership across sectors. Finally, changes in banks’ organisation, structure and strategies are likely to reflect, or “co-evolve” with changes in non-financial firms’ organisation, structure and strategies. Therefore, analysing changes in banking and finance should provide us with good insight into change in national capitalism as a whole.

3. Outline of the study

Chapter 1 presents the existing empirical evidence on changes in finance and banking. Chapter 2 discusses the literature relevant to the questions spelled out above, delineates the conceptual framework of the research and presents the methodology used. Chapter 3 explores French and Italian savings banks’ history and presents their situation prior to changes. Chapter 4 analyses the origins, nature and functioning of state-administered credit systems in France and Italy and their dismantling in the 1970s and 1980s. Chapters 5 to 8 present and analyse the research findings. In particular, chapter 5 addresses the regulatory changes undergone by the savings banks sector over the past two decades; chapter 6 focuses on mergers and acquisitions and changes in savings banks’ sector boundaries; chapter 7 deals with changes in savings banks’ governance structures; and chapter 8 analyses changes in savings banks’ business strategies. Chapter 9 concludes and chapter 10 discusses the implications of the research.

15 16 1. FACTORS AND DIRECTIONS OF CHANGE IN EUROPEAN BANKING: THE EXISTING EVIDENCE

1.1 The forces of change in European banking

Since the late 1970s, the environment of European banks has been profoundly transformed. Five forces can be identified behind this transformation: financial globalisation, shifts in industrial countries’ macroeconomic regimes, regulatory changes, technological innovations and changes in customers’ behaviour. To these five factors one may add, for Western European countries, the pressures linked to economic and monetary integration, especially after the 1986 Single Act.

1.1.1 Financial globalisation and the growing interdependence of financial markets

Today financial globalisation, characterised by a heightened volume of exchange and the growing interdependence of financial markets, seems more salient than global trade as a political and economic phenomenon. As is well known, hundreds of billions of dollars worth of stocks and bonds are exchanged each day on the world’s stock markets – which far exceeds the financial payments requested by international trade. Financial interdependence has reached unknown levels since the early 1900s.

Financial globalisation has a three-fold implication for domestic financial systems. Firstly, financial actors located, for instance, in Milan or may draw into a broadened pool of resources consisting of instruments used to spread their risks, or diversify their portfolio through stocks and bonds issued in New York or Tokyo. Secondly, financial actors – and regulatory authorities – face new constraints. For instance, foreign stock ownership might – and often does, although in a diversified manner (see Goyer 2004) – force domestic financial firms (and other businesses) into business strategies not desired or foreseen by domestic owners.

17 In addition, institutional investors might – and often do – require compliance with international norms or standards in terms of accounting and financial transparency. Third, domestic financial actors face new competition from financial institutions and instruments located abroad, but now accessible to domestic firms and households.

1.1.2 Shifts in the macroeconomic regime

Shifts in industrial countries’ macroeconomic regimes represent a second major change in the environment of European banks. A comprehensive synthesis of such a shift is provided by Forsyth and Notermans: “the growth regime of the 1950s and 1960s relied on monetary and fiscal policy (macro-policies) to stimulate demand and thereby promote growth and employment, while it used labour market policies and regulation of financial markets (micro-policies) to curb inflation; by contrast, the dis-inflationary regime of the 1980s and 1990s relied and still relies primarily on monetary policy (macro-policy) to fight inflation and maintain external balance, and on supply-side policies, including selective tax cuts and other investment incentives (micro-policies) to promote growth and employment” (Forsyth and Notermans, 1997).

Such regime change had tremendous implications for financial systems, especially those state-administered systems such as France or Italy (see chapter 4 for an expanded presentation and discussion of such systems). In both countries, until the early eighties, budgetary deficits (incurred to finance public investment programs) were monetised by the central bank; and Treasury bonds were mainly absorbed by the banking sector, thanks to a tight system of constraints and incentives produced by regulatory authorities. Banks – especially savings banks – were therefore provided with cheap and guaranteed resources, and able to maintain a large interest spread8.

8 The interest spread is the difference between active interest rates, i.e. the rates charged to the clients for (mainly) new loans, and passive interest rates, i.e. the rates paid to clients for deposits.

18 In France, that accommodating policy mix (associated with what some authors called France's “overdraft economy”9) was definitely abandoned in 1983 with the adoption of a “competitive disinflation” strategy, based on fiscal stability, wage freeze, a strict monetary policy predicated upon imported disinflation through the “franc fort”. Indeed, with the monetary policy essentially focused on the defence of the French Franc’s parity vis-à-vis the Deutsche Mark, banks lost the certainty of being refinanced by the central bank in case of default. This trend accelerated with the removal of credit ceilings in 1984-86, and of exchange controls in 1990.

Similarly, in Italy, high inflation and rising public debt led to the “divorce” between the Treasury and the Bank of Italy (henceforth Bankitalia) in 1981. That year, Bankitalia was officially relieved from its obligation to buy Treasury bonds unsold to banks, thereby putting an end to the monetisation of the deficit. However, the role of Bankitalia as guarantor of financial market stability ended up carrying on the relationship in an indirect manner – since the central bank, weary of excessive flows of treasury bonds on the market and of its consequences in terms of interest rates, would have to buy those bonds anyway. But the seed of a shift in macroeconomic policy was planted. Along the 1980s, but especially during the early 1990s, deficit reduction became a top priority, and after the 1992 lira devaluation the central bank began to pursue a strict monetary policy predicated upon price stability, and driven by the number one political priority: joining the EMU.

Such changes in macro and micro economic regimes echoed and reinforced the opening of financial markets (to capital flows and foreign investment) and led to increased competition within them – which deepened financial globalisation, as mentioned above. Indeed, the lift of capital controls and the abandonment of deficit monetisation policies, both increased the depth (and therefore the attractiveness) of financial markets and gave them, in return, greater leverage on macroeconomic policies pursued.

9 France’s “overdraft economy” (term coined by scholars in the 1980s) was characterised by selective credit subsidies and a very loose monetary policy, which allowed a continuous channel of cheap financial resources to the economy, but also created a structural inflationary bias and deficit in the balance of payments; overdraft relied on indirect (intermediate) finance, and banks could afford, during the 1960s and the 1970s, a very low level of reserves, having the certainty of being refinanced by the Central Bank. With the end of the overdraft economy, banks had to strengthen their internal structure and change their strategies (de Boissieu, 1990). See chapter 4 for a more detailed analysis.

19 Recent fiscal and social reforms throughout Europe completed the shift in macroeconomic policy regimes evoked above. The slow transformation of European countries’ welfare and pension systems has paved the way to a greater involvement of financial firms and financial markets, akin to US or British pension funds. In Germany, for instance, a 2001 pension reform allowed employees to invest 0.5 % of their gross salary in private schemes, rising to 4% in 2008. This is far from cancelling out the state- run pension system, but should nevertheless benefit managed savings and might encourage a shift from traditional savings to such schemes.

Fiscal reforms might, too, have an impact on national financial systems. In Germany, again, a 2001 reform of the income and corporate tax regimes disposed the abolition, from January 2002, of capital gains tax on corporate sales of shares in other companies, which threatened cross-shareholdings at the core of German commercial banks’ activities and, more importantly, was still expected to trigger a wave of M&As aimed at increasing shareholder value in German businesses. This reform also concerned non-profit banks, although in an indirect way, since it could create new incentives for mutual banks to “de-mutualise” and take advantage of a more liquid market in corporate shares, as has been occurring in Great Britain for instance.

1.1.3 Changes in regulation

Shifts in industrial countries’ macroeconomic regimes led to, or accompanied profound changes in financial regulation10. Three broad trends can be identified: privatisation, de-segmentation (of financial activities), and a shift from “structural” to “prudential” regulation.

The 1980s marked the eve of a new wave of privatisation in industrialised (as well as developing) countries11. All sectors were concerned, especially public utilities, oil firms, transportation companies, postal offices and financial and banking firms. The United Kingdom, under Margaret Thatcher’s leadership, led the fray, with the privatisation of steel, mining and transportation companies in the 1980s. But the case of France is, arguably, even more spectacular.

10 The precise causality between macroeconomic changes and regulatory changes will be addressed in chapter 4. 11 Which were joined, of course, by Eastern European “transition” countries in the 1990s.

20 Upon their arrival in power in 1981, President Mitterrand and his socialist government launched the widest-ranging nationalisation program since the immediate postwar reconstruction (see Machin and Wright, 1985). Among the newly nationalised firms were three large banks (Crédit industriel et commercial, Crédit du Nord and Crédit commercial de France) and two financial firms, Paribas and Suez.

A few years later, however, a newly elected right-wing government headed by Prime Minister Jacques Chirac reversed that policy and sold dozens of previously-nationalised companies – among which several of France’s largest financial institutions: Paribas, Suez, the Banque Nationale de Paris (BNP), the Société Générale, the Crédit Lyonnais... Privatisations were suspended in 1988 (upon President Mitterrand’s reelection and socialist’s victory in the parliamentary elections), and resumed in 1993 under another right-wing government, but continued in the late 1990s under the leadership of socialist Lionel Jospin. Privatisation, pursued on and off since 1986, has dramatically reduced the size of public ownership in finance and industry, tailing well behind the reversal of the 1981 nationalisation wave. As of 2003 only five banks were still owned by the French State, in contrast to 36 in 1983. The only remaining financial entities within the orbit of the French State are the Caisse des Dépôts et Consignations, the financial arm of the Postal Office (now totally corporatised12), an insurance firm (CNP assurances), a housing credit firm (Crédit immobilier de France) and the Banque de développement des PME.

Italy also offers an apt example of far-reaching privatisation. And, again, banking and finance stood at the heart of privatisation programs implemented in the 1990s. During that decade, the state first corporatised, and then sold shares it owned in three large banks through the public holding IRI: Comit, Credit, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro. At the same time, the 1990 Amato Law transformed savings banks from public to private entities. Privatisation continued in the 1990s with public divestitures in all sectors, ranging from telecommunications to energy and the airline industry (The Italian Treasury still holds a minority share in Alitalia, the country’s national carrier, which also seems to be soon for sale).

12 A state-owned enterprise is said to be corporatised when it becomes a distinct legal person from the state, with autonomous management and budgeting.

21 Besides privatisation, policy changes from the early 1980s to the mid- 1990s were characterised by a new wave of “de-regulation” following that of the 1960s and profoundly transforming the banking regulatory regime in most European countries, along the lines of market opening (or de-segmentation) and expansion. As Gardener argues, a deregulated banking environment is “predicated to a large extent on the economic desirability of a strong market orientation, a demand-determined emphasis, in banking strategies.” (Gardener, 1994: 59.)

Those regulatory changes, along with the shift in macroeconomic regimes described above, entailed a profound transformation of the role played by the state in the economy. This change is even more apparent in what John Zysman called “state-administered credit systems” (by opposition to market-based and bank based financial systems; see Zysman, 1983), such as France and Italy.

However, such transformations do not seem to have led to a straight- forward retreat, or withdrawal of the state, as some popular accounts may have suggested at the outset of the 1990s (in the early years of “transition to market” in East European economies, and in the aftermath of the anti-State rhetoric at work under Thatcher and Reagan in the West13). Available evidence pleads for more nuanced views. First of all, as Garret and Lange have pointed out, public spending has increased in many countries, rather than decreasing (Garrett and Lange, 1997). Secondly, de-regulation and re-regulation waves have followed different paths that do not lead to the same level of state involvement (see Vogel’s comparison between Japan and UK: Vogel 1999). Third, one should not reduce state intervention to a single quantitative dimension. As Linda Weiss has showed, state capacity is multi-faceted and privatisation/ liberalisation policies affected just one side of it (Weiss, 1997).

In fact, along the lines of the arguments just mentioned, financial regulation changed its nature. To sum up, there was a shift from structural to prudential regulation. Regulation is structural when the state directly intervenes to shape the structures of the financial system – through the discretionary authorisation of new entrants, setting interest rates, setting credit ceilings, market segmentation…

13 Of course, the actual policies pursued by the successive Reagan administrations in particular, which ended up increasing public deficits, contradict somehow the rhetoric then used.

22 Prudential regulation means that the state should guarantee the effective functioning of the financial market, through control and monitoring of prudential ratios by banks and other financial institutions. Within that new framework, traditional regulatory authorities, such as the central bank or the Treasury, did not disappear or become obsolete: they changed their mission – for instance, they started monitoring competition rather than actually engineering it. In addition, new regulatory authorities were set up – for instance, the Commission des Opérations de Bourse (COB) in France, or the Consob in Italy.

Besides changing the nature of state involvement in the economy, such regulatory changes profoundly transformed banks’ playing field – especially in countries such as Italy and France, where the banking and financial sectors had heavily relied on state ownership and regulation until the 1980s.

1.1.4 Changes in technology and in clients’ behaviour

Since the 1970s, a series of technological innovations took place that radically transformed the business of finance over successive years. Powerful, high-speed electronic networking has allowed real-time information flows across markets and between institutions – interconnectivity becoming the cornerstone of financial markets’ interdependence. Technological innovation has streamlined banking and financial business organisation, and has changed clients’ relationships with their banks: automatic teller machines (ATMs) first allowed multiplying the territorial rooting of banks; e-banking later allowed clients to perform many operations at home.

Changes in customers’ behaviour put further pressure on banks and financial institutions to adjust. Large firms were the first to change their financing behaviour. With rising interest rates and the emergence of stock markets in the 1970s, many large firms throughout Europe started resorting to the market (through commercial notes and bonds) to finance their investment needs, thus leaving their traditional banking lenders in search for a new strategy. With the rapid growth of the stock market in the 1980s and 1990s and the availability of new instruments (as well as new services geared towards helping firms access market finance), many medium-sized firms were also tempted to shift from bank loans to bonds issued on the market.

23 Changes in clients’ behaviour were not circumscribed to banks’ liability side. More recently, households too have been modifying their financial behaviour. First, they have been offered the possibility of diversifying their portfolio and starting to earn real interest14 on some of their savings. Secondly, households are increasingly switching their funds from short- term savings to protect themselves against the risk of becoming unemployed, to longer-term investment destined to complement their pensions. Overall, “banks’ twofold dependence on money markets and credit ratings today plays a similar role to the last-century’s fear of a depositor’s run on the bank.” (Verdier, 2002).

1.1.5 European monetary and financial integration

A last key factor of change in the environment of European banks consists of the changes in the regulatory regime that have accompanied the acceleration of European integration after the mid-1980s. Baltensperger and Dermine (1990) identify three regulatory periods since the 1950s: a first period, from 1957 to 1973, marked by deregulation of entry to domestic banking markets; a second period, from 1973 to 1986, characterised by the first attempts towards the harmonisation of domestic regulations; and a third period, from 1986 on, marked by the efforts to create an integrated European financial market.

The first period ended with the adoption by the European Council of Ministers, in 1973, of a Directive prohibiting barriers to the domestic banking and financial markets. However, persisting capital restrictions and regulatory differences seriously hampered effective cross-border competition. Harmonisation really took off with the 1977 Directive “on the Coordination of Laws, Regulations and Administrative Provisions Relating to the Taking up and Pursuit of the Business of Credit Institutions” (hereafter known as the “First Banking Coordination Directive”). That directive gave a definition of banks as credit institutions (which would, as we will see in chapter 3, further legitimise French and Italian lawmakers in their attempts to de-segment the banking market) and established the home country control principle, whereby supervision of credit institutions operating in various member countries would be the responsibility of the home country of the parent bank.

14 From the mid-1970s until the mid-1980s, the real interest rate earned on administered savings (“Livret A”) in France was negative, given a fixed interest rate and high inflation.

24 Several minor Directives in the early 1980s completed those first harmonisation efforts, notably establishing European standards for accounting and consumer protection. Still, as Baltensperger and Dermine note, integration was not achieved by this first wave of European regulation. Capital restrictions were still in place in most EC countries, and member countries retained a quasi-discretionary power on the regime of authorisations to create new banks.

The third and last period identified by Baltensperger and Dermine is the run-up to the completion of the single market, triggered by the 1986 Single Act. The 1985 European Commission White Paper on the internal market set guidelines for a single banking license, home country control and mutual recognition. Those principles were embodied in the Second Banking Coordination Directive, proposed by the European Commission in 1988 and adopted by the Council of Ministers in December 1989. That Second Directive aimed at ensuring full freedom of banking services across Europe by 1992. In particular, it provided for minimum capital requirements and the creation of a single banking “passport” allowing any bank authorised to operate in one member country to sell its products and services to all others.

Building on Baltensperger and Dermine, one could further add two periods: one spanning from 1992 up to 1999, which is marked by the run-up to the monetary union, and the following period (from 1999 until present), characterised by a fully integrated monetary union and the absence of regulatory barriers to the establishment or operation of banks in any member country. In any case, the acceleration of European monetary and economic integration, along with the build-up of a common European regulatory regime on banks and financial institutions constitute tremendous changes in banks’ environment, which cannot but profoundly impact banks’ strategies and structures.

With the introduction of the Euro as a single currency and the broadening of the single market, European authorities are indeed increasing pressure for the dismantling of state subsidies (and guarantees and protection in all sectors), in the name of competition and free-market principles. Recently, for instance, the European Commission increased the pressure on German Landesbanken for receiving direct state aid. The fourth biggest German bank in terms of assets, Westdeutsche Landesbank (WestLB) was fined for this reason in 1999. In 1992 WestLB, owned by the state of North Rhine-Westphalia and the region’s publicly owned savings banks, had acquired from the state the assets of a housing development agency.

25 Commercial banks claimed that the transfer was an illegal injection of capital at below market prices. The European Commission ruled in their favour, deciding that WestLB had received illegal state aid of 808 million euro, the value of the housing agency plus accrued interests.

The Commission has been investigating other similar cases, and a complaint by the European Banking Federation challenging the whole German system of state guarantees led to the abolition of state guarantees15. At stake are the special guarantees and the excellent credit ratings enjoyed by Landesbanken. If these guarantees are stricken down, either the ratings will be adjusted to the real financial situation of the regional banks, forcing them out of business, or the banks will have to find new sources of equity to support their vast balance sheets. They would have to cut services and shred businesses. Privatisation might even appear possible.

Furthermore, with the Euro and the increased cross-border competition it entails, certain banking practices seem hardly sustainable. This is the case, for instance, with a decades-long agreement on free checks that limited competition in the French banking sector. Under this rule, banks may not pay interest on current accounts, in exchange for not charging customers for the cost of processing checks. As of December 2004, the French government was planning to reform this agreement, which should lead to renewed competition in the sector and “anchor” more solidly banks in profit-maximisation (cost-minimisation) strategies. More importantly, the emergence of new actors in finance and banking (mutual funds, investment funds…) increases the competitive pressure on banks and traditional credit institutions.

Finally, one should mention the role played by international regulation, in particular regulatory changes pursued by the Bank for International Settlement – instrumental in diffusing prudential ratios adopted by national and international regulatory authorities. The introduction in 1988 of the “Cooke ratio”, in particular, set the basis for prudential regulation by national authorities and created a “minimum profitability constraint for banking assets” (Lévy-Lang, 1990)16.

15 Taking effect in July 2005; an agreement was reached in 2004 between the EC, German Lander and the Landesbanken to soften the impact of the abolition of state guarantees on banks’ ratings. 16 The Cooke ratio, adopted with the first Basle agreement in 1988, sets the minimal amount of own funds a bank should possess in function of the risks born by its liabilities. More precisely, the Cooke ratio imposes two constraints: (i) the ratio (own funds + quasi-own funds)/total liabilities should be superior to 8%; and (ii) the ratio own funds/total liabilities should be superior to 4%.

26 With the Basle II agreement, signed in 2004, banks will be submitted to individual risk management with the Mac Donough ratio (successor of the Cooke ratio), which should start being implemented in 2006.

1.1.6 Convergence mechanisms

The vast transformations in European banks’ regulatory, technological and competitive environment in the 1980s could not leave banks unaffected. In fact, even while the transformation of banks’ environment was under way, many observers made conjectures on what changes banking would undergo (see European Commission 1990; and PriceWaterhouseCoopers 1988). In particular, four trends were identified: (i) growing competition; (ii) banking disintermediation – that is, the crowding out of bank intermediation by market actors and activities; (iii) the marketisation of banking – that is, the increased reliance of banks on financial markets for their revenues, and the transformation of banking strategies to better suit market incentives and constraints; (iv) the “rationalisation” of banking structures – that is, the restructuring of the banking system through mergers and acquisitions. This restructuring trend was also to lead to a fifth expected change: the emergence of an integrated European financial market, with cross-border mergers leading to the constitution of truly European banking or financial groups operating on a level playing field – the same market with identical instruments and regulations.

Finally, since the same changes affected European national financial systems, those systems were expected to converge on one another and appear more alike. In particular, along with dis-intermediation, banks were to become much more market-oriented – being more responsive to competition, better able to rapidly adjust their strategies. This led to the widespread expectation that non-profit, cooperative or public banks were bound to lose their identity – or disappear (PriceWaterhouse, 1988).

Such expected convergence was not limited to finance and banking; a growing literature saw “globalisation” leading to irresistible convergence, across countries, of both macroeconomic performance and microeconomic structures (see, for a review, Berger 1996). Berger lists five mechanisms for convergence: competition, imitation, trade, capital mobility and diffusion of best practice (Berger, 1996). These five mechanisms are all associated with globalisation. Deeg (1999) adds the technical revolution, and the pressure to adopt lean production – both of which could be subsumed into the ‘imitation and ‘diffusion of best practice’ category.

27 Some of these mechanisms are pure market mechanisms, such as competition or trade. Others are not. For instance, imitation or the diffusion of best practice also occurs through self-consciously pursued harmonisation. According to Deeg, “because national economies are organised around different rules and institutions that create structural advantages and disadvantages for their firms in international competition, firms in one nation will push for a ‘level playing field’ leading to the harmonisation of economic policy, regulation and, ultimately, economic structures.” (Deeg 1999).

There are also ‘pure’ political mechanisms – several “convergence” and “divergence” scholars agree that changes are driven by the policy decisions of financially powerful states. Eric Helleiner has emphasised the role played by the United States in the transformation of the international political economy (Helleiner, 1994). Similarly, Loriaux underlined how the crisis of the interventionist model in France was provoked by the policy shifts within the hegemon (Loriaux, 1991, 1998a, 1998b). Finally, even the proponents of the “convergence” view accept the idea that change does not happen simply as a result of external pressures, but out of a combination of external pressures with ‘domestic pull’ – that is, the action of domestic actors pushing for a specific agenda that reinforces and transforms external pressures into policy (Ogata 1996, Upham 1996). However, the actual changes observed in the late 1980s and the 1990s departed significantly from the convergence story.

1.2 The evidence: mixed outcomes

1.2.1 Growing competition in the banking market

The changes in banks’ environment mentioned above were expected, as early as the 1980s, to intensify competition on the banking market and force all banks and financial institutions to radically adjust their business behaviour and strategies. In particular, the already mentioned 1988 PriceWaterhouse study on the expected impact of the completion of the internal market argued that the latter should bring to a levelling of prices across a broad range of economic sectors – among them banking and finance (PriceWaterhouse, 1988). Price levelling has not taken place (yet?). But competition has definitely increased throughout European banking markets.

28 Across countries, successive EU regulation has indeed lifted the barriers to entry on national markets for foreign banks; and indeed, foreign banks have entered national markets, although at a varying rhythm and with varying successes: in France, for instance, 17% of all active bank branches in 2004 belonged to foreign banks or banking groups; in Italy, foreign banks held a 21% market share in the 2003 market for deposits17.

But competition has increased above all within countries, following market de-segmentation and the lift of price controls. In some countries, increased competition can be observed through the rapid rise in the number of bank branches. This is the case in Italy, where the number of bank branches has jumped from 23,460 in 1980 to 30,890 in 200418. In others, even though the number of bank branches has not changed, or has varied only at the margin (such as France, where the number of bank branches increased from a total of 25,490 in 1984 to a total of 26370 in 200419), increased competition can be seen through the diversification of banks’ products and services: for instance, the multiplication of savings products at the beginning of the 1980s clearly threatened French savings banks’ quasi-monopoly on the market for savings deposits.

More importantly, perceived competition has increased, even where or when competition has not effectively increased yet. In many European countries, the advent of the Euro and the substitution of national currencies in 2002 were expected to unleash a new wave of competition; banks anticipated the change by previously modifying their strategies. Similarly, where banks were not directly threatened by other banks or financial intermediaries, they nevertheless modified their behaviour as if competition had increased. This phenomenon was effectively captured by the theory of contestable markets (Baumol, Panzar and Willig 1982). According to this theory, a perfectly contestable market is one in which entry and exit are absolutely costless. In such a market, competitive pressures supplied by the perpetual threat of entry, as well as by the presence of actual current rivals, can prevent monopoly behaviour20.

17 The data is from central bank annual reports in both countries. 18 Source: Banca d’Italia, Bolletino statistico, 1980 and November 2004. 19 Source: Banque de France, Bulletin, December 2004. 20 Although the theory is not universally accepted and presents many questionable elements (for instance the overlooking of regulatory barriers to entry), it still provides a good approach to analyse the mechanisms by which the threat of competition is internalised by firms.

29 1.2.2 The growth of financial markets

The growth of stock-markets has led to: an increased reliance on external finance for large companies; a wave of financial innovations (with new instruments such as credit and currency swaps, futures and caps etc.); and the emergence of new financial actors. Faced with these developments, banks were expected to lose their central role in most European countries’ financial systems, to the profit of market finance, epitomised by stock market activities. Indeed, “market” finance represented 12% of external finance for large firms in 1980, in contrast to 35% today21 – meaning that bank loans have, logically and at least in relative terms, lost ground.

However, European finance today is still highly intermediated (intermediated finance still represented around 75% of total external finance of non- financial actors from 1992 to 1998 in France and Germany22). But while this intermediation was essentially based on credit until the 1990s, it now increasingly involves hybrid forms of finance, with banks and other intermediaries being active market actors, and earning a sizeable portion of their revenues from market activities. Moreover, the parallel increase in “securitisation” has led to an increasing dependence of banks on financial markets (both for credit ratings and off-balance sheets operations).

1.2.3 The marketisation of banks’ business

Commercial and non-commercial banks in most European countries have undergone significant changes in their organisation, profit strategies and their product mix. Banks have become hybrid, somewhere in between markets and traditional financial intermediaries – a phenomenon that has been called “marketisation” of banking, “market intermediation” (Courbis, Froment & Karlin, 1990), “variable geometry banks” (Lubochinsky and Métais, 1990), or “assetless banking” (Giddy, 1985).

In particular, there has been a shift in banks’ product strategies: banking intermediation in the traditional sense (lending and deposit activities) has decreased, while “market transactions” (financial instruments operations) have increased. Banks are now multi-product firms, which draw from financial markets enough resources to counterbalance traditional asset and liability management.

21 Source: The Financial Times, October 23, 2000. 22 Source: Paranque et al., 1999.

30 Decomposition, more target risk analysis and management overcome the diversification and scale strategies previously pursued – trends reinforced by the new Basle accords23. In addition, securitisation permits the outsourcing of risk management, while helping to de-emphasise lending – a necessity for banks facing increased competitive pressures on the lending market. Already, the big German banks get most of their revenue from these activities.

Moreover, banks throughout Europe have grown much more shareholder value-oriented, with a strong emphasis on profit objectives and performance targets such as return on equity or return on assets24. The increasing importance of profitability and ROE were pointed out in 1994 (Morgan Stanley, 1994). In addition, the IEF report emphasised the growing importance of value-added – i.e. the value corresponding to the excess of revenues on costs. Value-added strategies are intrinsically market- oriented – since, as the IEF report points out, “Value-added returns and the respective costs are increasingly based on comparisons with other, competing products and services in the market. […] Value-added is an externally focused, opportunistic measure” (IEF 1999, p.8).

However, again, those changes are not all-encompassing. Onado’s 1990 work on a sample of 108 Italian banks showed that banking competition had undeniably increased in Italy during the 1980s, but that did not result in fundamentally altering banking performance or business (Onado 1990). Increased competition was, according to Onado, a kind of “lop-sided process”, characterised by a mere transformation of bank revenues from direct intermediation to placement fees. “Alternatively stated, banks have not lost their relationship with the customer and that certainly helped to maintain segmentation (by location, type of deposit, class of customer, size of accounts, etc.)” (Onado, 1990: 104). More recent evidence supports similar findings. Affinito et al., in particular, emphasise the persistent differences in the balance sheet structure of European banks (Affinito et al., 2003); while Murinde at al. and Flier et al. point to the divergent business strategies followed by banks across European countries (Flier et al., 2003; Murinde et al., 2004).

23 Interestingly, as pointed out in the IEF 1999 report, in 1997 the European Savings Banks Group, in comments made during the debate on the completion of the Internal market, underlined that current European banking regulation mainly derived from rules elaborated within the Basle Committee, which themselves reflected the practical supervisory needs of international commercial and investment banks (IEF 1999: p.19). 24 See “Blot on the landscape”, The Banker, February 2001, pp.44-46.

31 1.2.4 Shifts in corporate ownership and control

Market and regulatory pressures have also led to a wave of corporate restructuring in banking, characterised by two trends. A first trend is the continuous and rapid decrease in the number of credit institutions. In France, for instance, from a peak of 2,152 in 1987, it fell to 1,837 in 1991, 1,445 in 1995, and 1,143 at the end of 199925. The decrease is almost twofold in 12 years. All banks were affected, but especially mutual and cooperative banks (down from 663 in 1984 to 155 in 1999).

A second trend is the increased concentration in banking. In France, for a long time, the banking sector had been characterised by very little concentration, compared with other sectors. Only one bank, the Crédit Agricole, had a market share of over 10% (of both total loans and deposits). And the restructuring activities that took place in the 1980s and the early 1990s did not affect much the level of concentration of the banking sector, since they happened within same groups (mergers between ‘banques populaires’, savings banks…) By contrast, since the mid-1990s, new, large-scale M&A activities have signaled an acceleration of concentration in the sector26. One can cite the takeover of Crédit du Nord by the Société Générale in 1998, the takeover of Paribas by the BNP (and the failed takeover of Société Générale by the latter) and, of course, the takeover of the Crédit Lyonnais by Crédit Agricole in 2003.

However, contrary to what the 1989 Cecchini Report predicted, such restructuring did not lead to a complete upheaval of the banking sector in most European countries. First, many banking markets remain characterised by a high number of operators – far from the markets for automobile, oil, or electricity, for instance. In France and Italy there are about a thousand active banks and financial firms. Secondly, a closer look at the banking M&A that took place in the 1990s shows that those mergers occurred mainly between banks belonging to the same networks (savings banks, cooperative banks) or credit institutions active in the same market. Thirdly, European banking markets remain less concentrated. In France, the CR5 ratio (ratio of concentration of the 5 biggest credit institutions vis-à-vis the whole banking sector, in terms of assets) was 39,20 in 1998 (against 41,30 in 1995, but 34.45 in 1990). In Germany, the ratio is even lower: it stood at 19,15 in 1998, from 16,67 in 199527.

25 Source: Banque de France, Internet site, August 2001; see chapter 4. 26 The number of M&A operations over FFm 500 jumped from 54 in 1994 to 98 in 1998 (Source: Banque Magazine, February 2000) 27 Source: European Central Bank Statistics, June 2001

32 Finally, again contrary to most expectations (European Commission 1989; PriceWaterHouse 1988), there is no unified European financial market. Cross-border mergers between financial institutions have been rare and have not led to a level playing field at the European level. National authorities have been busy strengthening or creating their own national champions, and remain wary of the idea that a foreign bank, be it from another European country, should take over a large national bank28.

1.2.5 Limited convergence between banking systems

The literature provides evidence on financial regimes appearing more alike. Vitols (1997) presented evidence supporting the argument that the differences between the three ideal-types of financial systems identified by Zysman (1983) - securities market-based systems; bank-based systems and state-based, administered credit systems, are fading away. The latter, in particular, are unraveling everywhere, while market and bank-based systems seem to be taking on similar features. In Germany, for instance, the close relationships between companies and their banks have been weakened by the increased ability and willingness of large corporations to avail of the services of competing banks, especially in foreign markets, or to resort to market finance (Lutz, 1998). In addition, moving beyond the boundaries of finance and banking, dominant economic and sociological theories of organisation assert that globalisation is leading to a convergence towards a single model of the firm29.

Story and Walter’s book on European financial systems also cites evidence showing that the construction of an integrated financial market in Europe (a development that accompanies and reinforces the “globalisation process” itself) reveals a strong converging trend to similar financial regimes, despite a “battle of systems”30 (Story and Walter 1997).

28 See the recent public exchange between EU Commissioner for Internal Market and the Governor of the Italian central bank on the degree of opening of the Italian banking sector. 29 See Fligstein, 1996, for a critical account of this literature. 30 Here is the difference between financial systems and regimes, according to Story and Walter: the financial system is the ensemble of relationships between financial institutions, whereas a financial regime is the ensemble of rules that enable these relationships to take place. “In equilibrium, the process of financial intermediation evolves within a financial system that is regulated according to a hierarchy of norms, effectively implemented” (Story & Walter, 1997, p.106). This is a tricky distinction, since even the authors show some confusion in their analysis of the European situation. Subtitled “A battle of systems”, their book is indeed much more focused on financial regimes… We will see later on how that confusion might have important consequences at a theoretical level.

33 Others, such as Forsyth and Notermans, point towards broader convergence at the level of macro-economic regimes (Forsyth and Notermans 1997). Such convergence is attributed to a variety of reasons: the pressure of international trade and finance; the obsolescence of Keynesian economics; the unraveling of those coalitions (or policy communities) that had supported the previous regulatory arrangements (see Moran, 1984).

Yet if differences between financial regimes tend to fade away, financial systems remain quite distinct from one another. In other words, although Zysman’s third ideal-typical financial system – the state-administered model – has clearly collapsed, banking intermediation remains the prevalent source of corporate finance in most continental European countries. Several recent works (Busch, 2002; Deeg, 1999; Vitols, 1999; Lutz, 1997; Perez, 1997) show indeed that banking systems resist rather well to convergence pressures. Deeg and Vitols present evidence supporting the persistence of non-market forms of financial intermediation and of a sizeable banking sector in bank-based systems (Deeg, 1992 and 1999 and Vitols, 1999). Others, such as Labye and Renversez, do acknowledge that “market intermediation” has increased in countries such as Germany or France, but emphasise that this form of intermediation “cohabits” with more traditional, credit-based intermediation (Labye and Renversez, 2000). Here we can observe a slight difference from the interpretation evoked before: instead of divergence, Labye and Renversez speak of “limited convergence” or convergence towards… distinctiveness vis-à-vis stock market based economies. Similarly, Soskice opposes “bifurcated convergence” to “uniform convergence” (Soskice, 1999).

Moreover, even national banking systems differ from one country to the next. In a 1994 study (which drew on data from the late eighties), Molyneux, Lloyd-Williams and Thornton found that “competitive conditions” in banking were still diverse across European countries (Molyneux et. al., 1994). But these authors found the same trend towards the emergence of a handful of large banks over time “in almost every developed country”. In other words, the changing structural characteristics of the banking system looked very much alike across continental Europe: France, Germany, Italy and Spain were characterised by a group of dominant or “core banks”, who were being challenged (to a varying degree) by mutual or cooperative banks with a strong regional or local focus (see Molyneux et al., 1994).

34 The same authors, however, rightly pointed out that the existing “evidence” on competitive conditions in banking markets is often inferred from market structure variables, such as concentration ratios, branch numbers, and number of banks (Molyneux et al., 1994). There is yet no simple, linear relationship between market structure and effective competition, especially in the light of contestable markets theory. The only valid empirical study up until the 1990s remained, in that perspective, the PriceWaterhouse study on the “costs of non-Europe” (PriceWaterhouse 1988). Molyneux, Lloyd-Williams and Thornton used a non-structural measure of competition (the Ross-Panzar statistic31) to investigate competitive conditions in banking in five European countries, from 1986 to 1989. They concluded that as of the late 1980s, commercial banks’ revenue in all of these countries “behaved as if earned under monopolistic competition”, noting that this significantly diverged from contestable markets theory, which holds that potential competitors force competitive pricing strategies upon incumbents. (Molyneux et al., 1994: p.25)

Similarly, in a 1994 study on Italian banking, Cesari, Conti and Onado found that “the sign and speed of changes are by no means clear”, although previous works carried the expectation that competition forces would put pressure on national banking systems and eventually lead to convergence of market structures and business conditions. Furthermore, the same authors found that increased competition (from 1986 to 1990) led to a reshuffle of market shares in individual segments, rather than changes in the aggregate market shares of individual banks. They concluded by saying that “even in an integrated country, even in a period of deregulation and greater competition, differences tend to remain” (p.39).

More recent evidence gives mixed support for the convergence thesis. Several works exploring the degree of integration between European financial systems point to the significant convergence of macro and quantitative indicators. Calcagnini, Farabullini and Hester, for instance, show that money market interest rates have converged across European countries in the twenty years preceding the advent of the single currency (Calcagnini et al., 2000). Similar observations are made regarding interest yields on stocks and government bonds by Danthine et al. (2000).

31 The “Rosse-Panzar H statistic”, first elaborated by Rosse and Panzar in the late 1970s and then used and refined by several banking economists, measures the sum of total revenues related to input prices. Rosse and Panzar, and the users of the H statistic after them, hold that such value cannot be positive if a firm is a profit-maximising monopoly. Indeed, under such conditions, an increase in input prices will increase marginal costs and, consequently, total revenue.

35 However such macro-level convergence does not necessarily lead to micro-level convergence. In fact, the evidence for banking systems convergence is much less straightforward.

Building on a cross-country and longitudinal study of banking in 10 countries from 1993 to 1997, Murinde et al., for instance, find that convergence across European banking systems is only found in terms of loans to the private sector and foreign liabilities; but not in terms of loans to public administrations, demand deposits and time and savings deposits (Murinde et al., 2004). Flier et al. have studied the diffusion patterns of regulatory and technological developments in five European countries (France, Italy, the Netherlands, Sweden and the United Kingdom) on a 27-year period (from 1972 to 1999) (Flier et al., 2003). They find that at the national level, differences (in the pace of diffusion) tend to decrease over time; but at the firm level, they find significant differences between strategic behaviours amongst countries. According to them, such findings indicate “divergence and room for managerial intentionality in the process of strategic renewal” (Flier et al., 2003: 27). Affinito et al., for their part, show that there is a great dispersion between the average balance sheet structures of European banking systems – their study covers 11 countries for a 1996-2001 period (Affinito et al., 2003).

Thus, there is contradictory evidence on both the nature and the direction of the actual changes that took place in banking and finance during these past two decades. National financial systems seem to have simultaneously converged and diverged; profoundly changed and kept the same characteristics. Nowhere are these paradoxes more apparent than in the most idiosyncratic sectors of European banking: savings banks.

1.2.6 What about savings banks?

Savings banks have been exposed to the same “environmental” changes affecting other banks or financial institutions. But their peculiar characteristics made them even more vulnerable to those external pressures. First of all, state guarantees, or statutory protection for their non-profit activities, are threatened – both by de-segmentation and competition law. This is especially true in countries such as France and Italy, where savings banks were part of state-administered credit systems. Secondly, increased competition and marketisation, similarly, threaten their non-profit and redistributive purpose.

36 Third, competition and corporate restructuring threaten their independence and their viability as locally rooted financial institutions. In sum, savings banks are presented, it seems, with a difficult alternative: to adjust to their new environment – and lose their identity and specificity; or to disappear. How have savings banks reacted so far? Is there a common (converging) adjustment path across countries?

The existing evidence is mixed. In many countries, the total number of savings banks has shrunk over the years, along a pace much more rapid than in the commercial sector. Moreover, savings banks have actively taken part in the M&A wave of the 1990s. In France, in 1999, the network of Caisses d’épargne et de prévoyance took over Crédit foncier de France; and more recently, the savings banks groups went ahead with the takeover of the merchant bank operations and subsidiaries of the state-owned Caisse des Dépots et Consignations. In Italy, Cassa di Risparmio delle Province Lombarde (CARIPLO), Milan-based biggest Italian savings bank, struck an alliance in the 1990s with a large former public bank, Comit, leading to the formation of Banca Intesa, Italy’s largest banking group. Similarly, savings banks from Turin and Bologna formed alliances with other former public banks, before merging to form large banking groups. And the restructuring wave is not over. In 2002-2003, there were talks of status change for German savings banks, in order to allow them to merge with each other or with privately owned banks. This discussion arose when, with the perspective of the removal of state guarantees, one expected a spur in M&As – but the legal status prevented, for instance, a merger between two neighbouring savings banks such as Frankfurt’s Sparkasse and the Nassauische Sparkasse. Discussions around status change often referred to the French and Italian example32.

Furthermore, since the early 1990s, savings banks have also taken part in the “universalisation” of banking33. Savings banks now look more like commercial banks, with their presence in most markets, their ability to offer any service to any kind of client; their “statutory homologation” with commercial banks. Quesada (1994) finds that Spanish banks in general and savings banks in particular have integrated the financial innovations rather well. And according to Gardener, the growing role of the marketing function in savings banks indicates the growing “demand- determination” of banks’ strategy (Garderner 1994).

32 See « Status critical for Sparkassen » in The Banker, August 2002, pp.27-29. 33 As Revell (1994b) notes, the term “universal banking” has come to mean many things different to many people. The two defining criteria, according to him, are that the universal bank (i) undertakes both retail and wholesale business and (ii) operates in other countries than its home country.

37 However, the existing evidence equally points to the resistance or resilience of savings banks’ identity in the face of homogenisation pressures. French savings banks, for instance, have not disappeared, nor aligned to commercial banks status. Actually, in 1999, they became a cooperative group, moving further away from for-profit banking. In Italy, although savings banks have indeed lost their non-profit purpose, most remain locally rooted and at the service of their old clientele. In both countries, savings banks still hold an edge in savings accounts and related products. More puzzling still, despite their limited adjustment, savings banks in most continental Europe (and especially in France and Italy) have not lost their stronghold position within the banking sector, as numbers quoted above have indicated.

To sum up, the evidence on changes across financial systems is ambiguous: there seem to be some strong common trends and even convergent forces at play across national banking systems; but there also seems to be persisting idiosyncrasies within each system, preventing fully fledged convergence – and savings banks seem to be a good example of persisting cross-country variation. How can one make sense of this mixed evidence? In other words, how can one theoretically account for persistent cross- country variation in national financial systems, especially with regard to savings banks?

38 2. ORGANISATIONAL AND INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE IN NATIONAL FINANCIAL SYSTEMS

2.1 Explaining varieties of financial systems: the role of institutions

2.1.1 Explaining cross-variation in history: the static role of institutions

Strictly speaking, there is no cross-country comparative work on savings banks34. There is, however, a vast comparative literature on financial systems. This heterogeneous literature builds on a stylised fact: financial systems vary from one country to the next. Moreover, this literature addresses two closely related but distinct issues. The first one relates to the origins of cross-country variations in financial systems. The research question is the following: how do we explain the existence (and the origin) of different financial systems between nations?

The second issue has to do with the persistence of cross-country variations throughout the years. This later issue has given rise to a literature that is closely linked to the wave of comparative political economy works that, since the 1970s, have sought to understand the variety of adjustment patterns of countries / systems in the face of growing external pressures to change (technological change, globalisation…). The question addressed in this literature is the following: why are national financial systems not converging on each other (or on a third model)? This issue specifically relates to the research question tackled in this study – namely, the direction of changes. It has come to the fore with the debates about globalisation and its impact on national paths of economic development and national production systems.

34 Apart from the already cited 1999 IEF report. There are comparative historical works on savings banks, but they mostly rely on a juxtaposition of monographs. (See Mura, 1996; and Mentré and Mérieux, 2002).

39 2.1.2 Cross-country variation in the presence of convergence pressures: the dynamic role of institutions

Path-dependency lies at the core of the neo-institutionalists’ theory of institutional change, which itself constitutes the pillar of recent works that seek to explain the persisting variation of national financial systems in the face of globalisation and homogenisation pressures. According to those works, it is institutions that shape adjustment (and non-adjustment) patterns. Vitols, for instance, finds that Germany’s bank-based financial system’s resilience is due to the stability of patterns of savings and investment by households and companies alike (Vitols 2004). Such stability is in turn linked to low levels of income inequality (favourable to long-term savings and risk-adverse behaviour from households) and the characteristics of the German production system. Therefore, the German financial system, despite Anglo-Saxon inspired regulatory reform, remains true to its post- war founding principles – since it is embedded in the broader political economy of German capitalism. In her work on Spain, Sofia Perez underlines the role domestic politics played in bending the regulatory reform in a certain direction – cogent with the interests of a small group of reformers within the central bank and of private bankers (Perez 1997). Deeg and Perez (2000) further argue that the limited convergence of corporate finance and corporate governance systems between countries has much to do with the politics of reform; and the ways in which external pressure is mitigated by internal institutions. Similarly, Lutz argues that the extent of regulatory convergence is linked to the existence (or absence) of what she calls “institutional veto points” in the domestic political system (Lutz 2003).

In fact, most of the recent studies on banking and finance cited here – even though they are more substantial on the empirical side than on the theoretical side - explicitly rely on new institutionalism to explain national financial systems’ persisting differences. In particular, those persisting differences are attributed to (a) the interlock of various institutions shaping firms (banks or financial institutions)’ expectations and behaviour, (b) institutions’ path dependence and (c) the role played by regulatory authorities and politics in mitigating external pressures on domestic firms (banks). Those three mechanisms stand at the heart of the “varieties of capitalism” approach, which, itself, builds on the broad theoretical literature on new institutionalism. Further analysis of these two related theoretical frameworks is thus required.

40 • Neo-institutionalism and persistent cross-country variation in national production systems

As is well-known, the rediscovery of institutions by social scientists in the 1970s has led to a new conceptualisation of the role institutions play in shaping economic and social agents’ behaviour and, therefore, social, economic and political outcomes. “New institutionalism” was defined both in opposition to the behavioural and structuralist theories in vogue in the social sciences in the 1950s and 1960s; and in contrast to the “old institutionalism” present in the works of economists, sociologists and political scientists in the first half of the XXth century (Veblen, Commons, Schumpeter…).

In the field of comparative political economy, the neo-institutionalist agenda was given a strong impetus from the crisis that affected industrial countries in the 1970s and, above all, the variety of responses to it. As Goldthorpe has argued, distinct institutional matrices produce diverse responses to similar economic problems (Golthorpe 1984). A first generation of neo-institutional studies thus addressed the variety of post-crisis adjustment patterns among industrialised countries, focusing in particular on the effect such adjustment patterns had on national economic performance. These studies were followed by a second generation of works in comparative political economy interested in the differences between the structure (not the performance) of national economic systems, and their persistence over time (Berger and Dore 1996; Crouch and Streeck 1997; Boyer and Hollingsworth 1997; Kitschelt et. Al 1999; Quack et al. 1999; Hall and Soskice 2001; Whitley 2002).

Most of these works argued that globalisation pressures do not lead to convergence in the functioning and organisation of economic systems. Moreover, most of those studies explicitly based their theoretical frameworks on neo-institutionalism. Institutions, they argue, shape social outcomes, and thus give their distinct flavour to national forms of capitalism. As Whitley puts it, “specific patterns of economic organisation result from, and are effective within, particular institutional environments so that variation and changes in the latter generate differences in the former” (Whitley 1995: 5). This causality occurs at different levels and runs through various channels.

41 Soskice, for instance, argues that institutions structure coordination between and among firms, which in turn shapes national production regimes (Soskice 1999). Kristensen claims that different institutional contexts determine different firm-types (Kristensen 1995). And, according to Quack and Morgan, national institutions shape national patterns of organisational innovation and adaptation (Quack and Morgan, 1999). In addition, most of these authors explicitly identify the key institutions that shape production regimes, innovation or organisation patterns. These include the financial system (the literature heavily draws on a distinction between market and bank-based financial systems), industrial relations, welfare arrangements, and corporate governance institutions. Fligstein adds cognitive institutions, under the form of “conceptions of control” that influence actor’s behaviour – and, ultimately, national patterns of behaviour (Fligstein 1995).

Of course, there are several types of neo-institutionalism. Hall and Taylor list the three main strands: historical institutionalism, sociological institutionalism and rational choice institutionalism (Hall and Taylor, 1996). The problem with the second generation of comparative political economy works is their difficulty to theoretically account for the permanence of institutional frameworks in front of external pressures to adjust. The third generation of neo-institutional works, what we call here the “Varieties of capitalism” (VOC) approach, after the homonymous book by Hall and Soskice (2001), aimed precisely at overcoming such difficulty.

• The Variety of Capitalism approach

The VOC approach has been applied to a broad range of constitutive elements of national production systems – industrial relations, corporate governance, corporate finance... The starting question of VOC works is the same as that tackled by the earlier generations of comparative political economy works. Namely: what can explain national capitalisms’ tendency to diverge despite strong convergence pressures? In their seminal work, Hall and Soskice (2001) proposed an answer based on two innovative hypotheses: (i) the hypothesis of comparative institutional advantage; and (ii) the hypothesis of institutional interlock and path dependence. According to Hancké (2001), these characteristics distinguish VOC theory from other forms of neo-institutionalism, analysed above.

42 The theory of comparative institutional advantage developed by Hall and Soskice systematises previous theoretical arguments and empirical findings and builds on trade theory, and in particular on Ricardo's law of comparative advantage, which states that countries specialise in the production for which they have a (relative) comparative advantage in trade. In VOC works, comparative advantages arise from different institutional configurations, or different ‘national models of organisation’ (Quack et al., 1999). More precisely, institutions (or web of institutions) endow firms with different capacities to innovate. Coordinated market economies, for instance, are characterised by institutions (apprenticeship, work councils, house banking) that encourage long-term, incremental innovation; liberal market economies, by contrast, are characterised by institutions (stock-markets, flexible labour markets…) that encourage radical, short-term innovation (Hall and Soskice 2001).

The second progress accomplished by Hall and Soskice (as compared with earlier works on comparative political economy) consists in explaining why and how such comparative advantage persists – in other words, why national capitalisms remain distinct. Hall and Soskice formulate two key assumptions: on the one hand, modern economies are based on institutional complementarities that produce specific sets of constraints and incentives for economic actors, which make institutional change very difficult. On the other hand, institutions are path dependent – hence the resilience of national capitalisms over time. The second assumption will be discussed in section three, since it is a core feature, not only of VOC works, but of new institutionalist approaches in general. The first assumption is analysed in detail in the following paragraphs, along with the institutional approach used in all four theories mentioned above.

Institutional interdependence, or institutional interlock, consists in the fact that, as Soskice puts it, “each element of the institutional framework reinforces the other” (Soskice, 1999, p.110); and, one could add, each element calls for the other, or makes it necessary. In other words, institutional interlock is not the contingent outcome of heterogeneous forces; it is functional. For instance, in Germany vocational training (a property of the skills production sub-system) requires both long-term finance (a property of the corporate finance subsystem) and corporate control by stakeholders, including creditors and workers (a property of the corporate governance subsystem) (Soskice 1999; Hall and Soskice 2001).

43 Here the authors build on previous works showing complementarities between various institutions, especially employment contracts and long-term finance (Aoki 1994).

Within such a framework, external pressures to change (i.e. macroeconomic shocks) are mediated by internal institutions which mitigate its impact on single firms; even as one piece of the institutional framework (for instance, corporate governance rules or corporate finance behaviour) tends to change, other pieces remain more or less stable; therefore, on the whole, firms face a stable institutional environment which prevents a massive shift in corporate behaviour. In dynamic terms, adjustment patterns vary between countries because each national economy is embedded within a specific web of inter-related institutions. In other words, firms adjust to a shock (and thus change their behaviour) but within the boundaries of the various institutions that determine their behaviour; hence the different outcomes brought by adjustment to similar external forces.

Both Verdier’s theory of the origins of universal banking and the works on banking and finance inspired by neo-institutional (and in particular VOC) theories of change suggest, therefore, two relevant hypotheses for our two cases. The first hypothesis is that varieties of (savings banks’) adjustment patterns are caused by the idiosyncratic and systemic characteristics of institutions surrounding actors and shaping their behaviour through a stable set of incentives and constraints. The second hypothesis is that resistance to change is reinforced over time, either through “strict” path dependency or through political intervention (protection) – the latter being reconductible to Verdier’s mention of interest group politics (Verdier 2002). Although very useful, this combined theoretical framework presents several weaknesses that are addressed in the following section.

44 2.1.3 The weaknesses of the neo- institutionalist story

Neo-institutionalist works rightly emphasise the role of institutions in shaping individual firms’ response to external shocks and determining aggregate adjustment paths. Furthermore, one critical contribution of such literature to our understanding of the functioning and evolution of national financial systems lies in its insistence on the role of politics and public policy in the production of incentives and constraints that shape, in turn, (banking) firms’ behaviour. However, such approaches also present two weaknesses that become apparent when applying them to our cases.

• Overlooking organisations

First, such analyses overlook the organisational dynamics at play within (banking) firms’ adjustment strategies. This is all the more apparent when looking at two similar sets of firms (savings banks), placed in similar institutional environments (state-administered credit systems) and exposed to similar external pressures, who embark on different adjustment strategies. Given institutional similarity, variety or divergence cannot be solely attributed to institutions and institutional constraints and incentives. In other words, there must be some other variable that produces such different outcomes. Such variable might be found within firms (banks) themselves, that is, within their organisation.

Yet most neo-institutional works do not pay attention to the organisation, and focus on institutional change at a systemic level (Soskice 1999; Vitols 1999, 2001; Thelen 2001) even as some of them (in particular Hall and Soskice 2001) claim to put the firm at the centre of their analysis. In fact, those works seem to mistake institutions for aggregate patterns of behaviour. More fundamental, however, are the theoretical problems associated with new institutionalism. First, neo-institutionalist theory is unable to model agent’s behaviour independently from institutions. There is no room, in this model, for understanding agency other than a simple reaction to institutional change (or persistence). More recent works have instead emphasised the autonomous role of firms and managers in choosing the adjustment paths (see, in particular, Morgan 2005).

45 Secondly, institutions always end up being treated as an exogenous variable. Institutions shape the external environment of firms. As Hancké argues, firms are seen as institutions-takers – not institutions-makers (Hancké, 2002). This view might be correct when looking at small firms in large economies; it is not, however, when analysing large French firms’ adjustment patterns, as Hancké convincingly shows (Hancké, 2002). In recent works this interaction has been more systematically analysed (Morgan 2005).

• Problems with neo-institutionnalists’ theory of change and use of narrow path dependence theory

Comparative political economists are not only interested in cross- country variation; they also aim at understanding the trajectories of one political economy over time. Most comparative political economy works, as shown above, rely therefore on descriptive accounts of historical trajectories (of countries, sectors, firms). The problem is that they rarely theorise these trajectories – why do they take the turn they seem to have taken? Is the dynamic endogenous? What are the mechanisms ensuring the reproduction or the transformation of a system/institutional configuration over time?

This under-theorisation of change is common to many works in social science, which not only treat timing and sequence as irrelevant (see Pierson, 2000a, for a critique), but also make longitudinal inferences from cross-country comparisons (Tilly, 1984). As Pierson convincingly argues, “it is not the past per se but the unfolding of processes over time that is theoretically central” (Pierson 2000a: 265). Neo-institutionalists, however, have made a strong effort to integrate such a conceptualisation of historical change in their theories. To most of these authors, the key dynamic behind institutional resilience is path dependence. Broadly speaking, path dependence theory (henceforth PDT) consists in the argument that past events, however small in importance, may have large consequences – and that particular courses of action, once started, can be difficult to reverse.

46 As mentioned above, the early objective of the neo-institutionalist literature was to confront the convergence thesis. Neo-institutionalist scholars showed the opposite was true: capitalisms persist in their variety. This early concern, however well-founded, built into a flawed binary vision of change in modern economies: a system either converges or diverges (that is, it remains the same). Path dependence theory helped buffer the divergence thesis. In a sense, the neo-institutionalist literature developed the assumption that national economic systems are homogeneous and consistent over time, i.e. they present similar static characteristics that evolve in the same direction. In Crouch and Farrell’s words, users of PDT emphasise “coherent logics of ordering” (Crouch and Farrell, 2002).

This assumption raises a double issue: at the empirical level, it does not account for contradictory evidence (simultaneous change and non-change). Taking, again, the German example, one quickly notices that not only is the financial system dual; its various sub-systems are moving in different directions: large banks are converging on an international model, while small public banks follow the same old path. There is, therefore, convergence and divergence at the same time (Deeg, 2002). This modified version of PDT is not alien to the narrow formulation provided by Pierson, who specifies in his seminal article that “change continues, but it is bounded change – until something erodes or swamps the mechanisms of reproduction that generate continuity.” (Pierson 2000: 265) At the theoretical level, moreover, change does not have to be necessarily associated with convergence, that is, with a process of adjustment towards a single efficient outcome. There are other types of change than changing paths: there is change within the path, there are changes off the path… The trouble with path dependency is that one can always conceptualise a broader “path” that would contain any observed change. Attempts to sketch alternative possibilities are numerous but remain underdeveloped by the literature. Kitschelt et al., for instance, speak about ‘refracted divergence’, in which “some of the past patterns of diversity disappear, are replaced by new ones, reflecting institutionally mediated responses to the challenges posed by the new environment” (Kitschelt et al. 1999b: 442). Similarly, Deeg has tried, in successive works, to endogenise change – or to find endogenous bases for incremental change. Such attempts are not fully satisfactory; a better solution would be to go back to the original formulation of PDT (see next section).

47 2.2 The role of organisation and timing in the dynamics of change

Neo-institutionalism, and neo-institutional theories of change are good at explaining (i) the origins of cross-country variation in economic structures and (ii) the reproduction mechanisms that help perpetuate variation over time. However, as seen above, they present significant weaknesses, which are all the more apparent when they apply to the case of French and Italian savings banks. Indeed, differences in the institutional framework do not seem to be at the root of different adjustment patterns in the two countries; change has occurred, but it seems that it has taken a much more complex form than the bilinear convergence/divergence possibility assumed in neo-institutional theories of change. Those weaknesses might be overcome by (a) emphasising the organisational dimensions of change and (b) adopting a more flexible use of path dependence.

2.2.1 Organisation, governance, strategy as the dependent… and independent variables

The twin hypothesis developed here is that firms (savings banks) (i) are institution-takers AND institution-makers (Hancké, 2002); (ii) are organisations, and are influenced by organisational dynamics and power structures. First, firms are institution-takers and institution-makers. In other words, they sometimes have to adjust to exogenously-induced institutional change; and they sometimes can induce institutional change that upholds their own behaviour. For instance, large firms in France in the early 1980s were exposed to dramatic shifts in their external, institutional environment (nationalisations); over time, however, they built on that changed environment (the arms-length relationship with their benevolent public owner) to shape the institutions that conditioned their successive redeployment (Hancké, 2002). An important implication is that firms face different types of institutions, on which they have different degrees of influence. Specifically, for instance, individual firms or sectors might be unable to influence macroeconomic policy or industry- wide regulations, but they might be capable of shaping sector-wide regulations and policies directly affecting them. Hence the multi-faceted relationship between institutions and firms’ behaviour.

48 The second hypothesis developed here is that firms and sectors are organisations, and are therefore influenced by organisational logics and power structures. This hypothesis has a double implication. First, it means that individual banks’ and banking sector’s organisation constitute a good dependent variable – in other words, it might be useful to analyse change at the organisational (sector, firm) level rather than at a broader institutional level. Several authors acknowledge the important role of organisation at the level of the banking firm. Gardener points out that paying attention to organisational design helps to respond to two fundamental drives in modern firms: specialisation and coordination (Gardener, 1994).

In particular, Gardener argues that the kinds of organisational changes he studies (the rise of marketing functions within banks) are “in large part the product of a greater demand orientation in banking strategies”, adding that “a bank’s organisational structure may be seen simply as a kind of interchange system between the external (outside) environment and the internal resources of the bank.” (Gardener, 1994: 61.) Similarly, Morison’s work on organisational changes in UK clearing banks emphasises the links between external and internal change. Morison argues that organisational change is peculiar (both difficult and interesting, as he puts it) in banking, given that industry’s specificities, namely: the pace of change, the interdependencies between the different parts of banking business, and geography (Morison, 1994). He, like Gardener, takes organisational change as the dependent variable, arguing that it results from changes in banks’ environments and shifts in banks’ strategic priorities. Morison argues that changes in British banks’ environments during the 1980s – mainly regulatory changes, technological changes and changes in demand – were both driven by and the cause of “increased pressures on industry profitability and increased concern to enhance financial performance, where necessary by radically reconfiguring the business being undertaken” (Morison, 1994: 81). Morison insists that the causality between structure and strategy (and performance) is blurred – and his arguments implicitly pave the way for introducing path-dependent-like dynamics, such as, for instance, feedback effects. Morison sees five phases in the organisational evolution of “a typical clearing bank”, which are historically contingent: from the unit bank to the multi-branch bank, from trust companies to refocused banks in the 1970s and product- driven banking groups in the early 1990s.

49 Beyond the organisation within individual banks, the organisation of coordination at the sector or industry level constitutes a key factor behind the peculiar structure of national banking systems and, beyond, of national production systems. VOC scholars themselves have emphasised the role of coordination in the conceptualisation of their ideal-types of varying capitalisms: liberal market economies, where competition prevails, on the one hand; and coordinated market economies on the other, where non-price coordination prevails (Soskice 1999). Both forms of coordination, Soskice argues, “tend to encourage the development of long-term cooperative relations, between one company and another, between companies and employees, and between companies and their owners” (p.106). Sector and group coordination shape the various institutions that form, in turn, the particular framework of constraints and incentives faced by firms – corporate governance, corporate finance, industrial relations. In a sense, then, sector and group coordination could be considered as ‘meta-institutions’ – institutions shaping other institutions. The organising principles characterising coordination are thus the core elements of the specificities of national capitalism. For instance, Deeg shows how the federal organisation of German public and savings banks is key in structuring sector coordination (Deeg 1999)35. In that case, the territorial rooting of coordination is a constitutive element of German capitalism both as the ‘shape’ of coordinated action between actors and as a form of economic organisation per se (in other words, it is both the wine and the bottle of wine). Similarly, Quack and Morgan (1999) emphasise variation in the institutionalisation of sectors. Such arguments fit well with Verdier’s thesis about the linkages between state centralisation and banking market segmentation (Verdier, 2003).

Sector coordination is a key component of European savings banks’ history. Sector organisations have long helped maintain the cohesion and distinctiveness of savings banks. Such organisations are not poised to disappear. In Germany, for instance, where, by 2005, savings banks will lose the system of guarantees provided by their public owners, there is a renewed emphasis on savings banks’ own sector support mechanism, through the giro association, which will constitute the basis for rating36.

35 The importance of such ‘primary’ organising principles for patterns of institutional creation is also mentioned by Skocpol et al.’s recent work on NGOs in the United States (Skocpol et al., 2000). 36 See “Basis of ratings for Germany’s Sparkassen set for change”, The Banker, September 2002, p.16.

50 Understanding how these meta-institutions work and change is thus an important part of understanding institutional change and persistence within national financial systems. From a convergence standpoint, one would expect banking de-segmentation to have put an end to the ancient sector organisation of savings banks and to have replaced it with more competition. From a divergence standpoint, by contrast, coordination should have been maintained, keeping its specific features in each country. Again, then, our task is both to understand what happened and why it happened.

In the research the issue of organisation has been broken down into two main elements. The first one is what I call “shift in savings banks’ corporate boundaries”. This is obviously in reference to ‘orthodox’ and Williamsonian views of the firm, which ignore its boundaries - focusing instead on the bundle of contracts the firm is supposed to be. These views of the firm are, I argue, central to the divergence literature. By focusing on shifting boundaries I am assuming, by contrast, that there is such a thing as corporate boundaries – and, indeed, changing those boundaries was one of the most problematic issues of the 1990s, both for policy- makers and savings banks actors.

The second element is concrete sector organisation, through hard (or formal), as opposed to soft (or informal) institutions: mainly, sector banks and associations, which were a strong feature of both the French and Italian banking system in the 1970s. This second part is closely related to the first one, since it deals with the ‘interior’ of sector boundaries (as opposed to the definition of firm and sector boundaries mentioned above). This dialectic questions Hollingsworth’s distinction between bottom-up and top-down sources of sector change, and more precisely his categorisation of sector boundaries as a ‘top-down’ mechanism, along with the imposition of rules by public authorities (Hollingsworth 1994).

• Balance of power within the organisation: the issue of ownership and control

From what has been said above, the role of organisational dynamics appears to be central in shaping firms’ institutional strategies and corporate behaviour. Organisational dynamics, in turn, can be linked to the evolution of the balance of power within firms, and in particular the evolution of ownership and control. Patterns of corporate ownership and control are among the key characteristics of national economic systems.

51 For many economists (and policy-makers), an efficient market for corporate control guarantees good economic performance. This relationship, indeed, stands at the core of a rich literature that emerged in the 1990s, building on Eastern Europe “transition economies” and on previous works on corporate ownership and control (see La Porta et al., 1999 and 2001, for a review). The aim of most studies belonging to that strand of research is to explain differences and variation in firms’ and nations’ performance by looking at legal and social institutions, such as the patterns of ownership rights, the effectiveness of law implementation, legal culture and structure and so on. Discussing this literature is, however, outside the scope of this study.

What interests us, rather, is to understand the evolution of savings banks’ corporate governance patterns in France and Italy. Again, the analysis aims at uncovering transformations in a comparative way, so as to understand the differences the two countries may or may not continue to exhibit at that particular level of organisation. Beyond the fact that, as mentioned above, control and ownership patterns are often seen as key factors in a country’s economic development, there are two further reasons to focus part of our analysis on this issue. The first one is that banks’ ownership and control is and has been a central issue in both the reforms of the banking sector and the debates around it (see chapter 5). The second reason is that corporate governance is perhaps the single institution where political economy scholars locate the major source of resistance to convergence. Indeed, quite similarly to those economists interested in the role of cultural factors in explaining economic change and non-change, many works within the Voc literature try to assess the role of specific institutions in preventing or facilitating the drive towards a competitive market for corporate control (see, for instance, Soskice 1999; Casper 1997).

This study will explore the evolution of savings banks’ corporate governance to understand the relationship between institutional change, organisational change and shifts in ownership and control. The hypothesis explored here is that there are multidirectional relationships between those three levels of analysis: institutional and organisational change shape patterns of ownership and control, while patterns of ownership and control influence institutional and organisational change.

52 3. THE ROLE OF SAVINGS BANKS IN THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIES IN THE XXTH CENTURY: THE CASES OF FRANCE AND ITALY

3.1 The rise of savings banks

3.1.1 Origins and diffusion throughout Europe

The first savings banks were created in Europe in the late XVIIIth – early XIXth century. Indeed, “the savings bank concept is a European idea” (Kohler 1996), which first took root in continental Europe. According to recent works, the world’s first savings bank was the Ersparnisklasse der Allgemeine Versorgungsanstalt (savings section of the Prudential Institute), created in Hamburg in 1778 (Wysocki 1996). In the late XVIIIth century several similar institutions were founded in Northern Germany: the Leihekasse der Grafschaft Lippe (now Sparkasse Detmold), in Detmold; the ancestor of the Landessparkassen zu Oldenburg in the city of Oldenburg; and Kiel’s savings bank, all three created in 1786. The savings bank movement then spread throughout all German territories, reaching a number of 110 banks in 1825. Savings banks were established in Switzerland at around the same time, with a Dienstenzinskasse (employees’ cashier) founded in Bern in 1787, the Caisse d’Épargne et de Dépôt founded in in 1789, another one in Zurich in 1805 and then in other cities.

But the savings banks movement took its real impulse in Great Britain, from which it then spread to the entire world. Some local savings banks were created in the late XVIIIth century by British aristocrats. Savings banks gained ground in England and followed a rapid expansion path during the first decades of the XIXth century: there were 289 savings banks in Great Britain in 1820. Savings banks gained official consent in 1817 with a bill that created the trustee savings banks system. In 1841, the British Isles had 555 savings banks. From Great-Britain, the savings bank movement then reached Denmark (with its first savings bank created in Holsteinborg in 1810), Ireland (Kilkenny, 1816), the Netherlands (with two savings banks established in 1817: in Workum and Haarlem), Scandinavia (Norway, Sweden, Finland) in 1820.

53 France and Italy followed suit, respectively, with the establishment of a savings bank in Paris in 1818 and in Padua in 1822 (see next section). Savings banks were then established in Belgium (Tournai, 1825), Spain (Madrid, 1838), Portugal (Lisbon, 1844) and Luxembourg (1853). By the mid-XVIIIth century, therefore, savings banks were established and operated throughout most of Western Europe. The savings banks movement then reached other parts of the world, such as the United States (first savings bank created in 1816) and the British Dominions (Australia in 1835, New Zealand in 1847).

3.1.2 The early developments of savings banks in France and Italy

The first French savings bank was the Caisse d’Épargne de Paris, founded in May 1818 by Benjamin Delessert, a philanthropist and member of the protestant high bourgeoisie. As Duet notes, however, at first the expansion of the savings banks movement in France was quite slow: only two Caisses were founded in 1819 ( and Metz); one in 1820 (Rouen); four in 1921 (, , Brest and Troyes); two in 1822 ( and ); one in 1823 (Reims), none from 1824 to 1827, one in 1828 (Nimes); two in 1830 ( and Rennes): thirteen new Caisses in twelve years.

The process of expansion accelerated after 1833: 257 Caisses were created within five years, which brought the total number of French savings banks to 284 in 1839. That number reached 364 in 1848, 536 in 1880, 546 in 1900, and 560 in 1930. The number of savings banks stabilised after the Second World War, at around 556 Caisses. The stabilisation of the creation of new savings banks was compensated by the rapid increase in savings banks branches (see section 2.2.1).

In Italy, the first savings banks were founded in 1820s in the more economically-advanced, Austrian-ruled regions of Lombardy (Milan) and Veneto (Padua, Rovigo, Venice, Udine, Castelfranco Veneto). The pattern that followed the creation, in 1823, of the Cassa di Risparmio delle Provincie Lombarde, or Cariplo, is typical of many cases throughout Italy: first, a “central charity committee” (Commissione centrale di beneficienza) was set up by the Austrian authorities during the 1816 famine to coordinate assistance measures intended for the victims of the famine; the committee was asked to set up a savings bank for the region, which it did in 1823.

54 The savings bank, originally aimed at “craftsmen, workers and the less rich”, soon attracted upper middle-class clients in search of rare investment opportunities. Cariplo grew fast, and within a year it had branches in seven out of the eight provinces of Lombardy.

Following Lombardy and Veneto, savings banks were then founded in Piedmont and Tuscany, with the Casse di risparmio of Turin (1827) and Florence (1829); savings banks soon mushroomed throughout the Grand Duchy of Tuscany: Prato (1830), Pistoia (1831), Siena (1833), Pisa (1834)… A savings bank was founded in Rome, in the Papal States, in 1837, followed by Bologna (1837) and Ferrara (1839). The regions of Romagna (which belonged to the Papal States) and Marche were soon speckled with savings banks: Forli (1839), Ravenna (1840) and Rimini (1841) on the one hand, Pesaro (1840), Ascoli Piceno (1842), Macerata (1845) and Jesi (1846) on the other hand. The Duchy of Modena had two savings banks founded in those years: first in Carpi (1843), then in Modena (1846). The total number of savings banks rose from 25 in 1840 to 60 in 1850 and 91 in 1860 – but more than half of deposited funds (86 million lire), by that date, were held at Cariplo in Lombardy.

Only belatedly did the savings bank movement reach the Southern regions – only, in fact, after the fall of the Bourbon rule over the kingdom of the two Sicilies. Interestingly, Southern savings banks were founded, unlike their Northern counterparts, by the State: in Palermo, the Cassa Centrale di Risparmio Vittorio Emanuele per le Province Siciliane was set up in October 1861 by order of the king, and was controlled by the State through its regional representative, the Prefect, who appointed board members. In Naples, the savings bank was similarly created from the top, in 1862; but, after a few years of operation, it was merged with the Banco di Napoli, the multi-secular issuing bank, and became a division of the latter.

3.1.3 The peculiar identity and purpose of savings banks: Philosophy…

At the root of the savings banks concept were the ideas of self-help promotion on the one hand (the idea that individuals should be educated to manage their funds in a sustainable manner) and access to lending on the other (the idea that poorer borrowers should be freed from usury). The latter had already led to the establishment of pawnbrokers in XVIth century Spain and Italy (the “Montes Pietatis” and “Monti di pieta”, respectively).

55 But savings banks differed from pawnbrokers on many accounts, among which lie the freedom to save whatever amount of money, the payment of interest and the liquidity of deposits. Moreover, and more importantly, pawnbrokers did not emphasise self-help and individual emancipation: these were teachings from the Enlightenment, and they impregnated the origins of savings banks.

The philosophy at the origins of the savings bank movement helps explain why the creation of the first savings banks in all countries was a private, localised initiative. Duet speaks of congruence between the initial localised organisation of savings banks and their mission37. Local initiative was not limited to wealthy individuals: local authorities became involved too – this was the case in Italy and the Netherlands, but especially in Germany. In Belgium, the first savings banks were founded as part of an initiative to create a network of municipal savings banks.

Beyond individual bankers and philanthropists, however, the “public order” potential of savings banks explains why the State later on played an active role in promoting the establishment of savings banks. Early successes in attracting a considerable volume of savings also shed much light on the potential benefits such institutions could accrue to the State. Postal savings banks were founded in Great Britain in 1869, France38 and Italy in 1875. Most of these state-owned savings banks were very successful in attracting a sizeable proportion of savings; in Belgium, for instance, the Caisse Générale d’Épargne et de Retraite (CGER), a public entity created in 1865, accounted for 90% of all banking deposits as early as 1890 (Vanthemsche, 1996).

Finally, the philosophy at their origin gave savings banks a peculiar identity whose main components they kept throughout the XXth century. These core components of savings banks’ identity include: (i) savings banks’ social responsibility; (ii) savings banks’ local rooting and (iii) their focus on private individuals (mainly low income earners) and on small and medium-sized businesses.

37 The same author notes, quite interestingly, that the creation of savings banks presented a paradox: while they were locally rooted (bottom), they were founded from the country’s social elites (top) (Duet, 1999). 38 Postal savings banks, helped by their diffuse network reaching out to those remote rural areas yet deprived of savings banks, soon proved to be savings banks’ fiercest competitors. In Great Britain, for instance, by 1900 the Postal office savings banks had 5 times the number of depositors of the Trustees savings banks, with more than twice as much deposits.

56 Savings banks’ particular mission led to or was tied to a peculiar way of doing business, on both sides of the balance sheet. On the liability side, savings banks differed from existing commercial banks (up to the middle of the XIXth century) in that the funds they managed did not come from their own funds or from the deposits given by a small group of wealthy individuals: they mainly came from small savings. In that regard, the initial funds provided by savings banks’ often wealthy founders did not intend to be invested, but were an investment in themselves, geared towards allowing the nascent institutions to start collecting savings from modest clients. Indeed, savings banks’ corporate identity built first and foremost on savings deposits, which constituted in many cases and for a long time their core liability (they remain so for the French savings banks). As Wysocki points out, when they were first introduced, savings deposits represented a true product innovation, since they were not offered then by other financial intermediaries (Wysocki, 1996).

Savings deposits were conceived for small amounts of money – the kind of savings commercial banks were uninterested in, since they implied diseconomies of scale and did not allow for a flexible policy on the asset side. In other words, lending money on the basis of small deposits was not an attractive business for XIXth century bankers. From the depositors’ point of view, savings deposits represented the first medium tailored to their needs – the first entry into the world of credit. In addition, savings deposits presented three characteristics that made them attractive when compared to the alternative (that is, keeping the money at home): (a) they were interest-bearing deposits (although the interest rates paid on savings deposits were, and have ever been since, small in comparison to other types of banking products, they were still better than no interest at all); (b) they were secure (both because lending was at first either forbidden or strictly regulated, and because many savings banks benefited from public or State guarantee); (c) they were liquid (upon a short period of notice).

Beyond savings deposits, savings banks faced limitations on their liabilities at the outset, especially ceilings on deposits (in Great-Britain, under the 1817 Trustee Savings Bank Act; and in France and Italy in successive regulations). However, over the years (but at different points in time in different countries), savings banks opened themselves to other forms of liabilities – such as sight deposits, generally along with the development of payment procedures, and in particular cashless payment procedures (checks and money transfers).

57 Germany was an early starter, with a 1908 law that allowed savings banks to issue checks, and with the 1909 creation of the first giro association in Saxony. By 1924, savings banks covered the entire territory through their giro network. Denmark quickly followed suit, introducing savings banks’ checks in 1914. In all remaining European countries, however, this diversification of business on the liability side took place much later: Greece in 1953, UK and Ireland in 1965. France stands among the late comers with the authorisation to draw checks dating back to 1978.

On the asset side, savings banks differ from one period to the next and from country to another. Most savings banks faced early limits on lending – mostly articulated in savings banks’ statutes, before being included in state regulations. Danish savings banks did not engage in lending until the 1840s. Nor did the French savings banks; the latter were allowed by an 1829 Decree to invest part of deposited funds into savings accounts held at the Treasury. The Act of March 1837 entrusted the administration of such funds to the “Caisse des dépôts et consignations” (CDC) – the French Treasury’s financial arm, which invested most of its assets in long- term government securities. The transfer of funds was nothing but an option, left to the choice of local savings banks – but they all chose that option at the exclusion of others (such as investments in industry). Therefore the Decree of April 15th, 1852, which made it mandatory for all funds collected by savings banks to be transferred to the CDC merely sanctioned a de facto restriction.

The preferred asset, for most European savings banks during the XIXth and early XXth century, was government securities. According to a 1817 act, British savings banks’ trustees were required to invest their funds in a special account with the British Commissioners for the National Debt, who paid a guaranteed fixed annual interest. Investment in government stock and other public debt securities (such as local government loans) was not limited to British savings banks – it was a widespread practice in France, Denmark and Italy . Such reliance on public bonds was often associated with legal or regulatory provisions in savings banks’ statutes. They could also be interpreted, as Wysocki contends, “as a measure for the precautionary securing of liquid resources where the possibility existed for such instruments to be used as collateral for advances at times of sudden increased demands for payment.” (Wysocki 1996:18).

58 When savings banks were allowed to engage in lending activities, they usually turned to mortgage loans, which to this day represents a typical lending activity for savings banks. As Wysocki argues, mortgage loans combine the high security requirement for the use of savings deposits and relatively simple administration. In many cases, mortgage lending offered a secure alternative for government securities, or vice versa. In Italy, for instance, mortgage loans did not take off until the late 1870s (when government securities reached a low point), and represented up to 56% of savings banks’ total assets in 1960, then declining in favour of government securities; in Germany, government securities were slowly dethroned by mortgage loans as the main asset at the turn of the century.

Beyond government securities and mortgage lending, savings banks did not, at first, engage in other forms of lending, with the exception of German and Danish savings banks, which, in the early XIXth century, offered personal loans, bill businesses (Germany) and loans, guarantees and bills (Denmark). In the 1830s and 1840s, ministerial decrees in Prussia promoted the establishment of district savings banks to provide personal loans and to meet the need for credit of industry and agriculture. However, an 1838 bill restricted lending to mortgages and the acquisition of public sector securities, and put ceilings on small loans.

3.2 Evolution of the role of savings banks within European political economies

3.2.1 The run-up to the 1900s: expansion and (limited) modernisation

In the final decades of the XIXth century, European savings banks experienced large fluctuations associated with the fluidity of financial systems at that time. In France, both the number of savings banks and their turnover grew at a rapid pace.

Despite this expansion, however, French savings banks remained, as a whole, reluctant to diversify their business or to adopt modern banking techniques already used in other countries. The growth that followed their “start-up phase” (until 1875-1880 according to Moster and Vogler) did not bring forward modernisation. Indeed, according to most observers (Duet 1999, Moster and Vogler 1996, Thiolon 1979), from the late XIXth century until the mid-1960s French savings banks remained “fossilised” within an archaic business model and under a stringent relationship with the State.

59 This is not to say, however, that the “savings banks world” was homogeneous in its reluctance to change. There were modernisers, such as Eugène Rostand, chairman of the savings bank of Marseille at the turn of the century, who attempted to link the growing collected funds to local economic development and social cohesion (through targeted investment programs); but their attempts at modernising savings banks failed (see next section).

In Italy, the number of savings banks doubled from 91 in 1860 to 183 in 1880, mainly in the Marche and Southern regions (where the newly created savings banks were mainly small institutions). Total deposits at savings banks grew fast as well, increasing tenfold in forty years; by 1904, total deposits amounted to ITL 1,777 million. Cariplo still led the fray, however less dominantly, with ITL 688 million in 1904, or 39% of the total. Cariplo’s balance sheet was second only to that of the main issuing banks (Banco di Napoli, Banco di Sicilia). Tuscan savings banks followed with 11.5% of total deposits, then Veneto, Emilia, Piedmont. Southern savings banks, although numerous, represented only 9% of total deposits.

Savings banks’ trademark activity, on the asset side, was mortgage lending – as in other European countries, with the notable exception of France. In 1860, it is estimated that 56% of Italian savings banks’ total assets were made up of mortgage credit. By the third quarter of the XIXth century, virtually all savings banks granted mortgage-secured loans, especially in agriculture. However, successive State regulations constrained the mortgage lending business through market segmentation: an 1866 Act limited mortgage bonds issuance to four major banks and two savings banks (Milan and Bologna). Each bank was assigned a territory where it was able to offer such products. Eventually, other banking institutions were invited to join in other parts of the country. In 1884, a new law abolished territorial monopolies and allowed authorised credit institutions to extend their mortgage credit activities over the whole national territory; among savings banks, the only one to take up that opportunity was Cariplo. A few years later, in 1890, the State created the Istituto Italiano di Credito Fondiario (Italian mortgage credit institution), which became, besides Cariplo, the sole institution authorised to offer mortgage credit on a national basis. As a whole, by the end of the XIXth century, mortgage lending had decreased in importance. It remained a marginal instrument for financing investments in agricultural production – although for some banks, it represented a sizeable part of business: Cariplo, for instance, dedicated 64% of its mortgage lending, from 1866 to 1885, to finance the acquisition of agricultural land.

60 Despite its decreasing importance, however, mortgage lending had enabled savings banks to develop credit and lending functions which, according to Clarich, successfully shielded them from competition from Postal savings banks after 1875 (Clarich, 1984: 22).

In the final third of the XIXth century, Italian savings banks, like other banks, turned more and more towards public securities, which accounted for 9% of total assets in 1860, 46% in 1880 (against 20% for mortgage loans) and 56% in 1904. These changes, as Hertner notes, mirrored profound transformations in the economic structure of the country, with the State and public corporations taking a leading role in fostering “heavy” investments in infrastructure and industry (Hertner 1996).

Apart from (decreasing) mortgage lending and securities, most savings banks did not venture into other types of investments until late in the XIXth century. Cariplo, for instance, did not propose bill discounting to ordinary clients until the turn of the century – whereas the latter constituted a widespread business outlet among large, non-savings banks. Only a few savings banks in the Emilia and Romagna regions made an exception, with the Cassa di risparmio di Parma, for instance, whose lending made up 60% of its assets in 1890 – mainly consisting of credit discount to agriculture. Overall, however, savings banks’ business strategy remained driven by its liabilities – small savings. That is why the new generation of cooperative banks that appeared in the late XIXth century, the Banche Popolari, reaped immediate success and were called by some observers “improved savings banks” since, beyond collecting small-scale savings, they also made sure to invest those funds into productive undertakings by their members (see Clarich, 1984: 21). On the other hand, savings banks precisely and repetitively boasted their careful lending strategy, a cornerstone in the stabilising role they aimed to play within the financial system.

3.2.2 Regulation at the turn of the century

In several countries, savings banks’ self-regulation prevailed until the last decade or so of the XIXth century, which witnessed government regulatory intervention39 in banking, and in particular in the savings banks sector. Germany, again, was an exception, since Prussia passed a Sparkassen- reglement as early as 1838, which became the “basic law” model for savings banks throughout German states; so did the United Kingdom, with the 1817 Bill that founded the Trustee Savings Bank system.

39 By contrast with direct state intervention through setting up public or quasi-public banks.

61 The late XIXth century expansion of savings banks met closer scrutiny from public authorities, in a period of stricter regulations on banking and finance. In many European countries, the 1880s saw the first wave of regulatory efforts towards savings banks: Denmark’s 1880 Savings Banks Act, which created a supervision authority; the 1904 Savings Bank Act in Great-Britain, which eased the restrictions on deposit (ceilings) and lending; the 1895 law in France and the 1888 law in Italy.

• France

During the XIXth century, French regulatory authorities (i.e. the Treasury) were especially concerned with the rapid growth in deposits that, since they were mostly invested in public debt, risked inflating State debt and reducing its creditworthiness. In the preamble of the Law of July 20, 1895, reference was made to the “threatening expansion” of deposits. There were two ways of dealing with such expansion. One was to diversify the use of funds. The other was to impose limits on deposits. The first part of the alternative was at the centre of a debate that arose after 1885, when several law proposals were discussed in Parliament – a debate known as the “quarrel on the use of funds” (see Duet, 1999).

That debate pitted reformists against the defenders of the status-quo. In addition, there were two groups of reformists: one moderate and one radical. The moderate reformists, headed by MP Hubbard, proposed the diversification of the use of funds by the Caisse des Dépots – away from rentes d’Etat towards lending to local governments, chambers of commerce and other para-public entities. Under this proposal, savings banks would have had the responsibility of “suggesting” the beneficiaries so that there be “a tangible link between lending and the deposited funds” (cited in Duet, 1999: 48). However, that idea was not even discussed, its vindication corresponding to parliamentary recess. Yet it would lay the basis for the Minjoz reform some 60 years later (see next sections).

The second group of reformists, more radical, was led by Eugène Rostand, chairman of the Savings Bank of Marseille, lawyer and newspaper director, a colourful character, who argued in favour of the free use of funds by savings banks - on the German and Italian model – mainly through mortgage lending, investment in bonds issued by welfare institutions and cooperative credit.

62 Such proposal, in Rostand’s view, did not endanger the security of funds, since it circumscribed the political risks tied to rentes d’Etat; furthermore, it guaranteed a more efficient allocation of funds since private actors were, in his view, better equipped and had more incentive to do so.

The 1895 law, however, marked the victory of the status quo. Even the slightly innovative proposals put forward by the law’s rapporteur (such as the possibility for the Caisses to use a fraction of collected funds to be invested in the local economy) were wiped away by the parliamentary debates. The law was mainly concerned with sustaining the value of the State pensions (rentes) and by imposing limits on deposits. The latter - the second element of the alternative facing regulators, constituted a constant in French regulatory policy since the early XIXth century: the ceiling on deposits was first set at FRF 3,000 in 1835, down to FRF 1,500 in 1845 and FRF 1,000 in 1851, raised to FRF 2,000 in 1881 and lowered again by the 1895 law to FRF 1,500, from which level it did not move until 1916. According to Moster and Vogler, therefore, the 1895 Act represented a “Malthusian choice” that “froze the whole system until 1945” (Moster and Vogler 1996).

The Treasury and the CDC were staunch defenders of the status quo. However, the 1895 restrictive regulatory regime cannot be seen as imposed by conservative State actors on reformist savings banks. Actually, most savings banks administrators (who then played the leading role in governing the Caisses) were strongly attached to the status quo and reluctant to diversify the use of funds, let alone to actually manage them. At their 1890 Congress, which discussed the Rostand proposal, only 5% of participants declared themselves in favour, despite the former’s careful wording – the free use of funds was only proposed as an option to savings banks and circumscribed to 25% of funds (Duet, 1999). Even local experimentation by three savings banks was rejected at the same Congress. As Duet notes, such aversion to risk, or at least to innovation, was probably not only characteristic of savings banks managers but also of their clients, who, even though many of them were small and medium entrepreneurs, did not demand another use of funds by the Caisses.

63 There were two exceptions to the restrictive regulatory regime put in place by the 1895 law: the regulations concerning the savings banks of Alsace and Lorraine and those concerning the Post Office Savings Bank (see above). After the 1871 German annexation of Alsace and Lorraine, the most important savings banks of the Land were authorised, by an 1895 Act, to use freely 40% and 50% of the funds collected in favour of local authorities. Subsequently, a 1912 Act provided savings banks with largely independent management and lifted the ceilings on deposits from DEM1,000 to DEM4,000. The Act provided that up to 20% of deposited funds should be invested in securities, up to 50% in loans to local governments and other public institutions and up to 20% in mortgage loans to individuals. After the French sovereignty was recovered, the same regime persisted until 1984, despite modifications.

• Italy

In Italy, the legislation governing the savings banks sector evolved slowly over the years and presented numerous inconsistencies. Like in the French case, regulation of savings banks was at first a matter of self-regulation, mainly through the statutes – whose diversity preserved the initial institutional pluralism among Italian savings banks. Only in the second half of the XIXth century did the State and other public authorities start intervening.

Those statutes initially imposed strict limitations (ceilings and floors) on the volume of deposits and restricted the range of possible uses for the funds collected (safety was the main concern) to public securities, public bonds, and lending to local governments. Along the years and with the transformation of savings banks’ clientele (with the apparition of the middle-class), savings banks implemented statutory changes that allowed them to differentiate among various types of deposits (to which various ceilings, floors, conditions, … corresponded) and allow for more profitable use of funds.

With the increased economic relevance of savings banks came the end of the statutory freedom Italian savings banks enjoyed in their first fifty years of life. The first regulatory act specifically targeted to savings banks was a Sardignia Law of 1851 that created fiscal incentives for savings banks to limit their lending and remain welfare institutions. A Piedmont law of 1851 treated savings banks merely as charitable entities; that law inspired other regional regulations passed during the same decade.

64 As seen above, some savings banks were also concerned with successive legislation on mortgage bonds issuance and mortgage lending in general.

Those regulations all revolved around the issue of the exact nature of savings banks, their legal identity, and the regulatory authority that should monitor them. In 1876, a decision by the State Council (Consiglio di Stato, the highest juridical institution for administrative law) put savings banks on an equal footing with other credit institutions in terms of constraints on lending and the use of funds. But that decision did not put an end to the ongoing debate on the nature of the Casse di risparmio. In particular, it was unclear whether savings banks should legally be assimilated to charitable institutions that, among other things, benefited from a favourable fiscal status – which explains why savings banks, who rejected the qualification of charitable institution given their economic role, did not embrace commercial banks’ status either. That debate provided the background to Italy’s first country- wide legislative act towards savings banks, the law of July 15, 1888, n.5546, “sull’Ordinamento delle Casse di Risparmio”.

Like in France, the State’s legislative intervention happened in a context characterised, on the one hand, by the extension of the State’s involvement in the economy (especially through the realisation of ambitious and costly public works programs, such as the construction of railways…), with a simultaneous rise in public spending financed through the issuance of bonds; and, on the other hand, by the State’s attempts to insert itself into civil society so as to crowd out the competing influence of the Catholic church40.

The 1888 Act, like France’s 1895 law, set up general guidelines for the entire sector, while giving savings banks “considerable freedom of movement within the confines of their own self-imposed statutory basic rules”41. The 1888 Act drew largely from the first savings banks congress, which was held in Florence in 1886. Like in France, savings banks’ top administrators did not agree on which direction regulatory reform should take – although unlike France, the discussion was less about the substance of regulation than about its extent.

40 Clarich compares the 1888 Law with a 1890 law on welfare institutions, the latter aiming to bring under the control of the State local welfare institutions founded by or linked to the Church (Clarich, 1984: 34). 41 Ministero dell’Agricoltura, dell’Industria e del Commercio, Le Casse Ordinarie di Risparmio in Italia dal 1822 al 1904, Roma 1906, cited in Hertner 1996.

65 Against a “radical” group of savings banks that was firmly opposed to any state intervention at all, the 1886 Congress gave reason to a more moderate group of banks intent on playing the card of legislative intervention precisely to protect savings banks from further encroachments from the part of the state. Both groups, however, strongly supported the supremacy of the status as a source of regulation; and they were determined to defend savings banks’ autonomy with respect to statutory design and changes.

The 1888 Law, therefore, confirmed savings banks’ nature as credit institutions; and it reinforced the emancipation of savings banks from their founders. In particular, the law conferred legal personality to savings banks, recognising the existence of such a thing as “Casse di risparmio” (art.1 and 28 of the law); provided them with organisational autonomy; submitted the creation of new savings banks to the approval of the Ministry of Agriculture, Trade and Industry; obliged savings banks of “foundational” origins to differentiate savings banks’ patrimony and administration from that of the founding entities (art.4); provided that the original contributions to savings banks’ equity should be returned to the contributors.

A key part of the law was dedicated to what is now called the “corporate governance” of banks, and was aimed at freeing savings banks’ activity from the influence of private interests. The law put an end to the relationship between the holding of shares and the quality of member of the board or the general assembly; and banned the payment of dividends to stakeholders. These two dispositions (art.5 and 6 of the 1888 law) effectively transformed, as Clarich notes, the general assembly from the representative organ of shareholders into the “place of confluence between all relevant economic and social stakes within the community” (Clarich, 1984: 36).

In the same spirit of recognising both savings banks’ autonomy and their nature of credit institutions, the 1888 law did not impose constraints on savings banks’ use of funds, merely underlying the need to avoid “imprudent business practices”42.

42 Although Clarich notes that the terminology used in the law somewhat tempers this recognition of the banking nature of savings banks; in particular, art. 1 of the law emphasises savings banks’ role in collecting savings, while it does not mention their role and function as lenders (Clarich 1984: 40).

66 The law also emphasised the importance of small savings, and authorised the opening, by savings banks, of current account deposits43. For all other aspects the law referred to statuses, thus giving rein to savings banks’ autonomy of decision in the field of business operations. At the prospect of savings banks becoming fully-fledged credit institutions, the 1888 law also paid careful attention to patrimonial ratios; in particular, in addition to the obligation of constituting a “fondo di dotazione” (own funds) at the moment of the constitution of a new savings banks, the law provided that 90% of annual profits should accrue to a reserve fund of up to 10% of total deposited funds. In that way, according to Clarich, the legislators wanted to strengthen savings banks’ financial solidity, to enable them to face the greater risks involved by a more dynamic credit activity (Clarich, 1984).

The three application decrees signed shortly after the law, although they contained several regulatory elements typical of the State’s relationship with charitable institutions, include dispositions that further asserted savings banks’ commercial raison d’être. Furthermore: according to Clarich, such regulations, taken together (the 1888 law and its application decrees) actually paved the way for a legal recognition of the banking firm as such – while the 1882 Code of Commerce ignored the specific role and functions of banks, apart from minor provisions – which became a reality in 1893, with Italy’s first banking law. In addition, at around the same time, even the Monti di pieta, those institutions that appeared in the XIVth century – their mission being to lend small amounts of money to poor households – were seen as the predecessors of savings banks, and were gradually acquiring banking characteristics – the Monti were submitted to the 1888 law as well.

Overall, therefore, while the French and Italian reforms of the late XIXth century express a common concern towards regulating savings banks and towards a greater monitoring from the state, the content of the reform was quite dissimilar: restrictive in France, much “looser” in Italy.

43 According to Pin (1973), that disposition was critical for the future of savings banks, in that it paved the way for a transformation of the latter from non-monetary financial intermediaries into monetary intermediaries.

67 Moreover, these reforms fit neatly within the framework of Verdier’s argument, examined in chapter 1: in France, centralisation led to functional segmentation, and the state pre-empted savings banks resources. In Italy, by contrast, a much weaker state (in a historically less centralised country) did not impede savings banks in the development of their business, especially on the asset side. These reforms had a strong bearing on the successive development of savings banks, as we will see in the following sections.

3.2.3 The second period of expansion: 1900-1945

The first decades of the XIXth century saw a rapid growth of savings banks in most European countries. Such growth can be attributed to many factors, among which: (i) strong economic growth following the 1890s slump; (ii) a profound change in the social and demographic structure of industrial societies (with growing working classes accompanying the diffusion of industry); and (iii) the slow rise of real wages within the working class, leading to higher savings.

As Vanthemsche further noted, the late XIXth century also witnessed an important change in the practice and philosophy of savings. As seen above, the conception at the core of the savings movement animated by philanthropists was that savings were a long-term effort by the individual – and so should be promoted. From the 1890s on, however, other savings practices emerged (short-term and collective) that crystallised into new organisational forms – in particular, in Belgium and Germany, the consumer cooperatives linked to the labour movement or to Catholic farmers. Those new organisations at first diverted sums from already established savings banks. Soon, however, they created their own savings banks.

In some countries, the 1910s and 1920s offered savings banks new opportunities to diversify their business. In Germany, for instance, the First World War allowed savings banks to hold a foot in the securities business; and a 1921 decree lifted the restrictions on deposit and current account transactions, authorising them, in particular, to lend against bills and to purchase securities on behalf of customers. These were important steps in German savings banks’ path towards universal banking; in a few years, German savings’ total intermediated funds jumped from 1.5 billion Reichsmarks (1924) to 16.5 billion Reichsmarks (1934). In this regard, France and Italy represent two contrasting situations.

68 • France

In France, the first half of the XXth century did not witness significant growth or developments within savings banks. Duet showed that the volume of deposits in1950 of constant prices differed little from that of 1925 or even that of 1890. There were 585 savings banks in 1952, a figure not very different from that of the late XIXth century, and 3,000 deposit-receiving agencies in 1946, up only 50% from the number four decades earlier. Several factors may account for such stagnation. First among these was savings banks’ risk aversion, reinforced by the French state’s primary focus on public debt (and not on private investments – see previous section). Secondly, price and monetary fluctuations from the 1910s up to the 1950s caused considerable swings in the value of deposits in constant francs.

The Postal savings banks (Caisse Nationale d’Epargne, or CNE) did better than its private counterparts, making up for its late start – and benefiting from private savings banks’ lethargy. The number of savings accounts at the CNE rose from 5 million in 1904 to 10 million in 1935 and 12,728,000 in 1945 – more than the savings accounts held at private savings banks, which amounted at around 11,892,000 that same year. The volume of deposits grew simultaneously from FRF 1 billion in 1900 to FRF 5 billion in 1914 francs in 1933, to reach the level of private savings banks in 1945.

Overall, according to Duet, CNE’s and private savings banks’ customers accounted for nearly 60% of the population in 1955; and savings deposits accounted for as much as 33% of the country’s monetary resources in 1938. Such “giant” deposit institutions were, however, “dwarves” in lending or even direct securities holdings.

• Italy

In Italy, the first decades of the XXth century were characterised by huge swings in market shares and important innovations on the asset side (in contrast to France), and the permanence of high market shares in savings deposits (like in France). On the liabilities side, savings banks maintained, until the late 1930s, the dominant market position they had secured since the mid-1850s: from 68% of total fiduciary deposits (savings and current accounts) in 1870 (against 26% for commercial banks and 6% for cooperatives) to 73% in 1900 (after a slight decrease during the 1880s), to 75.6% in 1932 (against 16% for commercial banks and 8.4% for cooperative banks) (Polsi 2001).

69 On the asset side, and despite the prevalence of public securities in savings banks’ assets at the turn of the century, most of the Casse di risparmio also engaged in other types of assets. The 1893-94 banking crisis and the 1897-98 general economic downturn led to a new dynamism on the asset side from the part of savings banks. The latter were also certainly stimulated by the rapid growth of new commercial banks created in those years, such as the Banca Commerciale Italiana and the Credito Italiano. Even at Cariplo, which made no mystery of its conservative investment policy (a “splendid isolation” according to Confalonieri), the proportion of public securities out of total assets dropped from 68% in 1897 to 48% in 1913, while the bill portfolio increased from 1.5% of total assets in 1897 to 7% in 1913. In Milan, the bill portfolio mainly consisted of loans to the railway and electricity sectors and to major industrial firms. Moreover, Italian savings banks played an especially important role in the development of agricultural credit.

In addition, savings banks became a resource often tapped by the central bank or the regulatory authorities in times of crisis through, in particular, their participation into loan syndicates to sectors in difficulty (such as the steel industry in 1911 or even the banking sector in 1907). Savings banks were also invited by the Treasury to contribute to the capital of the central credit institution for cooperatives (the future Banca Nazionale del Lavoro), created in 1913. In that sense, it has been argued that savings banks acted as “mute participants” in the constitution of major public financial institutions (Conti and Ferri 1997).

The First World War had a huge impact on Italian savings banks’ business. First, money printing and inflation eroded the propensity to save; second, the issuance of public securities crowded out liquid savings; both phenomena led to a fall in savings banks deposits, from ITL 2,730 million in 1913 to ITL 1,070 million in 1919. On the asset side, public securities again rose in savings banks’ balance sheets: from 42.6% of total assets in 1913, public securities rose to 68% in 1919.

The 1920s marked a “return to normal”, with a renewed growth in deposits (which amounted to ITL 3,400 million in 1928) and a new decrease in securities out of total assets (49% in 1920, 32% in 1928). However, the war years had taken their toll, especially on the asset side, and savings banks did not recover fast enough to compete with commercial banks, which played the central role in the second phase of industrialisation – while savings banks were still facing statutory restrictions when it came to financing industry.

70 3.2.4 The 1930s regulatory changes and their impact on savings banks

The 1929 stock market crash and the ensuing financial and economic crisis, which affected all industrial countries, led to a dramatic re-haul of the financial and banking regulatory regimes in all European countries. Savings banks also faced both general banking law reforms that affected them (see next chapter) and specific reforms aimed at the sector. The latter showed similarities between countries.

First, stronger administrative regulation stood at the core of savings banks regulatory reforms. In several countries, the 1930s reforms made regulations more stringent and imposed on savings banks a series of obligations and restrictions unknown before. In Belgium, a December 1934 Royal Decree established a system of legal supervision that entailed authorisation for the creation of new savings banks, minimal capital requirements, limitations on the use of funds, interdiction of shareholdings in trade or industry, and supervision by an “Office Central de la Petite Epargne”, created that same year. In Denmark, a May 1937 law delimited savings banks’ business and distinguished different categories of authorised investment.

In some cases, however, the 1930s regulatory reforms actually led to empowering savings banks by expanding their business horizons. In Germany, a first series of Presidential decrees in 1931 severed the organic links between savings banks and local governments, by granting banks legal personality, transferring to new entities the ownership of their own funds, separating the board of directors from local government (while maintaining the system of local authorities’ guarantees). The 1933 Banking Inquiry, which was prompted by the banking crisis and aimed at streamlining savings banks’ business (at the “instigation of their competitors”, according to Mura 1996), actually ended up legitimising savings banks’ extensive line of business, and especially short-term loans and giro transactions. Finally, the 1934 Reich Credit Act extended to savings banks the regulatory regime applied to commercial banks

State control over banking in general and savings banks in particular were not, however, circumscribed to authoritarian regimes. In countries such as Great Britain, for instance, the financial strains imposed by the First World War and then by public (mostly military) investment programs led to the issuance of War Savings Certificates managed by a War (then National) Savings Committee, competing with both the Post office savings banks and the Trustees savings banks to attract British subjects’ savings to channel them into government treasury needs.

71 • Italy

In Italy, the regulatory changes of the late 1920s and 1930s were intertwined with the particular political economy of the fascists’ authoritarian regime, put in place progressively after 1922. The new regime’s economic interventionism – which was not too dissimilar from state intervention in democratic countries – led to four major developments concerning savings banks.

First, the 1926 Banking Act, the first of its kind, because it identified credit and banking as a specific area for regulation. The law identified the Bank of Italy as the sole and thus the central issuing institution; it imposed new requirements on all banks, including savings banks, and included (i) the introduction of an authorisation regime for the creation of new banks, delivered by the Ministry of Finance; (ii) the introduction of mandatory reserves; (iii) the introduction of an obligation of information; and (iv) the introduction of ceilings on loans to private individuals. Furthermore, the 1926 law created a new regulatory regime, whereby commercial banks were submitted to supervision by the Bank of Italy and the Ministry of Finance – while savings banks remained under the supervision of the Ministry of the Economy, formerly known as the Ministry of Agriculture, Industry and Commerce. Importantly, all other legal and administrative regulations governing the savings banks sector were maintained, provided that they did not clash with the principles laid down in the 1926 Act. In fact, as Clarich argues, the 1926 law followed a logic close to the one that had prevailed in the 1888 law on savings banks; among the new measures included in the 1926 law as steps towards ensuring the protection of depositors, were minimum capital requirements and mandatory reserves, both of which had been first created for savings banks by the 1888 law.

For that reason, savings banks were relatively unaffected by the 1926 law. The latter just extended to savings banks the more stringent supervision rules applied to commercial banks, including the authorisation regime.

A second major trend was the forced restructuring of savings banks. This, like the 1926 law, was a reaction to a rapid (“chaotic” according to Clarich) rise in the number of banks and bank branches in the preceding years.

72 The Legal Decree of February 10, 1927, n.269, disposed a radical revamp of the whole sector: savings banks with total deposits of less than ITL 5 million were required to merge with larger institutions, while savings banks with total deposits of between ITL 5 million and ITL 10 million had the possibility of doing so. Further regulations in 1938 disposed that savings banks with less than ITL 30 million in deposits should merge within the provincial capital’s savings bank. As a consequence, the total number of savings declined sharply: from 205 to 98 in one single year (1930), and then to 78 by 1939. The 1927 Act also forced savings banks to unite at either provincial or regional levels in Federations, each of which was required to set up a common guarantee fund to be used in the event of customer default. Finally, the 1927 Act also impinged on savings banks’ statutory autonomy by transferring the power to amend those statutes from the annual general assembly to the administrative board – much easier to control for the state. A further 1938 reform (by decree) disposed that the appointment of the chairman and vice-chairman of the board of savings banks would be decided by the State supervisory body, after consultation with the ACRI, savings banks’ association.

A third key component of the regime’s interventionist approach to banking was credit segmentation. As early as October 1923, a Royal Decree stipulated that savings banks could open new branches only in areas where they were already operating. Interestingly, this measure, which was a first step towards the territorial limitation of competition in banking, was suggested by savings banks themselves at their congress held in Trieste the previous year. Furthermore, the foundation of all new savings banks branches was to be subject, to approval, by the Ministry of Economic Affairs.

Further credit segmentation was introduced by the 1936 Banking Act, which re-organised the entire banking sector and introduced a strict division of business activities for various types of banks. This specific measure did not have a particular impact on savings banks, although they were included under the category of “credit institution” for the first time. The 1936 Act also remodelled the regulatory institutional framework, with the creation of a specific supervisory body with inspection powers, the Ispettorato per la difesa del risparmio e per l’esercizio del credito – an institution headed de facto by the governor of the central bank and dependent on the Bank of Italy for operations and personnel.

73 But despite those new institutional arrangements, which concerned savings banks as well, the latter still abided by the 1888 regulation and their own statutory provisions – an ambiguous regulatory regime that remained in place up until the 1980s. Finally, the authoritarian flavour of the 1927 reform was confirmed with the introduction, by a February 1938 legislative decree, of the government appointment of the chairman and vice-chairman of the savings banks, upon a proposal made by the Ispettorato and after advice from the national Federation of savings banks.

Savings banks were therefore subject to an interventionist regulatory framework that for the first time threatened their autonomy; and they collectively expressed their concerns at their sixth annual congress in 1937. Ironically, the 1936 law also crowned their previous efforts to see their “banking identity” recognised, with their assimilation to the broad category of “credit firms” (aziende di credito). More importantly, a small passage of the 1936 law implicitly maintained the authorisation given to savings banks by previous legislation to lend medium and long-term through mortgage credit and lending to moral persons.

In fact, beyond the regulatory elements mentioned above, the 1936 law left intact the previous regulatory framework and all measures relative to the organisation and functioning of the Casse di Risparmio.

3.2.5 Increased coordination at sector level: the role of savings banks’ associations

Around the turn of the century, savings banks started to organise at sector level within each European country. The most achieved example of such sector organisation is, of course, Germany where, since the early 1880s, savings banks created associations44 entrusted with the twin task of promoting savings banks’ interests and diffusing the idea and practice of savings among the population. The associational movement among German savings banks set the stage for the establishment of the giro system, which followed a 1908 state act that gave savings banks the right to draw checks.

44 The first one being the Association of savings banks in Rhineland and Westphalia, created in Hagen in 1881.

74 As Mura notes, “the introduction of cashless payments by the savings banks proved to be a watershed for the development of the German ‘savings banks units’” (Mura 1996: 108). The giro system was a clearing system, where regional giro associations, together with savings banks, acted as guarantors for the central giro institutions (“Girozentralen”) through which giro payments were cleared.

The first savings banks and giro associations were set up between 1920 and 1925, as well as the Girozentralen, most of which later became independent banks45. During the late 1920s – 1930s, most Girozentralen merged with state banks (Staatsbanken and Landesbanken), thus leading to the emergence of powerful Landesbanken / Girozentralen at the Land level. The giro association was led by the Deutsche Zentral. Giroverband, which created savings banks’ central bank, or Girozentrale, in 1918. Finally, the Deutscher Sparkassen und Giroverband was created in 1924, unifying at a national level the giro and savings banks networks. The association, as Mura notes, was set up as a public corporation, to be able to function as guarantor for the liabilities of the Deutsche Girozentrale.

The role of the giro associations was to operate as savings banks’ regional clearing institutions – holding cash deposits for savings banks, transferring liquidity to cash-deprived savings banks. One of the 1931 emergency ministerial decrees obliged savings banks to hold cash reserves at the giro institution, further strengthening the role of the giro organisation. But the sector dynamics embodied in the giro system did not stop there. The association played a key role in making the savings banks sector more homogeneous and powerful: in 1927, it enacted “status-types”, which became the basis for further state regulation of savings banks; it created a research and a training institute (1928); it engaged into national advertising campaigns, gave managerial instructions, and published journals. The association survived national-socialism, but after the war it was reduced to guarantor of the Deutsche Girozentrale, while its associational functions were transferred to another body in 194746.

45 Giro central banks soon engaged in lending of their own – they started offering short-term personal loans in 1921. 46 The “Arbeitsgemeinschaft Deutscher Sparkassen und Giroverbande und Girozentralen” (Union of German Savings Banks, Giro Associations and Central Giro Institutions), later renamed into the “Deutscher Sparkassen und Giroverband e.V.”

75 From that time on, the association continued playing a key role defending savings banks’ interests (for instance, against threats by the occupying powers of abolishing the savings banks payments network) and (successfully) lobbying successive governments to shape banking regulation in favour of savings banks’ interests.

The strong sector organisations existing in Germany had but weak counterparts in France and Italy.

• France

Up until the post-war years, French savings banks were loosely organised at the regional and national level. At the regional level, the 550 savings banks (in 1900) belonged to broad regional associations – there were seven of them in 1958, covering large territories and including several dozens of members each. These members would meet once a year at a general meeting and a congress, whose agenda reflected the concerns of the time (ceiling on deposits, interest rates…). At the national level, the regional associations belonged to the Conférence Générale des Caisses d’Épargne, a national association founded in 1911. The Conférence Générale was competent for concluding collective wage agreements; it set savings banks’ line of conduct for discussions at the Commission Supérieure (the regulatory authority - see below); and it represented savings banks at the institutional level.

Besides the “official” sector organisation, a Bureau Central des Caisses d’Épargne was created in 1906 as a private initiative and under the form of a partnership owned by the Laurent family. At first, the Bureau Central functioned as a marketing agency for the Caisses d’Épargne; it then extended its reach to sector publications (the Journal des Caisses d’Epargne) and even training activities (see below).

However, until the post-war years the truly effective sector organisation was a corporatist body, the Commission Supérieure. The Commission was created by the 1895 Law as an advisory body working with the Ministry of Finance on the regulation of savings banks, and focused on savings banks’ functioning and organisation. The Commission Supérieure was composed of 22 members, 12 of whom represented savings banks and were appointed by the Conférence Générale.

76 Over the years and until the post-war years, the Commission Supérieure worked as a platform for dialogue between savings banks, the Treasury and the CDC.

• Italy

In Italy too, coordination between and among savings banks first arose as a reaction against the first attempts at state regulation, in 1881 – savings banks then collectively presented petitions to the Parliament against a law proposal that assimilated them to welfare institutions. That first aggregation led to the organisation of the first national congress of savings banks, which was held in Florence in 1886 and aimed at elaborating a common strategy to be submitted to the Parliament. As mentioned above, the 1888 law largely drew on those suggestions.

Meetings were then organised at the regional level, and a standing committee was created for purposes of representation and lobbying. Only in 1911 however, at their second national congress in Turin, did savings banks agree to found an association, the Associazione fra le Casse di Risparmio Italiane, or ACRI, which was officially born in April 1912, with its headquarters in Rome and 150 members (out of the 184 then existing savings banks). ACRI’s original mission was to provide advice to its members on matters relating to legal, financial and fiscal issues. It soon became, however, the central political organ of savings banks, some of whom regularly asked to have the ACRI systematically associated to any state regulation towards the sector. In 1912, the association started publishing a Bulletin, which became the Rivista delle Casse di Risparmio in 1926. In 1938, ACRI founded a guarantee fund, called “fondo per anticipazioni a casse di risparmio”.

In 1919, savings banks undertook a significant step in furthering their coordination at the sector level, through the creation of a financial umbrella organisation, the Istituto di Credito delle Casse di Risparmio (ICCRI) – the official creation took place in October 1921. Conceived on the model of the German Girozentralen, the ICCRI was set up as a public corporation whose capital was entirely owned by savings banks. The mission of the ICCRI was fourfold: (i) to permit money transfers between savings banks; (ii) to work as a lender of last resort; (iii) to function as a clearing centre and (iv) to engage in lending activities.

77 In the first years after its creation, the ICCRI subscribed to government securities on the behalf of savings banks. The ICCRI was the first among banking categories’ central institutes (in the following years the Banche Popolari’s central institute was also founded), and remained the most important in financial terms.

The ICCRI’s first success was the introduction of checks (assegni bancari di categoria), which it supervised, and which successfully appealed to savings banks’ clientele throughout Italy. The peculiarity of such checks was that the ICCRI committed to fulfiling its clearing obligations even when those checks were issued by single savings banks (against a deposit). With savings banks’ extensive network throughout Italy, check holders, even clients of the smallest savings banks, held a means of payment universally recognised and accepted.

Beyond these two institutions, savings banks also created several Istituti di credito fondiario (land credit institutions), while savings banks in the Veneto region created in 1929 a consortium to integrate their lending activities in the agricultural sector (called “Istituto Federale delle Casse di Risparmio”, or Federalcasse). The latter got its inspiration from the 1927 decree and the local and regional Federations, which, however, probably because of their top-down, government-imposed origin, remained inactive for a long time.

Interestingly, the gradual constitution of an autonomous financial system around savings banks occurred simultaneously with the gradual erosion of the private identity of the sector, both through government intervention and through jurisprudence (Clarich, 1984). In several key decisions, from 1907 to 1930, the court of cassation, the highest judiciary authority for civil law, definitely confirmed savings banks’ public nature and submitted conflicts within the sector to the Council of State, the highest organ for administrative law. Besides, many elements in savings banks ‘regulation (their non-profit aims, the use of benefits for philanthropy, the public appointment of board members) concurred to define them as public entities. Throughout the years, therefore, and until the late 1980s, savings banks were considered as part of the broad category of public credit institutions (Istituti di Credito di Diritto Pubblico).

78 In both France and Italy, therefore, the creation of sector institutions and the strengthening of sector coordination were closely linked with state regulation and intervention; on the one hand, savings banks’ first national congresses and efforts at coordination coincided with the growing awareness of a community of interests and of the need to have those interests recognised and guaranteed at the state level. On the other hand, in both countries the state’s need for savings banks’ resources and support led to the cooptation of savings banks into some form of corporatist organisation (such as the Commission Supérieure of the late 1890s in France) that, subsequently, fostered sector coordination and cohesion. However, there were differences in the degrees of sector cohesion, individual savings banks’ production and management of network externalities, which were much stronger in Italy.

3.3 Savings banks in the post-war political economy of France and Italy

3.3.1 From the periphery to the centre of the credit system

During the decade following the 1930s regulatory reforms, savings banks development and growth was, like those of other banks, considerably affected by the preparation of war and by war itself. Expansion slowed down, and public securities started to rise again as a proportion of total assets. Immediately after the war, therefore, savings banks focused on lifting such constraints. The post-war years saw again, in many countries, the growth and expansion of savings banks – in terms of deposits: in Belgium, for instance, annual growth rate of savings fluctuated between 10% and 22% until the mid-1970s; savings deposits at Belgian savings banks increased six-fold from 1944 until 1959 and six-fold again from 1960 until 1974. In Germany, savings banks’ turnover increased from about 8 billion DEM in 1950 to 56 billion DEM in 1960 and 188 billion DEM in 1970.

During the post-war period savings banks’ business not only expanded: it also changed considerably. On the liabilities side, there was a decline in deposits, and especially savings accounts, in favour of savings certificates and bonds. On the assets side, there was a decrease in lending to the public sector (54% of all assets in Belgium in 1947) and a parallel increase in mortgage credit, while savings banks started diversifying their market and product strategies.

79 • France

Savings, and in particular the funds collected by savings banks, played a key role in financing the reconstruction of France. Savings banks were then part of the “Treasury circuit”, the financing circuit controlled by the French State, and helped transform financial maturities – a task which the weak capital market could not fulfil. The circuit worked as follows: savings banks collected savings (liquid funds), then transferred to [them] the CDC. The CDC converted those funds into medium and long-term financing (illiquid investments), granting loans directly to the local authorities and financing housing construction (through the Crédit Foncier de France, a state-owned mortgage credit institution) and making productive investments through the Crédit National (a state-owned credit bank).

Because of savings banks’ role within the Treasury circuit, both the Caisse des Dépots and the Treasury opposed any diversification of savings banks’ business, either through direct use of funds or the introduction of checking accounts. According to Moster and Vogler, “both used the argument of the social mandate, legal form and the diversity of the savings banks, their excessively loose organisation as an association and their lack of banking experience” (Moster and Vogler 1996: 82). The tax exemption on first savings accounts and the strict regulations preventing savings banks from entering the banking business were conceived by regulators as balancing measures which corresponded to savings banks’ dual nature. As François-Xavier Ortoli, Minister of Finance in 1968, put it, “the privileged position of savings banks is connected with both the particular origin of their funds and the customary use of funds.” (cited in Moster and Vogler 1996: 91).

But neither were savings banks convinced of the need for diversification or modernisation. In the post-war years French savings banks were “more concerned about the supply of funds than their use.” (Moster and Vogler 1996: 82) Therefore their main worries were the ceilings on deposits and the interest rate. The ceiling was raised regularly, almost every two years, from 1944 to 1958. By 1960, the maximum amounted to 10,000 new francs, and was raised again to 15,000 francs in 1964 – to the disappointment of the savings banks’ association, the Conférence Générale, which has asked for more.

80 In the two decades following the Second World War, most savings banks staff and managers could perhaps agree with that negative definition by René Laurent, head of the Bureau central: “it is an error to maintain that savings banks are banks. (…) In particular, savings banks do not, by themselves, invest the funds entrusted to them by the depositors. By contrast with banks, they engage in no transaction other than collecting deposits and paying interest on them. (…) [In addition], it is the characteristic of savings banks, as non-profit- making institutions, to carry out activities of a social nature. The social work characteristic is substantiated by the honourary activities of the board members, the use of the surplus for social purposes and the belonging to the broad family of prudential institutions.” (quoted in Moster and Vogler 1996: 91)

In the late 1940s, however, there was some debate at the Conférence Générale about the need to amend Article 1 of the July 1895 law, which disposed that all funds collected by the savings banks should be channelled to the Caisse des Dépots. Some savings banks actors pleaded for the introduction of a (limited) free use of funds, on the model of what had been done in Alsace-Lorraine’s savings banks, whose derogatory regulatory regime, inherited from their forty years stay within the German Empire, was further confirmed by a 1954 law.

In October 1947, therefore, the Conférence Générale submitted a petition that aimed to “grant the normal savings banks the possibility of direct investment of their deposits up to 30% in loans to the local authorities and up to 10% in mortgage loans”. This petition was carried over by Jean Minjoz, – then a socialist member of Parliament and chairman of the savings bank of Grenoble, - and gave birth to the so-called “Minjoz law” passed in June 1950. The Minjoz Law did not give savings banks the autonomy to manage part of their collected funds; rather, it authorised them to “propose” to the CDC loans to local authorities representing up to 50% of the annual increase in deposits. Loan applications were submitted and approved by a committee formed in each department and chaired by a representative of the CDC. The CDC then gave a fixed fee for savings banks for each successful loan application – substituting the interests savings banks might have earned had they had the right to make loans directly. The Minjoz was an immediate success, and led to a renewed effort by savings banks to increase deposits. The latter rose from FRF 47 billion in 1951 to FRF 219 billion in 1955.

81 Another timid step towards business diversification was the authorisation to open savings-for-home-ownership accounts, granted by an April 1953 law. Under such schemes, the special deposits opened at individual savings banks or at the Caisse Nationale d’Épargne were forwarded by the CDC and placed at the Crédit Foncier for granting loans. These schemes, however, did not meet with the same success as the Minjoz law loans: after five years, by the end of 1957, only 90 savings banks (out of 583) had opened just 944 savings-for-home-ownership accounts with FRF 328.9 million of deposits. A further innovation took place in 1955, with the same limited impact: in that year, the Commission bancaire, the banks’ regulatory body, authorised savings banks to invest part of their own funds (called “fortune personnelle”) in personal social loans – loans targeted to low-earning individuals. After three years of the new regime, only 20 savings banks had ventured into that new possibility.

• Italy

During the 1930s and 1940s, Italian savings banks were, like all commercial banks, first encouraged, then (during the war years) forced by the state to include large quantities of government debt securities in their investment portfolios. Thus, in 1930, securities accounted for 31% of total assets; by 1938, that figure had risen to 44.2%, and reached 57.6% in 1945. Meanwhile, prices soared, an inflation fed in part by the almost exclusive reliance of the Italian state on printing banknotes for financing the war effort. It is estimated that in the second half of 1947, consumer prices had risen to 40 times their 1938 level.

In this context, savings collapsed: in 1938, the total savings per depositors amounted to ITL 95 lire (in 1913 gold prices); by the end of 1947, that figure had fallen to ITL 17. Savings banks were the hardest hit by the war economy, since their depositors – lower-income groups – were the most affected by the crisis. In addition, savings banks had had to compete with the Post Office Savings Bank who was allowed by the Italian government in 1927 to increase the interests paid on the treasury certificates (“buoni fruttiferi”) it issued, thus attracting savings away from private savings banks. Moreover, the 1936 banking reform, which had installed the segmentation of the banking market, ended up steering commercial banks towards short- term borrowing (en lending), which led them to compete with savings deposits at savings banks.

82 For all these reasons savings banks’ market position declined: their market share fell from 32.2% of total deposits in 1938 to 20% in 1945. Savings banks’ concerns in the aftermath of the war were therefore to get back on their feet and address the needs of their traditional clientele – rather than trying to expand into new markets.

It is in this context that savings banks completed their transformation into full-fledged banks, operating strategically on both sides of the balance sheet – and not any longer focused solely on liabilities. During the 1950s, 1960s, 1970s savings banks increased their activities on the assets side at the local level. In particular, several studies have shown how savings banks emerged as the first lenders to small business in the areas that in the successive decades (the 1970s and 1980s) would become the industrial districts, the cornerstone of the “Third Italy” (Conti and Ferri, 1997). From the 1930s through the 1980s, indeed, savings banks held a 30%-more market share in the lending market in townships comprised in the industrial districts areas (Conti and Ferri 1997). Economic dynamism also translated into the territorial expansion of savings banks. Although, by the end of 1960, the number of savings banks remained steady at 79 (their 1940 level), the number of branches had risen fast: from 240 in 1940 to 506 in 1940 to 2,465 in 1960. It is important to note that those branches were concentrated in the Northern (1,336 branches) and central part of the country (796) while the Southern regions savings banks numbered only 178 branches47.

Such modernisation bore fruit. During the mid-1950s, surfing the wave of the economic boom, savings banks started inverting the negative trend that had affected them since the late 1930s. Indeed, between 1950 and 1960, the annual growth of the Italian GDP amounted on average to 5.9%, second only to West Germany among Western European economies. The economic boom led to higher savings and more deposits. In only five years, from 1955 to 1960, total deposits at savings banks rose from ITL 781 million (1913 prices) to ITL 8,346 million, and in the same period, deposits per capita rose from ITL 17 to ITL 163. This impressive growth was not, however, limited to savings banks – therefore, it did not radically improve savings banks’ market position. Savings banks’ market share of total deposits rose from 21.6% in 1955 to 24.4% in 1960.

47 But in those regions, as Hertner rightly points out, the two former issuing banks – namely the Banco di Napoli and the Banco di Sicilia – did carry out similar functions as savings banks in other regions; and the former could count on a sizeable branch network (Hertner 1996: 210).

83 Such expansion was facilitated by a series of favourable regulations adopted by successive governments in the late 1940s and 1950s. Since right after the war, the governor of the central bank, who received in 1947 the responsibility for the whole supervision of the banking sector, had advocated support for small and medium-sized banks and local credit institutions. From 1948 on, such banks (which included savings banks) were given preferential treatment for the authorisation of new branches – such authorisation, as we will see in the next chapter, was a key part of the “subjective” regulatory regime in place up until the early 1980s. Successive governments shared the central bank’s concern with small and local banks, and therefore with savings banks. In August 1947, when minimum reserve requirements were introduced as part of a policy package aimed at guaranteeing monetary stability, savings banks were explicitly exempted. In 1949, savings banks were authorised to issue interest-bearing treasury bonds, so that they had some long-term capital to fall back on. In November 1953, the Treasury Ministry issued a decree lowering the interest paid on Post Office treasury certificates that, as mentioned above, constituted an attractive competitor of savings banks’ savings deposits. Two months later, the government approved an increase in the interest yields on savings accounts.

3.3.2 Organisation of savings banks in the 1960s and 1970s

The post-war expansion of savings banks’ business, their central role in the reconstruction of France and Italy, and their important political role led to a strengthening of sector coordination and organisation, comparable to what simultaneously happened in other European countries (with, for instance, the creation of the Groupement Belge des Banques d’Epargne in Belgium in 1945, of the Danmarks Sparekasseforening in Denmark, founded in 1947).

• France

In France, the regional associations (the Conférences Régionales) became in post-war years more effective in voicing their claims. They started submitting petitions to the CDC and to the Ministry of Finance, expressing their concerns over issues such as interest rates, deposit ceilings, but also the Minjoz loans, banking competition…

84 Such a petition did represent effective layouts for future regulatory efforts by the government (such as the 1950 Minjoz law). Technical coordination also took place at the regional level, through the Groupements d’Études Techniques (technical working groups): such groups gathered managers and organised exchanges on a range of technical matters, including marketing and advertising, accounting, data processing and personnel. At the national level, the Conférence générale started organising national annual meetings where, from 1967 on, the Finance Minister was a regular participant.

The Bureau Central, under the leadership of René Laurent, also further developed savings banks’ sector coordination and identity. In 1949, it published all the regulations regarding savings banks, which became the savings banks code in 1952; it opened, in 1942 and then in 1945, an École de l’Épargne (savings school), which provided courses for savings banks’ executives and then for new employees; in 1957, a Centre de Recherche sur le budget familial (family budget research centre) was set up, its mission being to spread out savings ideas through, mainly, family associations and schools. The Bureau central even started publishing a children’s magazine, “Dominique” (187,000 copies in 1966), dedicated to encouraging the “spirit of savings” among the young.

Savings banks’ sector organisation underwent rapid changes in the late 1960s – early 1970s. First, following the Racine Commission’s works (see below), the Conférences régionales and the Conférence nationale became, respectively, the Unions Régionales and the Union nationale – with unchanged mandates. More important, however, was the creation of the GREP and the CTIR.

The GREP, or Groupements Régionaux d’Épargne Populaire (regional savings groups), were set up by decree in December 1969. They were owned jointly by local savings banks and by the CDC. Their role was to issue savings certificates, thus diversifying the collection of liquid savings, to fund the personal loans which savings banks started to give in 1971. The GREP were, in effect, savings banks’ “regional competitors”: despite being partly owned by them, they were, in practice, mostly controlled by the CDC (who staffed most of the GREP with its own personnel) and did compete with savings banks on the market for liquid savings. Moreover, through advertising and training within savings banks (especially on all aspects pertaining to lending), they did exert some kind of guardianship on them.

85 At the same time, however, savings banks gave themselves the means to coordinate more effectively and regulate better the financial flows between them, the GREP and the CDC. During the 1960s, local savings banks grouped together to create regional information technology centres (Centre techniques informatiques régionaux, or CTIR), conceived to facilitate data processing and the exchange of computerised information between banks. Interestingly, in contrast to the GREP, the CTIR were bottom-up creations, formed on the basis of existing computers and in connection with planned new investments in information technology. The first CTIR was created in Nantes in 1966; others followed quickly (Lyon 1967, Limoges and Toulouse 1968, Roubaix 1969…). By 1972 there were 15 CTIR recognised by the Union nationale, which numbered 406 member savings banks, representing 83% of deposits. Computerisation brought about the formation of savings banks’ inter-bank payment system, through a clearing centre created with the help of the CDC.

• Italy

Cooperation and association between savings banks increased considerably during the post-war era. ACRI, the Italian Savings Banks’ Association, played an especially important role in this regard. First, the national congresses organised every two or three years offered savings banks the opportunity to exchange views and, more importantly, to let themselves be known to the regulatory authorities, who were almost systematically represented at such congresses with their highest representatives (the governor of the central bank and the Minister of the Treasury). ACRI was also very active as an interest group, and succeeded in achieving preferential treatment for savings banks at several occasions – such as the 1972-73 tax reform, which exempted savings banks’ earned interests from taxation. The ACRI did not have a direct say in the central bank’s decisions; but collectively, savings banks were the major holders of shares of the central bank’s capital.

The ICCRI (savings banks’ financial institute), on the other hand, became during the 1970s a major lender to the public sector, mainly at the local level. The ICCRI received funds from savings banks, which they paid at a high interest rate. In the late 1970s, statutory changes authorised the ICCRI to lend to the private sector as well, and increased savings banks’ grip on the Institute.

86 In 1972, the ACRI and the ICCRI (savings banks’ clearing institution), together with the major savings banks, created the Institute for the Automation of Italian Savings Banks (Istituto per l’Automazione delle Casse di Risparmio Italiane, or IPACRI), which became the driving force behind the computerisation of savings banks.

3.3.3 Modernisation trends in the savings banks sector during the 1960s and 1970s

In the 1960s and 1970s, some savings banks continued their modernisation: in Germany, for instance, the savings banks’ labour union successfully pushed for reforms encouraging the further transformation of savings banks into modern, autonomous business units, with the clear separation of labour between the board of directors and the administrative board, and the right for savings banks to manage their own staff. In Germany still, the lift of restrictions on the opening of bank branches in 1958 and the subsequent liberalisation of interest rates (in 1967) led to increased competition within the banking sector, with savings banks successfully holding to, and even expanding their market shares. Again, however, savings banks’ post-war development differed between countries and regulatory regimes.

• France

In the late 1960s, a renewed effort of modernisation came through. These efforts were preceded by a few regulatory reforms aimed at spurring competition in the banking system: the authorisation granted to non-savings banks for opening savings accounts (1957) and the generalisation of saving-for-home-ownership schemes to all banks in 1965. These regulatory reforms ended up increasing the competitive pressure on savings banks, which still benefited, however, from tax exemption on interests applied to savings accounts. Furthermore, non-savings banks’ access to the market for liquid savings was not compensated for by the possibility of savings banks to open check accounts.

Faced with growing competition on their own market, savings banks started seriously considering the idea of an extension of their own business to include other areas. A first issue, of course, was that of the free (autonomous) use of funds – outside the Treasury circuit.

87 This issue was addressed in 1965: in the same year that banks gained access to saving-for-home-ownership schemes (SHOs), savings banks gained autonomy on the management of such schemes. In other words, starting that year, savings banks were authorised to grant loans under those schemes, pending agreement with the CDC ensuring the smooth functioning and financial stability of the system. In practice, as Moster and Vogler note, savings banks “entered the lending business under the supervision and mediation of the Caisse des Dépôts” (Moster and Vogler 1996: 87-88). Alongside the main SHOs loans, savings banks were authorised to grant additional loans financed from secondary savings accounts, and not exceeding a quarter of the annual growth in such deposits.

In early 1968, a “Commission on the modernisation and development of savings banks”, composed of representatives of the savings banks and of State institutions (Treasury and CDC) was set up, with the mission to propose reforms to modernise savings banks. The Racine Commission (named after its chairman, Jean Racine) submitted its report in May 1968, in which it proposed three main measures. The first and the third of such measures consisted in the abandoning of the tax exemption of the Livret A savings accounts against the extension of savings banks’ business to other areas. The second, alternative measure consisted in a temporary maintenance of Livret A’s favourable fiscal status and the gradual extension of savings banks’ business. The Racine Commission, importantly, also recommended reducing the number of savings banks, mainly through mergers and acquisitions. In 1967, out of the 568 existing savings banks, most were mono-branch institutions; only 118 banks had more than ten branches, and many were open only two or three days a week. Subsequent regulatory evolution (during the 1970s) showed a preference, from the part of the state and of savings banks, for the second solution suggested by the Racine commission: the gradual expansion of savings banks’ business.

French savings banks’ lending business picked up in 1971 with the first “personal loans”, outside savings-for-home-ownership schemes, which gave savings banks complete freedom in risk assessment and choice of borrowers. Personal loans were aimed at financing housing construction of the acquisition of consumer goods (“family loans”). They were financed from secondary savings accounts and from the accrual of resources from savings certificates issued by the Groupements Régionaux d’Épargne et de Prévoyance (see above).

88 • Italy

In the first half of the 1970s, Italian savings banks were still clearly distinct from the rest of the banking system in terms of their balance sheet structure: in 1973, 51.4% of all deposits at savings banks were in savings accounts, whereas in other banks the latter represented only 38.5% of all deposits. On the asset side, savings banks had a negligible international lending activity, with foreign currency operations and overseas credit representing 0.9% of total assets in 1973, against 21% in other credit institutions (on average). In parallel, savings banks placed a sizeable proportion of assets into public securities, which even increased during the 1960s to reach 38.1% in 1973. Finally, savings banks lent more, in relative terms, than other banks to households and to public institutions – even though, overall, almost two thirds of their lending was made to business during the same period.

However, by the mid-1970s, savings banks had undergone considerable changes. Starting in the late 1950s, Italian regulatory authorities gradually allowed the alignment of savings banks with other credit institutions, thus (slowly) reversing the preferential treatment given to the former at the end of the war. In 1956, the taxation of savings banks had been put in line with that of other credit institutions. Two years later, the minimum reserve requirements were extended to savings banks – but the minimum was set at a lower level than for other categories of banks. That last provision was repealed in 1975. In 1962, the Interministerial Committee for Credit and Savings (Comitato Interministeriale per il Credito e il Risparmio, or CICR) decided to allow branches of two different savings banks to set up in the same local market. In 1966, the CICR adopted a standard statute for savings banks (the “statuto tipo”), which aimed at harmonising savings banks’ business practice and governance. In particular, the statuto-tipo allowed savings banks to invest 40% of their resources in medium-term lending or assets. This loosening of the separation of maturities, which had applied since the mid-1930s, was then extended to other credit institutions, in 1972, albeit with less freedom – since the latter could invest medium-term only 8 to 10% of their resources. In 1973, when the central bank introduced ceilings on the volume of lending, it applied the measure to all categories of banks.

89 Furthermore, since the early 1960s Italian savings banks operated a fundamental change in the structure of their assets – while they consistently, until the late 1970s, relied on deposits for more than 70% of their assets, they gave increasing weight to sight deposits. In 1958-62, savings deposits at savings banks represented 75.5% of total deposits, against 24.5% for sight deposits – the highest proportion of savings deposits in any banking category; in 1977, by contrast, savings deposits and sight deposits represented, respectively, 44.9% and 45.1% of total deposits – while both cooperative banks and ordinary banks had a larger proportion of savings deposits as compared with sight deposits48!

By the late 1970s, Italian savings banks held an important position within the credit system. Collectively, their lending amounted to more than a fifth of total lending by banks (21.7% in 1978, right behind “ordinary” banks at 27.6% but before public and cooperative banks); and they had the highest number of clients on the asset side. They held sizeable shares of the deposit market – 27.7% of total deposits, against 25% for ordinary banks and 20% for public banks.49 Their strongest position was on the market for savings deposits. In addition, quite interestingly, several studies have shown how savings banks were the first banks of industrial districts (Conti and Ferri, 1997;)

Conclusion: Italian and French savings banks in the 1970s

The compared history of French and Italian savings banks from their origins until the 1970s raises three observations. First, by the late 1970s French and Italian savings banks had developed along two seemingly different paths. Italian savings banks were of a much lesser number and larger average dimension than their French counterparts; French savings banks were mostly savings collecting institutions, while Italian savings banks had developed into quasi-universal banks, despite and above market segmentation. Network externalities were, in France, mostly borne by the state (through the Caisse des Dépots); in Italy, they were managed by the savings banks themselves, through their sector organisation.

48 Source: Banca d’Italia, Bollettino, various years. 49 Data is from Banca d’Italia, Bollettino, various years.

90 Beyond those differences, however – this is the second observation, French and Italian savings banks still resembled each other. The first source of similarity is common to other savings banks throughout Europe, and it has to do with savings banks’ enduring peculiar identity. By the late 1970s, savings banks in France and Italy were still distinct as compared with other categories of banks. Such distinction built on five key features, which mirrored their origins: (i) savings banks’ non-profit nature and social responsibility (exerted through the redistribution of revenues to stakeholders); (ii) savings banks’ ad hoc legal nature (in both France and Italy they were considered as public, non-state entities); (iii) savings banks’ peculiar business profile (specialisation in savings product on the collect side; in mortgage and loans to local government on the lending side); (iv) savings banks’ territorial rooting (both in governance structures and in lending preferences); and (v) savings banks’ sector organisation – which made them exist as true sectors.

A second source of similarity between French and Italian savings banks sets them apart from other European savings banks: it is their insertion, since the post-war period, within a state-based credit allocation system. Such a regime was put in place during the 1930s and 1940s, and ended up maintaining savings banks, in both countries, under the authority of the state. The Next chapter will further analyse this aspect.

A final observation is that savings banks, even in France where they seem to have been “frozen” in their development by regulatory authorities, have displayed signs of transformation, both in their organisation and their operations, long before the top-down changes in regulatory regimes brought in the 1980s and 1990s. This aspect will be analysed in chapter 5.

91 92 4. THE UNRAVELLING OF ADMINISTERED CREDIT SYSTEMS AND ITS IMPACT ON BANKING

Introduction

France has a well-explored tradition of state interventionism in the economy (see Shonfield, 1965; Zysman, 1983; Hall, 1986; Schmidt, 1989). Such tradition has pervaded the financial system throughout the XXth century, leading scholars to conceptualise an ideal-typical state-administered credit system, represented by France, as opposed to bank-based and market-based systems, respectively epitomised by Germany, the United Kingdom and the United States (Zysman, 1983). State-administered credit systems are characterised by (i) the administrative setting of the volume and price (interest rates) of lending and (ii) the dominant role played by state or para-statal institutions in the allocation of credit.

Several other countries, alongside France, experienced state-administered credit: Korea, Spain, Japan, all resorted to state control over credit allocation to finance their economic development in the post-world war II years. Italy might be associated with this group of countries as well, although at first sight it appears, historically, as a bank-based system – with banks playing the prime role in financing firms. However, from the late 1930s until the late 1970s, the Italian state enforced strict control over the allocation of credit, making its financial system become strikingly similar to that of France and the other state-administered credit systems just mentioned.

During the 1970s, however, several factors severely altered the functioning of state-administered credit systems – both external and internal. At first, governments responded to such pressures to change by strengthening the state’s grip over credit allocation. The failure of such attempts, however, led to the gradual but rapid dismantling of state-administered credit system and the end of “credit activism in interventionist states” (Loriaux, 1991; Loriaux et. al., 1997). The French and Italian financial regulatory regimes were durably transformed, which led to the transformation of the financial system itself.

93 As mentioned in chapter 3, savings banks played an important role in such systems, both as stabilisers and as sources of funding for state- administered credit. This dual role mirrored the ambiguity of state policy towards savings banks, acting both as a regulator and an actor of the credit system. The dismantling of state-administered credit systems, therefore, had important consequences on savings banks themselves, through the direct changes brought to their institutional environment (much more market-oriented). Savings banks reacted with the revamp of their own regulatory regime (analysed in chapter 5). The present chapter will thus explore the origins and nature of state-administered credit in France and Italy; and its initial strengthening and then dismantling in the context of the 1970s crisis. It will then explore the implications, for savings banks, of the dismantling of state-administered credit in the late 1970s and early 1980s.

4.1 The origins and functioning of state-led credit allocation in France and Italy

4.1.1 The crisis of the 1930s and its consequences on the banking system

The 1929 stock-market crash and its aftermath led to a complete upheaval of credit and banking regulations in France and Italy.

• Italy

In Italy, a late comer in terms of industrial development when compared to France and Great-Britain, in the absence of an autonomous capital market or of institutional investors banks were directly involved in the capital accumulation process (see Gerschenkron 1962 for the linkages between late industrialisation and bank- or state-based credit allocation). In the last quarter of the XIXth century, large private banks therefore played a key role in supporting the nascent national industry, either through acquiring and selling shares in industrial firms, or through granting medium and long-term loans. Two banks played a particularly important role in financing industry – especially export- oriented industry: the Società Generale di Credito Mobiliare Italiano and the Banca Generale. These banks had been modelled after the Crédit Mobilier, a bank founded in France by the Pereire brothers which financed industry through the acquisition and sale of bonds.

94 In 1893-94, a serious economic and banking crisis led to the demise of the Credito Mobiliare and the Banca Generale, and their substitution by mixed banks, created on the German model by a pool of Italian and foreign bankers (mostly Austrian and German). Those mixed banks – the Banca Commerciale Italiana, later called Comit; the Credito Italiano, later called Credit; and the Banca di Roma - were conceived as an improvement of the credit mobilier type of banks: besides the acquisition and sale of bonds and stocks, they would draw on deposits to finance their operations.

Mixed banks became, over the years, highly exposed to industrial firms who, in turn, were highly leveraged and depended on rising profits to be able to pay their debts. The 1929 stock-market crash, the subsequent collapse of the gold standard in 1931 and the ensuing economic and financial crisis, which depleted business firms’ revenues and stocks’ value, therefore seriously affected the banking system and especially the mixed banks. Italy had already faced a smaller-scale banking crisis in 1921 with the bankruptcy of the Banca Italiana di Sconto, one of Italy’s foremost commercial (mixed) banks. In the following months, bank runs led the state to a first attempt at adjusting the regulatory framework to perceived new threats to the stability of the financial system. Those attempts culminated in the 1926 reform, mentioned in chapter 3. However, that reform left unchanged the root of systemic instability: the bank-industry nexus. The 1930-31 crisis, moreover, was of a much larger scale.

The impact of the unfolding international crisis was so stronger that since 1927, the Italian currency had been pegged to the British pound50, and was therefore exposed to the strong fluctuations in exchange rate that followed the end of the convertibility of the pound into gold. Italy went through a severe balance of payment crisis. Firms’ solvency shrunk. Comit and Credit saw the value of their industrial shareholdings fall as their principal “clients” ran into trouble – such large firms as Montecatini in the chemical sector, Edison in the energy sector, Fiat in the automobile industry, Pirelli, Ilva, Terni… The mixed banks system was threatened. Bank runs multiplied, leading to many bank failures – especially among the small rural and catholic banks (Ferri 1992).

50 Since the famous “quota 90” speech by Mussolini, where the dictator, apparently moved by impulse, decided to anchor the lira to the pound.

95 Total collapse of the banking sector was avoided in part because of direct state intervention. First, the state created an Istituto di Liquidazioni, which then became, in 1933, the Istituto per la Ricostruzione Industriale (Institute for Industrial Restructuring, or IRI), which took control, in 1933-34, of the three former mixed banks (Comit, Credit and Banco di Roma) and their industrial shareholdings. Secondly, as mentioned in the previous chapter, the state proceeded to radically change the regulatory framework governing credit institutions. Such efforts culminated in the Legal Decree of March 1936, converted into law in march 1938. As Clarich notes, the 1936 reform was the concrete application of the principles of “interventionism” then in vogue in fascist circles – but not only. It represented “one of the most coherent and complete examples of administrative planning based on segmentation” (Clarich 1984: 56).

• France

In France, the economic depression was less pronounced than in Italy, but it lasted longer. The relative low intensity of the depression can be attributed to the mildness of the banking crisis of 1931-33 in France, which was the consequence both of limited foreign financial commitments in 1931 and of the traditional caution of most major banks in their relationships with manufacturers. In fact, there were 670 bankruptcies in the banking sector from 1929 to 1937, but those were mostly local banks. Only one major bank (the Banque Nationale de Crédit) failed, and a rescue operation organised by the Treasury, the Bank of France and the other banks succeeded in avoiding a panic. The banking crisis took a dramatic turn only with the outburst of several financial scandals involving politicians (the Ostrik and Stavisky scandals of 1932 and 1933). Therefore banking regulation was not changed until regime change in 1940-41.

At the centre of the policy interpretations of the crisis of the 1930s in both countries lie the close links between banks and industry. Indeed, the bank runs of 1930-31 led to a credit squeeze to heavily indebted firms who could not, therefore, repay their loans to banks; at the same time, the stock-market crash meant that banks’ industrial shareholdings lost their value, and banks were unable to face depositors’ demands. The first policy response to the crisis was therefore the severance of those bank-industry links, so as to shield savers from risks inherent in industry.

96 4.1.2 The new regulatory regime of the late 1930s: market segmentation, tighter regulation and state intervention

• Market segmentation

The 1936 and the 1941 reforms in France and Italy, respectively, were founded on three pillars: market segmentation, tighter regulation and state intervention in the credit system. Market segmentation primarily took the form of functional specialisation, which consisted in the separation between short-term, medium and long-term liabilities. The basic assumption behind functional specialisation was that the maturities of assets should correspond to the maturities of liabilities, so as to ensure the liquidity of banks’ balance sheets and, ultimately, prevent bank runs and protect savings. Regulatory authorities held that short-term lending should be exclusively dedicated to help firms face cyclical downturns (cash-flow problems); while long-term lending should finance productive investment. In both countries, therefore, banks were to specialise in specific segments of the banking business. The primary goal of functional specialisation was to shield deposits from the risks associated with corporate lending.

In France, a series of reforms passed in 194151 defined banking operations according to their maturity, and distinguished among banks that were allowed to conduct them all or in part: deposit banks, merchant banks and financial institutions. In Italy, the 1936 law similarly distinguished between those banks that collected short-term savings (called in the law “aziende di credito”, or credit firms) and those that collected medium and long-term savings (the so-called “istituti di credito speciale”, or special credit institutions).52 The law also provided that the possibility to offer medium and long-term credit53 depended on the authorisation of the central bank. The former mixed banks were excluded from that possibility and barred from holding stocks or shares in industrial firms, while the special credit institutes received a legal monopoly on long-term lending. In effect, most of the lending offered by credit firms was to take the form of cash-flow financing.

51 Laws of June 13 and 14, 1941. 52 This distinction is made explicit in articles 5 and 6, and parts V and VI of the 1936 law. 53 Short-term assets and liabilities bore maturities up to a year; Medium-term assets and liabilities bore maturities comprised between one and five years; and long-term assets and liabilities bore maturities longer than five years.

97 In addition to functional specialisation, the Italian and French banking regulatory regimes of the late 1930s were characterised by the multiplicity of statuses, laws and bylaws that divided the banking system in several segments, or sub-sectors. This fragmentation of the banking sector in both countries was increased in the post-war period with the creation of a series of new (public) financial institutions. Thus by the early 1950s the Italian banking sector was composed of five broad segments. The first segment consisted of “ordinary” deposit banks (“banche ordinarie di credito”) that operated on the short and medium term. These banks were constituted as joint-stock companies and operated mainly on local banking markets (at the exception of the largest ones, such as the Banco Ambrosiano, Banca nazionale dell’Agricoltura…); supervision of those banks was the responsibility of the Banca d’Italia.

A second segment included local and regional cooperative banks – the Banche popolari and the Casse rurali ed artigiane. These banks were prevalently local and addressed the needs of specific clienteles – craftsmen, workers and small industry and commerce for the former, small firms for the latter. Smaller cooperative banks have long benefited from a benevolent attitude from the part of regulatory authorities, both regarding their regulatory obligations (less stringent than for other banking categories) and the regime governing their creation and territorial expansion.

A third segment included “public” banks, which consisted in fact of three distinct bank categories: savings banks, state-owned national interest banks and public law banks. These three categories shared the characteristic to be legally considered as public entities and to be directly controlled by the government, which appointed executive directors in savings banks, the whole board in the case of the other two categories. “National interest banks” (“banche di interesse nazionale”, or BIN) were the three former mixed banks that had been acquired by the state through IRI (Comit, Credit, Banca di Roma)54. Public law banks (“Istituti di credito di diritto pubblico”, or ICDPs) were large banks deemed to fulfil public interest missions. They were: Banco di Napoli, Banco di Sicilia, Banco di Sardegna, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro, Monte Paschi di Siena, Istituto San Paolo di Torino.

54 The BIN category was created ad hoc in the 1936 law.

98 A fourth category included the so-called special credit institutions (“Istituti di credito speciale”, or ICSs). Those institutions were the only ones authorised to offer long-term financing. ICSs could take two forms. First, they could be created within existing banks as autonomous “sections” (sezioni), that is, business units – for instance, the BNL had sections specialised in lending to the small and medium industrial firms55, the movie industry and tourism. Other important sections were those of the Banco di Napoli and of the Banco di Sicilia. ICSs could also take the form of specialised financial firms. Those were, mainly, the IMI (Istituto Mobiliare Italiano), Mediobanca, Efibanca, Interbanca, Centrobanca and the IRI which, beyond owning the three BIN, managed their former shareholdings in industrial firms and bond- financed the big industry.

The fifth and final segment consisted of financial institutions created by the state apart from the banking system to serve the needs of specific territories or industries56: the Cassa per il Mezzogiorno (Cassa per le opere straordinarie di pubblico interesse per il finanziamento dello sviluppo del Mezzogiorno, or Casmez), created in 1950 to manage the funds given by the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development to foster economic development in the Southern regions; the Mediocredito centrale, created in 1952 to finance small and medium industrial firms, along with regional institutes; and the web of regional and interregional institutes created by local and regional banks and firms, supported by the state and financed in part by the Mediocredito centrale and the Cassa per il Mezzogiorno. In the southern regions, for instance, those were the IRFIS (Istituto regionale per il finanziamento alle medie e piccolo industrie della Sicilia, created in 1950), the CIS (Credito Industriale Sardo, created in 1953), and the ISVEIMER (Istituto per lo sviluppo economico dell’Italia meridionale, created in 1938).

55 The only such section in Italy to be a distinct legal entity from the founding bank. 56 The state-promoted creation of those institutions corresponded with the strong reluctance of monetary authorities to have industrial investment financed by the banking sector.

99 The French banking system, in the post-war years, was similarly segmented in four parts. The first segment included commercial banks (deposit banks, medium and long-term credit banks, merchant banks) and private financial institutions (stock-trading houses, credit institutions…), who received an authorisation from the national credit council (Conseil national du crédit, or CNC)57; were controlled by the central bank; and monitored by the banks’ control committee (Commission de contrôle des banques, or CCB).

The second segment of the French banking system consisted of banks with specific legal statutes – mainly, networks of cooperative banks, such as the Crédit populaire, the Crédit agricole mutuel, the Crédit mutuel agricole et rural, the Crédit cooperatif, the Crédit mutuel, the Banque Française du Commerce Extérieur. These banks, which often had their own central financial institutions, were also endowed by the state with public interest missions, and could distribute state- subsidised credit to their members. For this reason such banks were not monitored by the central bank or by the CCB, but by various Ministries, among them the Ministry of Finance, which delegated their control to the Department of the Treasury.

The third segment of the banking system was composed of financial institutions belonging to the public sector and, under the control of the Treasury, were in charge of financing specific business sectors. The Crédit national financed lending to industry; the Crédit foncier and the Comptoir des entrepreneurs offered real estate and mortgage lending; the Crédit Hôtelier lent to the tourism industry, etc. These institutions were often private firms but because of their public service missions, were controlled by the state who appointed their executive directors.

Finally, the fourth segment of the post-war French banking system included public institutions – mainly the Caisse des dépôts et consignations (CDC) and its subsidiaries – that managed public lending portfolios. The CDC was monitored by a parliamentary committee and attached to the Treasury. Among its subsidiaries were the Caisse d’aide aux collectivités locales, the Caisse de prêts aux organismes d’habitations à loyer modéré…

57 Those banks were registered with the CNC and hence were also called “registered banks”.

100 The network of the savings banks, as well as the Postal savings banks (the Caisse Nationale d’Epargne) were directly under the CDC’s authority. Finally, the Post and Telecommunications administration managed the postal checking accounts, under the supervision of the Treasury; and the Treasury and the central bank itself managed deposits and were therefore part of the public segment of the banking system.

As seen above, banking market segmentation in both countries was the fruit both of historical evolution (with the creation of specialised institutions along the years) and of the regulatory regime of the 1930s and its sequels – functional specialisation and the multiplicity of legal statuses and categories. Such a structure survived until the 1980s in France and 1990s in Italy.

• Tighter banking regulation

The second pillar of the 1930s reforms was tighter regulation. The regulatory powers of existing regulatory agencies were increased; and new regulatory agencies were created. In Italy, the 1936 law reorganised the regulatory apparatus around three institutions: the Committee of Ministers (and the Ministry of Industry), the Ispettorato per la Difesa del Credito e del Risparmio (Ispectorate for the defence of credit and savings), and the central bank. The law then gave extensive and discretionary powers to those three institutions, which reduced to a large extent the autonomy enjoyed until then by banks and credit institutions. Banks’ information obligations were especially increased, starting with the obligation to deliver accounting documents twice a year to the central bank. The Ispectorate was given the power to perform inspections and inquiries; that power was transferred to the central bank after the war, when the whole Ispectorate was re-located within the Banca d’Italia.

In France, the 1941 reforms instituted a banking license and submitted banks to the monitoring powers of the Ministry of the Treasury. These reforms were confirmed after the war, together with the nationalisation of the central bank, the Banque de France, and of the nation’s first four deposit banks. A 1945 law confirmed the segmented structure of the banking system and delineated the principles of banking regulation. Inspection powers were similarly assigned to the central bank, and banks were submitted to information obligations.

101 • The interventionist role of the state in credit allocation

The third pillar of the 1930s banking regulatory regime was, beyond market segmentation and tighter banking regulation, the direct intervention of the state within the allocation of credit. As seen above, by the late 1930s a consistent part of the credit system was owned or controlled (either indirectly or directly) by the state. Before the war, state intervention took two forms: ownership of banks or financial institutions on the one hand; and control of ad hoc credit instruments on the other hand, directly linked to the government or to public agencies.

State intervention was not simply the outcome of authoritarian regimes (fascism in Italy from 1922 on; in France, petainism since 1940). First of all, many democracies (such as Great Britain or the United States) simultaneously adopted similar policies or regulatory regimes – including a stronger state intervention in the economy. Secondly, even in Italy “fascist” creations were the continuation of the experience launched before and during the First World War by a group of key political players from various origins and ideological affiliations – such as Francesco Saverio Nitti and Alberto Beneduce. These actors shared the conviction that, to foster Italy’s industrialisation and modernisation, one needed the work of a “visible hand” transforming savings into productive investments; that such work request state intervention, given savers’ low trust into medium and long term financial endeavours; and that, finally (and crucially), this intervention should have taken place outside of the administration’s traditional realm, namely through ad hoc entities, in which Barca sees institutional investors ante litteram (for a short review of the Nittian bases of Italy’s postwar economic structure see Barca 1997). In sum, once functional specialisation was in place Italy renounced to resort to banks for the financing of industry.

These ideas, and the men behind them, therefore led to the creation of public institutions specifically designed for collecting savings to finance medium and long-term investments: the INA (Istituto nazionale delle assicurazioni, or national insurance institute) in 1912, the Consorzio per Sovvenzioni su Valori Industriali in 1914, the Consorzio di credito per le spese pubbliche in 1919, the Istituto di Credito per le Opere di Pubblica Utilità in 1924 and the Istituto di credito navale in 1928.

102 With the crisis of the 1930s, and the collapse of the mixed bank model, the fascist government accelerated the trend, as seen above, through the creation, first, of the Istituto mobiliare italiano, or the IMI in 1931; and, second, of the IRI in 1933 – which then took control of the three national mixed banks. The IRI at first was conceived as a kind of temporary bad assets management company, dedicated to the ridding of those bad assets. Already in 193658, however, the IRI became the owner of the entire capital of the three BINs and the owner of their industrial shareholdings – which represented, by the late 1930s, 21% of the capital of all joint-stock companies existing in Italy. And in 1937 the IRI lost its temporary nature.

In addition the Italian government created or helped create a number of special funds or financial institutions to help ailing industries. These institutions were either owned or controlled by the state, who also appointed board members in legally distinct entities such as the Casse di risparmio (since 1936). Regulatory authorities in both countries were, in addition, the places where the interventionist state would direct credit allocation through specific regulations, specific incentives, tax and legal loopholes. Such state intervention would be strengthened by post-war “developmentalist” concerns.

4.1.3 State-led credit allocation in post-war France and Italy

The banking regulatory architecture put in place in the late 1930s in France and in Italy was substantially left unchanged in the post-war years, even as both countries changed the form of their government. Rather, policy- makers in the 1940s and 1950s reinforced the interventionist role in the credit system assigned to the state during the 1930s. In both countries, indeed, reconstruction needs and political change helped put in place a “developmentalist industrial policy” (Loriaux 1991) that relied on state- led credit allocation and an accommodating monetary policy.

58 With a decree of May 25, 1936 (n.1042).

103 • France

Post-war industrial policy was characterised in France by subsidies, credit controls, indicative planning and intervention in state-owned industries. In 1945-46, successive governments nationalised several large firms in key industries – among them the four largest deposit banks: Crédit Lyonnais, Société Générale, Banque Nationale pour le Commerce et l’Industrie, Comptoir d’Escompte de Paris. Industrial firms that were nationalised included the car-maker Renault, the chemist and pharmaceutical firm Rhone-Poulenc and utilities such as the Compagnie Générale d’Electricité. Eventually, the state used its ownership of those companies to direct (and fund) strategic investment and production choices. To a large extent, the Fordist accumulation regime – characterised by mass production of standardised goods - that emerged out of the 1950s was a state- sponsored one.

Indicative planning was the second key instrument of industrial policy, starting with the Monnet Plan of the late 1940s and successive five-year plans. Planning gave public priorities for investment research and development, and set prices and interest rates. During the 1960s, France’s industrial policy was still characterised by ambitious cross- sector programmes, epitomised by the Fifth Plan (1965-1970), the Convention État-sidérurgie in 1966 and the Plan Calcul in 1967. When, during the late 1960s – 1970s, planning lost its importance, state-owned firms became instrumental in directing investment and production, mostly through ownership and financing of private industrial firms. Public firms set up joint-ventures with private ones: so did EDF-GDF with Thompson; Paribas with Elf-Aquitaine…

The last years of the De Gaulle presidency were marked by the state’s will to help create national champions, namely large firms capable of competing on the world markets. So the government participated in the constitution of large industrial groups through mergers and acquisitions: Saint-Gobain-Pont-à-Mousson, Rhône-Poulenc, Péchiney- Ugine-Kuhlman, Thomson-CSF… State-owned banks were associated with such restructuring process, which concerned the banking sector too – as with the merger in 1966 between the Banque Nationale pour le Commerce et l’Industrie and the Comptoir d’Escompte de Paris, resulting in the creation of the Banque Nationale de Paris.

104 During the 1970s, industrial policy shifted from supporting national champions to supporting specific sectors or niches – telecommunications, aircraft, electrical generators, and arms. In addition, the state multiplied rescue operations towards ailing industries and firms, or “lame ducks”. So the state created the Institut de Développement Industriel (Institute for Industrial Development, or IDI), originally designed to take over companies in difficulty and then return them to the private sector profitable enterprises. In 1975, public support to private industry reached 126 billion francs, or 9% of France’s GDP. Of this amount 4.1 billion francs in subsidies and 334 million francs in loans were for targeted sectors, 149 million francs in subsidies and 8.6 billion francs in loans went to restructuring (Bellon, 1980).

State-directed credit allocation, together with national industrial planning and nationalised industries, constituted the cornerstone of the post-war dirigisme rule. Subsidies were first and above all provided through the Fund for Modernisation and Equipment (Fonds de Modernisation et d’Equipement, or FME), which became in the late 1960s the Fund for Economic and Social Development (Fonds de Développement Economique et Social, or FDES), financed directly from the budget. The FME was originally created to manage the funds received under the Marshall Plan, and was directed at financing investment by large industrial firms. In 1949, the French state financed 41% of industrial investment (against 20% for self-financing, 26% for short-term bank loans, 6% for medium-term bank loans, 7% for bonds) (Hautcoeur, 2003). Such policy represented a rupture from the pre-war pattern of state economic intervention since, as Schmidt put it, “during the Third Republic, the state was more focused on maintaining the balance among social groups and protecting established interests than on promoting economic growth” (Schmidt 1996).

However, this centralised system gave way to large fiscal deficits and rising inflation. Hence the decision, in the early 1950s, to increasingly rely on state and para-statal institutions, such as the Caisse des Dépôts et consignations, within the Treasury circuit already evoked in chapter 3. The “Treasury circuit” had been put in place since the XIXth century, but it really acquired its centrality in French developmentalism only in the post-war era. The circuit had been built on the premise that the state was better able (than financial markets and private banks) to (i) mobilise savings to finance long-term investment and (ii) offer cheap money to investors.

105 The Treasury circuit built on three layers (Zerah, 1993). The first layer consisted of a series of state and para-state financial institutions offering low interest-bearing loans to specific sectors. Those institutions included the Caisse des Dépots et Consignations (CDC), who financed local governments; the Crédit National, specialised in industrial loans; and the Crédit Foncier, which issued mortgage loans. All those state and para-state institutions were required by law to deposit part of their resources at the Treasury. The second layer of the Treasury circuit was composed of the Post Office and the savings banks, which were mainly collect institutions geared to collect savings from households. The Post Office was required to deposit the collected funds at special accounts at the Treasury; while the savings banks, as seen in Chapter 3, had to deposit the resources drawn from the Livret A accounts at the CDC. The third layer of the circuit was made up of public and private banks, which had to hold a part of their mandatory reserves in Treasury bonds. In addition, banks could offer loans guaranteed by the state at certain conditions.

At the centre of the circuit stood the Treasury, which could “draw on multiple accounts to finance public spending without issuing bonds or relying on deficit spending, transforming short-term deposits into long-term loans and subsidies.” (Loriaux, 1991) Loriaux further notes that, since the money borrowed by the Treasury from those institutions to pay off the state’s creditors ultimately found its way back to the banks, the post office or one of the financial institutions that composed the Treasury circuit, “the Treasury had the unusual capacity to feed its “reserves” with money of its own creation” (Loriaux 1991: 65-72). Therefore, the Treasury circuit offered policy-makers a tool that they could use to redistribute money while avoiding the dangers of inflationary financing as well as the political liabilities of increasing state income through higher taxes (Patat and Lutfalla 1986: 140-41)

In the mid-1960s, De Gaulle government’s fiscal conservatism put heavy constraints on the Treasury circuit, leading to the 1966-67 banking reforms59. The reforms led to a disengagement of the Treasury from industrial policy while keeping the interventionist logic of the Treasury circuit.

59 The so-called “Debré decrees” of January 25, 1966; December 23, 1966 and September 1st, 1967.

106 In effect, the reforms shifted the responsibility of financial transformation (of short-term capital into long-term loans) from the Treasury to banks themselves – among whom, to a limited extent, savings banks (Patat and Lutfalla 1986: 140-41). The reforms encouraged banks to lend at medium-term to certain sectors by extending the eligibility of such loans to rediscounting at the central bank. Simultaneously, however, the state discouraged the banks from making other types of loans by placing quantitative restrictions on the overall growth of credit – mechanisms known as “l’encadrement du credit”. The State could therefore direct lending to a sector by lifting credit restrictions on it. In addition, the state could make medium-term loans to such sectors eligible for discount at the central bank, thus reinforcing the attractiveness of such sectors.

The banking reforms led to a gradual loosening of banking segmentation. Deposit banks were authorised to receive deposits with a maturity superior to two years, and merchant banks were allowed to receive deposits. The Debré decrees similarly loosened the conditions imposed on deposit banks’ shareholding in business firms. Simultaneously, the regime of authorisation for the creation of bank branches was loosened as well; the number of bank branches doubled between 1967 and 1975.

• Italy

In Italy, too, the immediate post-war era was dominated with “developmentalist” concerns that drove much of fiscal, monetary and industrial policy until the late 1980s. However, in contrast to France, those concerns were continuously balanced with concerns for the external and internal stability of the currency. Such views have been associated with key figures in Italian post-war policy-making: Luigi Einaudi (governor of the Central Bank, then Minister of the Treasury in 1948), Donato Menichella (his successor at the head of the Bank of Italy), Guido Carli (Menichella’s successor), the liberal party... As in France, industrial policy in Italy relied on public subsidies, state- ownership, credit controls and indicative planning (“programmazione economica”). The latter took rise in the fifties with the “Schema Vanoni” of 1954 and the 1952 law, both of which gave economic policy the twin goal of modernising the economy and reaching full employment. However, planning never achieved a prominent role in economic policy-making – and its practical achievements are rare (Graziani, 2000).

107 In Italy, state-led industrial development primarily relied on state- owned enterprises. The Italian state owned, in large part through the public holding IRI60, controlling stakes in many large firms in key sectors – such as Finsider in steel, Agip in oil and gas, Autostrade in highways, SME in the agro-business… Another large public holding, the Ente nazionale idrocarburi, or ENI, was created in 1953 to ensure Italy’s full control over oil and gas production and compete with the “seven sisters”, the seven major oil multinationals61. As seen in previous sections, upon its creation the IRI was conceived as an extraordinary, temporary instrument to rescue Italy’s ailing industries; before the war, however, the IRI was made permanent. In the immediate post-war, moreover, the IRI evolved into a large public holding with the mission to promote Italy’s industrialisation.

Interestingly, therefore, in contrast to France, state-led industrial development in Italy did not occur through nationalisations62, but through the transformation (the institutionalisation) of rescue instruments and temporary bailouts into stable instruments of state control over the industry, and state financing of industry (Barca, 1997; Barca and Trento, 1997). State-ownership was indeed conceived so as to allow the allocation of cheap credit to public and private industry, while giving managers of public firms a large margin for the manoeuvring they might not have had with private owners (Barca and Trento, 1997). Indeed, the IRI and ENI were public but autonomous bodies (“enti pubblici”). In addition, as Barca and Trento argue, the IRI’s central offices functioned more as a financial heart than as a control centre. This peculiar configuration embodied the double refusal that marked Italian post-war politics: the refusal of a pervasive and direct control of the state on economic matters (a refusal certainly fed by the rejection of the fascists’ authoritarian regime of the previous decades) and the refusal to let national industry (and credit) fall into the hands of the markets. On the one hand, market mechanisms were rejected because of (a) the absence of financial markets, (b) the historical reluctance of savers to finance industrial investments and (c) for fear of conflicts of interests and of exposure to conjonctural crises.

60 IRI was controlled by an ad hoc administrative board where the main economic ministries were represented: the Ministry of Industry and the Ministry of the Treasury. 61 The ENI was created by law in February 1953 (law n.136 of February 10th, 1953). 62 Apart from the nationalisation of electricity in 1963 with the creation of the Ente nazionale Energia Elettrica (ENEL), a public holding.

108 On the other hand, the public administration was rejected for its perceived rigidity and inability to manage credit allocation – and since in Italy, more than in France, “liberal” economists and politicians, such as Luigi Einaudi or Donato Menichella, disposed of a strong policy influence. That choice formed what Barca coins as an “extraordinary compromise” (compromesso straordinario), which “avoiding both statalism and hyper-liberalism, paved the way for the mobilisation of savings and financial resources, entrusted to hands capable of completing the industrialisation of the country” (Barca 1997: 12).

The path chosen was a half ground, although arguably closer to state-led development patterns than market models. All political forces agreed about the leading role the state should play in favouring and supporting development and about the need to avoid having the state bureaucracy manage those large firms that had ended up within the public realm. This solution (relying on public but autonomous entities financed by public or semi-public credit institutions) was all the easier as the managers already in place were known to be capable and dedicated to the modernisation of the country - such as Enrico Mattei, the charismatic founder of ENI and its first president; Donato Menichella (at IRI until 1946, successively at the Bank of Italy); Oscar Sinigaglia (Finsider); Gian Lupo Osti (Terni)… These characters often played a key role in establishing the post-war compromise. Such “agreement”, although never, of course, formalised, it took place within the Christian-Democracy, which became the locus of the compromise (see Barca, 1997).

The credit system was designed to support Italy’s industrialisation without putting savings at risk and, therefore, was within the boundaries of the 1936 banking law. The first layer of the post-war state-led credit allocation system was the IRI and ENI, through which the state channelled funds to the firms they owned and controlled (public firms) and the private firms with whom they had established strong links. For instance, Comit, Credit and Banco di Roma held non controlling but important stakes in Falck, Fiat, Montedison, Olivetti, SNIA, Bastogi…(see Ferri and Trento, 1997). In addition, Mediobanca, the private merchant bank created by the three BINs (and hence a creature of public entities) played a major role in supporting the emission of bonds by large private firms in the 1960s, 1970s and 1970s. As Barca notes, it is the staff of the IRI that, in the late-1940s, drafted Italy’s official proposals to use US imports and Marshall funds.

109 In 1948-1949, the latter were prevalently used to acquire productive machinery, through the intermediation of IMI and with the largest industrial firms, such as Fiat, as main beneficiaries. Within a few years, credit allocation and investment financing in strategic sectors such as steel, oil, telecommunications, and highways, all fell within the sway of those large public institutions – most of whom were the IRI and the ENI.

Beyond the IRI and ENI’s roles, state-led credit allocation took successive forms, and two periods can be distinguished in the establishment of the post-war credit system. At first, until 1948, national unity governments63 insisted on the direct participation of both banks and the state in the reconstruction process. On the state side, this policy emphasised the role of subsidies. Various instruments were created that were directly financed by the Treasury. A 1946 law64 made available 13 billion lire to finance long-term investment needs in large industrial firms. In 1947, a Fund for the financing of the mechanic industry (Fondo per il finanziamento dell’industria meccanica, or FIM) was created within the IMI (but liquidated three years later).

The second consequence of the credit policy implemented in the immediate aftermath of the war was that, in order for banks to be directly involved in reconstruction, the rule of functional specialisation put in place by the 1936 law had to be loosened. Banks should be allowed to finance industrial investments. Interestingly, however, that policy decision did not lead to the abandonment of the 1936 law; the political support for the banking regulatory regime inherited from the fascist era was too strong to be overruled. Therefore the breach of the 1936 law took the form of the autonomous “sections” founded by individual banks (see previous section) and authorised by law. Those sections were to lend on a long-term basis to industrial firms, while being organically separate from the banks’ other businesses. They benefited from a large state guarantee on the funds lent – around 70% on average; and the state paid part of the interests charged on the loans. The state guarantees and interest contributions drew on the Marshall Funds managed by the Treasury.

63 Governments with the participation of most political parties, including the Communist Party. 64 D.lgs 449 of May 8, 1946.

110 The first of these was the section for the funding of small and medium industrial firms, created at the BNL in December 194765, which was endowed with 2 billion lire paid by the Treasury; following the sections created that same year within the Banco di Napoli (endowed with 1 billion lire), the Banco di Sicilia (endowed with 2 billion lire) and the Banco di Sardegna.

After 1948, however, and with the advent of a centre-right government (still headed by De Gasperi) and the appointment of Luigi Einaudi first, then Donato Menichella, as governors of the Banca d’Italia, the state-led efforts to revamp the credit system changed direction. The government’s monetary and credit policies were now explicitly geared towards protecting savings and the financial rents of the middle classes on the one hand, and maintaining the external stability on the other. One pillar of the compromise was, indeed, the aim to solidly anchor middle classes within the economic and political system, drawing on the fascist experience (where disenfranchised middle classes, ruined by the successive financial and economic classes massively joined the ranks of the fascist party). Moreover, the stability of the currency represented a way to maintain the country’s credibility and rigour in the context of export-led growth and development.

The aim was to keep banks and industry separate (and thus return to the spirit of the 1936 law), while allowing for an effective transfer of resources to industry, small and large firms alike. At the same time, there was a consensus both on the leading role the state should play in the new organisation of the credit system and on the need to keep credit allocation outside public administration. The solution that was adopted then consisted in the creation of new financial institutions, and the strengthening of existing ones that would serve as buffers between deposit banks and industrial borrowers, and finance their lending through bonds, state guarantees and subsidies, while benefiting from special discounts at the central bank. Those institutions operated at two levels: regional and national.

65 D.lgs 1419 of December 1947

111 At the regional level, one found the 11 regional credit institutes (“Mediocrediti regionali”) and their central refinancing institution, Mediocredito centrale, created in 1950 and 1952 – all operating in the centre and northern regions; and the southern regional institutes, namely IRFIS in Sicily, CIS in Sardegna; and ISVEIMER for the whole south. The latter were autonomous from Mediocredito centrale: they received public (state) funds and funds from the Cassa per il Mezzogiorno, which was created in 1950 (Peluffo 1997).

At the national level stood the “special credit institutions” that had been created outside the banking system in the 1930s and 1940s. First among them was the IMI, created, as we have seen above, in 1931. The IMI played an important role in managing specific funds for industrial investment, such as the FIM. In addition, in 1950 the government authorised the use of 10 billion lire from the European recovery program (Marshall Plan) to finance productive investments by small firms. This sum was managed by the IMI and another special credit institution, Arar-Spei66. Besides the IMI, other special credit institutions were created after the war, by banks or groups of banks but with the support of the state: Mediobanca was founded in 1950 by the three national interest banks, together with the public insurance companies INA, Generali and RAS, and Bastogi and the Banca d’America e d’Italia. Efi, which then became Efibanca, was created by the BNL and played an important role in financing export lending. Centrobanca was founded by the Banche popolari and Interbanca by ordinary banks.

As in France in the 1960s, the rise of developmental concerns in Italy was accompanied by a gradual loosening of functional specialisation. Credit segmentation had already been circumvented by banks’ practice in the 1960s (Monti 1983). Moreover regulatory authorities themselves recognised the “mixed” nature of large deposit banks. As early as 1944, a ministerial decree67 authorised public credit institutions to finance long-term loans to industry. That same year, savings banks were authorised by regulatory authorities to lend long- term, provided that they operated within statutory boundaries. Savings banks were also authorised to offer medium-term liabilities, which, after all, constituted their true raison d’être.

66 Law 258 of April 18, 1950. 67 Decree n.367, Nov. 1st, 1944.

112 In 1972, the Ministry of the Treasury authorised ordinary banks and Banche Popolari to offer long-term lending for up to 8-10% of their assets68; in 1975 the ceiling was raised to 15%69. In 1977, the introduction of fidi bancari (bank guarantees) extended the range of long-term operations by banks.

4.2 The crisis of the 1970s and the unraveling of state administered credit systems

4.2.1 The underlying weaknesses of state-led credit allocation systems: moral hazard in the overdraft economy

The first weakness of the French and Italian state-administered credit systems, which appeared in the early 1970s, lies in the moral hazard created by the “overdraft economy”. Indeed, French and Italian state-led development policies had given rise to what French economists called an ‘économie d’endettement’ or overdraft economy, according to which hikes in interest rates had little or no impact on business demand for credit (see Loriaux, 1991, for an exhaustive analysis on France). Businesses, operating under the policy-induced expectation of assured borrowing power (or other financial support), responded to increases in the cost of credit simply by asking for more credit (higher interest rates produced cash-flow problems that firms addressed by borrowing more). This created a moral hazard. The expectation of assured borrowing power impeded the government’s efforts to use interest rate policy to slow monetary supply growth and thus regulate the supply of money to currency markets.

In that sense, therefore, as Loriaux noted, and quite paradoxically “the politics of easy credit did not breed a moral hazard. It is, rather, the moral hazard that bred the politics of easy credit” (Loriaux, 1991). This is a paradoxical view since a moral hazard could seem to be the outcome of a state-led credit allocation system. In such system, indeed, as post-war France and Italy had experienced, banks and markets did not have the incentive to exert substantive monitoring on credit allocation; while borrowers had the insurance of obtaining cheap money through state guarantees and subsidised prices or interest rates.

68 Decree of March 23, 1972. 69 CICR Decision of May 27, 1975.

113 In fact, moral hazard led to a strengthening of state-administered credit, since it became politically difficult, if not impossible, to allow for the failure of indebted banks or firms. Therefore “the French state was generous with its credit policy because it feared the political costs of parsimony.” (Loriaux, 1991). Such a system could work insofar as the main beneficiaries of state-led credit allocation – large firms – could continue to grow and to improve their productivity. Once, however, productivity slowed down and firms’ debt grew state-administered credit would run into serious problems.

Moral hazard was aggravated by the multiplication of objectives assigned to industrial policy in the 1960s – hence to state-led credit allocation: rescuing ailing firms or sectors, investing in less developed sectors or territories. In addition, in Italy “the assignment to state-owned enterprises of objectives other than profit (…) made inevitable the mixing between public firms and political parties” (Barca and Trento, 1997: 217)

The second weakness of state-administered credit originated in the absence of the external constraint and the availability of monetary policy as an adjustment tool. In France, as Loriaux has argued, the “overdraft economy” of the post-war period, with its lax monetary policies linked to the state-administered credit rationing system, had enabled firms to prosper despite a high level of indebtedness by allowing high rates of inflation that governments would periodically counter through aggressive devaluations of the franc against the dollar, which in turn would give French firms a comparative advantage (Loriaux, 1991). In addition, while Italy and France both embarked on an export-led industrial strategy during the 1960s (once reconstruction was over and European currencies had been made convertible again), they suffered from unfavourable specialisation within the international division of labour: they produced low-capital intensive consumption goods and did not produce the means for their production (machinery, tools), which they imported from countries such as Germany. Such specialisation presented a contradiction with the Fordist accumulation regime: while sustaining internal demand required high wages, the two countries’ trade specialisation demanded low wages so as to lower the prices of exported goods. The only way out was to resort to devaluation, which alleviated the pressure on wages while effectively lowering the price of French and Italian export goods.

114 Devaluation was not new to France: successive governments often resorted to devaluation during the 1950s and the 1960s. In addition, some of their trading partners, notably Germany, chose to re-valuate their currencies. Devaluations, however, have sustained effects only when used as a temporary measure to save time (through a boost in exports) so as to adjust industrial capacities in the meantime and, in the medium term, to change a country’s trade specialisation (towards higher capital intensive goods). This was the path chosen by Germany and Japan in the 1950s: they chose an undervalued currency precisely as a way to shield their exports during the re-qualification of their industrial apparatus. Such was not the strategy behind the French devaluations. Most importantly, the resort to devaluation was possible only insofar as exchange rates were fixed and capital was not very mobile. In other words, the survival of state-administered credit was dependent upon the functioning of the Bretton-Woods system of fixed exchange rates.

The case of Italy was different in this respect: both the Bank of Italy and key figures of economic policy-making made sure that the stability of the lira was respected, even during the difficult years of 1963 and 1964. The stability of the lira earned itself the title “Oscar of the currencies” in the late 1950s.

The third weakness of state-administered credit was its reliance on political compromises that were dependent on stable industrial relations and continuous growth without inflation. In France, that comprise involved around (i) civil servants dedicated to developmentalism; (ii) the gaullists, who were determined to strengthen the state’s capacity to steer the economy; (iii) the Communist Party and unions who limited their claims to a fair redistribution of the “fruits of growth”; (iv) business classes who accepted increases in real wages in exchange for increases in productivity. In Italy, the main components of the compromise – a “compromise without reform” (Barca 1997) – were (i) the “Nittians”, or the elite followers of Nitti, who believed in the unrivalled capacity of private managers of public institutions to manage credit allocation and favour productive investments; (ii) the free-market economists school, who rejected any form of state intervention in the economy; (iii) the Communist Party, which made, as early as 1945, a “developmentalist” choice (Barca speaks of a “productivist” option) favouring reconstruction and industrialisation over more immediate political gains that might have been earned through more aggressive, pro- labour policies; (iv) Catholic politicians and intellectuals with social leanings; (v) large and medium business interests, although divided on many issues; (vi) what Barca calls the “Washington option” – the US interests in a pacified and allied Italy.

115 The stability of such compromises was predicated upon a series of specific external conditions. In particular, the views held by unions and the Communist party on the one hand and by business and centre or right- wing political parties on the other, depended on continuous economic growth and the smooth redistribution of the fruits of growth. Once growth slowed down (as it did in the late 1960s) redistributive conflicts occurred, leading to the unravelling of compromise. Moreover, the power held by the Gaullists in France and the Nittians in Italy (both in administration and political circles) was threatened by generational and ideological changes.

4.2.2 The twin crisis of the 1970s: the crisis of the Fordist model and the collapse of the gold exchange standard

The early 1970s was characterised by a twin crisis that affected most industrialised economies: an internal crisis – that of the Fordist accumulation regime; and an external crisis, provoked by the collapse of the gold exchange standard and the rise of exchange rate instability, along with growing trade and financial interdependence (what in France is known as the contrainte extérieure, or external constraint). This twin crisis adversely affected state-administered credit in France and Italy by undermining the fragile balance on which such a system was predicated.

• The crisis of the Fordist regime of accumulation

The Fordist accumulation regime, experienced by the United States since the 1920s, and in post-war Europe, was based on mass production (and consumption) of standard goods and services by large firms and unskilled workers, low unemployment, redistribution of productivity gains to both labour and capital, and accommodating monetary and fiscal policies. The crisis of the Fordist regime, which started in the late 1960s, was both an industrial and labour crisis (on the Fordist regime and its crisis, see Aglietta 1976; Boyer et al. 1978 and Boyer, 1990, for a synthesis). The industrial crisis was essentially a crisis of capital over-accumulation. With the use of productive capacities at their maximum, and the catching-up of real wages, capital in the late 1960s was increasingly unable to find productive outlets. The Fordist crisis led, on the world market, to the shift of competitive advantage from mass-production industries to manufacturers able to produce specialised, high-quality goods, often in small, customised batches, and to undertake continuous innovation and to target high value- added market niches.

116 Not anticipating such a shift away from Fordist firms, capitalists (and the state) in both France and Italy invested heavily in non-productive segments and employment: services of course (hence the rapid development of the tertiary sector in the late 1960s – early 1970s), but also monitoring jobs in factories, where workers’ behaviour had become openly defiant of existing working conditions and discipline. Sales, health, building, and real estate were the favourite destinations of domestic capital, feeding what was known in Italy as the “rent inflation” (inflazione della rendita). In addition, in those years domestic capital was increasingly attracted by profit opportunities abroad, giving rise to what is known in Italy as the “fuga dei capitali”.

A successive strategy, tried out in France in the second half of the 1970s, was to aggressively promote an outward-oriented industrial strategy (acquisitions of foreign factories by French groups, for instance), while encouraging dualism at home – i.e. the outsourcing of parts of the production process to small firms staffed with unskilled labour, often migrant workers. Such dualism was, however, defensive rather than offensive and did not create the conditions for the emergence of an alternative industrial structure (See Berger and Piore, 1982). In Italy, for historical reasons small and medium firms had played a more important part in the country’s development; and in the mid-1970s it appeared clear that those firms were better able to sustain the new external environment than large firms, to a large extent because of small firms’ reliance on their own funds (in contrast to large firms’ high levels of indebtedness). The late 1970s saw, simultaneously, an increased interest in small firms from scholars – this is when the literature on industrial districts started to appear (see Beccattini, 1977; and Bagnasco, 1978). However, at that time the external pressure was so strong, and public deficits so high that any large-scale industrial restructuring strategy would have appeared too risky.

Beyond that crisis of over-accumulation, the second main component of the crisis of the Fordist accumulation regime was the rapidly deteriorating industrial relations. This deterioration had two origins: on the one hand, unions had successfully capitalised on collective wage bargaining during the 1960s, and reaped significant results in terms of real wages (which caught up during that decade, bringing an improvement in workers’ purchasing power); on the other hand, with the slowdown of productivity in the late 1960s, firms put in place new strategies to increase the output-per-worker, and workers became less and less satisfied with working conditions.

117 Such dissatisfaction culminated in 1968 and the three following years. It is estimated that on average, from 1967 to 1969 France lost 52 million working days per year because of strikes – against 1.8 million in 1965-1966. Italy, in 1969, lost 200 million working days to strikes. 1969 marked the beginning of the so-called “hot Autumn” – rising tensions in industrial relations (De Rosa 1990). Within a few years, work stoppages increased sharply, and union membership rose as well; as a consequence, product wages rose 13 and 10 percent in 1970 and 1971, contributing to a severe profit squeeze in the Italian industry.

The slowdown in productivity, the rise of unproductive capital uses and labour unrest led to a sharp decline in economic growth during the early 1970s. In 1973 industrial output in France and Italy was actually lower than it had been the previous year. At the same time, the rise in monetary wages led to an upsurge of inflation, fed by a wage-price spiral. In Italy, successive labour agreements led to the full indexation of wages on prices (the so called “scala mobile” and “punto unico di contingenza”) Even before the oil shock (and its dramatic consequences on domestic price levels), therefore, inflation was on the rise. The crisis of the Fordist model undermined the French and Italian state-administered credit systems: the moral hazard generated by the overdraft economy was aggravated by the fall in productivity, revenues, and inflationary pressures. Therefore, the debt and productivity crisis in large firms threatened the very basis of France’s and Italy’s development strategies. Secondly, state-led Fordism (and credit allocation) relied on a political compromise (see sections above) that depended on the stability of industrial relations in large firms. In France the statist pattern of economic policy-making relied on close relationships between top civil servants and top managers at large businesses (Schmidt 1996). With the outbreak of social tensions, the political compromise was in trouble: the Communist Parties of both countries were outflanked by left-wing movements, which in turn radicalised the Communists; and the financial and industrial elites felt disenfranchised and embarked on a strategy that openly broke away from the political compromise of the 1940s-1950s.

118 • Balance of payment crises and the rise of the external constraint

The crisis of the Fordist accumulation regime at home coincided with changes in “hegemonically structured international political economy” abroad (Loriaux, 1991; 2003). Post-war exchange-rate stability relied on the Bretton-Woods system of fixed but adjustable exchange rates. That system, once the convertibility of European currencies was re-established in the 1960s, depended in turn on the willingness of the United States government to forbid internal adjustment through the manipulation of the dollar’s external value. As Loriaux has noted, American monetary and fiscal policy in the 1950s supported new, post-war international trade and monetary arrangements that sought to make Keynesian policy possible under free trade. But American policy began to turn more “nationalist” (in Loriaux’s words) in the 1960s in response to international and domestic conflict. Nationalism in monetary affairs – refusal to address inflation in the key international currency – brought down the Bretton Woods in 1971 (See Loriaux, 1991; and Helleiner, 1991). The demise of fixed exchanged rates occurred within a context of rising cross-country capital flows. Increased capital market interdependence, variable exchange rates and the two oil shocks created high levels of exchange rate instability throughout the seventies. The demise of fixed rates left the French and Italian political economies in a difficult situation.

Indeed, French and Italian developmentalism had arisen within the framework of a forgiving international monetary environment. The possibility of multilateral ratification of change in fixed monetary parities internationalised the inflation that developmentalism tended to produce. But the post-1973 non-system of floating rates made that kind of internationalisation impossible. The cost of price inflation was borne entirely by the inflationary country’s balance of payments. For trade dependent countries like France and Italy the cost was high. Floating rates generated the threat of vicious circles of inflation and currency depreciation. Inflation depleted the demand for French and Italian exports. But the demand for certain imports, notably petroleum and other raw materials bought in dollars, and proved insensitive to price hikes occasioned by depreciation. Imported price hikes aggravated inflation as they percolated through the economy, further sapping market confidence in the currency.

119 As a consequence of exchange rate instability, trade balance rapidly deteriorated during the early 1970s, while neither France or Italy could attract enough foreign capital to repay their foreign debt. This unbalance led to severe balance of payment crises during those years. While the crisis of Fordism had put pressure on French and Italian developmentalism (and state-led credit allocation) from the inside, exchange rate instability put external pressures on both countries.

Of course, the balance of payment crisis was triggered by the 1973 oil shock, which followed a gradual rise in the price of natural resources in the previous decades. The four-fold increase in oil prices in the autumn of 1973 had a particularly strong impact on oil- dependent countries such as France and Italy, and created a huge commercial deficit that was not compensated by capital inflows.

4.2.3 The first responses to the crisis: from monetary restriction to strengthening the credit administered systems

The oil shock, the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in the early seventies, along with the decline of the monetary hegemony exercised by the United States made it impossible for France and Italy to continue using inflationary growth strategies as they had done in the past, and, as far as France is concerned, to use periodic aggressive devaluation to adjust for inflation. The first policy response to the balance of payment crisis was, therefore, was the resort to restrictive monetary policy in 1973. That policy reversal did not last and was itself reversed as early as 1975. It is not before the late 1970s and the early 1980s that restrictive monetary policy made its come-back in both countries. The restrictive monetary policy practiced in 1973-75 in both countries led to a strengthening of state’s grip over credit allocation, giving birth to “l’encadrement du credit”, or state-administered credit. This move reflected the belief that further state control of credit and investment could help shield the domestic economy from destabilising forces both abroad and at home. Interestingly, state-administered credit did not falter with the return to an expansionary monetary policy in 1975-76. It survived its birth as a temporary adjustment tool, and actually came to embody the paroxystic version of state-led credit allocation that had been practiced since the late 1930s in both countries.

120 • France

In France, the first reaction to the crisis was a restrictive monetary policy. In late 1973, monetary market interest rates were raised to a record 15%. The impact on French industry was dramatic: investment in industry declined by 9.5% in 1975; that same year, bankruptcies had increased by a fourth as compared to 1974. At the same time, if inflation in 1975 was effectively lower than what it had been in late 1973, it was still higher than France’s trade partners (notably Germany). These results, together with the election of a new president of the Republic in May 1974 (Valéry Giscard d’Estaing), put an end to that short-lived restrictive monetary policy and led to a Keynesian “relance”. Priorities were now set on revitalising domestic demand, through an expansionary policy mix characterised by (i) renewed public investments (and, therefore, rising fiscal deficits) into industrial programs such as the nuclear power plant construction program; and (ii) an expansionary monetary policy, with monetary market interest rates falling from a maximum of 14% in 1974 to a minimum of 6.5% in 1976.

Such a policy failed to improve a domestic demand that had been durably affected by the uncertainties unleashed by high inflation rates and exchange rate instability since the early 1970s. It did, however, worsen the external balance. France’s trade balance deficits increased in 1975, leading to the French franc’s exit from the “snake”70 and a 10% devaluation – which deepened the crisis by increasing inflation without improving the trade balance. The deterioration of external balance, together with a shift in internal politics (the demise of the president’s Gaullist allies) led to another policy shift, this time towards austerity, characterised by the Barre government’s decisions to remove price controls in some sectors; provide tax incentives to encourage the acquisition of shares (to stimulate the growth of financial markets and decrease the dependence upon banks as a source of funding)71; institute with large public firms development contracts that directly tied state subsidies to market performance. Monetary policy was, again, tightened to reach and maintain external balance.

70 The snake was the monetary system established in 1974 by members of the European Community to shield their currencies from exchange rate instability. It consisted of a loosely fixed exchange rate regime, where currencies were allowed to appreciate/ depreciate by a margin of 2.5%, then increased to 5%. 71 The “Monory package” of 1977-78, after the name of the Minister of the Economy.

121 The restrictive monetary policy of the early 1970s led to the establishment of “l’encadrement du credit”, or administered credit, which had its roots in the 1966-67 banking reforms (see previous sections). In the previous years, traditional “developmental” policies were seen to have met their limits, and French policy-makers renewed the financing instruments at their disposal. First, the Pompidou administration revived the Fonds de Développement Economique et Social (FDES), whose importance had shrunk under De Gaulle (Loriaux 1991). The Fund was mobilised to channel billions of francs into key industries, such as steel and automobiles. Besides the FDES, a series of new instruments were created in those years to channel funds into ailing sectors or strategic firms: the Interministerial Committee for Industrial Restructuring (Comité Interministériel pour les Restructurations Industrielles, or CIRI), set up in 1974, whose mission was to help ailing small and medium firms; the Interministerial Orientation Committee for the Development of Strategic Industries (CODIS), which subsidised investment in innovative technologies, especially at large firms; the Institute for Industrial Development (Institut de Développement Industriel, or IDI), whose mission was to help skill adjustment and job transfers in declining industries; later, the Special Fund for Industrial Adaptation (FSAI), set up in 1978 to support investment in regions with high unemployment, which was particularly active in shipbuilding and automobiles; the National Agency for the Promotion of Research (ANVAR), whose mission was to support small and medium size firms that invested in innovative products or technologies. Most of those instruments were put to the service of an industrial policy that had shifted from supporting national champions to creating and sustaining “lame ducks”.

Secondly, administered credit took the form of administrative controls and ceilings on the volume and price of credit. In other words, through the various instruments mentioned above, the government had in effect the power to set interest rates – and especially to set favourable interest rates for the specific sectors or firms it aimed to help or finance (the lame ducks). Moreover, the government imposed a series of ceilings on the volume of credit to be offered by banks and financial institutions; in effect, to support one sector it had only to lift the restrictions imposed on lending to that sector. By the late 1970s, therefore, banking and lending rates were mostly set by government or government agencies. For instance, the interests earned by the French savings banks on their savings deposits were set by decree signed by the Minister of the Economy.

122 Industrial policy under De Gaulle involved the restructuring of large firms through vertical integration and horizontal diversification. Such policy was not limited to public firms; private firms were also encouraged to grow through financial incentives: subsidies and loans targeted to regional development, research, foreign exchange guarantees… (Bellon 1980). In 1975, according to some estimates, public support to business (including public purchases and direct aid) amounted to 126 billion francs, 9% of French GDP (Bellon 1980). In the seventies, the increasing reliance of the government on votes of shopkeepers and small firms led to increased subsidies to small firms. The Seventh Plan, for instance, set 816 million francs to be allocated to SMEs.

The ultimate upturn of state-administered credit was the nationalisation, in 1982, by the newly-appointed Socialist government, of 5 industrial groups72, 39 banks73 and 2 financial firms (Compagnie financière Paribas; Compagnie financière Suez). The 1982 law74 disposed the nationalisation of all banks with deposits amounting to more than a billion francs; in addition, the law suppressed private shareholdings in state-owned banks (BNP, Société Générale, Crédit Lyonnais)75. There had been a vivid debate, among Socialists, on the extent of state control over the neo-nationalised firms (from 50 to 100%). The 1982 nationalisations led, actually, to a variety of situations: some firms were 100% controlled by the state; others were controlled by the state, but with minority shareholders; yet other firms were indirectly controlled by the state through other public firms (such as the Banque Paribas, owned at 75% through the Compagnie Financière de Paribas). As a whole, by the end of 1982, the public banking sector included 146 banks and 157 financial firms (Lacoue- Labarthe, 2001). As a result of these nationalisations, by the end of 1982 89.7% of total deposits were held at state-owned banks; and 84.8% commercial lending and 82.5% of banking staff belonged to the public sector (Lacoue-Labarthe 2001).

72 Compagnie générale d’électricité, Compagnie de Saint-Gobain, Péchiney Ugine-Kuhlmann, Rhône-Poulenc SA, Thomson-Brandt. 73 Among those 39 banks stood merchant banks such as Banque Worms, Banque Rothschild, Banque Hervet; large commercial banks such as Crédit du Nord, Crédit Commercial de France (CCF), Crédit Industriel et commercial (CIC)… 74 Loi 82-155 of February 11, 1982. 75 Private shareholdings had been authorised by a 1973 law up to a 25% ceiling, for national banks’ staff. The 1982 law led, therefore, to a re-nationalisation of national banks.

123 • Italy

In Italy, a severe balance of payment crisis occurred in 1973, leading to the signature, in early 1974, of a standby agreement between the Italian government and the International Monetary Fund (IMF). This agreement provided for a 1.2 billion dollar loan from the IMF to Italy to solve its balance-of-payment crisis; in exchange, the Italian government committed to limit the expansion of domestic lending through the setting of a ceiling of 22,400 billion lire to the growth of “total internal credit”76, a new target agreed upon by the IMF and the Italian government. This agreement predictably led to an increase in interest rates and a decrease in banks’ lending to firms; it also – non incidentally – provoked the demise of the government that had negotiated the agreement in March of 1974.

With the ceiling on total internal credit, the Bank of Italy, for the first time since the 1950s, shifted its focus from interest rates to the volume of lending in the economy; and it used a target for aggregate lending to pursue a restrictive monetary policy. That landmark change, however, did not last: in 1975, monetary policy turned expansive again. Several factors explain this short-lived change in monetary policy. First, new forms of shop-floor representation and workers’ rights led to an overhaul of the scala mobile in 1975 and the setting up of a Workers’ Statute, which indexed wages on inflation for 90 % of workers. Plant-closure legislation was eliminated, and firms’ ability to lay off workers for disciplinary reasons was virtually abandoned. Labour activism led the central bank to expand credit by the second half of 1970. According to Epstein and Schor, social expenditures constituted a crucial link in the cycle of labour militancy / fiscal growth / monetary accommodation in the 1970s (Epstein and Schor 1989). Secondly, the CTI target never represented the main monetary instrument used by the Central Bank; the exchange rate policy was that instrument. In those years, taking advantage of the continuous devaluation of the dollar via-a-vis the deutchemark, the Bank of Italy practiced a double-faced exchange rate policy: devaluations vis-a-vis the deutschemark (the deutschemark area represented Italy’s first export market) and stability, even slight reevaluations with the dollar (the dollar area representing the country’s primary import market).

76 Total internal credit was an aggregate measure that included private and public lending to firms.

124 So, after one year of restrictive monetary policy, by 1975 monetary policy became expansive again. However such expansion was entirely absorbed by public finance needs, and did not alleviate lending restrictions bearing on firms since the early 1970s. The opposite happened: with the shift of objectives from stable interest rates to the control over the volume of lending, rising public deficits automatically led the central bank to increase constraints on lending (the “massimale sugli impieghi”) and, therefore, reduce lending to large firms. Interestingly, both the 1974 monetary restriction and the return to monetary expansion worked towards the strengthening of state-administered credit. Already in 1973 the Treasury circuit had been strengthened with the twin imposition of ceilings on bank loans and of portfolio constraints forcing banks to hold a percentage of the increase in their deposits in fixed-rate securities77.

The portfolio constraint was at first set at 6% (at least) of funds deposited in savings and current accounts; most of those funds were supposed to go to bonds issued by IMI and IRI, but also those issued by major public utilities (the state-owned electricity and oil concerns – ENEL and ENI, respectively). The portfolio constraint was frequently manipulated over the years: in 1975, 1976, 1978, 1979, 1980, 1981, 1982, the CICR regularly intervened to change the level and the destination of constrained funds (see Fenucci, 1996: 102-106). On average, more than a third of the increase of bank deposits was destined to the acquisition of public securities. The destination varied throughout the years; they included the IMI and IRI, CREDIOP, public utilities, Treasury bonds, bonds issued by “special credit sections for public works”, bonds issued to finance agricultural credit, highways… Importantly, the Bank of Italy managed to have some discretionary power over the distribution of securities. In effect, the central bank acted as a merchant bank to the service of the Treasury.

The 1973 changes were aimed at insulating the bond market from destabilising forces in the domestic and international economies. They also led to a reorganisation of financial intermediation.

During the previous decade, the weight of banks in credit allocation – especially ordinary banks – had markedly increased. Deposits as a percentage of household financial savings rose from 27.9% in 1963 to a peak of 55.4% in 1977 (Bank of Italy, Annual Report, various years).

77 CICR decision of June 18, 1973.

125 Increased banking intermediation was favoured by the central bank’s supervision, which, especially in the late 1960s (under the governorship of Guido Carli), loosely interpreted the law forbidding banks to engage in medium-term lending (Nardozzi 1983). The portfolio constraint reduced the interest differential between bonds and deposits, thereby encouraging households to buy bank deposits. This created a kind of “double intermediation” (Epstein and Schor 1989): banks collected savings from households, and either invested those funds in public bonds, or lent them to the Treasury and to special credit institutions, who in turn funded firms’ financing needs. From 1972 to 1981 banks supplied around 70% of the resources of special credit institutions. The Italian Treasury circuit was thus markedly reinforced – and the potential development of financial markets (where households and firms could have exchanged bonds and other types of financial instruments) was impaired.

The smooth working of the public overdraft economy (or, more precisely, the continuous postponement of the crisis) was predicated upon low interest rates and high inflation. The latter allowed continuous nominal public deficits to be almost totally compensated by the depreciation of the real value of financial assets (including public bonds): although nominal public sector deficits remained high during the late 1970s (they averaged –10% over the period 1975- 1980), their real value became positive in 1976 and 1979, reaching + 2.3% of GDP in 1980 (against a nominal value of –8.6%)! Of course, that same year the real value of households’ financial assets became negative (at –0.7%), while their nominal value had been consistently positive over the past decades. This paradoxical situation meant that households were “penalised” for holding lending capacity, paying the so-called “inflation tax” to borrowers. But not only did the inflation tax not represent a sustainable solution to rising public deficits; it also prevented solving the crisis of the Fordist production and accumulation regime; and high inflation rates became a source of concern for monetary authorities, who became more and more sensitive to monetarist thinking.

Beyond these shifts in monetary policy, successive governments tried in the second half of the 1970s to rationalise the industrial policy framework, characterised by an overlap of subsidies and support mechanisms and institutions. Renewed efforts were made to jump- start industrial productivity.

126 A law passed in 1976 instituted a “Fondo nazionale per il credito agevolato al settore industriale” (fund for facilitated credit to industry), destined in priority to the Mezzogiorno78. That law integrated existing mechanisms for “facilitated credit”. However, it borrowed the traditional instruments for the management of subsidies: single subsidies were decided by the Ministry of the Industry upon a proposal by an ad hoc ministerial committee, then distributed through special credit institutions.

In sum, the same vicious circle identified by Loriaux in France (overdraft economy – moral hazard – administered credit – more moral hazard) was at play in Italy. As De Cecco has argued, the 1970s crisis increased even more the rigidity of the “Beneduce system”, which “should have been declared obsolete ten years before.”, adding that “the bailout of ailing industrial firms (did) weigh on the financial system, as (did) the necessity to substitute private capitals that had fled abroad with new loans guaranteed by the state so as to avoid bankruptcy and unemployment. Inflation makes it convenient for firms to grow debts and send their capital abroad; and the state becomes indebted to maintain public and private employment”. (De Cecco, 1997)

4.2.4 The deepening of the crisis and the definitive abandon of administered credit

The macro and micro-economic situation in both France and Italy did not improve during the 1970s. In 1975, the growth of the Italian GDP became negative for the first time since the early 1940s: annual growth rate that year reached -3.6%. In the successive years, economic growth remained at low levels; industrial investment declined throughout the 1970s, as did firms’ profitability. Inflation, in the meantime, kept on rising – especially in Italy where it reached two-digit levels in the late 1970s, substantially higher than other industrialised countries. State-administered credit was clearly not a sustainable strategy.

78 D.P.R. n. 902, 1976.

127 Three other factors condemned state-administered credit as an adjustment strategy in both France and Italy. First, the external pressure that had appeared in the 1970s became a permanent threat to the two countries’ balance of payment, which significantly reduced monetary policy’s room for manoeuvre. In the early 1980s, ‘reaganomics’ – i.e. the peculiar combination of monetary rigor and deficit spending in the United States, – raised interest rates globally79, together with the exchange value of the dollar (which was still the currency of choice in international transactions). Such trends reinforced the external pressures on French and Italian policy. An expansive policy mix pursued in isolation had become almost impossible, as the French learned in 1982: then the neo-Keynesian policy put in place by the neo-elected Socialist president, Francois Mitterrand, was defeated by world stagnation and capital outflows. According to Loriaux, indeed, the external pressure had a decisive role in the dismantling of administered credit systems: “because credit activism was abandoned almost simultaneously in five such dissimilar countries (France, Japan, South- Korea, Mexico, Spain) one can reasonably infer that the force driving the process was common to all of them and must have had roots in the evolution of the broader global political economy”(Loriaux, 1998a: 1).

This overemphasis of the external source of domestic crisis has been criticised, especially, in France, by economists belonging to the regulatory school (see Boyer, 1978; and Lipietz, 1984). According to them, inflation and low growth were structurally produced by the crisis of the Fordist accumulation regime (mentioned above), characterised by a crisis of productivity, a shift in industrial relations and a shift in the industrial structures of each country. These were not the result of an excess demand and therefore could not be effectively addressed with the sole use of the interest rate as an adjustment tool. These two explanations are not exclusive one of the other; rather, it seems that the external and internal causes worked together to the demise of state-administered credit. A third factor behind the definitive abandon of administered credit was the growing importance of financial markets. In particular, fixed interest rates became increasingly unsustainable in the face of market conditions characterised by the offer of variable rates financial instruments; and, in a context of high inflation, the need from public financial institutions (Treasury, banks, special credit institutions in Italy) to finance their loans with (rising) variable rates. As a consequence, in Italy fixed rates led to shorter maturities on loans offered by SCIs (since they could not commit themselves to the long-term), and further weakened the financial situation of indebted firms.

79 Since the US were a large and powerful economy with a sound financial reputation, reaganomics created a high level of demand for money to the world’s markets, which led other industrial countries to increase interest rates.

128 4.3 Shifts in regulatory regimes and the end of credit activism

The limitations of early state-led responses to the crisis (the strengthening of state-administered credit), led to the consider consideration of alternative solutions – and in particular the dismantling of state credit. The new strategy was implemented in the 1980s: it entailed radical shifts in the macroeconomic as well as the industrial policy regimes. These shifts were radical and systemic: they concerned all aspects of economic policy.

4.3.1 The transformation of industrial policy

• France

As seen above, under Valéry Giscard D’Estaing’s presidency, industrial policy was given sensibly different goals than those that had prevailed in the previous decades. The priority was, especially after 1977 and the failure of Keynesian demand-led policies, to encourage national champions only in certain segments (créneaux) where they were already competitive; and to re-deploy resources towards stronger groups. With the Socialists’ arrival in power in 1981, and until the return of a right-wing government in 1986, the state shifted from “promoting rising sectors and leaving declining sectors to the market, to rescuing the declining sectors and leaving rising sectors to the market” (Schmidt 1996; p.85). The first Socialist government relied on direct state intervention to fulfil their goals – with the nationalisation of all large banks and industrial firms. At that time indeed, French firms were both highly indebted and not profitable; therefore, credit policy could not be mobilised to push for the structural adjustments that were needed – hence the resort to share ownership by the state. But nationalisation did not mean that the State should assume the strategic direction of large firms; its intervention was circumscribed to re-capitalisation and protection from market forces. In particular, the state reduced firm debt and funded industrial restructuring programs that lowered production and operating costs (see Hancké, 2002).

Moreover, nationalised firms did not remain within the orbit of the public sector for a long time. In 1986, the right-wing government that won the elections launched an ambitious privatisation program.

129 The first privatisation law80 listed 65 firms to be privatised within a 5-year period. That list included all banks (with the exception of the Banque de France) and insurance companies that had been nationalised in 1945 and 1982. Half of those firms were effectively privatised before the fall of the centre-right government after the 1988 general elections: three large industrial firms (Saint-Gobain, CGE-Alcatel, Matra); two small banks and six large banking groups (Paribas, Sogénal, Société Générale, the Crédit Commercial de France, Suez, CNCA – see next chapter for more details).

Loriaux, among others, claims that these shifts in industrial policy were all inspired by the same developmentalist ideology, still widespread in policy circles (see Loriaux, 1991; also Schmidt, 1996). What changed in those years was not the ultimate goals but the instruments of developmentalism: from budget-funded subsidies in the 1960s to bank- based credit controls in the 1970s to state ownership in the 1980s. As Loriaux further argued, “the instrumental change we observe must be weighed against the permanence of a developmentalist culture and the strength of representation of that culture at centres of economic and political decision-making” (Loriaux, 2002). Even the Barre government’s apparent pro-market policies did not mark the end of interventionism, just a different form of interventionism.

• Italy

In Italy, a first attempt at rationalising the fragmented industrial policy-making institutional framework took place in 1977 with the law n.675, which set up the CIPI (Committee for the Coordination of Industrial Policy), whose mission was to plan and coordinate the state’s policies towards industry. That attempt failed for many reasons, two of which have to do with the CIPI’s weak administrative influence (being located at the weak Budget Ministry) and its “low insulation from politics” (Ferrara 1989) especially from parliamentary politics. State incapacity to design and implement a reform of industrial policy contrasted with public enterprises’ determination to lead the restructuring process throughout the 1980s. Privatisation took off in 1983, the year in which, for the first time since the war, the purchase of enterprises by the IRI holding group was inferior in volume to the sale of enterprises (the ratio was 1 to 20).

80 The law of July 2, 1986; followed by a law of August 6th, 1986.

130 By the mid-1980s, policy-makers shared the concerns of top-managers of public companies towards restoring profitability to large firms through restructuring. As a report presented in the Italian Senate put it, “economic development cannot be pursued through demand-led policies, with industrial policy taking the back seat to ensure the satisfaction of demand. Now industrial policy must take the driver’s seat [in the absence of demand-led policies]”81. The emphasis was put on a supply-side industrial policy. In 2000, the IRI was finally liquidated, and its remaining shareholdings (in the national carrier, Alitalia; the public TV holding, Rai; and the manufacturing firm, Finmeccanica) were passed on to the Treasury.

4.3.2 The transformation of monetary policy

During the 1980s, in both countries, a profound transformation occurred in the realm of monetary policy. There are different interpretations of such change. According to Epstein and Schor, foreign exchange crises represented “convenient” opportunities for the central bank to engage in restrictive policies (Epstein and Schor), in contrast to the structural thesis developed by Loriaux et al (1997). What is not discussed, however, is that the aims of monetary policy changed dramatically during that time.

Between 1979 and 1980, both countries entered the European Monetary System, which had been conceived as a looser and smaller Bretton-Woods regime anchored on the deutschemark (beyond the ECU). Both France and Italy adhered, it seems, to impose external discipline on domestic actors (firms and policy-makers).

The transformation of the aims of monetary policy was simultaneous to a change in the institutional framework of policy-making. The latter consisted first and foremost in the emancipation of the Central bank from the sway of the Treasury; and in the subsequent redistribution of regulatory powers with the creation of autonomous regulatory authorities. The latter were inextricably linked to the content of monetary policy since, as Epstein and Schor have shown, independent central banks pursue more restrictive policies and are associated with lower rates of inflation – since they are disenfranchised from the interests of labour unions and labour parties and more prone to be dominated by bankers and investors (Epstein and Schor 1986).

81 Cited in De Rosa (1988).

131 • France

To combat the vicious circles associated with the overdraft economy, French authorities started, by 1974, assigning a high priority to stabilising the currency. France’s 1979 decision to join the European Monetary System was motivated by the government’s new monetary policy objective: to reduce inflation by pegging the franc to the Deutsche Mark. As argued by Loriaux and others, for France to regain control over its economy, it had paradoxically to relinquish its independence in monetary policy. The French consolidated their commitment to currency strength in the early 1980s following three devaluations (within the European Monetary System). The shift of emphasis in monetary policy brought reform to French finances. In the mid-1980s, under a Socialist government, France implemented far-reaching liberalising reforms in order, first, to wean business off state-controlled bank credit and direct it to the market for stocks and bonds and to international lenders, and, second, to make the French economy attractive to foreign capital so that foreign investment might compensate for the reduction in state-sponsored or supplied funds. As Loriaux put it, “France (and other nations) multiplied liberalising reforms to make its economy more appealing to – and better able to compete for – international capital.” (Loriaux 2003) The radical character of the reforms reflects the perceived need to eradicate moral hazard through the alteration of expectations by economic agents.

Such changes in strategy entailed change in instruments. Up until the early1980s, monetary policy instruments, such as interest rate policy, were mobilised to sustain the state’s industrial policy. With the increased pressures associated with the “external constraint”, in 1982-83, interest rate policy was assigned to the defence of the exchange rate of the French franc – with the “franc fort” policy, in other words the alignment of the franc on the Deutsche Mark. The nascent money market became the principal locus of central bank efforts to control interest rates.

Institutional changes accompanied this new policy, with the central bank gradually leaving the orbit of the Treasury, which had, until 1990, “legislative power” over monetary affairs. The Banque de France gained independence in 199382 and, simultaneously, control over monetary policy – which had for long been abandoned as an autonomous policy instrument. In 2000 most of the Banque de France’s monetary powers were surrendered to the European Central Bank.

82 With the law of August 4th, 1993.

132 As for industrial policy, it has been argued that the adoption of a restrictive policy-mix, first under Giscard, then under Mitterrand, was less a conversion to supply-side macroeconomics than the attempt to restore state control over the economy, in a dirigiste spirit (Schmidt, 2001). What matters here, however, is the outcome of such a strategic shift: a profound change in the instrumental and institutional nature of monetary policy in France.

• Italy

In Italy, the institutional features of monetary policy-making were changed, too. The major change occurred in 1981 with the emancipation of the Bank of Italy from the Treasury, the so-called “divorce”. Until then, the central bank was statutorily obligated to finance all fiscal deficits; the 1981 reform lifted that obligation.

During the 1950s and 1960s, under the governorship of Guido Carli, the Bank of Italy had been able to accommodate credit demands without risking excessive inflation and real wage increases – since, as Epstein and Schor argue, the working class was in a weak position during those years. The Bank did this by pegging the interest rate on government securities until 1969, after which it targeted monetary and credit aggregates. The central bank had for long voiced its desire for independence. Two important steps had already been taken in that direction: in 1969, the Bank of Italy was freed from unlimited fixed-rate financing of the Treasury. More precisely, the central bank remained the residual acquirer of unsold BOTs; but it was freed from selling and acquiring, on the secondary market, those bills which were above the required reserve level for banks. Treasury bills, in other words, lost their assimilation to the monetary basis.

The second step took root in the failure of the 1969 decision to create an effective market for Treasury bills. Thus a ministerial decree of April 1975, acting on the advice of the CICR (Interministerial Committee for Credit and Savings) of the same year, changed the rules of auction in tendering Treasury bills. From then on, access to auction was extended to non-bank financial intermediaries; the central bank, while remaining the residual acquirer of tendered bills, could compete with other auction members; finally, the price set by decree would become merely indicative, in effect giving the Bank of Italy the power to set the auction price.

133 The 1975 reform was a major step both towards central bank independence and towards the revamp of the Italian financial system. The creation of a private market in Treasury securities provided a mechanism for bond-financing of government deficits; at the same time, it paved the way for the growing influence of non-bank actors on financial intermediation.

These steps were, however, not enough, from the central bank’s viewpoint. Indeed, in its view, “excessive” public expenditures led to money growth and, under monetarist assumptions, to inflation. Government deficits averaged 12.5% of GDP in the 1970s, against 5.8% in the 1960s; in 1981, they reached 11.8%, compared to an OECD average of 2.2% (Monti et al., 1983). Government spending did not only create inflationary pressures. It also drowned out private investment: in 1978, public sector borrowing absorbed 70% of total domestic credit (Monti et al., 1983). Deficits were consistently criticised by the Bank of Italy (voiced in its successive Annual Reports) and led to a renewed claim for independence from its part. A few months before the divorce, Governor Ciampi pointed out that “the dimensions reached by public deficits set fiscal policy on a collision course with monetary policy […]; the broad possibility, for the Treasury, to access the [central bank]’s financing increases […] the risk that the control of monetary aggregates might lose its effectiveness in the short run83.” Similar views were expressed by the Monti commission, which was set up in 1981 by the Treasury to study the credit and financial system.

However, Epstein and Schor convincingly demonstrate the weakness of those arguments. First, after 1975 bond-financing substituted monetisation of the deficit – and central banks public debt holdings decreased. Secondly, private investment was not much crowded out – as a growing share of increased expenditure, after 1974, went to investment in firms, through subsidies and public financing (for a similar argument, see Giannola and Imbriani, 1992). Finally, the burden created by debt servicing was balanced by inflation, which led to negative real interest payments to bond-holders during the 1970s. This represented, as Epstein and Schor argue, hidden taxation on holders of government securities (Epstein and Schor 1989).

83 Carlo Azeglio Ciampi, “Tra mercato e controlli: aspetti operativi della politica monetaria”, Intervention by the Governor of the central bank at the banks’ association, Central institute of banks and bankers, Rome, 1981 – quoted in Monti and Onado (1989).

134 A more important factor leading to the divorce was related to financial – and in particular banking - intermediation. As mentioned above, the imposition of portfolio constraints and ceilings on bank loans led to the subjection of banks to state financing needs. This, according to Epstein and Schor, was equivalent to financial disintermediation – reflected in the sharp fall of bank loans to deposit ratios (Epstein and Schor 1989). This interpretation is questionable. First of all, quantitatively the share of bank deposits in households’ financial portfolio was still higher in 1980 (at 45% of total assets) than its level of 1970 (36%)? its 1965 level (30%). Secondly, as seen above, banks still fulfiled a critical intermediation function (at least until the late 1970s – early 1980s), although reduced when compared with the previous decade: instead of transforming household savings into lending to firms, banks channelled the former to the Treasury. Rather than disintermediation, this trend could be termed “dependent” or “state-led” intermediation – a reinforcement of the Italian Treasury circuit. In fact, during the 1970s the banking sector was solicited by the central bank to compensate for the collapse of the bond market; during that decade banks became almost the sole collectors of savings in the country.

However, that interpretation was widespread among the Bank of Italy, the Monti Commission and large commercial and savings banks by 1981. And it became more realistic after that, when deposits started losing their dominant position in household financial portfolios. Yet deposit disintermediation, owed more to the start-up growth of the bond market (unleashed by the 1975 decision mentioned above) than to the strengthening of the Treasury circuit. Deposit disintermediation was, in fact, the direct outcome of a consistent policy aimed at sustaining the growth of the bond and, later on, the stock market. Disintermediation was assumed to erode banks’ profitability. In 1980, the Bank of Italy noted in its annual report that “the circumstances that led to the widening of the interest rate spread might not recur. If they do not, the decline in intermediation will have adverse effects on banks’ profits” (Bank o Italy 1980: 97). However, during the 1970s banks had refrained from raising interests paid on deposits, keeping a profitable interest margin.

135 Perhaps more importantly, as Epstein and Schor point out, the decline in intermediation might be circumscribed to a handful of large, powerful banks, leaving aggregate profitability levels unchanged (Epstein and Schor 1989). As the 1980 Bank of Italy annual report noted, “the decline in intermediation affected most of all the three major commercial banks and the two largest savings banks” (Bank of Italy 1980: 102). From the central bank’s point of view, banking disintermediation was a complex issue: on the one hand, it led to the weakening of its main constituency and eroded its power of control over a sizeable part of the credit system; on the other hand, the marketisation of government deficits was seen as a powerful incentive to curb excessive public spending, and therefore to free monetary policy from it subjection to the Treasury’s will. In any case, both elements pleaded in favour of the divorce – and, in the medium term, the ending of the dismantlement of the Treasury circuit. It is important to note, however, that the Bank of Italy’s ambiguous attitude towards banking disintermediation has persisted until today.

With the 1981 divorce, the Bank of Italy was freed from the obligation to provide unlimited financing. Two elements, nonetheless, limited that independence. First, the Treasury’s ability to set floor prices on the bills it issued, constrained the Bank of Italy’s interest-rate policy and allowed de facto the Treasury to continue re-financing its debt (Locke ). Secondly, the Treasury could still force monetary financing through authorised overdraft of its account at the central bank84. However, the divorce effectively put an end to automatic monetary financing of government deficits. In addition, the divorce marked a return to the use of interest rates as an adjustment tool, this time in a market context. In fact, the divorce was linked to a broader strategy aimed at increasing the market’s role in the functioning of the credit system. As the director of the central bank, Lamberto Dini, said in 1980: “the full re-appropriation of monetary basis as an instrument for indirect credit control will allow the dismantlement of administrative constraints now imposed on the credit system”85.

84 Overdraft was authorised up to 14 percent of each year’s government expenditures; additional overdraft may be granted by the Parliament (Epstein and Schor 1989). 85 L. Dini, “Politica monetaria, disavanzo pubblico e fenomeni di ‘crowding out’” in Bancaria, 1980, n.12, p.1242.

136 The changes in monetary policy actually accelerated the crisis of the public overdraft economy – which was certainly one of the motivations behind monetary policy-makers’ determination to pursue an autonomous interest rate policy. While nominal public sector borrowing needs were consistently high during the1980s (fluctuating between 11% and 13.5%), their real value mechanically rose with disinflation and rising real interest rates: from -1.6% of GDP in 1981, it reached -2.6% in 1982, -4.3% in 1983, -6.4% in 1984, -6.6% in 1985, to a maximum of -8.5% of GDP in 1986 – while private firms real borrowing needs reached a maximum in 1985 at -3.5% of GDP86, and nominal values started decreasing in 1981.

4.3.3 Changes in financial regulation

• Changes in banking regulation

In both countries, together with monetary and industrial policy, the financial regulatory regime underwent dramatic changes during the 1980s. State-administered credit was definitely abandoned as a permanent feature of financial regulation87. Loan ceilings were abolished, portfolio constrains were lifted and functioning financial markets were established with the support of the state.

In Italy, during the 1980s, Treasury bills and state bonds gradually crowded out bank deposits in households’ financial portfolios: the latter represented, in 1975, 50% of households’ total financial assets (other liquid assets accounted for a further 20%); that number decreased to 45% in 1980; 34% in 1985; 26% in 1990; 25% in 1995; and less than 18% in 2000. In the meantime, Treasury bills (BOT) rose from 0% in 1975 to 9% in 1980 and 13% in 1985 and 12.5% in 1990. They lost their attractiveness in the 1990s, with the competition of stocks and shares. Treasury and public bonds rose in the late 1980s: they represented 13% of households’ total financial assets in 1975; 7% in 198088; 17% in 1985; 18% in 1990; 20% in 1995.

86 Source: Bank of Italy, Annual Report, various years. 87 As a top manager at the French central bank said in 1985, “l’encadrement du credit” could retain its use solely as a temporary instrument. 88 The 1975-1980 period marked a flexion in state bonds’ attractiveness for reasons explained above, i.e. high inflation and negative interest rates; the same period saw, as a response by the state, a more frequent resort to Treasury bills (BOT).

137 In France, the 1982 nationalisations wave, mentioned above, represented the last offshoot of developmentalist industrial policies – especially in the field of credit and banking. However, two aspects of the nationalisation process and its outcome seem to point to the opposite consideration: namely, and quite paradoxically, the 1982 nationalisation wave constituted the first step towards the dismantling of both state-administered credit and state-led industrial policies. First of all, the continuation of restrictive monetary policies severely constrained the extent to which the state could use its newly acquired banks to lend cheap money. Secondly, as Lacoue-Labarthe argues, there was no fully-fledged nationalisation of credit:

In 1986, the former Minister of the Economy, Pierre Bérégovoy wrote in the foreword of the “White Book” on the reform of financing of the economy (Livre blanc sur le financement de l’économie) that: “money must be mobile; then its cost is lowered, with the elimination of rents. Therefore, it becomes possible to clarify the role of the state by re-focusing its intervention on true priorities and by circumscribing its regulatory intervention to the general organisation and monitoring of capital markets”.

• State-supported rise of capital markets

In France, the state had to intervene repetitively to encourage the use of market investment instruments, such as mutual funds (in French, fonds communs de placement, or FCP) and investment funds (in French, société d’investissement à capital variable, or SICAV). FCPs and SICAVs were created in 195789 as a by-product of a reform aimed at fostering workers’ participation in firms’ benefits. They were not yet available until a 1963 decree90. It was not, however, until the late 1970s that FCPs and SICAVs became widely diffused, thanks to a favourable fiscal regime put in place by the government under Minister Monory91.

89 Law of June 26, 1957. 90 Decree of September 20, 1963. 91 Law of July 13, 1979; and decree of september 27, 1979.

138 4.4 Discussion

The dismantlement of state-administered credit lasted several years. It began in the late 1970s with the definitive adoption of restrictive monetary policies in both countries and the increased reliance on financial market instruments to coordinate credit allocation, and lasted until the mid-1980s, with the lift of price and volume controls and the de-segmentation of banking. Such a change in the broad institutional environment of savings banks led to a profound transformation of the sets (or matrixes) of constraints and incentives facing savings banks and, therefore, shaped banks’ behaviour.

The French and Italian state-administered credit systems created two sets of constraints and incentives: one general (common to all banks and banking categories) and one specific to savings banks. The general matrix of constraints and incentives consisted of four elements. First, functional specialisation led banks to focus much more on liabilities than on assets; even if restrictions on medium and long-term lending were loosened throughout the years, they did not allow banks to expand their lending business in a significant way. Secondly, functional specialisation, state support (state funding, subsidies, guarantees) and accommodating monetary policies discouraged the development of risk-management capabilities. This is the meaning of moral hazard: banks had the certainty of being refinanced or rescued by state institutions, and therefore did not have to pay particular attention to the risk of their endeavours. Third, functional specialisation and market segmentation constrained and discouraged competitive behaviour. Both on a territorial and a sector basis, banks or groups of banks relied on captive clienteles and did not, with rare exceptions, face the competitive pressures inherent to markets. Fourth, price and volume controls and fixed rates dis-incentivised profit- maximisation strategies and de-emphasised risk-management.

In addition to this general set of constraints and incentives, French and Italian savings banks faced specific constraints and incentives. First, because of their institutionalised role as stabilisers of the banking system (through their high number of depositors) and of specific incentives (fiscal privileges on savings accounts), savings banks were even less focused on assets and more on liabilities than other types of banks. State-centralised or controlled intermediation meant that savings banks did not have to care much about the use of funds they were collecting. Secondly, the state and political control (direct or indirect) over savings banks considerably restricted the latter’s margin for managerial manoeuvre.

139 This is especially true when comparing savings banks with other banks, even with those commercial banks in the orbit of the public sector (such as the commercial banks nationalised in 1982 in France). Importantly, these specific constraints and incentives created by savings banks’ broad institutional environment were reinforced by savings banks’ own history, characterised by cautious asset management and not-for profit business goals (see previous chapter).

The dismantling of state-administered credit in both France and Italy led to a complete upheaval of those matrixes of constraints and incentives. In the early 1980s, savings banks in both countries faced a completely transformed set of constraints and incentives that irrevocably altered their future expectations and – this is the argument developed in the next chapter – had a profound impact on savings banks’ strategies. Three elements stand out for their importance. First, the abandonment of accommodating monetary policies and the lift of price and volume controls created incentives for banks to develop risk-management capabilities. The shift in monetary policy put an end to moral hazard; banks lost the certainty of being refinanced and rescued by the state for having engaged in risky activities. Banks became responsible for setting the price and volume of their products and services, which could do nothing but change their way of doing business. Secondly, the shift from structural to prudential regulation put greater emphasis on banks’ solvability and patrimonial ratios. As a consequence, banks (and banking regulators) started to pay much closer attention to their levels of equity and their exposure to risk on the one hand; and to the issue of ownership and the sources of re-capitalisation on the other hand. Third, market de-segmentation and functional de-specialisation led to a rapid increase of competitive pressures affecting banks, and questioned the passive strategies followed in the past, which had been predicated upon stable market shares and captive clientele.

Importantly, these changes in the general matrix of constraints and incentives occurred prior to changes in the specific constraints and incentives facing savings banks. The next chapter will show how savings banks adjusted to those changes in their macro and micro environment by provoking regulatory change and trying to shape its outcome in a way favourable to their long-term strategies.

140 5. THE REGULATORY ‘NORMALISATION’ OF SAVINGS BANKS

5.1 Introduction

In the late 1970s – early 1980s, French and Italian savings banks were still regulated by laws from the 1930s and 1940s – laws that had been enacted with the specific purpose of avoiding a repetition of the crisis of the 1920s and 1930s.

The 1980s and 1990s, by contrast, are characterised by “paradigmatic shifts”92 in banking regulation in both countries –in that period the existing regulatory paradigm (market segmentation, credit ceilings, importance of public banks) was replaced by a new one (based on market de-segmentation, lift of administrative controls, introduction of prudential regulation, privatisation of public banks) (see Moran, 1991 for an overview). In that sense the reforms of savings banks93 have to be linked with the quasi-simultaneous reforms of the banking sector as a whole: in France, the two important periods of reform of savings banks were 198394 and 199995, while the laws of 198496, 199197 and 199698 changed the regulatory regime of the whole banking sector. In Italy, the key reforms of the savings banks sub-sector occurred in 199099 and 1998, while in 1993 and 1994 new laws were enacted concerning the banking system as a whole.

92 According to Peter Hall’s classic distinction between the three orders of policy change (Hall 1986). 93 Here savings banks are not taken as a simple proxy of the banking system as a whole, but as an analytical tool to understand the evolution of the two systems. 94 Loi n.83-557 du 1er Juillet 1983, “Loi portant réforme des caisses d’épargne et de prévoyance”. 95 Loi n.99-352 du 25 Juin 1999, “Loi relative à l’épargne et à la sécurité financière”. 96 Loi n.84-46 du 24 Janvier 1984, “Loi relative à l’activité et au contrôle des établissements de crédit”. 97 Loi n.91-716 du 26 Juillet 1991. 98 Loi n.96-597 du 2 Juillet 1996, “Loi de modernisation des activités financières”. 99 Legge Delega n.30 Luglio 1990, followed by the decree of November 1990.

141 More importantly, the shift in savings banks’ regulatory regimes occurred against the twin background of the dismantling of state-administered credit, analysed in chapter 4; and of savings banks’ growing demand for change, mentioned in chapter 3. The present chapter will focus on regulatory reform to address the main research questions laid out in chapter 2100. First, this chapter will compare savings banks’ regulatory reform process and outcomes in France and Italy. The research will seek to establish whether similar shifts in the macroeconomic environment, occurring in similar policy regimes (state-administered credit) lead to similar policy outcomes. Secondly, the chapter will assess whether potential differences in regulatory outcomes can be attributed to institutional differences. If regulatory changes simply translate or reflect changes in macroeconomic policy, then cross-country differences in regulatory outcome must be attributed to institutional rigidities. If, by contrast, regulatory changes incorporate actors’ strategies, then different outcomes might be linked to different strategies as well.

Findings have been regrouped under two headings. The first part analyses the regulatory changes and their broader meaning for the two countries’ banking system. Three main changes have been analysed: changes in savings banks’ legal status, changes in the structure of the savings banks sector, and changes in the operational scope of savings banks. The second part analyses the causes of such changes. The third part discusses the findings.

100 This chapter will focus on changes in the legal regime of savings banks, paying thus less attention to other types of regulatory changes – mainly, individual and general decisions taken by regulatory authorities such as the central banks and the regulatory bodies specialised in banking regulation . Legal changes are emphasised for three reasons: (i) the 1983 and 1999 legal reforms in France, and the 1990 and 1998 legal reforms in Italy did represent landmark changes in the regulatory environment of savings banks – in particular with regard to their legal definition, their status and ownership, and the scope of their operations; (ii) these reforms constituted, along with general banking reforms which accompanied or preceded them, the first large-scale regulatory change at the legislative level since the 30s and 40s; (iii) as legislative reforms, they gave rise to an important public debate, which makes it easier for the observer to understand the dynamics of the reform and the stakes at play. Of course sub-legal regulatory changes will also be addressed – since some of them had an importance of their own (such as the “Piano Sportelli” decision of the Italian Governmental Committee for Credit and Savings in 1978, or the various decisions on the “status-type” of savings banks taken by the French regulatory bodies during the 1970s), and interacted with legal reforms in ways that are relevant to the present study. But for reasons of space they will not be covered exhaustively.

142 5.2 Changes in the regulatory regime

The changes brought about in the 1980s and the 1990s by law-makers to the regulatory regimes of savings banks touched on all aspects of regulation. In both countries, however, three elements of change stand out: the transformation of savings banks’ legal status, the re-organisation of the sector and the (further) de-segmentation of the banking market.

5.2.1 Statutory ‘normalisation’

The outset of the reform period – the early 1980s in France, the mid-1980s in Italy – was characterised by a profusion of legal categories of banks on the one hand, and the great number of statutory public banks, on the other.

In France, by the early 1980s there were many categories of banks (from savings banks to cooperatives, to the Crédit Agricole, which had a status of its own, and to the banques d’affaires) legally recognised. In Italy two broad categories (commercial banks and special credit institutions) included in fact more than two dozen sub-categories, which entailed different governance and ownership structures. Commercial banks included: savings banks; public credit institutions (or Istituti di credito di diritto pubblico, which included several of the largest Italian banks: Banco di Napoli, Banco di Sicilia, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro, Istituto San Paolo di Torino, Monte dei Paschi di Siena, Banco di Sardegna)101; national interest banks (Banche di interesse nazionale, or BIN, including Banca commerciale italiana, Banco di Roma, Credito italiano)102; the Banche Popolari103; the Casse rurali e artigiane104; the Monti di credito su pegno105; and the commercial banks stricto sensu (private firms). Special credit institutions included: the Istituto Mobiliare Italiano, or IMI; Mediobanca106; Interbanca and Efibanca; Centrobanca107; and the IRI as well, which performed some credit functions.

101 These banks were public entities (Foundations), owned by the government and managed by directors appointed by the Treasury. 102 As seen in chapter 4, the BIN were owned by the Istituto per la Ricostruzione Industriale, or IRI, the giant public holding created in the 1930s, which managed state shareholdings. The BIN were above all used to finance the hundreds of firms in which IRI was present. 103 The Banche Popolari were cooperative banks with a peculiarity: although, as with other cooperatives, equity was unlimited, they had limited liability. 104 Cooperative banks. 105 Credit institutions which used to specialise in pawn-broking and small scale lending against mobile guarantees. 106 Mediobanca is considered to have been Italy’s sole true merchant bank up until the 1990s. 107 A kind of giro institution for the cooperative banks.

143 Among these banks the biggest (in terms of assets) were either public in status or belonged to the public sector largo sensu (being controlled directly or indirectly by the State or para-statal institutions such as the IRI). Savings banks held a special position, in that they were independent entities covered by public laws. But the biggest among them (Cassa di Risparmio delle Provincie Lombarde, Cassa di Risparmio di Venezia, Cassa di Risparmio di Torino) were controlled by political parties, especially the Christian Democrats (through the representatives of local governments on their boards, and the director and vice-director appointed by the Treasury). In France the government had launched in 1982 the second largest nationalisation wave in the country’s history, after that of the immediate post-war. Several dozens of firms went under state control, representing 11% of the country’s GDP108. Among them were 5 large banks and credit institutions (see introduction).

The regulatory reforms of 1983 in France and 1990 in Italy were first aimed at streamlining banking statuses and legal categories, which were a prerequisite for the restructuring of the whole sector (both in terms of the legal impediments to restructuring posed by the variety of legal categories, and of the various ownership structures embodied in those statuses). They led to a “normalisation” of the statuses of savings banks and a progressive reduction of the number of legal categories of banks.

• France

In the French case, the first thing the 1983 law did was to re-formulate the statutory identity of savings banks in order to bring it closer to commercial banks’. For the first time, article 1 of the law defined the Caisses d’Épargne as ‘établissements de crédit’109. This concept was of course the French translation of the ‘credit institutions’ introduced by the EC’ First Banking Directive of 1977.

108 See Loriaux (1991). 109 “Les caisses d'épargne et de prévoyance sont des établissements de crédit à but non lucratif. Elles ont pour objet la promotion et la collecte de l'épargne ainsi que le développement de la prévoyance pour satisfaire notamment les besoins collectifs et familiaux. A cet effet, elles sont habilitées à recevoir des dépôts, à consentir des crédits et à faire des opérations de banque au profit des personnes physiques, ainsi que des organismes n'exerçant pas, à titre principal, une activité industrielle ou commerciale. Elles sont habilitées à consentir des prêts, notamment aux collectivités et établissements publics, ainsi qu'aux organismes bénéficiant de leur garantie.” (Article 1, Loi 83-557)

144 Importantly, the 1984 banking law then extended the name to all banks, and thus completed the ‘normalisation’ of legal categories initiated in 1983110.

The mere definition of savings banks as credit institutions raised a number of issues, however. First, did it mean that savings banks would be submitted to standard credit regulations (especially in terms of credit ceilings then in vigor)? Secondly, were their banking operations to be submitted to the banking regulatory authority, the Commission de contrôle des banques like other credit institutions? Those questions were left unanswered in the design of the law111, which reflected the ambiguity of the government’s view about the role and function of savings banks within the French credit system. In particular, the issue of whether savings banks belonged to the public or private sphere was not solved – in fact it was not even raised during the debates over the law.

The issue was not solved until 1999, when a second major reform transformed French savings banks into a cooperative network – thus submitting their governance to the legal status of cooperatives112, while most aspects pertaining to banking activities fell under commercial law113. The cooperative status seemed to stem directly from their fulfiling national interest missions114. But some observers and actors of the banking regime disagreed. For instance, Senator Marini voiced his preference for listing savings banks’ stocks, like their Italian counterparts115; and Jacques Mayoux, a French banker, said that privatisation would have been a better solution, since it would have allowed mergers with commercial banks and equity financing on the market116.

110 However, de Juvigny argued that the 1984 banking law achieved only “moderate universality” – since it did not apply to the CDC or the postal financial services, and since certain categories of banks (mainly the cooperative ones) did not fall under the regulatory authorities for access to ownership (de Juvigny, 1990). 111 See also Cluzel (1984), p.120, for similar remarks. 112 which is the Loi 47-1775 du 10 septembre 1947. 113 Loi 66-537 du 24 juillet 1966 sur les sociétés commerciales. 114 Article 1 of the law read: “Le réseau des caisses d'épargne remplit des missions d'intérêt général” 115 See “Caisses d’Épargne: une réforme insuffisante”, in Option Finance, July 5th, 1999. 116 See Option Finance, january 18, 1999.

145 • Italy

In the Italian case, the statutory issue was even more salient. The 1990 law transformed the Casse di Risparmio in joint-stock companies, whose activities fell under the regulatory regime in vigor for commercial banks (and integrated in the 1993 Testo unico). However, they were 100% owned by a new entity set up by the law, the Fondazioni. These were public, non-profit entities owned by a variety of actors, among whom local and regional governments who had representatives on their board. Thus there was a certain ambiguity, which fed an intense academic and political debate on the public or private nature of the Fondazioni / Casse di risparmio entities. A closer look at the literature, however, reveals that those discussions revolved almost exclusively around the Fondazioni, not the Casse di Risparmio. The issue was not whether the Casse di risparmio would remain within the (public) orbit of the Fondazioni, but rather when were they to be privatised. This was a clear objective for policy-makers. As one Italian interviewee put it,

Two operations were necessary: make banks become private in ownership; and make banks become private in behaviour.117

And in assessing the impact of the 1990 law twelve years later, another actor of the reform said:

The process has worked, since banks have become subject to markets, to market rules.118

Besides, it is important to note that the 1990 law concerned savings banks as well as Istituti di credito pubblico, mentioned above – which clearly gave a sign as to where the law-makers situated the savings banks: in the group previously within the public domain, but that was to pass to the private one.

117 The same interviewee added, however, that these two operations were to be assumed by two distinct authorities: on the one hand, the government (through the Law Amato Carli); on the other hand, the central bank (through, in particular, the shift from activity regulation and regulation at entry with prudential regulation). (Interview, June 2002). 118 Interview, September 2002.

146 The Italian situation was thus both clearer and more obscure than the French one. It was clearer because savings banks had the status of commercial banks. It was more obscure in the sense that their ownership was still public. But this issue was intertwined with the pending re-organisation of the sector, which was pushed forward by subsequent reforms.

5.2.2 The re-organisation of the sector

The statutory reform was important symbolically; it was also instrumental in facilitating the re-organisation of the banking sector, the second core element of regulatory reform in both countries.

• Italy

In Italy, the separation of ownership and control (law Amato-Carli) and the transformation of ownership rights into shares that could be sold (in the future) on the market was a clear first step in that direction. At first, the Fondazioni were to hold their 100% stake in savings banks. But this “neutrality” was the outcome of a political agreement passed in Parliament; originally the government’s idea was to keep open the possibility for the Fondazioni to sell shares whenever they wanted119. Law-makers could not, however, move towards a real privatisation of savings banks120. As one of the key actors of the reform said121, another idea that circulated before the reform was the attribution of all shareholdings of the savings banks to the Treasury. But this solution was constitutionally difficult, and politically impossible, as we will see in the next part.

The status-quo did not last long: a law passed in 1994 lifted the ban on the sale of the savings banks’ shares owned by the Fondazioni, and a directive enacted a few months later by the Minister of the Treasury, Lamberto Dini (who had been one of the vice-governors of the Banca d’Italia in the previous years), from then on called the “Dini directive”122, created fiscal incentives for divestiture.

119 Hence the difference between the original design of law as presented in Parliament in October 1988, and the final text as passed by the Parliament in July 1990. 120 Interview with policy-makers, May 2002. 121 Interview, May 2002. 122 Direttiva n. Ottobre 18, 1994.

147 In particular, it exempted from capital gain taxation123 those Foundations that accepted to give up a controlling stake (50% of shares) in Casse di Risparmio.

The 1998 Ciampi-Visco law then institutionalised these incentives but put a time limit on them: they would hold for another four years after the law was enacted, but would decrease over the next three years (article 4a). After seven years the specific fiscal regime would be ended. Importantly, the 1998 law created fiscal sanctions as well: if the controlling stake was not given up within seven years, the Foundations would lose their non-commercial status (which entailed a favourable fiscal regime, reaffirmed in article 3a of the law) (art.4b). Thus the reforms of the 1990s showed consistency in pursuing the restructuring of the sector, but also showed a gradual shift from neutrality and incentives to sanctions, which reflected the slow moving of the Fondazioni in selling their shares in the savings banks (as we will see in the next chapter).

• France

In France, re-organising the sector was also an important item on the reform agenda. But it took a different direction: the French law-makers wanted to push for endogenous restructuring, meaning mergers and acquisitions among savings banks themselves rather than between savings and other banks. Thus the 1983 law did not clarify ownership as the 1990 law in Italy did. Rather, it emphasised the re-organisation of the savings banks sector, with the strengthening of a “tête de réseau” (network head) embodied in the Centre National des Caisses d’Épargne et de Prévoyance (CENCEP – which later became the Caisse Nationale des Caisses d’Épargne, or CNCE). The 1983 reform also created regional re-financing centres, the Sociétés Régionales de Financement (or SOREFI). This marked the beginning of the rationalisation of the network. A further step was taken with the decree of June 20, 1985124, which organised the “financial de-centralisation” of savings banks125: indeed, about 200 billion FF coming from “banalised” financial products were transferred from the Caisse des dépôts to the SOREFI created in 1983.

123 The capital gains tax was introduced by the law n.102 of 1991 – one year after capital liberalisation, and amounted at first to 25% of plusvalues. 124 Décret n. du 20 juin 1985. 125 According to Antoine Moster (2000, p.48).

148 But the strongest encouragement for restructuring came with a law of 1991 which dissolved the SOREFI and gave fiscal incentives to those savings banks who decided to merge. As will be shown in the next chapter, the 1991 reform was a decisive step in the re-organisation of the sector. Within a few years, the number of savings banks shrunk from 450 to a little more than 40 (today they are 33).

Again, if the purpose of reform was similar in the two countries, the changes actually took a different direction: in Italy, the Amato Carli law and its sequels were clearly aimed at transforming the major savings banks into the backbone of a re-organised banking system; in France, it was aimed at strengthening the sector itself.

5.2.3 Market de-segmentation and the path towards operational parity

The statutory normalisation of savings banks and the sectoral re-organisation went hand in hand with a third major regulatory change: the enlargement of savings banks’ operational scope. This was, again, a common element to both countries. The only difference was in the degree of change, and this can be attributed to different starting situations: in France savings banks were as of 1983 still very limited in the number of credit operations they could undertake, and the types of clientele whose needs they were authorised to address. By contrast, the limitations put on Italian savings banks’ operations (in particular the ban on medium and long-term lending) were common to all “commercial banks”, and there was no restriction attached to savings banks in terms of authorised business.

• France

In France, the 1983 reform authorised savings banks to pursue three basic banking services identified by law-makers: receiving deposits, lending, and providing means of payment126. However the very first article of the law restricted the scope of savings banks to collecting savings, and specified that they were non-profit organisations.

126 Articles 1, 2, 3 and 4 of Loi 84-46.

149 Interestingly, this limitation, far from vanishing in the following years, was instead reinforced by the legislators127. But a few years later, with the June 17th, 1987 law128, the Caisses d’épargne were authorised to lend to small and medium enterprises. At the beginning, a ceiling was put on the amount savings banks could lend (equal to 30% of total assets) to private firms. The ceiling was set for a transitory period of three years129 but was renewed in 1991130.

These limitations might be interpreted as a compromise between savings banks top managers and regulators; they guaranteed that most of the lending would go to public entities or to individual households, while giving time to savings banks to prepare for being competitive in the new markets. In fact, the 1983 parliamentary proceedings reveal that the crust of the debate revolved around these two issues: namely, allowing savings banks to operate on several markets, and to propose several new products; and at the same time guaranteeing the permanence of lending to local governments within the Minjoz contingents. The proceedings clearly show this tension between normalisation and particularism131. Diverging positions on these two issues also constitute the main differences between the wordings of the text of the law as voted by the Parliament and the wording of the law proposal132, introduced a year earlier.

127 In 1991 the following paragraph was added to the initial wordings of Article 1: “[les caisses d’épargne] utilisent leurs ressources relevant de l'activité bancaire et commerciale du réseau au profit notamment du financement de l'économie locale et sociale en appui aux collectivités territoriales.” (Art. 1&2, Loi 91-635 du 11 Juillet 1991). 128 Loi 87-416 du 17 Juin 1987. 129 Art.50,Loi 87-416 du 17 Juin 1987. 130 Art.2, Loi 91-635 du 11 Juillet 1991. It is interesting to note that the Parliamentary majority which voted the text in 1987 was different from the one who approved the 1983 reform and, further, that it had won the elections on a pro-business agenda. 131 In his report to the Assemblée Nationale, Mr. Taddei noted that the article 2 aimed at normalising savings banks as well: “il s’agit de donner au réseau une pleine capacité financière débouchant sur une banalisation relative et progressive des règles de tutelle et de contrôle pour une partie de la collecte de fonds et des emplois qui en résultent” (rapport Assemblée Nationale, n.1021, pp.22.) 132 Under the French Constitution, the law-making initiative belongs both to the Government (projets de loi) and to members of Parliament (propositions de loi). The practice, however, has shown a domination of laws initiated by the Government. Interestingly, in the present case the law originated in a proposal presented by Mr. Taddei, MP belonging to the governmental majority. It is likely, however, in this case as in many others, that the government simply aimed at reinforcing its legitimacy within the Parliament and thus “let” an MP introduce a government-promoted initiative. This is the interpretation of Cluzel (1984) as well.

150 As per the enlargement of activities, the initial proposal set out to limit deposits to individuals and non-profit entities; and lending to their depositors and to local governments and entities guaranteed by them. During the first discussion at the Senate Finance Committee, Senators expressed their concern towards what they saw as overly strict limits on two counts: on the deposits side, they saw the risks of excluding important potential depositors – such as the entities in charge of social housing (Sociétés anonymes de HLM). These risks were underlined in the report written by Senator Cluzel133, whose conclusions are synthesised in Cluzel (1984). The Senate thus proposed to enlarge the group of potential depositors (replacing “non-profit entities” by “entities not mainly involved in industry and trade”), which the government accepted134.

Regarding the Minjoz contingent, the 1983 law opted for the status quo. As Cluzel himself says, the last section of Article 1 (regarding this very issue) was the embodiment of such a critical mission135. The discussion of the public mission fulfiled by savings banks extended to the issue of definition as well: it explains why, for instance, during the first discussion of the law proposal in full session (séance publique) of the Senate, two amendments proposed by Senators belonging to different parties (one from the right-wing opposition, the other from the left-wing governmental coalition), attempted at including those dimensions in the very definition of the savings banks as in Article 1136.

133 Rapport à la Commission des Finances du Sénat, n.342. 134 Interestingly, after accepting the changes to the original wordings the Minister precised that the formula proposed by the Senate would not include private firms, even though the latter’s borrowings could be guaranteed by local governments since a law passed in 1982 – another evidence that savings banks were to remain within the public realm. The warning to exclude private firms from savings banks’ clients was repeated several time by the government’s representative. 135 Article 1, “bien que non indispensable, permettait cependant de confirmer la vocation traditionnelle et la mission première des caisses d’épargne dont les prêts sont destinés notamment aux collectivités publiques et aux organismes bénéficiant de leur garantie.” (Cluzel 1984, p.119) 136 Amendment n.58 suggested to define savings banks as “établissement à but non lucratif reconnu d’utilité publique”; and amendment n.44 added to the original definition the words “investis d’une mission de service public”. The juridical consequences of such changes were minor.

151 Thus two important notions coexisted in the 1983 law: first, savings banks were (finally) to be recognised operational parity with other banks, with less limitations than before regarding products or markets. Secondly, savings banks were still conceived as a peculiar kind of credit institutions, given their non-profit nature, their ‘historical mission’, and their functional role within the credit system. In the following years the regulatory authorities did put these principles into practice: authorisation to offer checking accounts (1983), to propose credit cards (1986) and to lift the ban to lend to firms (1991).

The 1999 law built on the 1983 reform, confirming the specificities of savings banks business scope, and further detailing the specific missions assigned to them, in particular financing social housing and local economic development137. The specificity of the Livret A was re-asserted as well. In addition, the first article specified that savings banks fulfil the general interest. The specific scope of the savings banks (referred to in the text of the 1999 law as a single network, rather than a group of individual banks as was the case in the previous legislative texts) is enforced through the mandatory138 funding of local development projects (called in the law ‘projets d’économie locale et sociale’, henceforth PELS), to which a part of the benefits goes. This amount should not be less than a third of the total benefits after tax. Simultaneously, though, the ceilings previously put on lending to private firms had disappeared from the law.

137 “Il contribue à la protection de l'épargne populaire, à la collecte des fonds destinés au financement du logement social, à l'amélioration du développement économique local et régional, particulièrement dans le domaine de l'emploi et de la formation, et à la lutte contre l'exclusion bancaire et financière de tous les acteurs de la vie économique, sociale et environnementale grâce en particulier aux fonds collectés sur le livret A dont la spécificité est maintenue.” (art.1, Loi 99-352 du 25 Juin 1999). 138 “Les missions définies à l'article 1er de la présente loi ainsi que les projets d'économie locale et sociale doivent présenter à la fois un intérêt en termes de développement local ou d'aménagement du territoire ou de protection de l'environnement et un intérêt en termes de développement social ou d'emploi. Chaque caisse d'épargne et de prévoyance tient compte des orientations définies par la Fédération nationale des caisses d'épargne et de prévoyance pour le choix des projets d'économie locale et sociale sur son ressort territorial ou pour apporter sa contribution à des actions régionales ou nationales entreprises par le réseau. Les projets d'économie locale et sociale financés par les caisses d'épargne et de prévoyance font l'objet d'une annexe détaillée au rapport annuel de la Caisse nationale des caisses d'épargne et de prévoyance.” (art.6, Loi 99-352)

152 • Italy

De-segmentation was less of a concern in the 1990 reform in Italy – but then savings banks were already on operational parity with commercial banks, as mentioned above. The existing regulatory segmentation, which distinguished short-term versus medium and long-term lending, and lending to large firms versus lending to households and SMEs, had been loosened in regulatory practice (see previous chapter) and did not discriminate savings banks from other banking institutions. The de-segmentation that followed (especially in 1993 with the Testo unico, which allowed all banks to lend both short and medium term) concerned all banks as well, and did not distinguish legal categories. Article 10 of the 1993 Testo Unico was straightforward, in that regard: it defined banks as firms (“a bank has the character of a firm”), whose scope is to collect deposits and lend money139.

5.3 The process of change: the role of ideas, interests and institutions

In both countries, a single process of change can be identified; despite shifts, turns, persisting ambiguities and contradictions, the 1999 and the 1983 reforms in France and the 1990 and 1998 reforms in Italy show an underlying, consistent idea of what savings banks should be. But the concrete “policy outcomes” were variable and incremental, and the origins of change were overlapping. In order to trace the causes of regulatory change, it is therefore necessary to decompose the process of change and analyse its different layers separately140. To do so it is possible to identify (i) the broader context that emphasised the need for adjustment; (ii) the debates surrounding the reform and (iii) the policy and institutional context which shaped the reform pattern.

139 “La raccolta di risparmio tra il pubblico e l'esercizio del credito costituiscono l'attività bancaria. Essa ha carattere d'impresa.” ($1, art.10, Decr.Leg. September 1st, 1983, n.385) 140 A few scholars have recently put renewed emphasis on theorising process of change: see Blyth, 2002 and Pierson, 2000.

153 The hypotheses explored here are the following (see also chapter 2): (i) faced with external pressures to adjust, savings banks’ top management in both countries transformed this necessity into an opportunity for pushing their own agenda through regulatory reforms; (ii) the divergent policy outcomes arise less from the “rigidity” of political institutions than to the peculiar socio-economic inheritance of savings banks that constrained their managers’ modernisation designs.

5.3.1 The role of exogenous shocks and of persisting market failures

As argued in chapter 4, the macroeconomic shocks of the 1970s and the failure of administered credit to mitigate their impact on the financial and real sectors dramatically altered the “matrix of constraints and incentives" faced by banks in both France and Italy (and, arguably, other European countries). At the outset of the 1980s, both economies were characterised by: (i) rising inflation and unemployment (stagflation); (ii) severe balance of payment problems; (iii) external constraint on economic policy – especially capital flows and speculative attacks on the French Franc and the Italian Lira. As seen in the previous chapter, the macroeconomic policy framework was radically transformed during the 1970s. First, monetary policy shifted from an accommodating tool targeting monetary growth to an autonomous, restrictive policy aimed at bringing inflation down through higher interest rates. Simultaneously, expansionary fiscal policies were progressively abandoned, given both the external constraint and rising public debt, which, in the context of positive (high) real interest rates, made public spending very costly.

In summary, strong and persistent exogenous shocks141 durably modified the macroeconomic policies of France and Italy and, simultaneously, led first to a strengthening, then to the gradual dismantling of state-administered credit. By 1982 in France, and 1982-84 in Italy (with the successive Piani Sportelli), it became clear that credit market de-segmentation would continue. Together with positive real interest rates, the increased role given to the stock-market in allocating credit, the diminution of inflation, and the diffusion of technological innovations led bankers to change their expectations concerning, in particular, future competition in the various segments of the banking market.

141 Of course, as emphasised in chapter 4, exogenous shocks were partly the results of endogenous contradictions in the post-war accumulation regime, as regulationists have observed.

154 Similar shifts in expectations were brought about by regulatory reform at the European level. As seen in the previous sections, the First Banking Directive, in 1977, first laid out the alternative foundations for banking regulations in Europe: shift from structural to prudential regulation, market de-segmentation, liberalisation of entry (especially for European banks desirous to operate in other countries than their country of origin), homogeneisation of legal categories. Those principles formed the pillar of banking regulatory reform throughout Europe in the 1980s.

Together with those changes in their macro and policy environment, French and Italian savings banks suffered from problems of their own, which increased the emphasis on the need to change. French savings banks were small, mono-product institutions, plagued with labour-management conflicts (1979 and 1980 saw a record number of strikes in the sector; and a well-publicised essay, in 1978, identified the “privileged” status of savings banks staff as one of the “scandals” of “corporatist France”)142. When it became clear that the State would not replenish savings banks’ equity, savings banks’ under-capitalisation became problematic in the prospective of greater competition and prudential regulation143.

Italian savings banks suffered comparable problems: insufficient equity levels, blurred ownership and governance, and a segmented market. The size of equity was indeed often used in public debates on Italian banking, and the argument went well beyond the necessity to comply with international prudential regulation, in particular the ratios set up by the Bank for International Settlements144. Size was seen as a prerequisite to face greater competition. This was a point repeated by interviewees as well. As one of them said, “it was a question of life or death”145.

The variety of banking categories was not perceived to be a problem per se. Interestingly, neither was, at first, the efficiency of savings banks. In many instances Governor Ciampi opposed the simplistic view that Italian banks were less efficient than their European counterparts146. Efficiency did become a problem later on (after the Amato-Carli law was passed).

142 De Clozets, 1978. 143 Prudential regulation building, as mentioned earlier, on patrimonial ratios to measure the solidity of single banks and, therefore, their capacity to operate certain business activities. 144 With the 1988 Basel agreement. 145 Interview, November 2002. 146 See in particular Ciampi (1982b), where the governor refers to a OECD study to relativise claims on the inefficiency of Italian banks.

155 In fact, several observers note that the failure of the 1994 Dini directive to encourage a sale of banking shares by the Fondazioni was due to the low market value of savings banks as compared with their accounting value147. It was not a fiscal problem, but an economic one: the low market value reflected the low profitability of CR148. But one interviewee turned the argument on its head: the Fondazioni did not sell their shares because the markets were low and there were no potential buyers… Whatever the interpretation, in this case, efficiency was seen as instrumental for the privatisation of banks, not as a problem per se.

This combination of pressures – exogenous shocks, shifts in macroeconomic policy, European regulatory reforms, and internal problems – formed the backdrop of regulatory reform in both countries. In fact most interviewees, both in France and in Italy, underlined the “naturalness” of the reforms. That is, in their view the legal reforms brought a solution to the “problems” of savings banks (low equity, blurred property rights) in line with savings banks’ “tradition”. This harmonious reconstruction of past events should be taken with caution. First, interviewees often show a tendency to offer re-collections that fit their actual positions/ideas. In this particular case, respondents at the head of savings banks or within regulatory positions at the time of the reform might simply want to give the impression that they did nothing wrong – in fact, did nothing but stick to the natural “course of history”. Secondly, we all have tendencies to retain the outcome of the process as the logical or natural one – forgetting all the twists and turns that occurred all along the process.

More importantly, the nature of the specific problems faced by savings banks, as well as the peculiar context that made them salient do not explain, by themselves, the outcome of the reform or the reform process. How do we understand, for instance, that new ownership took the form, in Italy, of privatisation and in France of the creation of a cooperative group? To get a more comprehensive understanding of the reform process and outcome, it is necessary, therefore, to pay attention to the formation of a policy consensus and to the political dynamics that led to the 1983 law in France and the 1990 law in Italy.

147 This point was also made during the parliamentary debates around the Ciampi-Visco reform. 148 See GU n.322, 1990

156 5.3.2 The resistible rise of a consensus about banking and state intervention

Before addressing the causal role played by ideas in the process of regulatory change, it is important to understand what those ideas were at the core of the reform in both countries and where they came from. Of course, such important reforms contained or made explicit a full range of ideas of all sorts. We can distinguish two sets of ideas related to two major issues: the role of the state in the economy and the nature of the banking firm. I am arguing here that the regulatory shifts of the 1980s and 1990s in the French and Italian savings banks sectors reflected a previous transformation of these two core ideas within the policy circles. These core ideas are themselves surrounded by several policy ideas: privatisation, de-regulation on the “state” side, and statutory normalisation, market de-segmentation on the “bank” side. It is necessary to distinguish between these two strands of ideas (primary and secondary) because, if the latter were still hotly debated during the 1980s (witness the debate in Italy around the issue of the public or private nature of the Fondazioni), the former were already soundly established and rooted in the academic and regulatory circles.

As emphasised in the first part, the 1983 law in France was still ambiguous as to where the savings banks should fit in terms of ownership: public or private, the issue was still open during most of the 1980s. Indeed, the critical issue spurring from the 1983 law and from the surrounding parliamentary debates was that of the adjustment of the Caisses to an evolving economic reality while not questioning the historical ‘mission’ and, above all, the role played by the Caisses in providing credit to local governments. But this ambiguity did rely on a growing consensus on what savings banks should be allowed to do as banks. Several times during the debate the assertion was made that “banks were firms like all others” despite the specific additional characteristics inherited by savings banks from their past. This was the sense of the intervention of the Minister for Finance (Jacques Delors) at the Senate in December 1982149. It was also re-iterated several times by the government representative at the meetings of the Senate Finance Committee, as well as by the Rapporteurs at the Senate and the National Assembly.

149 See JO des Assemblées, n.2454.

157 These orientations were shared by senior staff at savings banks as well. Those ideas stood at the heart of the “Ancian Report”150, which was written by a working group set up jointly by the Union Nationale des Caisses d’Épargne de France (UNCEF) and the Caisse des Dépôts et Consignations. Interestingly, the report, while stressing the peculiarities and the crucial role of savings banks in “directing the country’s savings towards priority objectives”151, also asked the permission for savings banks to operate fully as “family banks” – in essence, the members of the Ancian working group pledged for the lift of the ban on many of the deposit and lending instruments available to commercial banks, and on the means of payment as well. So both the Ancian working group and the 1983 law-makers seemed to share the same normative view on banks: namely, that they were doing a business inherently private, and that they should compete with each other.

This should not come as a surprise, since the first part of the 1983 law got its inspiration mainly from the Ancian Report. This was confirmed by interviews with the main actors behind the policy change. In summary, all interviewees who were working in the savings banks in the early eighties confirmed that they saw as “inevitable” the shift towards fully- fledged banks operating within a competitive market. The same view was held by policy-makers.

As for the ideas on the role of the State, evidence is more ambiguous. In 1981 a Socialist party-led majority won the Parliamentary elections, with an agenda centred on the “break” with capitalism. During the first 100 days in power, the new majority indeed launched a number of reforms that ended up in considerably extending the State’s reach on the economy (in particular through a wave of nationalisations). But two years later, after the famous U-turn operated by President Mitterrand, the policy direction radically changed. It is in this context that the 1983 reform of savings banks took shape, reflecting the ambiguous direction.

In Italy, the idea of the bank as a firm was not popular among politicians, at least until the mid-1980s. In 1982, the then central bank governor, Carlo Azeglio Ciampi, argued publicly that Italian banks were not that inefficient compared to other systems. In fact, he argued, quoting a comparison by the OECD, while spreads in Italy might be large, the margin of intermediation was lower in Italy than in the UK, but higher than Germany.

150 UNCEF/CDC, Pour un redéploiement du réseau Caisse d’Épargne – Caisse des Dépôts et consignations, December 1981. 151 Ibidem, p.2

158 In the late 1970s, all banks underwent a compression of their revenues because of growing competition by public bonds and quantitative limits on credit expansion (“il massimale”).

The private-public debate stood at the core of three law proposals presented to the Parliament by various political groups in the late 1970s. A first one, presented in February 1977 by several MPs belonging to the Partito Socialista Italiano152, aimed at giving local governments power over savings banks direction and management. This was a clear attempt at rooting savings banks in the public realm, in a definitive fashion153. That proposal was “re-proposed” a year later, before the Senate, with the same success (it was never debated)154. A second law proposal was presented in the Parliament in 1981, this time from MPs belonging to the Communist Party155. This proposal, too, aimed at creating strong organic links between savings banks and local governments, even though it maintained most of the existing governance mechanisms (in contrast to the previous proposal)156. A third proposal, contemporary to the first one, was presented by deputies belonging to the Christian Democrats Party in 1977157. This proposal differed from the other two in that it concerned all “public” banks (that is, savings banks, BIN and Istituti di Credito Pubblico), and tackled another issue: that of the ‘politicisation’ of those banks – which was quite ironical given Christian-Democrats’ presence in credit institutions. The goal set out in the proposal was to de-politicise public banks through the strengthening of monitoring and supervision mechanisms (with, for instance, the creation of an ‘elders’council’).

152 Proposta di legge Signorile, Colucci e altri presentata nella seduta del 24 febbraio 1977, recante Modifiche all’ordinamento delle Casse di Risparmio e dei Monti di credito su pegno di 1a categoria, Camera dei Deputati, Legislatura VII, Atti Parlamentari, Documenti – Disegni di Legge – Relazioni n.1205. 153 According to Clarich (1984), this proposal bore the risk of putting an end to savings banks’ autonomy as well. In that sense, the proposal shows a strange filiation with the law proposal presented by Giulio Tremonti twenty five years later for the Fondazioni… 154 Disegno di legge Cipellini, Scevarolli e altri comunicato alla Presidenza il 22 novembre 1979, recante Modifiche all’ordinamento delle Casse di Risparmio e dei Monti di credito su pegno di 1a categoria, Senato della Repubblica, Legislatura VIII, Atti parlamentari, Disegni di Legge – Relazioni – Documenti, n.503. 155 Proposta di legge D’Alema, Alinovi e altri presentata nella seduta del 14 luglio 1981, recante Nuove norme concernenti l’ordinamento e le funzioni delle Casse di Risparmio e dei Monti di Credito su Pegno di prima categoria, Camera dei Deputati, Legislatura VIII, Atti Parlamentari, Disegni di Legge – Relazioni – Documenti, n.2712. 156 Clarich (1984) emphasised the difficulty to reconcile the principle of linking savings banks and local government with the goal of giving a major operational flexibility to savings banks (Clarich, 1984, p.134). 157 Disegno di legge Grassini, Bartolomei e altri comunicato alla Presidenza il 4 ottobre 1977, sulla Amministrazione degli Istituti di Credito di Diritto Pubblico e nomine relative, Senato della Repubblica, Legislatura VII, Atti parlamentari, Disegni di legge – Relazioni – Documenti, n.91.

159 A common feature to all three proposals was the emphasis given to governance mechanisms in reaching the reform’s objectives. More interestingly, though, is the fact that none of those proposals foresaw the privatisation of public banks – or even, at least, the possibility of opening up public banks to private interests and purposes. But the failure of these proposals to gather consensus and eventually become law testifies the difficulty to reform public banks in the other direction as well. In other words, politically, the situation was stalled, and the predominance of “public” conceptions of banks did not translate into legal reforms.

At least, however, those proposals succeeded in encouraging savings banks to elaborate a common position. The opening statement at the twelfth national congress in Bologna in 1977 was a direct reply to the socialist proposal: savings banks firmly opposed any organic linkages between them and local governments. Instead, savings banks re-affirmed their claim to be put on operational parity with commercial banks158. The public horizon of savings banks remained, in their eyes, justified, but only as a correction to the “excesses that a market economy can lead to, so as to ensure the balance between […] the security of deposits and the support to those subjects enduring inflation159.”

This clear position expressed by savings banks gave rise, according to Clarich, to the “second phase” of the debate about public banks, as the same author calls it (Clarich, 1984), in which the central bank played an important role. Indeed, the conception of banks as private firms took root at Banca d’Italia in the 1970s, under the last years of Guido Carli’s governorship. The yearly reports of the central bank give a good overview of these changes in the institution’s thoughts about banks and the banking market during that period. In the 1971 annual report, for instance, Governor Carli insisted on the public nature of the banking system160. In the 1973 and 1974 reports, the focus had shifted to the efficiency of the banking system as a whole. Later on, the governorship of Carlo Azeglio Ciampi (the actual President of the Republic) was marked by the same emphasis on efficiency of the banking sector, which implicitly relied on the idea that banks were to operate as private firms.

158 According to Clarich (1984), this means that “The acceptance of the challenge of the market and of competition justifies the call for a revision of the existing regime, where it either favours or impedes the category.” (Clarich, 1984, p.137) 159 Final motion to the XIIth national congress, cited by Clarich (1984, p.137). 160 “Considerazioni finali”, in Banca d’Italia (1971), Relazione annuale.

160 But this did not entail any plea for the reform of the system from the part of the Central Bank. The Governor made this point repeatedly over the years: in 1980, for instance, he wrote that “public and private banks are a given in our credit system, which chose the firm as a model for the exercise of banking activities”161. Two years later, in a conference on savings banks, he made this eloquent remark: “in savings banks publicness is where it is”162. Again, in the 1982 annual report of Banca d’Italia, the Governor repeated the same notion163. The official position of the regulatory body was thus to re-assert that banks were above all banking firms, and should operate as firms; but this should not entail a break from the actual system.

Two White Books on public banks were released by the Central Bank in 1981164 and 1988165, which synthesised this view and translated it into broad policy ideas. The 1981 White Book began with an analysis of the banking situation that emphasised its “private firm-like” aspects, in particular the facts that on the operational side there were fewer and fewer differences between public and private banks, that there was no specific banking activity that could be linked to the public nature of banks166, that non-banking purposes were doomed to disappear167. As a consequence, the Banca d’Italia clearly set the stage for the pursuit, from the part of public banks, of business goals similar to those of private, commercial banks168. Furthermore, the 1981 White Book suggested that the most appropriate form of organisation for banks was the joint-stock company169. The diagnosis offered by the central bank was, therefore, unambiguous; this was not the case of the prognosis, in which most of the previous discussion was left aside.

161 “Considerazioni finali”, in Banca d’Italia (1980), Relazione annuale. 162 “Non si ha da far distinzione tra enti pubblici e enti privati ma piuttosto tra aspetti pubblici e aspetti privati, relativamente al medesimo ente. Nelle CR la pubblicità c’è dove c’è: essa non s’addice alla loro attività di impresa che per sua natura neutra ed assoggettata al diritto privato.” (Ciampi, 1982b, p.33) 163 “La redditività e l’efficienza sono comunque criteri fondamentali validi anche per questi intermediari, in quanto connaturati all’attività commerciale intrapresa, pur nell’ambito di uno scopo non identificato in via immediata nel lucro” (Ciampi, 1982b, p.31). 164 Banca d’Italia (1981), Ordinamenti degli enti pubblici creditizi; Analisi e prospettive, Roma: Banca d’Italia. 165 Banca d’Italia (1988), 166 “non potendosi individuare un nesso di strumentalità delle operazioni bancarie con speficiche e contingenti finalità pubbliche perseguite dall’ente.” (Ibid., p.7) And, later on, “l’attività bancaria di un ente pubblico è del tutto identica a quella di una banca privata” (Ibid., p.7). 167 “Le finalità extra bancarie sono oggi venute meno o perché direttamente perseguite dallo Stato quali funzioni sociali o perché assorbite dalla tutela del risparmio, che è affidata all’ordinamento bancario nel suo insieme” (Ibid., p.6). 168 “L’organizzazione degli enti pubblici creditizi deve consentire e anzi favorire lo svilupparsi della logica della redditività nell’agire degli organi e nei rapporti tra i medesemi.” (Ibid.,p.7). 169 “Il modello organizzativo più appropriato alle attività imprenditoriali è, nel nostro ordinamento, quello della società di capitali, e la stessa identità d’azione della banca pubblica e della banca privata rende opportuno riferire la struttura a un medesimo modello.” (Ibid., p.8)

161 The authors of the 1981 White Book focused, instead, on the problem of the low levels of equity among public banks and how to solve them. As Revell (1994b) rightly points out, additional capital can come from only two sources: retained earnings added to reserves and fresh capital injections raised on capital markets (or by owners). The authors of the White Book proposed, for those banks which had not been incorporated (and thus for savings banks), to create, alongside the banks’ equity (fondo di dotazione), an additional fund formed with the subscription of special shares issued by the banks (azioni di risparmio), which would not bear any claim on the banks’ management. Even more obscure is the part dedicated to changes in banks’ governance mechanisms, which were conceived to give more room to new stakeholders. After reviewing alternative solutions (among them a strict separation between ownership and management, which was to come back with the 1990 law), the authors recommended170 to keep the ‘firms’ as they were, with minority shares eventually given to financial institutions. That configuration would, according to the authors, ensure banks’ corporate development without running the risks of being too exposed to market forces171.

As we can see, the central bank did not come up with a clear roadmap, despite a seemingly unambiguous diagnosis and the recognition that public banks were in all aspects similar to commercial banks. The 1981 White Book was, nevertheless, important in that it was to be the official position of Bankitalia for the successive years (until the 1988 White Book). It was important also because it faithfully reflected the views held by the Banca d’Italia’s top executives. In fact, it was written by the Governor’s closest collaborators. Why this ‘timidity’ (or lack of imagination) in the prognosis? One interviewee, who was at Banca d’Italia at that time, said that the White Book, and the subsequent inaction of Banca d’Italia towards the reform of public banks, simply reflected the Governor’s political shrewdness; in other words, it fit the strategy then pursued by the Governor, who did not want to appear to take sides in a political contest.

170 This option was presented as the one best preserving the local characteristic of public banks, or “la caratteristica e i limiti di organismi legati forse troppo rigidamente all’ambito territoriale originario.” (ibid., p.12). 171 Dall’instaurarsi di questi rapporti potrebbero derivare più ampie possibilità di diversificazione degli impieghi e dei rischi, contribuendo anche per questa via alla solidità complessiva del sistema.” (p.12).

162 The 1988 White Book was very different from its predecessor. But it was made public at the time when discussions over the reform, between savings banks and the Minister of Treasury (Giuliano Amato), were already under way. Analysing the motives behind Banca d’Italia’s cautious behaviour is beyond the scope of this chapter. Suffice to say here that the two White Books both revealed the fact that top central bank officials were convinced of the “private business” nature of banking at least as early as 1981; and that, at the same time, they would not be among the forces of change to put those ideas into practice.

Later on, the reception of the 1990 law was quite positive, as shown by the introductory remarks by several directors of savings banks at the 65th world savings day. This reaction marked a clear change from the past. Until the late 1980s, privatisation was not only out of question, it was a “non problem”, as Cariplo’s president (and president of the ACRI) then declared (Ferrari, 1985). We can also use here a counterfactual: the mere fact that the savings banks did not oppose the 1990 reform through legal means is indicative. Indeed, by contrast, the Fondazioni did not hesitate to resort to the administrative courts in 1994, against the Dini directive, and more recently, in 2002, against the reform designed by Minister Tremonti. The “welcome” given to the Amato Law in 1990 was also emphasised by Clarich (1998).

By the time the reform process started, in both countries there was a broad consensus about the future of savings banks on the one hand, and the role of the state as a regulator on the other hand. But ideas do not have the power to impose by themselves. Why did the ideas pushed forward by regulators and savings banks’ top management in France and Italy become law? To understand this last aspect of regulatory change, one should consider the political dynamics at play in both countries at the time of the reform.

5.3.3 Seizing the political window of opportunity

Regulatory change took place, in the two countries, at a time of profound and rapid political change. As mentioned above, the context of the 1983 reform in France was very peculiar. The Socialist government went to power in 1981 on a left-wing platform, characterised by ambitious plans to reform the economy.

163 The first year of the Mitterrand presidency was characterised by a wave of nationalisations – especially nationalisations of banks - unprecedented since the immediate post-war period172; reforms of the labour market; and two devaluations. However, the policy alternative was quickly defeated by the exchange rate crisis and the failure of the ‘reliance’ in an international context of economic stagnation. Reforms were put to a halt by those within the elite bureaucracy and the Socialist party who convinced Mitterrand that the financial situation was not allowed to continue along the path chosen in 1981. Both the 1981 alternance and its reversal in 1982-83 provided a window of opportunity used by some of savings banks’ top executives. In fact, the Ancian working group was set up in June 1981, just a few months after the election. Both the timing and the explicit mandate of the working group were clearly aimed at influencing the new government, at a time when expectations for reform were high.

In Italy, by contrast, until the early 1990s there was no real change in the political balance of power that opposed, since the postwar period, the Christian Democrats (in power) and the Communist Party (in the opposition). ’s Socialist government, in 1985-86, did seem to represent a political alternative, but its existence relied on tacit support by the Christian Democrats – and the experience did not last long. Its most tangible effect, however, was to bring to power a team of reformists from the North. Only the collapse of the Christian Democrats, triggered by fiscal crisis and the “clean hands” anti-corruption trials of 1992-1993 put an end to the previous political regime and opened the way to regime change. Again, change was brought about through an alliance between key bureaucrats, policy-makers and savings banks officials. Minister Amato set up in 1988 an expert committee composed mainly of academics who had been involved in drafting the central bank’s second white book and linked to the savings banks world.

Here the comparison is enlightening. It tells us that in both cases the regulatory reform occurred at a time when a broad alternative macroeconomic policy had been tried and had come to a halt. Both political alternance and its shortcomings constituted the window of opportunity through which the reform could succeed.

172 loi no 82-155 du 11 février 1982 de nationalisation.

164 5.4 Discussion

5.4.1 Convergence and divergence in the regulatory reform of the savings banks sector in France and Italy

As set out in the introduction to this chapter, when discussing recent trends in national capitalisms most scholars agree on a descriptive hypothesis: that is, there is a certain level of regulatory convergence between national regulatory regimes. The evidence presented here does provide support for this hypothesis, with two important caveats however. First, the data show that if convergence is undoubtedly occurring, divergence is occurring as well and simultaneously. Put differently, convergence is not the only force at play in the regulatory evolution experienced by France and Italy over the past twenty years. It is interesting to note how the public-private equilibrium in savings banks was solved in radically different manners, but at the level of the banking system these two opposite solutions in fact fit within a very similar, if not identical trend.

The other two hypotheses presented in the introduction to this chapter deal with the causes of convergence and divergence. Several scholars claim that while convergence is the outcome of mostly external pressures, namely globalisation and europeanisation, divergence, on the opposite, is the product of the resistence of national institutions to such pressures. Whether convergence wins over divergence, or vice-versa, depends on the relative strength of such institutions – and the sustainability of the situation. In any case the two are elements of the same ‘dialectical movement’: external pressures versus national mobilisation of resources.

The findings presented here do not support that view. They do not deny the role of either globalisation or europeanisation pressures. Rather, those played at most as the “trigger” of change, and at least as a “catalyst” for change, giving an institutional justification to the deep reforms undertaken by governments in both countries. This is exactly the reverse of the thesis that ideas are pure justification of political reactions to exogenous change. Again, I am not claiming here that ideas – especially academic ones - have it all. Far from it. As Lee said, “As a working hypothesis, one might suppose that some modicum of conceptual gloss (or, alternatively, some veneer of empirical verisimilitude) made an idea more attractive to policy-makers than it would otherwise have been” (Lee, 1989, p.144).

165 Moreover, regulatory change was neither the direct translation of business groups’ demands for re-regulation (as claimed, among others, by Soskice 1999), nor the automatic reflection of international pressures, nor the sole expression of insulated elites’ reformist projects. Regulation should not be understood as a functional part of the system; neither should it be viewed as a pure autonomous force.

Mostly, reform resulted from the intertwining of political change, change in economic conditions, and the maturing of specific ideas regarding the nature of banking firms and the role of the state in the economy. This mix of factors bears some resemblance to the Spanish financial reforms analysed by Sofia Perez. According to that author the success of financial reform in Spain depended on the presence of at least three factors: (i) the way identities, networks and conflict among state elites are configured over time; (ii) the extent to which economic change interacted with domestic political conditions to alter the influence of different groups of policy-makers; (iii) the nature of the relationship between the financial sector and non-financial firms. In Spain, regulatory reforms were domestically rooted: “political struggles within the state served as the impetus for regulatory change, changing economic conditions as a facilitating factor, and accommodation with the banking sector as a constant” (Perez, 1997: 43).

A second hypothesis mentioned in the previous chapter is that convergence primarily resides in a change of path, while divergence results from path dependence. But, again, the two cases under study point to a different conclusion. Against path-dependence stands the fact that savings banks in France did not originate in the cooperative movement of the late XIXth century, and never had a similar governance structure to that created in the 1999 law. In fact, many interviewees within the French savings banks (both at the national and local level) pointed to the novelty of such a structure, and to the necessity for them to “learn” how to make it work. Some interviewees also pointed to the Crédit Agricole to show the contrast between the two establishments – the Crédit Agricole being born out of the cooperative governance structure.

Similarly, the creation of Fondazioni in Italy was also a “break” from the “path”, in the sense that for the first time the banking function and the socio- economic redistributive function were clearly separated. Although the Fondazioni were referred to by their creators (and by the savings banks themselves) as a “natural” development, they represented a clear departure from the century-long historical path followed by savings banks in that they asserted the necessity to separate these two functions.

166 5.4.2 Firms-led adjustment?

The evidence presented above shows how savings banks in both countries have been at the origin of regulatory reform and have tried to shape the policy outcome, both through setting the agenda and seizing the window of opportunity offered to them by the changing political environment. Those findings are in line with other works on adjustment processes in France and Italy during the 1980s. Hancké (2002) shows how, after the failure of government-led industrial reforms in the early 1980s, French large firms took the initiative, building on the changing labour and financial environment secured by the state. In that way, large firms could shape their own adjustment pattern. Similarly, Bianchi et al. (1989), dealing with privatisations in Italy, argue that in that country the privatisation process was not driven by political or government programs, but by public enterprises and agencies in order to reorganise and regain autonomy. Companies to be privatised were selected by the state holding management at the IRI, ENI, EFIM – a prerogative recognised by the Parliament.

Those processes were initiated with changes in top management at the IRI and ENI in 1982, the new managers being less disposed than in the past to undertake the variety of “public goals” (rescue of ailing firms, investments in strategic resources, employment protection, development of the Southern regions) that had been assigned to the state holdings and led to a multi-purpose industrial policy. These cases underline the second characteristic of this firm-driven adjustment process: the key role played by top management in the process. In particular, in the case of France and Italy, top managers’ pursuit of managerial autonomy (from state and political directions) drove the process of regulatory change. Top managers, who were a minority in savings banks staff in both countries, built on both the exogenous shocks and the political window of opportunity to impose their views on all other stakeholders: regulators, policy-makers, savings banks employees.

Once the reform was passed, savings banks’ top management could go ahead with their adjustment strategy, and proceed to build strong banking groups able to compete in a de-segmented banking market.

167 168 6. THE CHANGING BOUNDARIES OF COORDINATION:

SAVINGS BANKS’ CORPORATE RESTRUCTURING AND SECTOR ORGANISATION

6.1 Introduction

As seen in chapter 5, the policy reforms of the early 1980s in France and early 1990s in Italy aimed, in part, at re-organising the savings banks sector in both countries, so as to respond more adequately to a rapidly changing environment. Chapter 5 showed how similar concerns, in similar situations, led to diverse adjustment paths, from a policy point of view. It showed, moreover, that such diversity has more to do with peculiar dynamics and long-run historical legacies than to political or institutional path-dependence. This chapter will build on the previous one by looking at the post-reform restructuring path followed by the savings banks sector in the two countries. Then, again, the question addressed by this chapter is twofold: first, is there a diversity; secondly, can one attribute these differences to the distinct paths taken by policy reform evoked in the previous chapter? In other words, does the outcome of the restructuring process, fifteen years or so after the reforms, mirror the outcome of policy reforms? Or are there other factors at play?

This chapter focuses on two related aspects of savings banks transformation during the 1980s and 1990s: the re-structuring of savings banks through (mainly) mergers and acquisitions and the transformation of savings banks’ sector organisation. These two elements could be labelled, respectively, as the “external boundaries” and the “internal density” of savings banks sectors.

169 6.2 Shifts in savings banks’ corporate boundaries

6.2.1 Mergers and acquisitions in the savings banks sector

Both French and Italian savings banks have seen their numbers drop in the eighties and nineties. In France, there were 451 Caisses d’épargne in 1980, a number reduced to 33 by June 2003. In Italy, a same trend towards a drop in numbers can be observed, albeit considerably less pronounced: there were 90 Casse di risparmio in 1980, 65 in 2002173. Although they belong to different scales, which we will analyse later on, changes do follow the same decreasing trend. This trend is continuous over the years; it concerns, moreover, and perhaps more importantly, all categories of banks. The total number of French credit institutions fell from 1975 in 1980 to 879 in 2003; the total number of banks stricto senso174 from 1025 to 479. Similarly, the total number of Italian banks fell from 1250 in 1980 to 841 in 2000. All sectors were affected: commercial banks, cooperatives and savings banks. This is a strong indication that same dynamics were at play in all segments of banking.

Moreover, such a drop in numbers (the IEF 1999 report calls it “natural attrition”) occurred in other European countries as well: the number of Spanish savings banks fell from 81 in 1984 to 51 in 1996; in Austria, the number decreased from 131 to 74 over the same period; and in Norway, there were 133 savings banks in 1996 against 227 in 1984175.

The decreasing number of banks in both countries reveals an intense process of change in ‘corporate boundaries’ through mergers and acquisitions. And this is, again, true for all types of banks176. In France, although similar data is not available, almost 95% of the drop in numbers of savings banks can be attributed to mergers and acquisitions177.

173 Those are the numbers of legal entities, and do not reflect the fact that a) many Italian savings banks belong to banking groups and b) all French savings banks are parts of a single group. Those aspects will be addressed below. 174 Credit institutions include banks and other types of financial intermediaries: investment firms, specialised credit institutions (leasing or factoring firms), and so on. 175 All numbers cited in that paragraph are extracted from the IEF 1999 report. 176 Although it has slowed in the past few years, this trend has not stopped. For instance, the French Banques populaires group recently announced further mergers among its member banks in Alsace, thus bringing the number of Banques populaires to 20 by the end of 2003 (down from 42 in 1970). See “Banques Populaires: le Haut-Rhin va fusionner avec Strasbourg”, in Les Échos, February 2003. 177 According to Lacoue-Labarthe, 2001.

170 This restructuring wave was not the work of, say, an aggressive group of investors desirous of building financial groups. First, mergers were more important than acquisitions178. Secondly, most banking acquisitions that occurred during that period were “friendly” acquisitions179. Thus, one can say that this restructuring wave was the expression of a shared view, at least among banks executives180.

Given the evolution common to all kinds of banks, it is, therefore, possible to accept one hypothesis widely held in the current literature on banking181: that M&As were motivated first and foremost by the felt necessity to increase individual banks size in front of the seemingly irresistible de-segmentation of the banking markets. Other motives are the cession of certain activities by groups willing to specialise in some activities; the strengthening of their presence in “métiers de base” (traditional activities) through acquisitions; internal restructuring to simplify/ adapt internal structures to the evolution of the market/clientele.

As the then future president of the savings banks group, Charles Milhaud, said in 1989:

“We are going to witness, all around the world, the emergence of large groups with specialised branches. Indeed it is not possible for a bank providing, for instance, cashier services, to be competitive, in terms of the financial offer, with a bank that does not provide such service and does not bear network costs.182”

Milhaud added, two years later:

“Such restructuring aims at providing the network’s firms – this term of “firm” is important – with a sufficient size, especially in terms of own funds. This would allow them to ensure the full management of their balance sheet and adjust to the market’s new conditions.183”

178 A merger is an agreement between two legally autonomous economic units that decide to become one; acquisitions, by contrast, denominate the absorption of one firm by another one. 179 Hostile acquisitions, or takeovers, often occur on a market where a firm’s shares can be bought and sold easily. Acquisitions of non-publicly listed firms (which was the case for the majority of Italian banks in the early 1990s) cannot proceed without the decision by equity share holders to actually sell those shares. 180 This is an important restriction, as will be shown below. 181 This is also conformed by recent moves by Banques Populaires, officially motivated by the “need to get out of isolation”. See the previously cited article. 182 Milhaud interviewed by Professions du Sud-Est, September 1989. 183 Charles Milhaud interviewed in Le Méridional, February 27th, 1991.

171 As noted by the Institute of European Finance in its 1993 report, “the bulk of M&A activity in banking to date has been domestic and defensive” (Institute of European Finance, 1993, p.9). In fact, this motivation emerges from interviews with savings banks actors as well. All interviewees having played a direct role in the M&A wave of the 1980s – 1990s (12 interviewees in the two countries) emphasised the “irresistible” character of such moves. As one of the top officials of the Cassa di Risparmio di Roma at that time said:

During that period the liberalisation of bank windows was looming, and I realised one thing: the CR Roma would have become the object of attacks from other banks willing to settle in Rome. Since we could not protect ourselves, we had to expand. I had the idea to make a bank that would have become strong in the Lazio region. The merger with the Banco dello Santo Spirito allowed the CR Roma to strengthen its market shares in Italy184.

But the numbers reported above do not tell the whole story about the restructuring process at work in the two countries. First of all, mergers and acquisitions are but one particular way to restructure business. Other restructuring options (less easy to document) were undertaken by many banks in both France and Italy, two of which can be emphasised: strategic partnerships or alliances and banking groups. In the present cases, mergers and acquisitions were just part of a wider aggregation process that took place within the banking system as a whole. Secondly, not all banks participated into this restructuring or aggregation process: many local banks, especially in Italy, remained at the end of the 1990s both economically and legally independent.

This is not the case of savings banks. In both countries, all savings banks did participate in the aggregation process at play in the banking industry. In other words, all savings banks shifted their corporate boundaries, either in a radical and definitive way (through mergers and acquisitions) or in a softer, looser way (partnerships and alliances). All savings banks, therefore, participated in the emergence of banking groups.

184 Interview, 30.05.03.

172 6.2.2 The constitution of vertically integrated banking groups

• France

All France’s (remaining) savings banks are now part of a single banking group. This group is the outcome of a double aggregation process consisting of, on the one hand, mergers between and among local savings banks – resulting in the existence of 33 regional savings banks, legally autonomous entities; and, on the other hand, the tightening of operational and organisational bonds among these 33 regional savings banks. The group includes, besides regional savings banks themselves, several subsidiaries and partly owned specialised financial firms. Figure 6.4 shows the shareholdings of the Groupe Caisse d’Épargne, as of early 2004185.

The aggregation that gave rise to the Groupe Caisse d’Épargne is not dissimilar to the restructuring process followed by other groups, such as the Crédit Agricole, the Crédit Mutuel, and the Banques Populaires group. All these groups are, similarly, cooperative banking groups, which consist of a limited number of regional banks (between 20 and 40) and a group of national, specialised subsidiaries. Such “federal” groups differ from the vertically integrated banking groups that have risen around former public banks that were privatised in the late 1980s –early 1990s – BNP-Paribas, Société Générale. But all these banking groups share the characteristic of being a group – and this has been a strong trend across most segments of the banking system during the 1980s and 1990s.

• Italy

The Italian case is slightly different. There, too, has there been a clear tendency towards the constitution of large banking groups. But various groups, of varying nature, coexist and compete. Within the savings bank sector itself, one can distinguish three different aggregation patterns, which ended up producing three different kinds of banking groups.

185 This web of shareholdings is of course doomed to change over time. For instance, in September 2003 the CDC and CNCE announced that they had reached an agreement on a re-shuffling of ownership and control of former CDC subsidiaries, mainly CDC – Ixis.

173 The first pattern characterises the constitution of national banking groups, building on the alliance between a large savings bank and one of Italy’s former large public banks. This pattern corresponds with the emergence of Italy’s four most important banking groups: IntesaBCI, San Paolo IMI, Unicredito and Capitalia. To these four one might add two large banks: Monte Paschi di Siena (the oldest Italian bank, which has been legally associated with the savings banks category since the late XIXth century) and Banca Nazionale del Lavoro (a former public bank, where the Treasury has kept a small stake). All of these groups were created through a strikingly similar aggregation process, in which we can identify four distinct phases: a first phase in which a leading savings bank absorbs a smaller one; a second phase in which the resulting groups create specialised subsidiaries; a third phase in which the whole group associates itself with another major former public bank; and a fourth phase in which this alliance transforms itself into a new integrated banking group.

This pattern, which one could call the “national universal bank” pattern, appears clearly in the case of the formation of the Banca Intesa group, Italy’s leading banking group (in terms of assets). Banca Intesa’s short history starts with the Cassa di Risparmio delle Provincie Lombarde (Cariplo), historically the strongest and largest of Italy’s savings banks. In the 1990s, after the Amato law, Cariplo first acquired shares in a variety of local (Northeastern) Casse di risparmio, namely the CR della Provincia di Viterbo, the CR di Parma e Piacenza, the CR di Ascoli e Piceno, the CR di Biella e Vercelli, the CR di Citta’ di Castello, the CR di Foligno, the CR di Rieti and the CR di Spoleto. A following step was the merger, in 1998, of Cariplo with the Banco Ambrosiano Veneto (Ambroveneto), a commercial bank, to form the Banca Intesa Group. In September 1999, the group acquired Banca Commerciale Italiana (Comit), one of the main public banks previously owned by the state-owned holding IRI. In December 2000, the group incorporated Cariplo, Ambroveneto and Mediocredito lombardo – and one year later it incorporated Comit, becoming “Banca Intesa BCI”, renamed “Banca Intesa SpA” in 2002.

174 Another clear example of that pattern is the constitution of the Capitalia Group. The latter is the outcome of an alliance between a former Cassa di Risparmio (CR di Roma) and a large former public bank. The aggregation process started, again, in the late 1980s – early 1990s. In 1989-1991, the Cassa di Risparmio di Roma, which had first absorbed the Monte di Pietà di Roma in 1985, acquired the Banco di Santo Spirito (a commercial bank). In 1991 the CR Roma merged with the Banco di Roma to form the Banca di Roma group (officially created in August 1992). In 1997 the Banca di Roma group acquired shares from the Treasury in Mediocredito centrale (Credit), the other large long-term bank owned by IRI alongside with Comit, to form the Capitalia Group. In the same year, Mediocredito centrale acquired shares of the Banco di Sicilia, Sicily’s large former public bank. Two years later, the Banco di Sicilia was entirely absorbed by the new entity. The last move was the acquisition of shares into the Bipop-Carire group, itself the outcome of a merger between the Banca Popolare di Brescia (Bipop) and the Cassa di Risparmio di Reggio-Emilia (Carire). The Capitalia Group was officially formed in January 2002 with the integration of Banca di Roma, Bipop-Carire, Mediocredito Centrale and Banco di Sicilia. Both the Intesa and Capitalia Groups are vertically integrated but maintain the identity of the three main components.

A second aggregation pattern characterises the formation of regional banking groups with a strong territorial basis and often alliances with the Banche popolari, a form of cooperative bank – which one could call, therefore, the “regional group” pattern. The territorial element is fundamental within this pattern: the aim of such aggregation is to strengthen savings banks’ retail market positions through specialised joint-ventures – while keeping the local clientele networks and organisational flexibility. This pattern is common to several groupings among cooperative banks – mainly, small Banche popolari and the Banche di credito cooperativo. A good example of such a pattern is the Carige Group, which formed around the Banca Cassa di Risparmio di Genova SpA (Carige). The group was created in 1992 and included, besides Carige, Credito Fondiario della Liguria and Mediocredito Ligure (both specialised in medium and long-term lending); Columbus Leasing SpA, Columbus Factoring SpA and Columbus Domestic SpA (all were specialised subsidiaries offering para-banking services, created by the CR Genova in the late 1980s – early 1990s).

175 At first a multifunction group, in 1993 the Carige Group became a universal bank, with the merger between Banca Carige SpA on the one hand and the above mentioned entities on the other. In 1997-98, the Group grew with the acquisition of controlling stakes in the CR di Savona and the Banca del Monte di Lucca.

Other examples of such intra-sector, regional groupings include the Gruppo Bancario Banca delle Marche (resulting from the merger between the CR di Jesi, the CR di Pesaro and the CR di Macerata in 1994, and the acquisition of a controlling stake into the CR di Loreto in 1998) and the Gruppo Bancario Cassa di Risparmio di Firenze (which includes, at its head, the CR di Firenze, and the CR di Civitavecchia, the CR di Pistoia e Pescia, the CR di Mirandola and the CR di Orvieto).

A third pattern characterises those (small) savings banks that have remained independent, or formed a group on their own. These banks, or mono-banking groups are characterised by circumscribed territorial rooting and almost exclusive reliance on the retail market.

Out of 76 remaining savings banks186 in 2002, 16 followed the independent or small group pattern; 30 were owned, controlled by or headed a regional group; and 30 belonged to or were controlled by national universal banking groups.

6.2.3 Factors of divergence: the variety of aggregation patterns

The above two sections clearly show a similar tendency at play both within and across the Italian and French banking sector: a tendency characterised by shifts in corporate boundaries (mainly, but not only, through mergers and acquisitions) and the constitution of large banking groups. However, they also show strong elements of differentiation in both cases, again both within and across the two banking systems.

There are, first of all, a variety of aggregation patterns within countries. This is clearer in Italy than in France. In the latter, federal cooperative groups have risen to compete with national universal banks, and it is not clear whether these groups will move, or not, towards forming universal banks.

186 That is, remaining legal entities.

176 In the case of the French savings banks group, the growing centralisation that has come with autonomy from the CDC certainly points towards that direction. That is a view shared by all interviewees, whether they think it is necessary, inevitable, or regrettable (or all three together). For instance, the price and product policies have been so centralised that it has become impossible for single savings banks to choose another way. As an interviewee from a local Caisse said,

There are caisses who do not sell some products from the catalogue; but the opposite does not happen. To create a specific product is nearly impossible, for at least two reasons: (i) IT groupings are very difficult; (ii) you need the agreement from the Caisse nationale187.

And according to another interviewee (a top official at the FNCE):

Personally, I think that after a while the Caisses d’Épargne will lose their autonomy and become simple bank windows for the financial products designed and developed by the group’s specialised subsidiaries. All that for economies of scale188.

The same difficulty exists in the Italian case, albeit less evident. As analysed above, savings banks have followed roughly three different aggregation patterns (more precisely, two aggregation patterns and one non- aggregation pattern). But is it possible to draw a conclusion at this point in time? In other words, have aggregation patterns stabilised, or, on the contrary, do they continue changing? In the latter case, it is possible to imagine that some regional banking groups that have emerged from the cross-provincial alliance between savings banks and Banche Popolari will further merge into or become controlled by the four or five major universal banking groups.

This is already the case for several such regional groups, which constituted preliminary steps in the formation of integrated national banking groups: the Cardine Group, which was created through strategic alliances and cross-shareholdings between savings banks from Padova, Bologna, Venezia, Udine and Gorizia ended up within SanPaolo IMI.

187 Interview, 27.06.02. 188 Interview, 24.04.02.

177 The southern Carime group, which emerged out of a 1998 merger between the Cassa di Risparmio Salernitana, the Cassa di Risparmio di Calabria e Lucania, and Cassa di Risparmio di Puglia was similarly absorbed by SanPaolo IMI. Another example is Rolo Banca 1473, formed in 1996 by the alliance between the Credito Romagnolo and Carimonte, itself the outcome of a merger between the CR di Modena and the Banca del Monte di Bologna and Ravenna. Rolo Banca was acquired and incorporated within the Unicredito Group in 2002. There is no way to be sure that the Gruppo Banca delle Marche, or the Gruppo Bancario Unibanca, which are the outspurts of small savings banks, will not ultimately take the same path (a similar argument is made in Messori et al. 2003).

The uncertainty about the durability of this pattern variety can be partly balanced by looking at other segments of the banking system. Regional groupings represent a sizeable feature of the whole system – around 95 banking groups are identified by the ABI, among which two thirds are regional retail groupings. The regionalisation trend is especially strong among Banche Popolari, which have in many cases formed alliances with local or regional savings banks. Finally, the Italian banking system is still characterised by a high number of small cooperative banks, many of whom have formed local alliances.

A second interesting aspect of change – and a second element of differentiation - is the sector dynamics of banking aggregation patterns. In other words, shifts in firm boundaries have occurred mostly within bank categories: commercial banks with commercial banks, savings banks with other savings banks… Such intra-sector dynamics were stronger in France than in Italy where, as we just saw, the biggest savings banks choose to form groups by forging alliances with non-savings banks189. As a central bank official said,

Speaking of savings banks in Italy does not make sense any more. Because the Casse di risparmio are a very heterogeneous type of banks. Some of them are still very rooted, linked to the territory190.

189 Of course, it can be argued that the partners chosen by savings banks for these large deals were former public banks – and since savings banks were considered as quasi-public banks, there is a ‘sectoral’ flavour to the aggregation patterns that brought these banks together. 190 Interview, 19.02.02.

178 In the Italian case, differentiation occurred within the broad category of savings banks. The 1999 IEF report rightly points out that “at present it is hard to identify a single strategy for the Italian savings banks sector”, adding that “to some extent, strategies seem to be related strictly to size, which is very heterogeneous”. (IEF 1999, p.125.) The latter is a crucial issue: territory, or “localism” (that is, the extent to which banks or banking groups are rooted in a particular territory) is clearly a discriminatory variable between Italy and France. Several studies document the specific pattern of aggregation followed by most small and medium-sized Italian savings banks, which reveals a strong ‘sector character’ (Locatelli, 1998) consisting in a deep rooting (and continued investment) into the territory of origin.

In France, M&As occurred strictly within the category. They happened, furthermore, in an orderly territorial way: at the departmental, cross- departmental, and then regional level191, suggesting a very ordered re-structuring process (no cross-regional or cross-sector merger). In fact, sector institutions played a key role in encouraging mergers and shaping the emergence of integrated regional banks. In late 1989, the CENCEP commissioned a report from a consulting firm about the network’s future restructuring needs and ‘optimum’ size. The report’s conclusions were presented in May 1990, and the restructuring scheme was adopted by the CENCEP General Assembly in June 1990, where the director of Caisse des dépôts, Robert Lion, announced, obviously in agreement with the CENCEP, the plan to re-group the 187 existing savings banks into 50 units that should be “strong, autonomous and accountable”192. This decision had been long expected at the CENCEP, but any proposal to further re-organise the sector had previously met with strong reluctance from the unions, and was a bone of contention between the Caisse des dépôts and the CENCEP. Indeed, the former was keen on keeping a hand on financial links between savings banks and SOREFI. One month later, Raymond Douyère gave his own report to the Government. In July 1991, the new reform was passed, which institutionalised the re-organisation of the network. In 1991-92, following both CENCEP’s decision and the 1991 reform, savings banks underwent the most radical wave of mergers in their history: in a few months, the number of savings banks fell from 187 to 34 – a further reduction compared to the 1990 consulting firm report.

191 It should be noted, however, that the regional boundaries of the actual 33 savings banks do not exactly match regions’ administrative boundaries. 192 On that crucial date for the future organisation of the sector, see Le Monde, June 30, 1990 (“Les caisses d’épargne accélèrent leur restructuration”); and Moster (2000), p.52.

179 Interestingly, this process was largely driven by the group’s top executives: the chronology of events clearly points to the legislator playing a follower’s role in the 1991 transformation. In a special issue of La Lettre de l’Association pour l’Histoire des Caisses d’Épargne (n.5, December 2001), one can even read “The size of changes undertaken by savings banks led the legislator to modify the 1983 law to harmonise the legislation with the new organisation”.

6.3 Sector coordination

At the outset of the 1980s, French and Italian savings banks belonged to legally recognised and economically specific categories within the broader banking system. Both the legal and organisational characteristics of the “savings banks category” underwent tremendous changes in the subsequent decades, in seemingly different directions for the two countries. These changes in sector boundaries mirror and complement, in many ways, the changes in savings banks’ corporate boundaries just described.

6.3.1 The logic of vertical integration and the diverging fates of the sectoral banks

• France

In France, the centripetal dynamic that characterises savings banks’ aggregation patterns over the years goes hand in hand with an increased centralisation of financial flows within the group, through the emergence of a “sector central bank”.

At the outset of the 1980s, savings banks were part of a financial circuit essentially directed by the Caisse des Dépôts et Consignations (CDC). Figure 6.5 represents that circuit. The CDC managed administered savings resources collected by the savings banks, and gave back part of those resources to the banks for the use of financing local governments’ housing investment needs (the famous ‘Minjoz contingents’, which will be further explored in chapter 8)193.

193 From 1950 to 1971, savings banks were only authorised to present (support) loan requests to be funded by the CDC on their share of the Minjoz contingent; in 1971 they were authorised to directly fund those loans from the Minjoz funds provided by the CDC.

180 Such a circuit deprived savings banks of autonomy in the management of their financial resources and in the choices to be made in the use of those resources; denied their nature of intermediary; and maintained the unbalance between their large presence in the collect side and their marginal role in lending. A first change had been brought to the system in the late 1960s with the creation of the Groupements Régionaux d’Épargne Prévoyance (regional savings groups, or GREP). The GREP’s mission was to manage part of the new resources allowed to savings banks (among which the Livrets d’Épargne Logement and the bons d’épargne logement) and redistribute them to the Caisses so as to be used in loans to local governments. The GREP, jointly owned by the banks and the CDC, were a first step in delegating to the “savings banks world”194 part of the financial management until then entirely centralised at the CDC. However, the creation of the GREP did not fundamentally alter the structure of the circuit – and, in particular, savings banks’ subordination to the CDC and absent financial autonomy.

The 1983 law substantially modified this structure, by organising a real financial network among savings banks195. First, it replaced the GREP with Sociétés Régionales de Financement (regional financing firms, or SOREFI), entrusted with substantially the same role. However the SOREFI, in contrast to the GREP, had a direct responsibility on the resource side; in addition, their role was extended to all resources collected by savings banks, except the Livret A (and part of the CODEVI); and the SOREFI could directly use some of the resources to finance loans, limited by law to institutions specialised in industrial investment, backed by public entities. In sum, SOREFI were true regional banks operating like the Giro banks for the German savings banks.

A second, major change driven by the 1983 reform was the creation of a “network head”, the Centre National des Caisses d’Épargne et de Prévoyance (Savings banks national centre, or CENCEP). Finally, two funds were created by the 1983 law, which laid the base for group-level risk management: the Fonds de solidarité et de modernisation (solidarity and modernisation fund) and the Fonds commun de réserve et de garantie (common reserve and insurance fund). Both were managed by the CENCEP.

194 Since the GREP were distinct from the savings banks, but at the same time linked to them. 195 Duet sees in the 1983 law an unambiguous step towards the “re-conquest of [savings banks]’ independence” (Duet 2001: 72).

181 Following Duet, one can interpret the 1983 law as creating two parallel, but distinct, financial or intermediation circuits: a first one, public, based on the Livret A, regulated and headed by the CDC; a second one, private, based on all other resources, from then on managed within the network (by the SOREFI). The twin intermediation circuits created by the 1983 law are represented in Figure 6.6.

The 1991 law brought further substantial modifications to this architecture. First, it abolished the SOREFI, and simultaneously transferred balance sheet management to savings banks themselves. Within one year after the law was passed, SOREFI’s assets and liabilities were transferred to the newly formed regional savings banks, while their own funds were transferred to the CDC. Simultaneously, the law abolished the Minjoz contingent, allowing savings banks to finance their loans to local governments from ‘banalised’ resources (i.e. non administered savings resources), further distinguishing the public intermediation circuit (Livret A resources were to be entirely managed and used by the CDC) and the private one, described above. These were crucial changes, since they gave savings banks full autonomy in the management of their balance sheet.

In addition, the law created two national financial institutions, fulfiling the functions of a central cashier: the Société centrale de trésorerie (central treasury institute), which held regional banks’ current accounts; centralised excess of liquidity; and ensured inter- banking payments between the network and other credit institutions (including the central bank and the CDC); and the Société centrale d’émission et de crédit (central credit and lending institute), predominantly owned by the CE, which managed emissions for the whole network, ensured regional banks’ refinancing and organised national lending pools. This structuring was supposed to evolve towards the creation of a fully-fledged central cashier196. And in fact, in 1995, the two institutes were merged into a Caisse Centrale des Caisses d’Épargne et de Prévoyance (savings banks central cashier, CCCEP). To take, again, the German system as a comparison, the CCCEP was conceived as a Girozentralbank.

196 According to the CENCEP in La Caisse d’Épargne: une mutation réussie, Paris: October 1991.

182 The latest step in French savings banks’ road towards autonomy was the 1999 reform, which merged the CENCEP and the CCCEP together, into the Caisse Nationale des Caisses d’Épargne (savings banks national cashier, or CNCE) – the ‘associational’ components of the CENCEP being spun off to create the Fédération Nationale des Caisses d’Épargne (savings banks national federation, or FNCE), which will be analysed in the next section. In addition to centralising financial flows within the network, the CNCE also inherited all the specialised subsidiaries that, from 1988, were controlled by the CNCE through the holding Écureuil Participations (see Figure 6.4).

Strengthened coordination and reinforced autonomy were the twin outcomes of this process. As one of the French interviewees stated:

The reform allowed us to maintain the group’s cohesion, in contrast to what happened in Italy, with one single group, and one single bank operating on a single territory197.

However, coordination was subsumed into centralisation. The rise of the savings banks national cashier parallels, indeed, the radical shift of savings banks’ corporate boundaries during the 1980s and early 1990s, gave rise to a ‘federal’ banking group, where products were designed at the central level (through specialised subsidiaries), not at the regional one (see previous section). An additional relevant tendency related to the growing ‘merger’ between IT systems and the growing interconnection, promoted by the CNCE. There were 14 regional IT centres in 1990, down to 3 different platforms in 2003.

Similarly, one should note the pooling of communication resources through the birth of the “Précoce” network in 1987 (Précoce stood for “Premier Réseau de Communications des Caisses d’épargne”).

197 Interview, 24/04/02

183 • Italy

At this level of analysis, the Italian case displays fundamental differences to the French one. Starting situations were altogether different: first of all, at the outset of the period under study, Italian savings banks were fully-fledged banks, which had kept full autonomy over their balance sheets since their creation. Secondly, since 1919 Italian savings banks’ intermediation built on the guarantees and services provided by the Istituto di Credito delle Casse di Risparmio Italiane (Italian savings banks credit institute, or ICCRI).

Along the years, ICCRI increased its role from a risk-management tool to a fully-fledged credit institution at the service of savings banks, providing mainly treasury services, merchant bank services (for bonds) and ‘circular checks’, a typical network externality first experienced within the savings banks network – allowing customers to cash in checks at savings banks other than their own. The role played by the ICCRI was very similar, in that sense, to the one played by Girobanken in Germany. In the 1950s, a Fondo di Solidarietà e Sviluppo (solidarity and development fund) was created, together with Fondi di garanzia federali (federal guarantee funds) at the regional level. Beyond centralised financial services, such funds, together with the ICCRI, ensured the possibility of sector-wide investments – such as those in IT, whose costs were too high for the smallest savings banks198. In 1979, the ICCRI launched STACRI, an ambitious IT program that incorporated the payment system and systematised the circulation and sharing of data and information among savings banks.

A crucial change occurred in 1986 when all payments systems, including STACRI, were unified into an electronic Rete nazionale interbancaria (inter-bank national network). In addition, the ICCRI became, along with a few other specialised institutions, one of the operators of the network. This change was an important step towards the constitution of a unified banking market in Italy (what economists would call ‘a level playing field’), and formally marked the end of the ICCRI as a purely ‘savings bank’ actor. The second major change was brought about in 1993, with the transformation of the ICCRI into a joint-stock company, whose shares were then held by several major Foundations. The ICCRI was therefore privatised along savings banks – although its ownership still remained within the former savings banks sector.

198 As emphasised in Acciaro et al. (1985).

184 In November 1999, the Banca Popolare di Lodi, one of Italy’s largest cooperative groups, acquired a majority stake in the ICCRI –followed a few months later by a wave of acquisitions of savings banks. In January 2000, the ICCRI acquired the control of the CR di Imola; In 2000-2001, the BPL completed the merger between the ICCRI and the Casse di Tirreno SpA, head of the homonymous holding group, which in turn controlled the Cassa di Risparmio di Lucca, the Cassa di Risparmio di Pisa and the Cassa di Risparmio di Livorno. In addition, between 1999 and 2001 BPL made acquisitions or alliances with merchant banks and institutions specialised in credit services, thus building up on the ICCRI’s historical assets.

Thus, in contrast to what happened in the Banche Popolari sector (where the Istituto Centrale delle Banche Popolari fulfils missions to the exclusive benefit of banks belonging to the category), the Italian equivalent of CNCE soon disappeared as a sector central bank, mirroring the heterogeneous destiny of savings banks themselves.

6.3.2 The diminishing power of sector associations

The existence of strong sector associations has long characterised savings banks in Germany, Spain, and the Netherlands. In those countries such organisations play a key role in representing savings banks’ interests, steering exchanges between category members, and maintaining the cohesion of the whole sector. They generally are responsible for all issues pertaining to contacts with regulatory authorities, common strategies, and lobbying. Their organisation mirrors that of the political institutions with whom they are dealing (Deeg, 1999). France and Italy show, from this point of view, two contrasting histories.

• France

French savings banks did not create a formal sector organisation until the late 1960s. They did, however, participate in an institutionalised forum, called Conférence générale des Caisses d’Épargne (general conference of savings banks), which consisted in regular, national meetings of all savings banks. The general conference was replicated at the regional level through regional conferences.

185 The general conference fulfiled representation and proposition functions: in 1947, for instance, it was within its framework that the proposal leading to the Minjoz law was discussed and then presented to the government (see Duet 2001: 59). However, the General conference did not evolve into an organisation until 1969, much later, therefore, than the Italian savings banks. The reasons for this un-organisation probably lies in (a) the fragmentation of savings banks and their embeddedness in local political and economic networks, and (b) their ‘functional dependence’ from the Caisse des Dépôts.

In 1969, French savings banks set up the Union nationale des caisses d’épargne de France (French savings banks national union, or UNCEF), which was the first formal organisation (with its own staff and a legal status) to represent savings banks’ interests. UNCEF, with the 1983 law, disappeared and its activities were transferred to the CENCEP – which was, however, more than an association representing savings banks. As seen above, the CENCEP was conceived as the head of the savings banks network.

A true savings banks association did re-emerge two decades later, at the term of a process that saw the birth of an integrated banking group (see sections above). The Fédération Nationale des Caisses d’Épargne (national savings banks federation, or FNCE) was formally instituted by the June 25, 1999 law (articles 1, 6 and 15), and was created on September 29th, 1999. It has a “law 1901 status” – that is, it had the legal status of an association – but its name, “Fédération”, reveals higher ambitions: its core mission was indeed, to federate the 34 Caisses d’Épargne. In particular, the law gave four missions to the FNCE:

- to coordinate the relations between the Caisses d’Épargne and their owners, the sociétaires, and organise training for the latter, especially their representatives elected at the Sociétés locales d’épargne (SLE, see next chapter) and the Conseils d’orientation et de surveillance (COS, see next chapter); - to participate in the definition of the Group’s “strategic orientations”; - to set national goals for the “general interest missions” defined by Art.1 of the 1999 law, and especially the projets d’économie locale et sociale (PELS, see chapter 6); - to represent interests common to savings banks and their owners, especially vis-a-vis regulatory authorities.

186 The Fédération represents both savings banks and their owners. Indeed, it is owned entirely by the 34 Caisses d’Épargne (in contrast to the Caisse nationale, partly owned by the Caisse des dépôts), and its general assembly, the purposeful organ of the Fédération, is composed of the 34 savings banks represented each by three individuals: the President and one member of the COS, and the President of the Directoire. The General Assembly, which meets every year, appoints the 18 members-board of the Fédération, which is composed of 12 Presidents of COS and 6 Presidents of Directoire. The chairman of the board is a COS President.

This evolution, and in particular its ultimate twist in 1999, indicates the reinforcing of the group’s bank at the expense of the association. This is not clear in the formal institutional mechanisms, by which the FNCE seems to have gained in power as compared to CENCEP – in particular, its roles of coordination with and training owners seem to give it a strong leverage over the Group’s governance. This is not so in reality, as the next chapter will show. Finally, and perhaps more importantly, there is a strong perception by savings banks staff (both at the central and local level) that they are part of a banking group more so than a cooperative organisation. This element arose repeatedly in the interviews.

To sum up, the gradual increase of sector centralisation throughout the 1980s and 1990s, culminating in the current organisation, paradoxically did not play in favour of strengthening the particular identity of savings banks, but to an assertion of the savings banks as a “normal” banking group intended to compete with other banking groups – and not only the Crédit Agricole199. This trend is reflected in the new organisation of the Group, but above all in the real balance of power between the two national institutions, the CNCE and the FNCE. However, and this is an important point, there is no reason to say that the current balance cannot change.

199 In a revealing speech delivered at the FNCE in March 2000 and aimed at giving some indications to the FNCE on how to proceed to develop the “cooperative status”, an outside guest said “focusing on statuses, elections, is running the risk of emphasising too much issues of power and representation. [The Federation should] draw the attention out of the General Assembly and on to more open, useful and comfortable issues for managers and employees at the Caisses d’Épargne.” Speech reproduced in the first “Compendium” (Textes choisis et commentés par la Fédération Nationale des Caisses d’Épargne) published by the FNCE in 2001 (10,000 issues disseminated within the network).

187 Institutional features do not force one way or another. In fact, if the 1999 reform, which formally opened new ways to re-assert the savings banks’ particularities through the cooperative status and the creation of the Fédération, was bended by reality in another direction, future developments might well bend it backwards. This is all that is at stake with ownership (see next chapter).

• Italy

The Italian situation differs from the French one in two aspects: first, the Italian savings banks’ sector association has historically been more powerful than its French counterpart; secondly, in the early 1980s savings banks belonged both to the category’s association and to the commercial banks’ association.

The Italian savings banks’ sector association has been, historically, more powerful than its various French counterparts. It was founded in 1911, at a period when the Casse di Risparmio were undergoing strong competitive pressures from other groups of banks – when, that is, creating a unified body was felt necessary to lobby the government for protection (De Rosa, 2003: pp.130-9). Twenty years before, savings banks had met in a first national congress to organise themselves in the wake of a forthcoming law on the subject. The Associazione fra le Casse di Risparmio Italiane (Italian savings banks association, or ACRI) operated continuously ever since 1911, except during the fascist period, when it was replaced by a “Fascist federation of savings banks”200. In the postwar period, the ACRI asserted itself as a powerful banking lobby, linked with top officials at Banca d’Italia201.

Associational links between savings banks were very strong until the mid-1980s, through the ACRI, but also through national congresses organised every three years, and thematic meetings organised by single savings banks almost every year, without mentioning workshops and the annual celebration of the “world’s savings day”, which is still today organised by the ACRI and in which top officials from both the Central Bank and the government participate (in general, the governor and the Minister of the Treasury).

200 From 1938 to 1944. On that period, see De Rosa (2003), pp.380-9. 201 The central bank governor, from then on, became the official godfather of the ‘world savings day’ celebrated every year at ACRI. In addition, starting with governor Menichella, top officials at Banca d’Italia started to frequent regularly the savings banks annual congresses and other conferences organised by ACRI.

188 As an observer noted in the early 1980s, the strong associational linkages between savings banks were all the more remarkable in that they formed a very heterogeneous category, both in legal (see chapter 3) and dimensional terms (Pin, 1984). A former president of the ACRI (and CEO of Cariplo) called the association a “sociality leitmotiv” (Ferrari, 1985). The same emphasised how the links and exchanges between savings banks top officials operated “as if we were a single, large firm” (Ferrari, 1985, p.1038).

In addition to these associational linkages, moreover, most savings banks belonged to a regional or cross-regional Federation. But in the mid-1980s, doubts regarding Federations’ role rose, culminating in the disappearance of that particular level of association (Ferrari, 1985).

The ACRI did not, however, have the monopoly of savings banks associational linkages. Since the postwar period, the ACRI was “subordinated” to the Italian banks association, ABI, for all matters pertaining to inter-bank operations and self-regulation. Indeed, as mentioned above, the Casse di Risparmio were simultaneously members of the ACRI and of ABI. A fact that, according to one observer, “should not be surprising […] since savings banks are true and proper commercial banks” (Pin, 1984).

During the 1980s and 1990s, savings banks’ ACRI membership lost relevance, to the benefit of ABI. First, in 1985, the ACRI allowed national labour contracts to be negotiated directly at an ABI level. This was an important change since savings banks employees benefited from a particular status which included many advantages in terms of working hours, salary and union activities. It is also interesting to note that the ACRI’s decline started with losing its prerogatives on collective labour negotiation, before the Amato Law. The latter did indeed bring a major blow to the ACRI, since, by transforming the savings banks into joint-stock companies, it allowed them to become full members of ABI. In fact, this allowed a broad convergence in banking labour regulation, through the negotiations around the 1994 collective contract between ABI and the unions. Finally, since January 2000, the function of tutela (guarantee) of the Casse di Risparmio was transferred to ABI. In the words of a top official at the ACRI, the Association is now “supporting” ABI in his new function.

189 But ‘losing’ savings banks did not put an end to the ACRI’s existence, since it ‘gained’ new members in the person of Foundations, the new ex-owners of savings banks (see next chapter). Since the 1990 Amato Law, the ACRI has represented the Foundations. The legislator further institutionalised the ACRI’s role towards Foundations, in particular with a 1991 law202 on voluntary activities (which recognises the role Foundations play in financing voluntary associations) and a 1999 decree203, which confirms the ACRI as the official interlocutor of regulatory authorities for all matters pertaining to Foundations’ organisation and functioning.

6.4 Discussion

6.4.1 Shifts in boundaries and shifts in coordination modes: variation within and across countries

What both the French and Italian cases show is a shift from sector to group coordination. This is clearer in Italy, where, as we have seen, the category of savings banks as such ceased to exist in the early 1990s – and where the category’s association shifted its focus from savings banks to Foundations. The simultaneous emergence of large banking groups (a shift in savings banks’ corporate boundaries) completed this shift in sector boundaries. In France, the evolution has been similar despite the apparence. The category has been strengthened so much as to become a group – and lose the coordination characteristics of a sector category. External boundaries (both of banks and sectors) are reinforced by shifts in ‘associational density’, or group cohesion.

Again, this double shift (shift in sector boundaries and in sector cohesion) signals a change in the mode of coordination. This change, moreover, has been common to all categories of banks: savings banks, but also, cooperative banks (and Banche Popolari in Italy), and commercial banks.

However, both the processes of change and its outcomes vary across and within countries. As seen above, the strengthening of a ‘central cashier’ within the French savings banks network, and the spin-off of associational functions from the head of the network (itself merged with the central cashier) have had strong centripetal effects.

202 Art.15 Law 266/91 203 Art.10 Legislative Decree n.153/99

190 In Italy, in contrast, the network’s central credit institution, ICCRI, was privatised, while the savings banks’ association turned its focus away from savings banks to Foundations. In effect, the category exploded into several sub-groups, each following a different path of aggregation.

Changes have also produced variety within each country. This is clear in the Italian case, where savings banks have followed several divergent aggregation patterns, while the sector ceased to exist. As seen above, at least three subgroups of savings banks can be identified: a first one includes savings banks who have been absorbed, or who are now controlled, by large banking groups; a second group consists of savings banks who have re-grouped in regional alliances, either within the category or with banche popolari; and a third one is made up of those savings banks that have remained independent or formed a group on their own.

As Figure 6.8 shows, group centralisation has increased in both countries, while sector cohesion has increased in France and decreased in Italy.

Again, however, part of the divergence can be explained by the differing systemic relational properties of the units of observation (savings banks). In other words, the evolution analysed above reveals that French and Italian savings banks fundamentally differ in one critical property: their relation to the system. Therefore, one needs to take a systemic view to verify the validity of the comparison: have other Italian banks fulfiled a role that is functionally equivalent to the French savings banks? It does not seem so. Cooperative banks, be they Popolari or simple cooperatives, have not aggregated into a national federal banking group. These two categories are also, as the Italian savings banks sector, characterised by strong internal differences.

A final “test” of the validity of the analysis results exposed misgivings on whether the Italian case lags the French one. In other words, the trends shown by the Italian case might well be temporary and, in the long run, converge on the French model (full integration of all banks into national, federal banking groups). Again, however, this objection does not resists a counter-objection: the actual patterns of aggregation already exhibited by Italian banks differ from those followed by French banks in fundamental ways, the first one being the territorial variable. The regional level in aggregation processes in Italy has played a much more important role than in France, where the mergers of small local savings banks into large regional savings banks have been accompanied by strengthened group centralisation.

191 6.4.2 The historical- institutional roots of sector coordination

The second issue to be addressed here is the role institutions played in the changes analysed above. Since we are dealing here with the rules of the coordination game, the only prior or superior institutions are regulatory ones. Two kinds of institutions may be identified: static, boundary-definition institutions on the one hand; and dynamic, boundary-redefinition institutions on the other. The first category consists of all regulations pertaining to the definition of firm’s environmental boundaries. In particular, they are those regulations defining sectors, categories, and the ways in which they differ (corresponding to the ‘top-down’ sector characteristics in Hollingsworth, 1994); and the extension of the banking market. The second category refers to all rules that induce (or constrain) firms, in the present case banks, to redefine boundaries on their own. Characteristic of this category are fiscal incentives for mergers and acquisitions, for instance.

‘Boundary definition’ institutions have undergone tremendous changes in both countries. As shown in chapter 3, the very legal definition of the savings banks category (or sector) has changed. In the French case, from a sui generis category, the savings banks sector was assimilated to a cooperative banking group in 1999; in Italy, the category effectively ceased to exist with the legally mandatory transformation of savings banks into joint-stock companies in 1990. Moreover, the first article of the 1990 law was dedicated to mergers. Indeed, it explicitly provided that public credit entities “can merge with other credit institutions of any nature, even in the case in which they would become joint-stock companies”. At a broader level, in both countries legal boundaries were re-drawn for all sectors in the 1980s and the 1990s, leading to the official recognition of two main categories: cooperative and commercial banks.

‘Boundary re-definition’ institutions also underwent profound changes during the period under study, in both countries. In Italy, those institutions took two forms: on the one hand, legal and regulatory incentives for mergers and aggregation. These incentives, according to Zazzaro (2003), played a key role in pushing for aggregation during the 1990s. It is especially striking to see the acceleration of mergers and acquisitions after 1994, i.e. after the government took more decisive measures to encourage especially share sell-offs from savings banks owners, one key element in the process (see next chapter). On the other hand, the steering role played by the central bank might be seen as a key ‘re-definitional’ institution.

192 As said in chapter 3, the 1990 antitrust law confirmed Banca d’Italia’s power to authorise mergers and acquisitions among banks. This process might be paralleled with what happened in the previous large-scale aggregation process in the banking sector, i.e. in the 1930s. In 1927204, the government forced small savings banks to merge, and the gathering of remaining savings banks in local Federations. As reported in the ACRI’s first report on banking foundations, the Minister of the Economy then invoked the need to avoid “a remarkable waste of energy” and to facilitate monitoring by the government, “through a smaller number of Casse di risparmio with a broader range and less subject to local issues”205. That move brought to a rapid fall in the number of savings banks: from 200 in 1926 to 91 in 1938, and 81 in 1939206.

So regulatory institutions did change, as well as coordination. But did institutional change cause change in coordination? Here we have to build on the findings reported in the previous chapter, especially on the proactive role savings banks actors played in defining the substance of regulatory reforms. The emergence of powerful banking groups, and the positioning of savings banks within the group structure, reflects not a choice by savings banks actors of a strategy fitting the new (given) environment, but a choice by several key groups of actors to transform those very ‘institutions’. A multi-layered consensus (in Italy, between the Fondazioni and the political power, between top managers at savings banks and at the Fondazioni, among political forces, between regulatory actors) permitted the realisation of this radical institutional shift in the Italian and French banking sector.

To sum up, in France, the 1980s and 1990s saw the strengthening of a banking network, increasingly centralised around the Caisse nationale des caisses d’épargne207, itself slowly acquiring more autonomy from the Caisse des Dépôts. In Italy, the national level was never strong and was abandoned after it became clear that the former savings banks would become the backbone of the new banking system of the 1990s. But at the same time, one can see a very clear pattern of “endogenous” aggregation between and among savings banks before aggregation with other categories of banks.

204 Decreto legislativo of February 10th, 1927, n.269. 205 Cited in ACRI (1996), p.11. 206 That subsequent decrease in the number of savings was due to another legislative move that disposed mandatory fusion of some savings banks with Monti di credito su pegno (Law of December 14th, 1939, n.1922). 207 As said in Chapter 3, the CNCE was created with the 1999 law, but it retained some of the missions previously exerted (in a looser way) by the CENCEP.

193 In other words, the emergence of major banking groups in Italy was an orderly (although fragmented) process governed by the individual savings banks themselves. In a sense, then, this contrasting evolution follows institutional patterns well established in both countries. But if the peculiar characteristics of the process of change, and even some of its substantial characteristics, can be explained by institutional path-dependence, such explanation falls short of understanding change itself (its “triggers”, its directions).

If de-segmentation means the end of a form of compartmentalisation organised by the State, it does not mean the end of all forms of compartmentalisation. In both cases actors have re-organised in very distinct ways, leading to new forms of differentiation. Those forms of differentiation correspond to a minimal compartmentalisation (territorial and sectoral in Italy, sectoral in France) and are, therefore, subject to change, in the absence of further demands for stronger compartmentalisation.

194 Figure 6.4: Ownership and shareholdings of the Groupe Caisse d’Épargne in 2004

100% Clients

Sociétés locales d’épargne

100% 37%

65% Caisses Caisse La Poste d’Épargne des dépôts Caisse nationale 50.1% des Caisses 49.9% d’Épargne 35%

Sopassure 49.9% 49.9% 50.1%

36% 47%

Crédit Foncier CNP Eulia de France

40% 53%

Écureuil Vie Socfim Écureuil gestion CDC Ixis

Écureuil A3C Écureuil CDC Ixis Asset Management CDC Ixis Capital Markets Assurances IARD Participations Cicobail Saccef Gestitres Bail Écureuil Sogeccef Banca Carige

Crédit Logement San Paolo IMI

Real estate Insurance Specialised Investment bank financial subsidies and financial market activities

195 Figure 6.5: Intermediation circuit in the French savings banks sector before the 1983 law

Collect CDC Lending Livret A LEP Caisse Caisse Prêts Minjoz d’Épargne d’Épargne All other products: Livret B, Lending to Éopargne- households and logement… GREP associations

Lending to institutions specialised in industrial investment

Prêts d’intérêt régional

Figure 6.6: Intermediation circuit in the French savings banks sector in the mid-1980s

Collect CDC Lending Livret A LEP Caisse Caisse Prêts Minjoz CODEVI d’Épargne d’Épargne Lending to households and All other SOREFI associations products: Livret B, Éopargne- logement… Lending to institutions specialised in industrial investment

Prêts d’intérêt régional

196 Figure 6.7: Intermediation circuit in the French savings banks sector after the 1991 law

Collect

CDC Lending

Livret A CCCE LEP

Caisse CODEVI d’Épargne Lending to households and associations All other products: Livret B, Éopargne- Lending to logement… institutions specialised in industrial investment

Prêts d’intérêt régional

Figure 6.8: Evolution of group centralisation and savings banks sector cohesion in France and Italy, 1980-2000

Low sectoral cohesion High sectoral cohesion

Low group centralisation France High group centralisation Italy

197 198 7. CHANGES IN SAVINGS BANKS’ CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

7.1 Introduction

Besides facilitating savings banks’ corporate restructuring, the regulatory reforms in France and Italy allowed the streamlining of ownership and control – that is, corporate governance. Savings banks’ control had represented a key stake in the reform process – a process, as emphasised in chapter 5, driven by savings banks’ top management. Understanding changes in savings banks’ corporate governance requires, therefore, an analysis of the changing balances of power between top management and other actors (political actors, employees, clients).

Chapter 6 has shown how the regulatory reforms of the early 1980s in France and 1990s in Italy paved the way for a “piloted” restructuring of savings banks by their top management. Changes in ownership and control have accompanied those shifts in sector and firm boundaries: the former both facilitated and were reinforced by the latter. In other words, on the one hand savings banks’ corporate restructuring depended on the clarification of ownership and control (characterised by implicit privatisation in Italy, explicit autonomisation in France); on the other the redistribution of corporate control to the benefit of managers (as will be showed in this chapter) was strengthened and legitimised by corporate restructuring.

This chapter, therefore, addresses the same questions dealt with in the previous chapter, which mirrors the research puzzle presented in the first part of the study. On the one hand, the chapter seeks to understand the patterns of change followed in each country, with the goal of assessing the convergent/divergent forces at play across France and Italy. On the other hand, the chapter aims at identifying the factors of change and persistence in both countries. Corporate governance, as mentioned in chapter 2, is often identified in the comparativist literature, as one of the institutional pillars of contemporary capitalism.

199 In other words, ownership and control are seen as institutions that influence singular (and aggregate patterns of) behaviour. Here, by contrast, corporate governance is taken as the dependent variable. The ultimate aim of this chapter, therefore, is to assess whether and to what extent are changes in savings banks’ ownership and control attributable to changes in the institutional “matrixes of constraints and incentives” identified in chapter 4.

7.2 Ownership patterns

7.2.1 The starting point: whose savings banks?

Until the 1980s, neither French or Italian savings banks had clear owners. In both cases, savings banks were sui generis entities, whose location with respect to private or public law was ambiguous (see chapter 3), whose managers were co-opted within a pool of local power holders (notables). Savings banks’ equity, whether it had foundational or associational origins (in the Italian case), did not give rise to property rights over the bank or the bank’s revenues, and their benefits were redistributed through grants to local associations, or to finance social or artistic endeavours208.

As an interviewee (top official at the FNCE) said:

[In 1981] Savings banks’ ownership was confused: did they belong to the State? To the nation? That’s what Beregovoy [the Socialist Minister of Finance] said then. But what does that mean? Who is «the nation»209?

This ambiguity did not, however, place them in equidistance from private and public sectors. Savings banks were strongly associated with public intermediation circuits, where public entities – especially the Minister of the Treasury, in both cases – played a key role in the banks’ corporate governance. In France, as shown in figure 4.5 (see chapter 4), savings banks were not really autonomous entities, and were an element of the so-called ‘Treasury circuit’ (Zerah, 1993) in financial intermediation: decisions about lending and collect were made by the Caisse des Dépôts et Consignations, itself organically linked to the Treasury department at the Ministry of the Economy.

208 Such funds were tellingly called in France the “Fortune personnelle” (personal wealth) of savings banks. 209 Interview, 24.04.02.

200 In Italy, the two key members (Director and vice-Director) of the savings banks’ executive board were appointed by the Comitato Interministeriale per il Credito e il Risparmio (intergovernmental committee for credit and savings, or CICR), which was dominated by the Treasury as well.

Such unclear ownership lines were problematic, or more precisely became problematic for several reasons. First, they became problematic for savings banks themselves, faced with recurrent needs to increase equity (or recapitalise). Who should do that, and under what form? Since there were no equity owners, there was nobody to turn to when the issue of recapitalisation arose. As chapter 5 has shown, the need for recapitalisation (a precondition for systematic banking restructuring) was among the driving forces in savings banks reform process during the 1980s.

A second problem associated with blurred ownership was the ‘undue advantage’ it was perceived to give savings banks over other banks – by exonerating them from remunerating owners. This undue advantage became even more problematic after 1985 in Italy, and the introduction of prudential regulation. Unclear ownership meant, for savings banks, having more resources at disposal for complying with prudential regulation (equity-related ratios, reserves)210.

A third problem was the issue of power. In the context of a gradual loosening of the state’s grip on the banking system, and on savings banks in particular (see chapter 5), who would take a hold of savings banks, and therein control savings banks’ economic resources and political assets? In Italy, the power of the Ministry of the Treasury over executive directors’ appointments had a great political significance. The Casse di Risparmio were, indeed, a pillar of the Christian-Democrats’ Northern and Southern power base, and of the Communists in Toscana and Emilia-Romagna. There is no study on the relationships between the Casse di Risparmio and political power – just brief mentions in monographs or broader essays211. However, the existing evidence seems to show that Italian savings banks were much more of a national and regional political stake than their French counterparts – the Caisses did represent a political power place, but at the very local level.

210 The undue advantage given to savings banks by their public status also concerns the favourable ratings given to them by rating agencies (since they are backed by public entities, which cannot go bankrupt). Such was the argument used in recent years in Germany by commercial banks to criticise the “state aids” to Landesbanken. 211 See, in particular, De Rosa (2003) for a historical perspective.

201 In addition, since until the 1980s French savings banks did not pursue an active strategy on the asset side, savings banks in France were much less seen as an economic power holder than in Italy, where the Casse di risparmio could effectively allocate resources to “friendly” firms or clients. This is a key difference that explains much of the subsequent variations in ownership changes.

7.2.2 The Italian case: a successful privatisation?

In the Italian case, two clear periods of change can be identified. The first period, which runs until the 1990 reform, is characterised by attempts at internal change, that is, change within the sector itself. The failure of the latter led to legislators’ intervention in 1990. Following that external change, however, is a decade of tension between political authorities and “new” owners of savings banks desirous to keep a hold on them.

In the 1980s, several savings banks implemented statutory changes that were however quickly rebutted by the courts for encroaching upon constitutional matters (See Cassese, 1983 and Merusi, 1984). Those statutory changes were primarily aimed at allowing savings banks to raise new equity and change their governance mechanisms. Given the limits posed to such changes by the courts and the existing regulatory regime, savings banks starting pleading in favour of changes in the legislation. This was clearly expressed at several official meetings. At their 13th annual congress in April 1982 in Sicily, for instance, the Casse di Risparmio asked for a legal reform to change the rules governing the access to capital markets, then restricted, and the possibility to change their governance structures – introducing the separation between management, control and direction, on the model of the joint-stock company (Società per Azioni) (ACRI, 1995).

As mentioned in Chapter 5, this view was shared within the central bank, which made it explicit first in a 1981 White Book; and in a second White Book published in 1988, where it proposed that public banks be transformed into joint-stock companies, a status more appropriate for getting access to capital markets.

202 The second period of change started with the 1990 Amato-Carli reform, which can be read as an attempt to solve the three issues mentioned above. More precisely, the 1990 reform constituted an attempt to: i) allow savings banks to access to new shareholders for recapitalisation, and ultimately corporate restructuring; ii) level the playing field and iii) make sure that the transition from the public sphere to the private one would occur smoothly, and would ensure the gradual constitution of new owners and stable power groups. The Amato-Carli reform, as showed in chapter 5, created new legal entities, the Fondazioni, to whom the equity of savings banks (and of public law banks who belong to the same broad category212) was to be fully transferred. New owners were thus created ex nihilo.

During the 1990s, both the control of savings banks by Foundations, and the control of Foundations themselves stood at a centre of a hotly debated controversy. This controversy originated in the ambiguity created by the 1990 reform. In fact, the latter disposed that the Foundations should keep controlling shares in the savings banks from which they had been created. In addition, the 1990 law disposed that the management of shareholdings in Casse di Risparmio would constitute the raison d’être of the newly created Foundations.

The application decree of that same year blurred the picture by disposing, in contrast to the law it was supposed to transcribe, that managing shares held in savings banks were merely instrumental in producing revenues; and that the mission of Foundations was to pursue public interest and “social utility” goals, through actions in the field of welfare, scientific research, education, health and art. Foundations, therefore, would not (should not) become holding firms.

These contradictions stood at the heart of the subsequent debates, which lasted until 2003, and mainly revolved around three issues. The first one was: what should Foundations do with the shares they owned in savings banks? The second and the third issues were, respectively, what was the legal nature of Foundations and who should control them? These three issues were closely linked to each other, and represented a crucial stake for the Italian political economy as a whole. If Foundations were to retain controlling shares in savings banks, and were to be simultaneously recognised as public entities, controlled by other public entities, then a sizeable share of the Italian financial system would still belong to a broadly defined public sector.

212 Monte Paschi di Siena, Banco di Napoli, Istituto San Paolo di Torino, Banco di Sicilia, Banco di Sardegna.

203 If instead, Foundations were to be recognised as private entities with private owners, but kept holding majority shares in savings banks, this would imply a shift from public sector to a sui generis political economy, in which non-firms and non-governmental entities governed part of the financial system; if, thirdly, Foundations were to lose their control in savings banks, privatisation would become complete.

Policy-makers first moved to solve the first issue, that of Foundations’ control of savings banks. They introduced fiscal incentives for share dismissals. A 1993 law exempted the sale of shares by Foundations from tax on plus-values213. Then, a law passed in July of 1994214 eliminated the obligation over Foundations to keep control of Casse di Risparmio in which they held shares215; on the contrary, it obliged Foundations to relinquish control of the banks. Building on that law, a November 1994 directive (known as the “Dini directive”, from the name of the then Minister of the Treasury)216 specified the criteria and modalities of share dismissals from Foundations.

What is interesting is that the Dini directive did not address the issue of control upfront. Rather, its official aim was to encourage the Foundations to gradually diversify their risks. In fact, the two ‘parameters’ set up by the directive were: (a) that at least 50% of the resources (assets) used by the Foundations for the pursuit of their ‘institutional goals’ (finalità instituzionale) come from other sources than their shareholdings into the CR; and (b) that no more than 50% of Foundations’ capital be invested into shares of the CR. In a sense, then, the directive echoed, on the regulatory side, the prevalent portfolio management character of the management of CR shares by Foundations, which was continuously claimed by the latter in subsequent years. In addition, the Directive set a deadline (1999) for such control dismissal to take place.

Did the Dini directive impose an unwanted constraint on reluctant actors? This is what emerges out of several actors’ accounts and perceptions of the period. Many CRs resorted to the court to object to the directive’s dispositions. But, according to a central bank official, this was just foot-dragging on the part of the Casse di Risparmio; what they wanted was to earn more time.

213 Art.4, Law 489 November 26th, 1993. 214 Law n.474 of July 30th, 1994. 215 More precisely, article 7 bis of the cited law abrogated articles 13, 14, 15, 19, 20 and 21 of the Legislative decree n.356/1990 that contained references to the public control obligation. 216 Directive of the Minister of the Treasury of November 18, 1994.

204 This interpretation seems quite reasonable, in light of the lame performances of the stock-market in those years, which prevented from foreseeing the maximisation of gains on the sale of CR controlling stakes. By contrast, the ACRI, in its first report on Foundations, claims that a trend towards control dismissal could be observed before the Dini directive (ACRI, 1995). Subsequent years, however, proved it wrong. The 1990s were characterised by a constant struggle between policy-makers and Foundations around the issue of the control of savings banks.

Data gathered from savings banks individual documents and from ACRI annual reports on Fondazioni show a clear decline of ownership shares of Fondazioni in the CR. The median share started diminishing in 1994, and has diminished every single year since then. It is now (late 2004) around 14%. Of course, this general trend reflects different individual paths. In fact, one could classify Fondazioni in several groups, according to the importance of their ownership share and, more importantly, to the rhythm of dismissal. These data are reported in Figure 7.1.

Figure 7.1: Foundations’ stakes in Italian savings banks (nr. of Foundations)

100

90

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0 2000 1990 1992 1993 1994 1996 1997 1998 2001 1991 1995 1999 2002 Controlling stake Non-controlling stake No stake

205 The 1998 Ciampi law, when it was first introduced to the Parliament, was greeted with positive reaction from the world of savings banks. According to savings banks officials217, the law “finally recognised their private nature”. Such recognition was reinforced by the fact that the law, in the Foundations’ view, set up incentives, not obligations, for the sale of shares on the part of the Foundations. Foundations were right to see a shift in attitude from policy-makers – but the Ciampi law was passed in a context much more favourable to the sales of shares on the market.

The trend towards share dismissal accelerated in the late 1990s, and slowed down in 2001, due to the European Commission‘s decision to suspend the concession of fiscal incentives set in the law, arguing that these amounted to State aid, which runs counter to the principle of competition. Those Fondazioni that were intent on selling further shares thus (as of end 2004) suspended their dismissals, the time for the EC to close its inquiry. This event illustrates the importance of external incentives for ownership changes at the margin.

Overall, the Casse di risparmio had achieved, by the end of the 1990s, clearer ownership lines and ownership status. Why, however, did share dismissal seem such a painful process? Again, this issue raises conflicting interpretations. Government officials and policy-makers claimed that the Foundations were just reluctant to cede control over savings banks. Savings banks and Foundations officials disagreed. The 1997 ACRI annual report went on to say that “The action of Foundations in [the field of share dismissals] will be determined above all by market assessment and economic considerations.” (ACRI, 1997). All savings banks interviewees confirmed this view.

As one of them, a former savings banks official, said:

It’s not that Foundations do not want to get out [of banks’equity]. It’s just a matter of selling [their shares] at a good price. Sometimes it’s difficult to sell well the shareholding portfolio, it’s not easy218.

217 See the conclusion of their 1997 annual congress, in ACRI (1997b). 218 Interview, 30.05.03.

206 In fact, that interviewee added, Foundations’ shareholdings within savings banks are “more a problem for the Foundations than for the banks”219. Another interviewee, president of a major Foundation, shared this view:

Regarding shareholdings in the bank, they are just financial shareholdings; I have always thought this way. I have never defended shareholdings. In fact, had I been able to get rid of them, I would have invested in real estate220.

Another President said

About [the obligation to sell shares imposed by the government in 1998], I have nothing against it, if we can sell the shares for profit, and find alternative investment opportunities221.

However, the decrease in Foundations’ ownership did not solve the issue of effective control of savings banks. In other words, have Fondazioni seen their control decline along with ownership shares?

This question is difficult to answer, for at least two reasons: first, the dataset used above focused on Fondazioni’s stakes in their own banks – and not in other CR, excluding cross-shareholdings from the picture; second, control does not diametrically correspond to ownership. One has to look, therefore, at other measures of Fondazioni’s control, besides majoritary ownership. Indeed, indirect ownership, cross-shareholdings, and low ownership concentration (meaning that however little their shareholdings are, Foundations still count among ex-savings banks’ largest owners) all point to a persistent power of Foundations, both at the large banking groups and in medium-sized savings banks groups.

The Control of savings banks by the Foundations was as hotly debated as the control of the Foundations. The latter was intensely discussed during the 1990s (and early 2000s), in relation to the legal nature of Foundations. Were they public or private entities? That debate had obvious practical implications: were Foundations to be recognised as public entities, control by local government would have been justified – and savings banks would fall again in the public realm.

219 Interview, 30.05.03. 220 Interview, 06.05.03. 221 Interview, 14.02.03.

207 The private nature of Foundations was of course pleaded forcefully by the ACRI, and backed by several scholars such as Merusi (1993) and Galgano222. As the ACRI argued, the very concept of “Foundation” indicates the “civil society provenance of their patrimony” (ACRI, 1997).

Both, therefore, ownership and owners’ control were solved by the early 2000s. To completely assess the effective control of savings banks by Foundations, however, one has to turn to control mechanisms, which will be addressed in the following sections.

7.2.3 The French case: the choice of the cooperative model

In France changes started earlier but have not (yet?) brought a complete break with savings banks’ past. While the 1983 law did not address the issue of ownership upfront, the 1999 did, by giving savings banks a cooperative status – and thereby creating new owners under the form of cooperative membership (‘sociétariat’). Creating owners could not be achieved until savings banks could rely on their own capital. Therefore, the 1980s and 1990s were used by gradually constituting equity or own funds, through the accumulation of revenues and common funds at the network level (“fonds de solidarité et de modernisation”, “fonds commun de réserve et de garantie” – see chapter 6), which represented 49 billion francs in December 1990.

Apparently, therefore, the ownership problem in French savings banks has been definitely solved since the 1999 law. In practice, however, the issue of effective control remains open, as we will see in the following sections. French savings banks still do not have controlling owners. Internal documents, as well as interviews, showed that savings bank senior staff (both at the national and the local level) show no interest in giving the sociétaires real control; and staff at the Fondation nationale despair at finding owners interested in exerting their rights.

222 As noted in ACRI first annual report on Foundations, if the legislator gave Foundations a public nominal recognition, the latter authors claim that given the private origin of their equity, the mostly private locus of their creation, and the end of mandatory control disposed by the 1994 law, Foundations are private entities. (ACRI, 1995, p.17.)

208 7.3 Control and monitoring mechanisms

The second pillar of corporate governance, besides ownership and control patterns, is constituted by the mechanisms of governance within firms and groups. In other words, changes in ownership and formal control do not automatically translate into changes in the effective exercise of power within savings banks. The following two sections explore such mechanisms.

7.3.1 The French case: the resistible rise of managerial control

The actual governance mechanisms in French savings banks are described in Figure 7.3. As seen above, the 1983 law did not solve either the ownership nor the control issue. Representation of stakeholders was ensured through the establishment in 1983 of “Conseils consultatifs”. But those vague bodies, with no clear juridical basis and corporate legitimacy, did not really function, as a top official admitted in 1991223.

The true reform of control occurred in 1999. Under the 1999 cooperative status, each client of the Caisses d’Épargne can acquire up to 1000 euros in shares. Whatever the amount paid and the number of shares held, all subscribers are entrusted with an equal degree of ownership. Each owner exerts his/her ownership rights through two levels of governance: a first level, within a Société Locale d’épargne (SLE), which is a cooperative institution. There are several SLEs for each Caisse d’Épargne: each SLE covers a chunk of the territory on which the savings bank operates. Clients-owners belong to the SLE of their residency. Their shares entitle them to voting rights, on the (cooperative) basis of “one man, one vote”. SLE members meet at least once a year, at a general assembly where they elect the board.

The board, in turn, is entrusted with representing SLE members’ will through the Comité d’Orientation et de Surveillance (COS), whose members are elected by the SLE boards. The COS works like a monitoring board, since it appoints the three to five members of savings banks’ Directoire, which is the body that effectively runs the bank.

223 Lucien Peretti in La Revue des Caisses d’épargne, February 1991, p.17.

209 The effective exercise of their ownership rights by sociétaires met with serious difficulties early on. These difficulties were of two types. First, both the CNCE and the FNCE do not seem to have been wholehearted in their efforts first to “recruit” sociétaires and then to consider them as the real owners of savings banks. As mentioned above, the Fédération was entrusted with the mission to coordinate relations between savings banks and their owners. Its first task was to create the new owners, by selling equity to the public, and setting up, in parallel, the governance mechanisms through which ownership would exert its rights. The acquisition of shares started on January 1st, 2000 and ended on December 31st, 2003. In practice, this means that savings banks employees (“agents”) started to propose to their clients the acquisition of shares in SLE. After a year and a half, the number of clients-owners reached two million. As of March 2003, there were 2.7 million clients-owners. The original objective was to reach 4 million shareholders by the end of 2003.

But that objective was brought down to 3 million in 2003, one million less than initially planned. Indeed, each sociétaire has subscribed more than expected: on average, from 600 to 750 euros of shares. And, in 1999, the State was set for the Caisses d’Épargne objective of selling 2.42 to 2.87 billion euros in shares by 2003, the amount raised being affected to the Fonds de réserve des retraites (the State’s emergency pension fund). This was, in a sense, the “price of freedom”224 – the “transfer of ownership” authorised by the State.

As a consequence, the drive to attract new sociétaires responded first and foremost to a financial necessity: that of not “over-paying” the State in the operation225. Had the Group maintained the initial target of 4 million stakeholders, it could have ended up raising much more than the 3 billion euros originally targeted, and thus lost further money to the State. This operation, in sum, bears testimony to the low importance given by the Group to the effective number of their owners.

224 See “La Fédération des Caisses d'Epargne veut peser sur le projet stratégique pour 2004-2007”, in Les Échos, February 27, 2003 225 From interviews with savings banks managers and regulators.

210 Besides, it does not seem that either the CNCE or the FNCE expected to generate new owners through access to the sociétariat. A document disseminated by the FNCE in December 2001 is very revealing for that matter: it shows the potential returns that the Group could get from promoting sociétariat:

- a better fidélisation of a growing group of sociétaires, who will become more prone to acquire new products and services from their Caisse; - the emergence of a new “communication force”, since satisfied sociétaires will “sell” the Caisse d’Épargne in their familial and social environment; - the availability of a strong potential to be mobilised when needed; - the availability of a reserve of subscription to draw from [in the case of future capital needs]226.

As one can see, the drive to attract, “recruit” and satisfy sociétaires is not just a matter of finding owners. It is also (above all?) aimed at keeping and multiplying faithful customers. This objective is, of course, only half- heartly acknowledged at the FNCE –it is much more explicit at the CNCE. But this is one side of the coin. The other is that sociétaires themselves do not seem eager to exert ownership rights, as successive surveys conducted by the FNCE have shown. Of course, there is no certainty that those surveys are not biased : the Fédération might well see what it wants to see. However, one could oppose a counter-factual to this potential bias: in its power conflict with the CNCE, the Fédération has a vested interest in developing its power basis within savings banks – namely, the sociétaires themselves, whose interests it is supposed to represent.

In 1999, 2000, 2001, 2002, a series of quantitative surveys were thus conducted by the Fédération in order better discern the sociétaires profiles, their expectations and the degree of their desired involvement in the life of Caisses. The quantitative surveys were completed with qualitative studies of samples of sociétaires. This effort was systematised with the creation of an “Observatoire du sociétariat” within the FNCE. One of the consistent findings of such studies is that the most important motivations behind becoming a shareholder are (1) to earn dividends and (2) to benefit from special offers and banking services.

226 Fédération Nationale des Caisses d’Épargne, Un projet coopératif pour enrichir le projet stratégique des Caisses d’épargne – Promouvoir l’identité remarquable du Groupe Caisse d’Épargne, November 2001.

211 In a recent study, the FNCE found that only 19% of respondents identified the participation in the bank’s life as a reason behind acquiring shares227. Of course, it might be too early to judge whether this situation will stabilise in time. Nevertheless, the FNCE is now focusing its efforts on that small part of “motivated owners”. But the current situation does not favour the exercise of strong monitoring and control on the part of clients-owners.

A final, and critical obstacle to the effective exercise of ownership rights by the new owners is the role played the CNCE in the corporate governance of savings banks. As mentioned above (and shown on figure 7.3), the CNCE intervenes at a key moment of the governance chain: it gives its “agreement” on the Directoire (executive board) members appointed by the COS. The law is ambiguous as to what “agreement” means, and what is the precise extent of CNCE’s power over COSs’ nominees. In practice, however, all interviewees (be they at the CNCE, at the FNCE, or at the local savings banks) recognised the predominance of the CNCE in the choice of Directoire members.

In addition, the segmentation of SLE (there are 448 SLE for 34 CE) leads to a greater diffusion of ownership, which, in the legal-economic literature on corporate governance, is seen as the breeding ground for managerial control. As a local savings bank staff member candidly said:

The creation of 48 SLE in Picardie (a national record) enables us to be closer to our clients; but it also gives less weight to SLE …228

In sum, both the FNCE or the CNCE are ambiguous as to what they expect from sociétaires; in addition, key veto points are retained by CNCE in the governance process; and the FNCE – that is, the organ supposed to represent owners - has much less power than CNCE (see chapter 6). A first element that indicates the real balance of power is the sheer size of the two institutions, in terms of staff: the FNCE includes around 30 people, while the CNCE is staffed with more than 500 employees.

227 FNCE (2002), “Enquête quantitative auprès des sociétaires”, internal document, (done through 1224 phone interviews with sociétaires in December 2001 – January 2002). One should not rely on those numbers, since different numbers have been given by interviews or in the newspapers. What remains constant is the trend and the relatively low proportion of owners willing to engage actively in the savings bank’s life. 228 Interview, 22.07.02.

212 A second element is the fact that the FNCE participation into the definition of Group’s “strategic orientations”, set by the law, is marginal, and does not encroach upon the business goals that stand at the core of savings banks’ strategy (see next chapter). These are clear obstacles to any kind of substantial monitoring and control from owners.

There is a ‘cultural’ path dependent explanation to such a situation, which is given at the FNCE : the CE have no “culture” of cooperation (by contrast, for instance, with the Crédit Agricole). So the current outcome could reflect path-dependence, and the difficulty to change paths. But that does not explain change in paths, neither does it account for the fact that there is an internal conflict and the effective exercise of ownership is not doomed in advance.

7.3.2 The Italian case

As emphasised above, since the transformation of Italian savings banks into joint-stock companies, after the Amato-Carli law, the problem of ownership became a problem of control – that is, what degree of control could and should the Foundations exercise upon savings banks’ management and strategies. Since the governance mechanisms put in place by the successive reforms were, in contrast to the French case, in line with “normal” governance practice in private, joint-stock companies, the attention should shift to the control of senior management by Foundations.

Before the Amato-Carli law, top officials at savings banks were political appointees. The appointment system was called ‘terne’ (threes): at the moment of the renewal of the mandate of savings banks’ chief executive, the central bank proposed three names to the Treasury. The appointment was then decided at CICR meetings, in which the central bank governor had no say. It is notorious that once in the 1980s the Governor of the central bank was expelled from the meeting room for having expressed his views about the appointees.

Of course, this system became obsolete with the transformation of savings banks into joint-stock companies, and with the institution of formal governance mechanisms. A 1993 referendum abrogated the dispositions of a 1938 law that gave the Minister of the Treasury the power to appoint the President and Vice-President of those Casse di Risparmio with institutional origins.

213 In addition, the 1993 Testo Unico put an end to the Ministerial appointment of the President and Vice-President of the Banche del Monte, a category assimilated to that of savings banks. Therefore, while before the renewal of the boards in 1994-95, almost 19% of board members had been appointed by the Minster of the Treasury, by 1995 they were only 0.4%229. This shift benefited the ACRI, which almost doubled its appointees within the boards (from 8.4% to 15.5%), and cooptation by the board, which reached 9% of total members by late 1995. Meanwhile, members of the board appointed by local governments (cities, provinces and regions) still constituted in the late 1990s a sizeable part of the board: 43%; And Chambers of commerce appointed 19% of members. As for Casse di Risparmio with associational origins, more than two third[s] of their board members were coopted by the Assembly of stakeholders.

The appointment power then passed to savings banks’ legitimate owners, the Foundations. In addition to being able to appoint their men to savings board’s top management, Foundations were for a while able to have their own board members serve on banks’ boards. This was a logical continuation of the previous regime: in the immediate aftermath of the 1990 reform, it was conceivably difficult for Foundations to renew all executive positions either on their board or on savings banks’ board.

A 1993 ministerial decree230 further severed the links between Foundations and Casse di risparmio by disposing the incompatibility between mandates at the Foundations and the savings bank. In other words, top officials and directors of the Foundations who were also top officials at the controlled savings bank were forced to choose between one of their mandates231. This was a widespread practice in “institutional” Foundations: in November 1995, more than 11% of members of the Foundations’ administrative boards were also board members at the controlled savings bank – half of which were either the President or Vice-President of the Cassa di risparmio232. Statutory changes were completed in 1997; and in the 1995-97 period, 54% of board members were renewed. However, here again, the process of change was slow. In 1998, 24 Foundation board members (out of a total of 880) still held mandates within the controlled savings bank233.

229 According to data provided by ACRI (1995). 230 Decree of the Minister of the Treasury of November 26th, 1993, transposing a decision taken by the governmental committee on credit and savings (CICR) of August 1993. 231 Originally, in the 1990 reform, as the ACRI reports, compatibility between the two mandates was considered useful to facilitate transition from the old to the new regime (ACRI, 1995). 232 Data from ACRI, 1995. 233 According to ACRI, 1999.

214 They had to choose. As a top official at one of the savings banks said,

In all the Casse di risparmio, there was a powerful man. When they had to choose between the bank and the Foundation, after the spin- off, almost all of them chose the bank, because banks, more than Foundations, were seen as a power centre234.

Did this mean, however, control of the bank by its owner? It is not very clear. As one of the interviewees said,

We cannot generalise. Where there was a strong character, and that character chose the bank, then it was the manager who controlled the shareholder. Where the opposite was true, it was the shareholder who controlled the manager235.

7.4 Discussion

As seen in the previous chapter, the re-distribution of power that occurred within the savings banks sector in both France and Italy participated in a broader restructuring process within the banking sector as a whole. What can we conclude so far?

7.4.1 Ownership and the issue of power distribution

As shown above, the problem of ownership was solved in different ways in France and Italy (see tables 7.1 and 7.2). In France, the transformation of savings banks into a cooperative group and the gradual separation of savings banks from the Treasury circuit led to the creation of new equity and new owners – the sociétaires, within the specific configuration of the cooperative sector (one vote per individual owner). In Italy, savings banks’ ownership was also created ex novo, under the form of the Foundations, but that intermediary step served to gradually align the new ownership with commercial banks’ owners, through the functioning of the market for corporate control.

234 Interview, 30.05.03. 235 Interview, 30.05.03.

215 Table 7.1: Ownership patterns in France and Italy, 1980

France France Italy Italy Savings banks Other banks Savings banks Other banks Legal status Sui generis Public; Sui generis: Public; private “quasi-public” private Owners Unclear State; private Unclear State; private Ownership Concentrated Concentrated characteristics Effective control Managers; State; Political Political; Caisse private owners private owners des dépôts

Table 7.2: Ownership patterns in France and Italy, 2002

France France Italy Italy Savings banks Other banks Savings banks Other banks Legal status Cooperative Cooperatives Joint-stock Cooperative firm and joint-stock companies and joint-stock companies companies Owners Stakeholders Stakeholders Shareholders Shareholders and shareholders and stakeholder Ownership Diffused Diffused; Strategic ownersStrategic owners; characteristics strategic shares diffused Effective control Managerial Managerial Managerial Managerial

This difference in outcomes owes much to the difference, underlined at the outset of this chapter, in savings banks’ relation to power and power holders. In France, historically, savings banks executive boards were composed of local power holders: businessmen, politicians, in a word, notables. Savings banks were a local actor, and were locally important to politicians. They were, furthermore, autonomous in their governance, with coopted boards. In Italy, instead, through the appointment of key board members by the Minister of the Treasury, savings banks were a national political stake. Since the postwar period, most government appointees were Christian Democrats236 – and, in some specific cases, Communists, following an institutionalised bi-partisan spoils system.

236 According to Figliolia, 1981.

216 Reasons behind the changes in corporate ownership and control around the Foundations are closely linked to Foundations’ potential and real role within Italian capitalism. Interviews and parliamentary archives show that several policy-makers hoped to make Foundations become institutional investors, very much like mutual funds in the United States. In reality, more than institutional investors, Foundations have taken the other ‘path’ offered to them; they have become grant-making institutions similar to, or trying to resemble, US Foundations. This horizon was of course present at the inception, in the 1990 law – but there were widespread fears that Foundations would long loom as powerbrokers over Italian financial capitalism, which did not happen – mostly thanks to the rise of management control in banks and Foundations themselves. In fact, the diffused character of sociétariat in France and the breakdown of the savings banks sector in Italy ended up, in both cases, producing weak owners, while managers strengthened their grip on power.

7.4.2 A convergent trend towards management control

Indeed, savings banks in both countries have undergone a tremendous power shift in favour of managers. This trend is linked to the changes studied in the previous chapter: the wave of mergers and the emergence of big banking groups required specific technical and professional skills at the executive level, and shifted emphasis from ownership to guidance and management of savings banks through this period of rapid corporate change. Professionalisation and growing skill requirements for managers’ position reinforced this evolution. In addition, the increased differentiation between ownership, control and management have left, in a probably more durable way than corporate restructuring, considerable leeway to managers and have weakened owners’ effective power of control.

Such evolution is consistent with the leading role played by savings banks’ top management in the twin processes of regulatory reform (see chapter 5) and corporate restructuring (see chapter 6). In the face of of a radically altered environment (higher interest rates, higher competition, freer markets, regulatory changes) top managers at savings banks chose to modernise their banks, and this modernisation effort included the identification of clear owners and the institutionalisation of owners’ control – without, however, relinquishing power within savings banks.

217 218 8. CHANGES IN SAVINGS BANKS CORPORATE STRATEGIES

8.1 Introduction

As noted in the previous chapters, the past two decades have been characterised by far-reaching changes in banking, both in terms of what banks are doing and how they are doing it. Savings banks have taken part in this transformation. Indeed, since the 1970s French and Italian savings banks have gradually extended the operational (and territorial) scope of their business. In two decades, savings banks in both countries have become quasi-universal banking groups, offering a complete range of products and services present on most segments of the banking market (retail, investment banking, corporate finance…). These changes were especially remarkable in France, where savings banks transformed themselves from being, mostly, quasi-public institutions collecting savings for non-profit purposes, to banks focused on profitability and revenues.

Understanding these changes, how they relate to changes in the banking sector as a whole, and how they compare from one country to the next, is critical in assessing the validity of the neo-institutional theories of capitalist diversity presented in Chapter 2. As observed then, corporate behaviour is usually seen as residual, or as the ultimate dependent variable in a long causality chain – in that framework, corporate behaviour depends on, or is shaped by, existing institutions. This chapter will not discuss that claim. Rather, the following pages will investigate the various patterns of banking strategies and their evolution, and to what extent the changes in banking strategies can be directly attributed to broader institutional change.

In particular, as in chapters 6 and 7, this chapter addresses the two research questions formulated in chapter 2; namely, (i) do patterns of change show convergence / divergence between the two cases? And (ii) are those differences (similarities) in outcomes directly attributable to the role played by institutions in mitigating the impact of external pressures on domestic actors / processes of adjustment?

219 The first section presents and analyses changes in the strategy of savings banks, mostly relying on balance sheet and annual report data237. The second section puts things in perspective: how do these changes fare with the evolution of the banking sector as a whole? Finally, the third section discusses factors of change, in relation to the changes explored in the previous chapters: regulation (chapter 5), corporate restructuring (chapter 6), corporate governance (chapter 7).

8.2 From specialised intermediaries to quasi-universal banks?

8.2.1 The changing intermediation function of savings banks

Over the past two decades, savings banks in both Italy and France have radically transformed their business behaviour and strategies – reflected in shifts in their balance sheet structure. On the assets side, there has been a shift towards non-bank lending activities. In Italy, as Figure 8.1 shows, non-bank lending238 has continuously increased from the 1980s onward, from 28% of total assets in 1984 to 62% in 2000. In the meantime, bank lending has remained constant; the amount of cash and accounts held at the Central Bank have sharply decreased; and the proportion of assets held in securities has fallen down, too (from 28% of total assets in 1984 to 16% in 2000).

French savings banks have followed a similar trend. Figure 8.2. shows a continuous increase of non-bank lending, from 16.4% of total assets in 1984 to 31.5% in 2000. Overall, however, that proportion is still much lower than in the Italian savings banks sector. This difference can be explained by (i) the lower proportion of non-bank lending at the beginning of the period; and (ii), more importantly, the fact that a significant crust of savings banks’ “administered savings” resources (the famous “Livret A”) is still managed by the Caisse des Dépôts et Consignations (CDC) – which falls into ‘bank lending’ within savings banks’ balance sheet.

237 Balance sheet figures for Italy have been calculated from data provided by the ABI. It is important to note that these data are disaggregate (by single savings bank) and the figures used to build the graphics are a median value. I did not use the average value for the simple reason that some savings banks being much larger than others, it would have introduced a bias in the calculations. As for France, the calculations were made using annual report (aggregate) data by the Caisse Nationale des Caisses d’Épargne. Appendix A. shows the re-ordering of the balance sheet data I had to make. 238 That is, lending to non-financial firms and to households.

220 This point will be analysed in detail in the next section. What this means, however, is that assets held in “other credit institutions” (of which the CDC) still represents a sizeable proportion of total assets (41% in 2000), despite a continuous fall since 1984 (76%), which parallels the rise in non-bank lending. To note as well: the proportion of assets held in securities has increased, from almost nothing in 1984 to 15% in 2000.

Figure 8.1: Composition of Italian savings banks' assets, 1984-2000 (in % of total)

100

80

60

40

20

0 2000 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

Other assets Lending to clients Lending to banks Stocks Securities Cash and central bank account

221 Figure 8.2: Composition of assets in French savings banks, 1984-2000 (in % of total)

100

80

60

40

20

0 1993 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1994 1995 1996 1997 2000 1998 1999

Other assets Non-bank loans Assets in other credit institutions Securities

Changes in the composition of liabilities have been important, too. In Italy, as Figure 8.3. shows, the contribution of non-bank deposits to total liabilities (e.g. to savings banks’ resources) has fallen sharply over the period, especially during the late 1990s: from 73% of total liabilities in 1984 to 48% in 2000. At the same time, liabilities made of bank deposits and securities rose fast, especially after 1988. That year, securities rose from 1 to 5% of total liabilities, to reach 8% in 1989, 11% in 1990. In 2000, securities represented 23% of total liabilities. The evolution is similar for commercial banks. The evidence is straightforward: savings and commercial banks’ liability composition have converged. The two categories of banks display the same tendencies with respect to the diminished importance of current account deposits, the drop in savings accounts, the boom in deposit certificates, the increased reliance on bonds and “pronti conto termine”, a remunerated long-term account. The data shows, moreover, that where savings banks were lagging far behind commercial banks (for example in the market for deposit certificates), they have caught up and now display a very similar balance sheet structure.

222 Figure 8.3: Composition of Italian savings banks' liabilities, 1984-2000 (in % of total)

100

80

60

40

20

0 1993 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1994 1995 1996 1997 2000 1998 1999

Other Equity Reserves Liabilities in bonds Non-bank deposits Bank deposits

In France, as Figure 8.4. shows, the contribution of non-bank deposits to total liabilities has declined in the same proportion as in Italy: from 90% in 1984 to 59% in 2000. The proportion of bank deposits shows a more contrasted evolution, and seems to have returned in 2000 to the 1984 level. The proportion of secure debt has increased, from 0% in 1984 to 20% in 2000. The level of capital and reserves has decreased, and the number of “other liabilities” (mainly provisions or products of off-balance sheet operations) has increased as well.

In contrast to their Italian counterparts, French savings banks do not have a long history on the lending market. Starting from zero corporate lending in 1987 (the year savings banks were authorised to lend to firms), this type of asset was however bound to rise. Which it did: it now represents between 11 and 15% of total savings banks lending.

223 French savings banks (especially through the alliance with the CDC, which brought its merchant bank along) have also increased investment services; and similar to Italy, the share of administered savings accounts has dropped.

Figure 8.4: Composition of liabilities in French savings banks , 1984-2000 (in % of total)

100

80

60

40

20

0 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 2000 1996 1997 1998 1999

Other liabilities Capital & reserves Securities Bank deposits Non-bank deposits

What do all these numbers mean? At a broad level, these shifts in banks’ balance-sheet structures are a clear signal of a profound transformation in the “intermediation function” fulfiled by savings banks in both countries. Financial intermediaries, in the classical vision first conceptualised by Gurley and Shaw (1960), transform short-term liquid funds into long- term lending.

224 In Italy, savings banks were already fulfiling a classical intermediation function before the 1980s: the Casse di Risparmio were, in effect, channelling funds from households to firms and public bonds. In other words, they were transforming short-term money into long-term capital. Within time, they soon became more reliant on financial markets, while increasing their lending to non-bank clients – mainly households. The intermediation circuit was, therefore, not simply reversed (from “households to firms/State” to “firms to households”), but made more complex, signaling a critical transformation of financial intermediation as a whole (see chapter 4).

In France, change was even sudden. In the 1970s, savings banks were the collecting part of a broader intermediation circuit, headed by the CDC (see Figure 4.5 in chapter 4): the former were merely collecting savings, and transferred the funds to the CDC, which transformed those funds into long-term lending to firms and local governments. Now, in contrast, savings banks both collect savings and directly lend to firms and households; and, like their Italian counterparts, the intermediation function they fulfil has become more complex.

Viewed from a narrower angle, changes in the balance-sheet structure reflect, albeit imperfectly239, a clear trend towards the diversification of assets and liabilities on the part of savings banks – and the turn towards new clienteles and markets. This broad trend will be analysed in further detail in the next two sub-sections.

8.2.2 The diversification of savings banks products and services

• Italy

Changes in balance sheet structures reflect changes in the operational scope of savings banks. In Italy, the Casse di risparmio, as mentioned in the Introduction, were clearly more ‘bank-like’ than their French counterparts by the late 1970s: they offered a much broader range of products and services, and autonomously decided on their investments and the use of their resources.

239 Balance-sheet data are a limited source of evidence since they do not include a growing part of bank business (called, for that reason, “off-balance sheet activities”): mainly, all those services provided to clients (savings management, liquidity management, advisory services….).

225 However, the Casse di Risparmio did stand in a particular segment of the financial system, in the midway between credit firms (short-term operations) and ‘special credit institutions’, which operated in the long-term. Within the context of market segmentation, savings banks held a rather large and diversified position, financing public institutions investment, consumer credit, real estate and rural credit (credito agrario). Their lending revealed a preference for extra-industrial sectors (see Figliolia, 1981, Capriglione, 1977). There was, however, no legal constraint specific to savings banks regarding products and services: savings banks were part of a segmented credit system characterised by the separation of long and short term finance. In other words, taking the Hollingsworth formula again, there was no strong top- down imposition of boundaries as to products and services.

The full homologation of savings banks with commercial banks was not achieved until the Testo Unico of 1993240, which abrogated the specific legal regime of savings banks (as well as those of Banche popolari and the Casse rurali), and put an end to credit segmentation (short versus long term). But the real turning point was reached in the 1980s. During that period, Italian savings banks started offering “accettazioni bancarie”, pool medium-term finance, export finance. Services were developed as well, such as leasing or factoring241. Both services and specialised financial products were often offered through specialised subsidiaries. Again, however, these innovations were not specific to savings banks, and concerned all types of banks. According to Gualandri and Landri (1994), diversification was the result of convergence between the aims of policy-makers and those of commercial bankers.

• France

In France, the process of de-specialisation reflected in the balance sheet data presented above started in the mid-1960s, but proceeded very gradually. In the late 1970s, as a respondent put it, the CE were nothing (yet) but a “small collector of moneyboxes”.

240 Testo Unico in materia bancaria e creditizia, Legislative decree n.385, September 1st, 1993. 241 Leasing allows credit institutions to finance entirely the acquisition of real estate by a firm. The real estate good is owned by the bank, who collects a rent from the contractor. Upon the expiration of the contract, the client has the possibility to buy the good, for a price determined at the beginning, minus the rents paid until then. Leasing became very popular during the real estate bubble in the late 1980s, when rents sky-rocketed, thus allowing credit institutions to improve their profitability. But the real estate bubble, once it exploded, was also at the origins of serious financial troubles faced by French credit institutions in the early 1990s.

226 In other words, savings banks then were mainly a mono-product collecting institution. As argued in Chapter 5, the 1983 reform represented a turning point, the reform considerably extending the scope of activities savings banks could pursue. But some substantive changes had already taken place in the previous decade. In fact, the mid-1960s represent, in Duet’s threefold periodisation of the history of French savings banks, the “entry into diversification” (Duet, 2001).

Diversification took root on both sides of the balance sheet. On the collect (liabilities) side, the CE started distributing the Livret Épargne Logement (housing savings bankbook, or LEL) in 1965. In 1969, the bons d’épargne logement (housing savings coupons) were launched; and in 1970, savings banks started offering Plans d’Épargne logement (housing savings plan, or PEL). These products were all savings account products; but they differed from the Livret A by being more flexible (they were not ‘administered savings’, as was the Livret A, whose interest was determined by the government). Besides those savings account products, savings banks diversified liabilities by proposing investment instruments to their clients, mainly SICAV (Société d’Investissement en Capital Variable), which are managed investment funds. Savings banks’ first SICAV in stocks was launched in 1967; the first SICAV in bonds in 1969.

On the lending (assets) side, the 1950 Minjoz law allowed for part of the resources collected by savings banks under the form of administered savings to be used for financing local governments’ investments in housing (see chapter 5). But until the late 1960s, savings banks’ role was circumscribed to the transmission of proposals to the CDC, which then decided whom to lend to, and which managed lending procedures. Besides, savings banks were not allowed to develop lending to individual clients until 1969 and the creation of the Prêts Épargne logement (housing saving loans). Two years later, in 1971, savings banks were authorised to offer personal loans and housing loans.

Changes accelerated in the late 1970s and early 1980s. In 1978, savings banks were allowed to open checking accounts for their clients. This was a major break-through for savings banks, who until then were not allowed to offer any collect product other than savings accounts.

227 In addition, in the following years new administered savings instruments were created, such as the Livret d’Épargne Populaire (popular savings bankbook, henceforth LEP), in June 1982; and the Compte d’épargne pour le développement industriel (savings account for industrial development, or CODEVI) in October 1983. These products were “banalised”, i.e. they could be distributed by all kinds of banks. But savings banks soon took a lead in the distribution of such products, building on their experience with administered savings accounts.

Further product innovation took place in the 1980s: a first short term SICAV was launched in 1982; two new Fonds Communs de Placement (investment funds) were created in 1985 (Epareurop and Eparpacific); and two pension insurance instruments were launched in 1985 and 1987 (Plan d’Épargne Retraite). Among the most dynamic savings banks, the Caisse d’Épargne Bouches du Rhône proposed, in 1985, 11 investment products, all specific to the savings bank sector (Éparcourt, Eparpacific, Epardyn…). In 1991, the savings banks network offered 19 SICAV, 9 FCP, and collected 107 billion francs through those channels, or a 13% market share. In June 1984, a first savings banks bond was put on the market. In 1985, savings banks joined an interbanking coordinating entity that launched a nation-wide credit card (the Carte Bleue). The Plan d’Épargne Populaire (popular savings banks), a new savings product, was launched in January 1990. It was a success and created a very competitive market, but CE quickly got 20% of market shares. Finally, the 1980s also saw the creation of new lending instruments; in addition to housing lending, savings banks were authorised in 1985 and 1987 to lend to individuals and families. Mostly, however, these lending products were complementary to the various savings products savings banks were already offering (Prêts complémentaires livrets, prêts complémentaires plans…).

To sum up, while Italian savings banks never really differed from other categories of banks in terms of products and services, French savings banks did, until the 1980s and 1990s, when they underwent a progressive homologation of banking products and services across sectors, as shown above. During that period, French savings banks caught up on commercial banks.

228 8.2.3 Exploring new markets, targeting new clienteles

This catching up process in the French case, and the enduring similarity between Italian savings and commercial banks, was not limited to products and services; it also concerned clienteles and markets. Table 8.1 shows the composition of Italian savings banks’ assets and liabilities, by types of clients. Again, the ‘clientele mix’ of savings and commercial banks have converged: savings banks have increased their lending to households, which were already sizable in the mid-1980s; commercial banks, meanwhile, have almost closed the gap. Similarly, both savings and commercial banks have decreased their lending to the government and to private firms.

Table 8.1: Composition of liabilities and assets of Italian banks, by market

1980 1986 1995 1996 Savings All Savings All Savings All Savings All banks banks banks banks banks banks banks banks Lending 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 Households 17.79 2.78 18.42 3.62 37.67 35.31 38.74 35.96 Government 11.56 9.51 6.72 7.99 6.81 5.09 6.64 5.00 Non-financial 68.40 85.24 69.63 81.63 46.84 49.69 45.28 48.33 firms Other 1.49 0.00 1.44 0.00 7.97 9.25 8.37 9.87 Liabilities 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 Households 72.35 71.62 80.59 75.07 62.59 61.98 63.94 62.54 Government 10.34 7.69 4.19 3.83 2.87 2.72 2.96 2.85 Non-financial 15.20 19.43 13.73 19.27 7.47 9.45 7.32 9.16 firms Other 2.11 1.26 1.49 1.83 27.07 25.85 25.78 25.45 Source: Schena (1998).

On the liabilities’ side, the evolution is smoother, but sill shows similar trends at play for the two categories of banks: a gradual decrease of the reliance on households savings, on government and firms, balanced by an increase in other forms of liabilities (such as stocks and bonds).

229 In France, savings banks show a similar trend towards exploring new markets – but in a much more limited way. French savings banks are historically specialised in the market for individual credit and collect (see chapter 3). They are also well positioned in the NGO market and the local government market, again due to their historical role in financing local governments’ investment in social housing. However, the Caisses d’épargne are quasi-absent of corporate markets. Due to the lack of data on that issue, one can only rely on estimates provided by savings banks actors themselves. According to one of these estimates (given by a CE manager working in that domain), the situation is very heterogeneous within the group: one third of CE are well rooted in the SME market, one third is making significant efforts to increase their activities in that sector and the last third is totally absent of the market (see table 8.2.).

Table 8.2. Banking market shares in France

Deposits Lending 1986 1993 1999 1986 1993 1999 Commercial banks 49.9 46.6 38.9 50.7 50.3 44.3 Cooperative banks 45.3 52.3 59.6 24.7 27.2 37.1 Of which: savings banks 17.4 18.7 19.8 3.9 4.8 7.6 Others 4.8 1.1 1.5 24.6 22.5 18.6

Sources: Commission bancaire (2000), lacoue-labarthe (2001)

But the SME market is an explicit target for the savings banks group, as stated in recent commercial strategy papers released by the CNCE – along with the so-called “professional” market, that is the market of loans to professionals (medical doctors, lawyers…)242. The position on those specific markets depends greatly on the specific history of local Caisses – which accounts for the heterogeneity mentioned above. For instance, the CE of Picardie’s larger than average market shares in small firm lending are due to the acquisition of a leasing firm in 1995.

Market, clientele and product strategies have of course evolved together. The need to move into new markets, or to remain competitive in traditional markets, stimulated savings banks in both countries to innovate and multiply the number of products offered, while services tailored to the clients grew in importance.

242 The market for professionals corresponds to lending below 1.5 million euros; the market for small and medium size enterprises (SMEs) corresponds to lending between 1.5 and 15 million euros. Lending above that amount belongs to the corporate market.

230 For instance, one of the innovations of the early 1990s in the French savings banks group, the “Compte Satellis”, a treasury management service, was developed in 1991, at a time when the newly re-dimensioned group sought to enter corporate markets. As a top savings bank official said in the late 1980s: “The opening of the squirrel [the savings banks groups’ nickname] to the business firm’s universe corresponds to a strategy that needs to be pursued up to the end so that not to lose touch with competition”243.

8.2.4 From core businesses to large groups

The corporate strategies pursued by savings banks in the 1980s and 1990s relate to the shift in corporate boundaries analysed in chapter 6. Corporate restructuring, mergers, and acquisitions were a means to pursue the strategy of diversification just analysed, so as to become a universal bank or a multi-functional group. Conversely, diversification and competition in all markets were necessary to ensure the sustainability of external growth (M&As) strategies. French savings banks’ acquisition of the Crédit Foncier de France in 2003, belongs to that logic – as has been the continuous effort to build partnerships and set up specialised subsidiaries.

As an interviewee from the CNCE said,

In order to build all those national structures, we have to make partnerships, create profit centres. All these subsidiaries will be listed. To be able to maximise, a large banking group must be present on all types of activities (métiers). All of those structures must be united within the group244.

This strategy was, as we saw in chapter 6, systematically pursued by the French savings banks ‘network head’ after 1988. Subsidiaries built after 1988 by the CENCEP, with the CDC or specialised institutions, covered: off-balance-sheet activities, such as OPCVM Écureuil-Gestion (created in 1989), life insurance (Écureuil-Vie), damage insurance (MURACEF), leasing (Bail Écureuil, Mur Écureuil, Cicobail), capital-risk (Épargne Développement), project financing (Ingecep, created in 1990).

243 A top official at a SOREFI, cited in Le Méridional, June 9th, 1989. 244 Interview, 24/04/02.

231 8.3 Convergence and Resilience

8.3.1 Cyclical change or convergence?

Most of the changes presented above are common to all category of banks. In other words, the move towards universal banks is not specific to savings banks in either country. Banks tend increasingly to act in the same way: offer similar products to similar clients in the same markets, following comparable commercial targets. There is a clear trend towards operational isomorphism. This is true even for those credit institutions that were least considered as “banks”. This is the case, for instance, of the French Post office, which during the 1990s gradually asserted its banking identity. In 1994, for example, it gained (from the State245) the right to practice overdrafts; in 1998, it gained the right to pull back postal current accounts’ encours (Comptes courants postaux, ou CCP) worth 25 billion euros from the Treasury to one of its subsidiary (Efiposte).

The evidence displayed above therefore provides strong support both to convergence theories and to the ‘systemic congruence’ view also adopted by VOC scholars. However, this is not the end of the story. A more careful look at the data shows that strong divergence forces are at play beneath this broad converging trend.

8.3.2 The persistence of market niches: products…

The convergence story ignores, first of all, the persistence of market niches, which lead to divergent business strategies. What savings banks lost in statutory and legal peculiarities, they gained in building on their competitive advantages in specific niches. This is the argument made by De Boissieu, among others (De Boissieu, 2000).

• France

French savings banks are aggressively moving towards the corporate lending market. However they are still a small player in that market – and they know their real strength is household lending. All interviewees in the French savings banks group acknowledged this: “At the end of the day, that’s were our natural market is” said one of them246.

245 Since 1990, every four years the Postal office negotiates with the State, under a so-called contrat de plan (Planning contract), its strategy and its public service obligations. 246 Interview, March 2002.

232 The savings bank group, furthermore, remains among the main lenders to local governments, and the main providers of credit to public housing programs. In addition, the Livret A still represents a sizeable part of savings banks revenue.

What about other non-bank resources? The first section showed that French savings banks greatly diversified their offer of credit and services, but also of collect instruments, i.e. savings and deposits accounts. Looking more closely at French savings banks’ balance sheet structure, however, one quickly notices that a large chunk of non-bank liabilities consists of “special regime” savings accounts: Livret A247, of course, but also Pel, Lep, Pep, Codevi… Those collecting instruments represented 87% of non-bank lending in 2000, against 13% for credit and current accounts248.

The case of the LEP is interesting. Created in 1982, the Livret d’Épargne Populaire (LEP, or popular savings bankbook) was originally destined for low income households – individuals exempted from income tax, or paying a tax below a certain level. Conditions of access were broadened by a 1997 ministerial decision, setting a ceiling of 660 euros. Return for LEPs was originally set at the Livret A rate level, with a supplement to compensate the real negative return on Livret A, which persisted until the mid 1980s. Once real return on Livret A, however, returned to “normal”, the advantage given to LEP rate was maintained249.

Therefore, one can conclude that French savings banks did choose to diversify and diminish their reliance on the Livret A, which was preventing them from becoming fully-fledged banks; but at the same time, diversification took very familiar forms. In other words, French savings banks ventured into new activities by relying on “old” or traditional business practices and behaviour.

247 That part of Livret A not destined to the CDC. 248 Source: Groupe Caisse d’Épargne, Rapport Annuel 2000. 249 As emphasised by in Nasse and Noyer, 2003 (annex 2).

233 • Italy

In Italy, too, product diversification and homologation with commercial banks are neither complete nor irreversible. In 1981, in the Italian savings banks journal, an observer noted that the de-specialisation wave that started in the 1970s would be reversed, and that “the time has come to put in place a new specialisation, which would justify, within the frame of a pluralistic banking system, the existence of [bank] categories” (Ruozi, 1981, p.438).

The same observer added that while savings banks had to a large extent assimilated the operational characteristics of commercial banks, they maintained a “proper physionomy”, both on the assets and the liabilities side. The high proportion of liabilities made up of clients’ deposits (versus other bank loans, for instance) was evidence of the persistent rooting of savings banks in local markets. Ruozi further described a “complementary intermediation” to that done by commercial banks, corresponding to the “functional specialisation” of the Italian banking system. But divergence did not originate in persistence or path dependency. Ruozi equally showed that the shift from loans to bonds, which characterised Italian savings banks’ assets in the 1970s, reversed the postwar trend, which had seen a shift from bonds to loans (Ruozi, 1977).

The same comment could be made today. A longer-term perspective would show that the convergence of liabilities does not change the fact that savings banks have long been characterised by a heavy reliance on deposits from households. This was true in 1981 (see Figliolia, 1981), and still holds today. Conversely, the current shift to lending reverses a previous trend which itself reversed a previous one.

There is, then, a specificity in savings banks’ product strategies. Such a strategy is not opposed to that followed by commercial banks. As Figliolia noted in 1981, there is “no dualism or alternative, but complementarity and development of commercial activities in strict linkage with other activities” (Figliolia, 1981).

234 8.3.3 … And markets and territories

• France

As emphasised above, French savings banks are still heavily dependent upon their retail markets for their income. In particular, the Caisses d’épargne remain a major provider of special savings accounts to households. In addition, French savings banks hold niche positions in the lending market for local governments and for associations (non-governmental organisations). Savings banks’ large market shares in these two specific lending markets owe to their historical legacy, and in particular their experience of lending under the Minjoz law250 framework. The Minjoz law, as mentioned in chapter 5, was the result of heavy lobbying by savings banks through key politicians (of whom Minjoz himself), aimed at enlarging their operational scope. The Minjoz law created another, very specific intermediation circuit within the ‘Treasury circuit’ analysed in chapter 4.

Under this framework, savings banks could ‘sponsor’ borrowers (local governments) by presenting them to the CDC for lending. Out of that ‘sponsoring’ the Caisses earned a fixed commission. In 1971, the CE gained the right to manage lending contingents directly – assuming risks and earning interests251. Those funds were, at first, mainly aimed at financing investments into collective infrastructures – transportation, public housing…

In the early 1980s de-centralisation reforms passed by the Socialist governments increased local governments’ financing needs and fed the Minjoz intermediation circuit. After 1986, the majority of “Minjoz contingent” funds were destined for social housing. By the end of 1990, the government decided to put an end to those de-centralised Minjoz contingents; thereafter, Minjoz loans would be made solely by the Caisse des Dépôts. However, the Caisses d’Épargne continued providing funds to local governments (out of ‘normal’ resources) for financing investments into social housing252. During the 1990s, the Caisses d’épargne strengthened their position in the local government market by offering new financial products and services, such as project finance (through Ingecep, a product created in 1990), treasury management…

250 Law of June 24th, 1950. 251 CENCEP, Pour mieux connaître la Caisse d’Épargne, November 1984. 252 CENCEP, La Caisse d’Épargne: une mutation réussie, Paris: October 1991.

235 As for associations, savings banks were authorised in the early 1980s to finance the investments of those associations who benefited from local governments’ guarantee (under the Minjoz framework). Here again, their strong retail position at the local level, along with their local networks, helped tie strong links with associations.

• Italy

The Italian savings banks’ territorial rooting has long constituted the core of their identity. At their 1981 meeting in La Spezia, savings banks officials underlined the usefulness of savings banks as a category, and the necessity to distinguish oneself from other banks not in terms of banking products, but in terms of banking segments (Lisanti, 1981). Recent works have shown how savings banks’ business remains closely linked to local economic systems. Farabullini and Gobbi have shown, for instance, that savings banks remained, throughout the 1990s, the main providers of bank lending to small and medium firms belonging to industrial districts alongside Banche popolari, and ahead both of commercial banks and cooperative banks (Farabullini & Gobbi, 1997). In sum, savings banks have kept their leading role within Italy’s “localistic” banking system (Locatelli, 1998b).

Furthermore, Bongini and Locatelli argue that “in contrast to other banks, savings banks have chosen, following the liberalisation of bank branching, to intensify their presence in their regions of origin, which constitutes a specificity even with respect to Banche popolari, characterised by the density of local rooting” (Bongini and Locatelli, 1998: p.216).

8.3.4 The role of non-profit objectives in savings banks’ business strategy

As mentioned in the introduction and chapter 3, savings banks’ corporate identity is linked in part to the importance of non-profit activities financed by their revenues. However, the transformation of savings banks in the two countries had a profound impact on those non-profit activities – and their fate diverged in the two cases.

236 • Italy

The role of non-profit objectives in savings banks’ business strategy is marginal since the unambiguous divorce between banking business and general interest activities that took place in the early 1990s. The Legislative Decree 356/1990 specified the sectors of intervention. A 1991 law253 made mandatory for the Foundations to dedicate part of their annual revenues254 to constitute special funds at the regional level and at the disposal of voluntary associations. Non-profit objectives, therefore, were entirely transferred to the newly born Foundations.

• France

Like their Italian counterparts, French savings banks have long been committed to redistributing part of their revenue to the local economy, mainly through grants or zero-interest loans. In France, this tradition is associated with the diffusion of public baths and “workers’ gardens” (jardins ouvriers) in the late XIXth and early XXth century. This practice was essentially the prerogative of the local Caisses. Until 1994 there had never been any successful attempt to centralise, or at least coordinate such activities. In 1994 a Foundation was created: called “Fondation Caisses d’Épargne: Agir Contre l’Exclusion” (Savings banks foundation against social exclusion), it was set up to rationalise the uses of the fortune personnelle of the single Caisses. It defined three axes for intervention: fight against illiteracy, fight against the exclusion of the elderly, and fight against the exclusion of the unemployed.

The 1999 reform represented a major turning point for French savings banks’ non-profit activities. The law, indeed, obliged savings banks to direct part of their revenue to non-profit activities – the so-called “projets d’économie locale et sociale” (social and local economy projects, or PELS). The PELS correspond to the savings banks’ “general interest missions” (missions d’intérêt général, or MIG), recognised by law. The FNCE, whose mission was to coordinate non-profit activities at the national level, defined in 1999 three main axes for intervention, drawing on savings banks’ variable past experience: “local development” (including loans and subsidies for firm creation), “social cohesion” (subsidies to associations fighting illiteracy, for instance), and “quality of life” (housing, environment…).

253 Law n.266, August 11th, 1991, article 15. 254 Specifically, one fifteenth of their revenues, net.

237 What makes French savings banks original, especially compared to their Italian counterparts, is that non-profit activities are pursued along for-profit ones. The linkage is even stronger since, as a top FNCE official said,

In Italy, Fondations get their revenue from their assets, whereas in France, if the CE does not make profits, there won’t be any MIG255.

And according to another respondent,

The French situation is very peculiar: it’s the law that gives MIG to the CE. We are not sad about that. This situation is linked to history and to the culture of CE. It’s an incentive to make profits256.

This second quote, however, underlines the ambiguity of PELS. Yes, there is an incentive to pursue non-profit activities that is nestled within the very core mechanism of profit-making. But doesn’t it mean that, reciprocally, PELS could be conceived as a somewhat other form of profit making?

In fact, looking at the substance of some PELS themselves, for instance those within the “local development” axis, one quickly notices that they are more like capital-risk. This is duly acknowledged (within the Group) by the Fédération257. Asked about the linkages between redistributive goals and corporate interest, one interviewee responded:

We try not to link the two: it is not because we support an association that we will force it to open an account with us. We are very careful not to mix the two: first because we would compete with ourselves, secondly because it’s very complex258.

Added to the ambiguity regarding the nature of PELS, and the expectations nourished by the Caisses about them, is the ambiguity about the status of PELS within the day-to-day business activities of savings banks. There is no coherent practice across Caisses d’Épargne: MIG are sometimes the direct responsibility of a Directoire member; sometimes they are managed by junior staff.

255 Interview, 24/04/02. 256 Interview, 24/04/02. 257 For instance in the appendix to the internal document Orientations des projets d’économie locale et sociale des Caisses d’Épargne 258 Interview, 27.06.02.

238 In Picardie, for instance, responsibility for the PELS belongs to the Direction for Communication (headed by a junior manager). Besides the issue of location of MIG within the organisation, there is the issue of the sheer means attributed to their management. At the Fédération, all respondents acknowledged this was an issue. In Paris, for instance, only five agencies have someone specialised in MIG. As a respondent belonging to a regulatory authority told me in an euphemistic way,

One can question oneself about the means savings banks give themselves to manage those PELS259.

Overall, therefore, the exact “meaning” of PELS within the new Group is a moving target. But in the French case, in contrast to the Italian one, non-profit missions and activities have actually been reinforced by the law, rather than weakened or dissociated from profit objectives.

8.3.5 The persistence of differences among savings banks

Besides the arguments made above (about market niches), convergent trends that can be observed at an aggregate level also lose salience when looking at disaggregated data. This is especially true for Italy. Figures 8.5 and 8.6 show the balance of savings banks revenues between ‘old’ banking activities (the interest margin – right scale) and ‘new’ ones (revenues from services – left scale), in 1986 and 2000. What emerges from these data is the increased heterogeneity between savings banks over time, in terms of revenue diversification.

That diversity can be explained in the following terms. In the early 1990s, once savings banks were enabled to merge and expand on new markets, only the largest savings banks – and those integrated within a group – succeeded in diversifying their balance sheet structure. In addition, decreasing interest rates in the 1990s automatically reduced all savings banks’ interest margin, but those who suffered most were the banks essentially relying on lending to households and small firms – i.e. the smaller savings banks. These banks displayed a limited capacity or willingness to engage in new markets and the divide grew between these banks and the ones that did choose to invest in the development of new skills and services.

259 Interview, 06.03.03.

239 Whereas, in 1994 for instance, Cariplo clearly stood as an outlier in terms of its share of revenues generated from services as opposed to gains from traditional banking activities, by 2000 a small group of large savings banks had taken the same path. This trend explains why, on average, savings banks’ balance sheet structure seems to have converged on commercial banks’.

8.4 Discussion

8.4.1 The role of competition

Starting from the early 1980s in France, late 1980s in Italy, competition in the banking sector accelerated and intensified. The number of bank windows has greatly increased in Italy, along with the evolution of the volume of intermediated funds – that is, total banking collect and lending. The first clearly outpaced the second during the 1990s. This is a clear indicator of intensified competition, although still insufficient.

Indeed, it is first of all limited to the retail segment of the banking market, in which localised contact with the clients is a key factor of success. Secondly, it is theoretically possible that the multiplication of bank windows did not affect competition – in the case of segmented markets, where the increase in the number of bank branches helped credit institutions to reach out to their respective markets and clienteles, without affecting other credit institutions. This was obviously not the case in Italy in the 1990s, and the assumed correlation between the ratio number of bank windows / volume of intermediated funds and the intensity of competition seems to be valid.

A same observation could be made in France, where bank windows have increased in number, although to a lower proportion than in Italy. The issue is how did heightened competition affect banks’ strategy? During the 1980s and 1990s, the interest margin in Italian banking has diminished. In other words, the revenue drawn from traditional banking activities (collect and lending) has decreased, revealing a compression of passive and active interest rates260, at a time when wholesale banking is again in crisis261.

260 Passive interests are the interests paid by banks to accounts holders; active interests are the interests charged by banks on lenders. 261 See “Banque française: la réallocation des actifs en faveur des activités de détail sera durable”, Les Echos, April 22, 2003.

240 Such an outcome is often attributed in the literature, in part at least, to the effects of competition. Competition plays out either through an immediate threat on current market positions or an expected threat on future market positions. Competition, therefore, erodes monopoly or dominant positions in all segments of the market, thus leading to an alignment of the price of credit (interest rates) across all credit institutions. Again, factors other than competition have certainly played a role in the reduction in banks’ interest margins – above all, the monetary policy pursued by the central bank, in a context of low inflation.

Beyond prices (and interest rates), however, competition also provokes changes in the qualitative aspects of corporate behaviour – the markets, clienteles targeted, the products and services offered. In France, all savings banks staff interviewed insisted on competition as being the main driver for a strategic re-positioning towards new clienteles and markets. As one of them said,

I don’t think we can disconnect ourselves from the market: Crédit Agricole or Crédit Mutuel don’t do anything else [than us], but they have better results (coefficients d’exploitation)262.

This is a long-held view for some of the Group’s top executives. In 1989, for instance, Charles Milhaud, the future president of the CNCE and one of the main actors of change, said in a newspaper interview

We are in a new economic and financial configuration: how not take it into account and prepare our Caisses to analyse all constraints created by it ? Market demands produce changes that touch on our traditional activities and force us to integrate within our instruments all financial management tools now used by all credit institutions263.

If, in the 1970s, competition was less real than perceived (or anticipated), this changed in the early 1980s, with the creation of ‘banalised’ savings instruments – i.e. savings products available to all credit institutions. In addition, in August 1983 the rate served to LEP holders was set one point above that served to Livret A holders (8.50% against 7.50%) – which, in a context of persistent inflation, could do nothing but decrease Livret A’s relative attractiveness compared to other savings products.

262 Interview, 27.06.02. 263 In Revue des Caisses d’Épargne, February 1991, p.19.

241 The same awareness of rising competition and its impact on savings banks’ market shares can be found in Italy. Repeatedly, since the late 1970s, savings banks officials warned that change was an imperative in the face of competition. A defensive strategy was called for by top officials at several major savings banks in the mid-1980s: savings banks ought to renew the way they did business; otherwise, they would be crowded out by new intermediaries (Acciaro, Giovando, Molinari, Tommasini, 1985).

A similar point was made in 1985 by the then president of ACRI, who emphasised

The impossibility of survival in a niche that, sooner or later, would push the [bank] out of a continuously evolving market, which promises an agitated existence for those firms that do not quickly adapt264.

Although competition, whether effective or expected, did certainly play a role in bringing change in savings banks’ corporate strategies, it does not, however, explain why savings banks chose one specific strategy, or why strategies differed from one savings bank to another (in the Italian case). Secondly, the emphasis put on competitive behaviour does not automatically respond to changes in savings banks’ external environment, i.e. increased competition: it reflects specific dynamics at play within the organisation of savings banks in both countries, namely what I have called the “quest for autonomy” and the “pursuit of profitability”.

8.4.2 The role of changes in the regulatory environment

The impact of regulatory change on savings banks’ change in corporate behaviour is multi-faceted. First of all, the intensification of competition analysed above can be partly attributed to key macro regulatory changes, especially banking market de-segmentation (see chapter 5), which put an end to ‘top-down compartmentalisation’ (see chapter 4 as well). Secondly, regulatory changes specifically aimed at the savings banks sector (the 1983 and 1999 reforms in France, the 1990 reform in Italy) might have induced savings banks to opt for specific courses of action. For instance, the lift of restrictions on corporate lending, in the case of French savings banks, certainly helps to explain the rapid entry of savings banks into the corporate market.

264 Ferrari, 1985, p.1039.

242 However, again, as mentioned in chapter 4, changes in the regulatory framework led to the transformation of the framework of constraints and incentives faced by savings banks in both countries. It did not force savings banks into a specific course of action. To illustrate this distinction, one should think of the case of check accounts, which French savings banks were first authorised to offer in 1978: until 1981, very few Caisses actually explored this new opportunity, showing that other forces were at play than orient Caisses’ behaviour – organisational capacity, management’s availability, clients’ responsiveness…

The issue here is first to understand to what extent changes in corporate behaviour were determined by regulatory changes. It is, secondly, to understand how the variety of strategies pursued by savings banks can be explained by regulatory change. As for the first issue, it seems that, especially in the Italian case, those savings banks that preserved their specific business identity did so in the absence of any political-legal support or protection. Historically, as mentioned above, no substantial limitations were attached to savings banks’ activities (vis-à-vis commercial banks’ ones). Rather, until the mid-1980s the existing regulatory regime established a strong “firing wall” between short and long-term credit. Savings banks, as most publicly owned and commercial banks, were entitled to provide only short and medium term lending. But the Italian Casse di risparmio were on a much more equal footing with their commercial competitors than were their French counterparts. In addition, a 1978 decision by the Credit and Saving Governmental Committee (Comitato Interministeriale per il Credito e il Risparmio, o CICR) ended the ban on the creation of new bank branches, which led to a rapid increase of the number of bank windows in Italy. A further 1989 decision by the CICR totally liberalised the ATM opening regime265. Finally, a 1993 law, the Testo unico in materia creditizia, while incorporating the Second European directive on Credit institutions, drastically reduced the number of legal categories of banks266.

265 CICR deliberation of January 20, 1989. 266 Until the 1993 Testo unico, Italy had 10 broadly defined legal categories of banks: Istituti di credito di diritto pubblico (they were 6 in 1988) and Banche di interesse nazionale (3), which were state-owned (through the public holding IRI), Banche di credito ordinario or commercial banks (110), Banche popolari cooperative that had a cooperative status (127), Casse di risparmio (76), Monti di credito su pegno 1a categoria (7) and Monti di credito su oegno 2a categoria (2), both categories which were attached to savings banks, Casse rurali e artigiane that became the cooperative banks (726), foreign bank subsidiaries (38), and Istituti di categoria (5), that is,

243 In his speech to the Camera dei Deputati to present the Ciampi-Visco reform design, the relatore said that “Too many banks still limit themselves to collect and lending. Everybody knows that the rise of revenues from services is fundamental for banks to stay on the market. […] Savings management, product personalisation, corporate finance represent the challenge of the future. […] The legislator’s duty is to provide a certain framework for that process”267.

As for the second point, the Italian case clearly shows that a single set of regulatory constraints and incentives led to a variety of behaviours, thus questioning the explanatory strength of ‘regulation’ as a source of change.

The French case is more ambiguous, since a) the internal cohesion of savings banks and of the savings bank group was strengthened by regulatory authorities and b) there is no strong variety of strategies among savings banks. However, regarding the first point one can point out that the “privileged” status of the Livret A has been repeatedly questioned by policy-makers and regulators alike. In the 1996 annual report of the Commission Bancaire, Jean-Claude Trichet, the then Governor of the Banque de France, called for “restoring French banks’ profitability” and for ending the “distribution of certain specific products”. Behind that formulation many observers saw an implicit reference to the Livret A268. A few months later, a report by the Senate Finance Commission (so-called “Rapport Lambert”) called for the generalisation of the distribution of de-taxed bankbooks, such as Livret A (savings banks and Postal office) and the “Livret bleu” (distributed solely by the Postal office) – as well as a broader re-definition of the missions of savings banks. More recently, the Nasse-Noyer report, commissioned in 2003 by the Minister of the Economy, further questioned the necessity to maintain alive the Livret A.

Therefore, if, on the one hand, the principle of sector and group cohesion was regularly supported by regulatory authorities, on the other hand the latter did not support savings banks’ specialisation. Regulatory de- segmentation, which started in the 1970s and continued in the 1990s, was clearly aimed at creating a level-playing field within banking and finance and did not create pockets of protection and privilege for non-commercial banks.

267 Camera dei Deputati, Atti Parlamentari, Disegno di Legge n.3194, February 18th, 1998. 268 See for instance “Les Caisses d’épargne en danger”, in L’Humanité, December 13th, 1996.

244 In France, savings banks’ belated access to checking accounts (1978) and corporate lending (1985) coincided with the opening of “administered savings products” to other credit institutions: the Livret d’Epargne Populaire (popular savings book, or LEP) and the Compte d’Epargne Valeurs Industrielles (or CODEVI) were created in the early 1980s as a means given to commercial banks to tap into administered savings, while differentiating the sources of long-term finance (for housing and industry). In this context, the enlargement of savings banks operational scope was meant to balance commercial banks’ entry into administered savings.

In addition, the numerous changes that took place during the 1970s and 1980s did not lead the banks to automatically seize the new opportunities offered to them. For instance, deposit accounts, authorised in 1978, remained a marginal activity for many years. In 1984, for instance, or six years after the 1978 authorisation, deposit accounts still represented less than one percent of the Caisse d’Épargne des Bouches du Rhône’s total liabilities.

In both countries, therefore, neither the specific character of savings banks’ strategies nor their variety (in the Italian case) can be attributed to changes in regulation. A final argument against the regulation-driven explanation of change in corporate behaviour lies in the fact that, as shown in chapter 3, regulatory change in France (and, to a lesser extent, in Italy) was largely driven by savings banks themselves, since the postwar period (see Duet 1991). Duet speaks about “almost thirty years of endless lobbying for the authorisation to open checking accounts.” (Duet, 1986). Similarly, a top French savings banks official used the expression of “long march” in an article published in La Revue des Caisses d’Épargne in 1976, to qualify savings banks’ lobbying.

As emphasised in chapter 2, the various approaches inspired by new institutionalist theories claim that institutions shape (or structure) individual behaviour. The previous section already examined the relation between savings banks’ behaviour and regulation, which could be broadly understood as ‘political-legal’ institutions. VOC scholars often focus on the role played by several other institutions, among whom corporate finance and corporate governance. In the present case, it would be tricky to identify corporate finance institutions distinct from banks’ behaviour, since banks’ business is to “create” corporate finance. The next section will therefore discuss the role corporate governance institutions played in the shift in savings banks strategies, starting from the already mentioned IEF report, which argues that “the absence of majority [private] shareholders restricts market forces from being wholly effective in influencing banks’ current performances” (p.123).

245 Since both competition and regulation played a role in bringing about changes in savings banks’ strategies, but since neither competition nor regulation explains either the substance of such changes (Italian savings banks’ localism, French savings banks’ persistent reliance on traditional savings products) or the variety of strategies pursued, one has to turn to other two explanatory factors: the drive towards autonomy and the divergent quest for profitability.

8.4.3 The drive towards autonomy and the pursuit of profitability

The drive towards corporate autonomy has been a powerful factor behind the French savings banks’ gradual enlargement of their operational scope – while managerial autonomy was a strong driving force behind Italian savings banks’ changes in corporate behaviour. Corporate autonomy can be defined as the capacity of a firm to autonomously make key decisions about its resources and investment strategies. As seen in chapter 4, the emancipation of French savings banks from the CDC’s umbrella was a key motivation for savings banks executives. The transformation of French savings banks into ‘real’ banks, through the full control of their resources and the ability to determine autonomously the range of products they offered, meant a full emancipation from state-directed intermediation circuits. One does not need, however, to accept Duet’s teleological argument about the inevitability of such a transformation, akin to a return to the XIXth century origins (Duet, 1986: 148-149).

The issue of corporate autonomy is, however, a complex one. As we saw in chapter 6, French savings banks’ shift towards autonomy went hand in hand with group centralisation, which led to a decrease of autonomy at the local banks. As an interviewee, at the CNCE, said:

The CNCE’s principle is to say «OK, les Caisses, you are grown ups, you take care of the means to reach those objectives»269.

Managerial autonomy, in contrast to corporate autonomy, can be defined as the capacity of managers to build on their technical (and managerial) legitimacy to make key decisions about a firm’s orientation. Managerial autonomy was a factor in French savings banks modernisation, too.

269 Interview, 23.04.02.

246 In fact, gaining autonomy from the State (corporate autonomy) was associated with increased managerial autonomy, at least until the 1999 law and the apparition of owners. But as the previous chapter has shown, savings banks managers were then in a (strong) position to limit the effective exercise of control by owners.

In the Italian case, corporate autonomy was less an apparent problem. Savings banks were already autonomous entities by the early 1980s (from both a legal and economic point of view), in contrast to their French counterparts. As Figliolia noted in 1981, “there is no regulation that attributes to other banks the autonomy given to Casse di Risparmio” (Figliola, 1981: 1017). However, as noted in chapter 5, at least the largest savings banks were closely knit within power networks dominated by the Christian Democrat party on the ‘political’ side, and the Treasury on the institutional side. It is probable, therefore, that corporate autonomy played a role as a force for change – but its effects are likely to have been ambiguous.

Managerial autonomy is also an ambiguous factor in the Italian case since, as we saw in chapter 5, Foundations remain an important role as minority owners in many savings banks.

A second powerful factor for generating change has been the shift in savings banks’ corporate objectives. Here the concepts developed by Quack and others around the “social structure of performance” are useful. Morgan and Quack (1999), and Salomon (1999), have shown that different measures of performance, which entail different social structures, are at play in the banking sector. Beyond performance, however, one could argue that corporate objectives are social structures as well, and their substance does not automatically follow from changes in the external environment – such as competition.

In France, as mentioned in the previous chapters, until the mid-1970s savings banks were considered as a quasi-public institution collecting savings. Their transformation into real banks started through the ranks of a minority of savings banks managers and executives who carried on a different vision of the corporate mission savings banks should pursue than the non-profit, localised objectives then in vigor. This ‘business profitability’ objective grew in importance over the years, and became the top priority for savings banks.

247 As Charles Milhaud said in 1989: “The Spanish started [lending to business firms] in 1978. Since then they have become hyper-performing”270. According to a CNCE staff, the current commercial strategy of the savings banks group is entirely geared towards generating

new potential for growth in revenues (PNB) – since that in retail, there are no longer important growth potentials271.

In contrast, several interviewees (in particular the union members) spoke of savings banks abandoning their core mission, which is, according to them, to focus on lower middle class and poor households. As one of them stated,

What can we say? The savings banks are losing their soul272.

There is, therefore, a “conflict of visions” within savings banks, between those who wish to pursue profitability objectives similar to those of commercial banks, and those arguing that savings banks should follow more ‘social’ corporate objectives.

This conflict of visions draws on the drive towards autonomy analysed in the previous section. Managers – and in particular CNCE staff – built their technical legitimacy, and therefore their autonomy and power, on the profitability goals underlying savings banks’ performance273. In contrast, the staff who have remained ‘faithful’ to the old corporate objectives are locked in a minority power position, de-legitimised by managers’ use of external factors to buffer their arguments – which repeatedly surfaced during interviews, through references to ‘competition’, ‘our competitors’, or ‘customers’. Interestingly, however, the actual balance of power depends on a new factor, namely, the sociétaires, whose present non-involvement in savings banks’ strategies maintains managers’ autonomy and the domination of profitability goals over other objectives. This could change in the future.

270 Charles Milhaud interviewed in Professions du Sud-Est, September 1989. 271 Interview, 25.07.02. 272 Interview, 01.07.03. 273 Interestingly, among the specificities of the savings bank category emphasised by a former president of ACRI in the early 1980s were the fact that governance structures included persons (board members) who did not gain direct economic profit from their decisions; this allowed, in his words, to “temper that merchant’s instinct described by Bagehot” .

248 What about Italy? There, too, change in corporate behaviour was preceded by a shift in corporate objectives that reveal a conflict of visions. Along the 1980s, the ‘pursuit of profitability’ objective became widely shared amongst savings banks’ officials and top managers. This evolution can be observed through the proceedings of the multiple seminars, conferences, and annual meetings that took place during the period. At a meeting organised in 1981 by the Cassa di Risparmio della Spezia, for instance, several participants worried that in the name of functional specialisation savings banks would be forced into a specific role (that of guaranteeing savings), which would create an “operational cage” (Lisanti, 1981). In the same meeting, savings banks officials expressed their reluctance to indexing interest rates paid to depositors on inflation, and talked instead of fine-tuning pricing to specific products and clients; and of pushing for the development of services paid by the clientele. During the 1980s and 1990s, with the intensification of competition profitability received even more emphasis.

However, turning into for-profit enterprises did not necessarily mean losing savings banks’ specific business identity. In the 1980s, Italian savings banks could still be defined as “innovative firms in the roots of tradition” (Ferrari, 1985). Tradition, that is – especially savings banks’ specific governance structures according to Ferrari – were good at ‘tempering the merchant’s instinct’ (Ferrari, 1985 – a reference to Bagehot’s famous formula). Ferrari also distinguished between profit seeking and profit maximising, arguing that in the case of savings banks, seeking profits was subordinate to ensuring high levels of equity and funding local public interest activities. Turning to services was, according to Figliolia (1981), the best way to re-assert savings banks’ peculiar identity.

However, again, those changes are not all-encompassing. Onado’s 1990 work on a sample of 108 Italian banks showed, for instance, that banking competition undeniably increased in Italy during the 1980s, but it did not result in fundamentally altering banking performance or business (Onado 1990). Increased competition was, according to Onado, a kind of “lop- sided process”, characterised by a mere transformation of bank revenues from direct intermediation to placement fees. “Alternatively stated, he continued, banks have not lost their relationship with the customer and that certainly helped maintain segmentation (by location, type of deposit, class of customer, size of accounts, etc.)” (Onado, 1990: 104). If the situation has changed much since the early 1990s, savings banks remained, at least until the early 2000s, characterised by their localism and orientation towards small and medium firms (see section 8.3 above).

249 Figure 8.5: Italian savings banks' revenues from 'old' and 'new' banking activities in 1986 (in bn lire)

1,000,000

800,000

600,000

400,000

200,000

0 0 200,000 400,000 600,000 800,000 1,000,000

Figure 8.6: Italian savings banks' revenues from 'old' and 'new' banking activities in 2000 (in bn lire)

1,000,000

800,000

600,000

400,000

200,000

0 0 200,000 600,000 400,000 800,000 1,000,000

250 9. CONCLUSIONS

9.1 Summary of findings

Finding # 1: Simultaneous convergence and divergence of regulatory regimes

The regulatory reforms of savings banks in France and Italy present several commonalities: in both cases, the reforms aimed at (i) statutory normalisation, (ii) sector re-organisation and (iii) market de-segmentation and increased operational homologation. At the same time, however, there are considerable differences in the final (as of 2004…) outcome of the regulatory process. In Italy, the savings banks lost their specific legal status in 1990, and regulators and policy-makers encouraged savings banks to form alliances with other types of banks, thus encouraging the break-up of the sector. In France, by contrast, policy-makers guaranteed the unity and cohesion of the sector and transformed the nascent group into a cooperative holding. In other words, savings banks were placed at the opposite ends of the renewed public (cooperative) vs. private (commercial) balance in banking in the two countries.

Finding # 2 – Divergence as change rather than persistence

The factors of divergence and convergence do not fit neatly with the external pressures vs. internal (institutional) resistance story. The French case, in particular, shows that both divergence from the Italian case and from the “market-based” ideal-type resulted from a change of path, i.e. the transformation of savings banks into a cooperative group.

251 Finding # 3: Regulatory reform as a mix between ideas, interests and institutions

Regulatory reform in both countries resulted from the intertwining of political change, change in economic conditions and the coming of age of specific ideas regarding the nature of the banking firm and the role of the state in the economy.

Finding # 4: In both countries, one can observe the same shift from sector to group coordination…

Changes in savings banks’ corporate and sector boundaries have led to a shift from sector to group coordination in both France and Italy. Corporate boundaries have been profoundly transformed in both countries, where most savings banks have merged or formed close alliances with other banks. Simultaneously, there has been a decline in sector associations’ strength; and the re-shuffling of “sector banks” or central cashier corresponded to an increased centralisation at the group level – and the gradual obsolescence of sector financial solidarity.

Finding # 5: …However, group coordination came with increased sector cohesion in France, while in Italy it accompanied the breakdown of the savings banks sector

Despite finding # 4, there is no unambiguous convergence at the coordination level between the two cases. In France, group centralisation occurred strictly within the (old) sector boundaries, benefiting from the maintenance of sector-specific protections guaranteed by policy-makers; and the sector bank and head of network functions were merged into a powerful holding. In Italy, in contrast, group centralisation took place at the expense of sector cohesion: large savings banks “quit” the category to form powerful, integrated banking groups with commercial and privatised banks. In addition, savings banks’ specific financial linkages were either abandoned or subsumed within the banking system as a whole.

252 Finding # 6: Such institutional change at the coordination level owes much to organisational dynamics

Shifts in corporate and sector boundaries, and in coordination modes, cannot be attributed solely to increased returns to scale or to politics. Indeed, politics did play a role, but regulatory reforms were strongly influenced by some key savings banks actors and cannot, therefore, be considered as a purely independent variable. As per increased returns to scale (the key mechanism invoked by tenants of the narrow version of path dependence theory), it is difficult to identify, especially in the Italian case, a homogeneous set of actors all pushing for institutional change (in the same direction). Rather, shifts in coordination resulted from organisational dynamics: i.e., the alliance between a small group of top savings banks actors and of regulators and policy-makers interested in favouring the emergence of strong banking groups (either within or across the savings banks sector), while other savings banks actors followed suit (French case) or chose another path (Italian case).

Finding # 7: Divergence as a by-product of change

Again, divergence in the evolution of coordination modes is not simply the result of institutional stickiness. In both cases, the gradual disengagement of the State, along with the activism of the groups mentioned above, led to the re-organisation of coordination along “principles of differentiation” already present, although under a latent form, in the past: territorial dualism in Italy, versus “sector” (cooperative versus commercial) competition in France.

Finding # 8: French and Italian savings banks differ as to what solutions were brought, during the 1980s and the 1990s, to the ownership problem…

The lack of clear ownership was one of the issues at the top of policy- makers and savings banks’ top executives’ agenda in both countries the early 1980s. However, this same problem was solved by different means in the two countries. In France, after a long period (1983-1999) in which ownership was never clarified, the 1999 reform “created” new owners by transforming savings banks into a cooperative group.

253 In Italy, the 1990 reform addressed the ownership issue upfront by separating savings banks, which became joint-stock companies, from new owners, the Foundations, in turn owned by public and local entities. The subsequent decade saw a struggle between Foundations and policy- makers around the issue of effective control of savings banks.

Finding # 9: …However, the renewed corporate governance arrangements, in both cases, reflect the rise of managerial power

In practice, however, the new corporate governance mechanisms implemented in the 1990s ended up, in both cases, strengthening managerial control over savings banks. In Italy, political conflicts around the issue of banks’ ownership and control allowed managers to gradually strengthen their power. In France, the creation of new owners (the “sociétaires”) did not translate into effective ownership. Corporate governance mechanisms proposed by savings banks’ management, as well as the effective balance of power within the savings banks group and the lack of interest of the new owners towards their power of control, all played in favour of the strengthening of managerial power to the expense of the sociétaires.

Finding # 10: Again, institutional factors are not sufficient to explain these changes in savings banks’ ownership and governance

Regulatory changes had a direct impact on ownership and governance of savings banks in both countries. However, those changes were partly endogenous. Other institutional factors, such as the shift in coordination modes, co-evolved with ownership patterns, rather than shaping them.

Finding # 11: Over the past two decades, savings banks in both countries have aligned their business practice to that of commercial banks

Market de-segmentation, shifts from structural to prudential regulations, changes in clients’ attitudes and preferences, technological innovation, all contributed to a sharp increase in competitive pressures in the banking sector. Such pressures have led savings banks to enlarge the scope of their operations; adopt commercial targets and strategies widespread among commercial banks; behave more like a profit-making firm and less like a non-profit institution.

254 Finding # 12: However, savings banks have retained key distinct operational features

French savings banks’ collect is still heavily dominated by administered or semi-administered savings products. Their lending is still mainly oriented towards households and, to a lesser extent, local governments and non- governmental organisations. The cooperative status of the French savings banks group has sanctified the traditional redistributive mission of savings banks – although actual practice is ambiguous. In Italy, savings banks or former savings banks still lend to small-and medium enterprises and are a key financial partner of industrial districts. Again, the maintenance of local rooting is not a homogeneous phenomenon across the Italian savings banks sector.

Finding # 13: Such operational and business distinctiveness is, again, the outcome of various factors – the drive to autonomy, compartmentalisation…

9.2 Discussion

9.2.1 Research questions

The two overarching questions formulated at the outset of this study where: (i) what are the changes undergone by savings banks in France and Italy in the 1980s and 1990s – and do such changes show convergence or divergence across the two countries? and (ii) what explains French and Italian savings banks’ apparent different trajectories in front of common pressures to adjust?

The findings synthetised above help us respond to these two questions. A further discussion of this findings follows.

255 9.2.2 Multiple patterns of change

• Convergence and divergence

The findings presented in chapter 6, 7 and 8 show that convergence, co-evolution and divergence forces are simultaneously at play in the French and Italian banking sectors. There is convergence on a third model: the two cases show a move from the state-administered model to a hybrid bank-market model of finance. There is co- evolution: both countries have moved (in parallel) from state- administered financial systems to this new hybrid. There is divergence between the two cases: French savings banks have become an integrated cooperative banking group, epitomising France’s new functional dualism; Italian savings banks have ceased to exist as a category and taken on various paths mostly linked to territories, epitomising Italy’s new geographical dualism. One can therefore agree with Boyer, who argues that modern capitalism tends towards ‘homeostatic equilibria’ characterised by mixed convergence and divergence, both being two among a multiple array of possible configurations (among which collapse, catch-up…) (Boyer, 1996).

These observations are consistent with two hypotheses recently explored by the literature on comparative capitalisms, namely: (i) firms (economic actors in general) face a multiplicity of orders and (ii) the very nature of institutional complementarities might favour change instead of resilience. The first hypothesis is both empirical and theoretical (see Whitley, 1992b and 1999; Fligstein, 1996; Hancké and Goyer, 2005). Empirical observation tells us that multiple patterns of adjustment (or behaviour) exist throughout economic systems. Theoretically, the hypothesis derives from the argument that national business systems are characterised by the co-existence of multiple logics or conventions that influence the behaviour of single firms. This hypothesis does not need to lead to a constructivist view of firms’ behaviour; as Hancké and Goyer point out, it is perfectly consistent with the view that “while institutional frameworks may be considerably more malleable and open than the conventional views assume, systemic constraints of internal coherence impose limits on this openness” (Hancké and Goyer, 2005: 60).

256 • Variety in time

As noted in Chapter 2, new institutionalist approaches to economic and industrial change mainly rely on one specific theory of change, namely, path dependence theory. Yet the conclusions exposed above point to a much murkier nature of changes in the political economy. The corporate strategies pursued by French and Italian savings banks perhaps best illustrate these multi-layered characteristics of change. The 1980s and 1990s showed the capacity of savings banks to quickly adapt to a changing competitive environment – through product diversification, entry into new markets, targeting new clienteles, adopting new business practices. There was, clearly, a change of path. At the same time, however, savings banks in both countries pursued a niche strategy, building on the segments of a banking market where they had the stronger position: administered savings products, mortgage lending, lending to small firms – thus relying on their territorial rooting. These are clear instances of path dependence. In addition, firms (savings banks) played a central role in the transformation of the banking system in both countries – a role recognised central in the most recent theories of institutional change (Pierson, 2003; Thelen, 2004; Streeck and Thelen, 2005), and is explored below.

9.2.3 A management-led modernisation process

• The role of institutions

What is the role of institutions in fostering and shaping change in savings banks’ behaviour? As seen in chapter 2, the neo-institutionalist theory at the basis of most comparative works on modern capitalism assumes that actors’ behaviour is shaped or influenced by institutions – through various mechanisms, as Hall and Taylor (2001) point out: coercion, mimetism, constraints and incentives… The evidence presented in this research suggests apparently contradictory observations.

Institutions have certainly played an important role in shaping the path of change in both countries. Polity-linked institutions have determined the pace of the reform and its outcome. Among those institutions, the electoral system and the party structure certainly played a role in the gap between reforms in France (early 1980s for the first wave) and in Italy (late 1980s).

257 As for the reform’s outcomes, the linkages between reform-minded policy-makers, technocrats and top savings banks officials help explain how the actual reform mostly embodied designs previously elaborated by the savings banks themselves. There is, therefore, a continuous and bilinear interaction between (policy) institutions and (banks’) strategy.

The role of coordination institutions is much more ambiguous. As chapter 6 has shown, at the outset of the 1980s sector organisation was stronger in Italy than in France; this relationship was reversed in the subsequent decade. Therefore, differences in outcomes (the diverging cohesion of the savings banks sector in both countries) cannot be attributed to institutional differences. As shown in chapter 6, the shift in corporate and sector boundaries within the French and Italian savings banks sector has much to do with a shift in the internal balance of power, to the benefit of savings banks’ senior managers. In the French case, top officials at the savings banks allied with bureaucrats and policy-makers to push forward the aggregation and centralisation of the savings banks group. As chapter 7 has shown, moreover, the acquisition of cooperative status and the institution of new owners did not threaten managers’ power within the group, since governance mechanisms were carefully designed so as to prevent direct control from them, and since the state regulators showed little interest in the effective exercise of ownership rights within the group.

In an interesting study of British clearing banks, Morison notes the “traditional supremacy of geography as the primary organisational dimension, both domestically and internationally” (Morison, 1994: 84). As mentioned in Chapter 1, Morison mentions two other “organising principles” in banking: pace of change, and interdependence between various banking businesses. These three principles, however, do not maintain equal importance throughout the years. In fact, according to Morison’s periodisation of organisational change in British clearing banks, “phase five” (the early 1990s) is characterised by the lowering importance of geography, which he could see, for instance, in the decline of the role of the regional director.

258 Morison’s historical analysis can be transferred to cross-country comparisons – since, in methodological terms, both types of analyses share an interest in variation-finding, be it across time or across space. This framework becomes especially enlightening for our comparison between France and Italy. It seems that the divergence that occurred between France and Italy, in the 1990s, operated precisely at the level of the organising principles: in France, regulatory, pluralistic segmentation gave way to functional specialisation, while in Italy, the same type of segmentation, once abandoned by the State, gave way to geographical dualism. In other words, geography as an organisational principle has seen its importance grow along with the dismemberment of state-sponsored segmentation – in contrast to the British case. Such thesis is close to the arguments put forward by Verdier (2002, 2003), cited in chapter 2: banking structure in industrialised countries is shaped by historical state centralisation.

All these observations point to the non-univocal relationship between institutions and individual (or aggregate) behaviour on the one hand; and between institutions and change on the other. In the cases of French and Italian savings banks, there are three distinct institutional dynamics. First, shifts in the macroeconomic and macro-regulatory regime (including the international monetary regime) have changed the matrix of constraints and incentives facing savings banks. Secondly, savings banks have reacted by adjusting their behaviour AND modifying (or helping to modify) the micro institutions they were submitted to: specific regulations, sector organisation, ownership and control. In this case, findings can illustrate the double-loop relationship between firms and institutions proposed elsewhere: “the degree of complementarity between institutions varies across societies and firms are able to use this variability, both within societies and across them, to develop new patterns of action that in turn contribute to the reshaping of institutions at the national and the international level.” (Morgan, 2005: 415) Third, the adjustment process has revealed the role played by the “meta-institutions” just mentioned: state centralisation and territorial segmentation.

• The forces of change: competition and management’s quest for autonomy

As chapter 5 has shown, the regulatory reforms at the root of modernisation were strongly influenced by the policy ideas promoted by savings banks managers, who benefited from their proximity to political power (at the regulatory and parliamentary levels).

259 Macroeconomic shocks and policy shifts in the 1970s left those actors with the conviction that the structural conditions of banking business would be unequivocally altered in the subsequent decade; by anticipating change, savings banks could shape the reform outcome in the direction wished by top management. In particular, savings banks could hope to (i) free themselves from the state; (ii) give themselves the means to build banking groups able to compete in a liberalised banking market. Both objectives fit within the top managers’ quest for managerial autonomy (from the state and the market).

Such quest for autonomy also drove the post-reform corporate restructuring process in both countries (chapter 6), as well as the changes in corporate governance (chapter 7). Savings banks’ top managers succeeded in building integrated groups, either encompassing the whole sector (as in France), or through cross-sector alliances mainly at the regional and inter-regional level (Italy). At the same time, management carried a move from state control and blurred ownership to private ownership and control; but this was a gradual change, and in both countries senior management kept the banks under control – either through specific corporate governance devices, as in France; or through minority but controlling stakes by Foundations in Italy, impeding new owners to take control.

9.3 Implications of the research

9.3.1 The implications of changes in the savings banks sector for the banking system as a whole

Changes in the savings banks sector may have, and in fact have had strong implications for national banking systems as a whole. First, as argued in chapter 1, savings banks represent a sizeable part of national banking systems throughout Europe – both in terms of assets (lending, especially to local government, small firms and mortgage to households) and liabilities (collect of households’ savings). French savings banks, for instance, accounted for 17.8% of all deposits in 2003, and 42.3% of lending to NGOs. Italian savings banks, in the mid-1990s, represented around 30% of deposits and 26% of lending to firms. More recent data are difficult to collect given the restructuring trend in the Italian banking sector that led to many mergers among savings banks or between savings banks and other categories of banks. The sheer quantitative importance of the savings banks sector means, as emphasised in the Introduction, that changes in that sector cannot leave other segments of the banking system unaffected.

260 Secondly, patterns of change in the savings banks sector show many similarities with those followed by other bank categories, i.e. commercial and cooperative banks. Such similarities can be attributed to two factors: (i) the occurrence of external shocks that force all banks to adjust in a similar way – that is, the de-segmentation of markets and the shift from structural to prudential regulation; (ii) mimetism, or isomorphism between banking categories.

Third, savings banks interact with other segments of the banking sector, through competition or corporate restructuring processes. Many large and medium-sized Italian savings banks, as we have seen, have participated in the mergers and acquisitions wave that has led to the constitution of Italy’s four major banking groups. On the business level, if savings banks have engaged in isomorphic behaviours, adopting business practices and goals from other banking categories, it is not unconceivable to think that in the process savings banks increased the creditability and the attractiveness of such business practices and goals for other banking actors.

9.3.2 The implications of changes in banking on national economic systems

A second broad implication of the research has to do with national capitalisms as a whole. As argued in the introduction, many scholars have emphasised the centrality of financial systems in national capitalisms. More precisely, financial systems generate some of the defining characteristics assumed by national economies. For instance, bank-based systems enable firms to access long-term finance in exchange for stable ownership and control patterns. As a consequence, changes in financial systems cannot leave other (real) economic sectors unaffected.

In the case of savings banks, their traditional clientele (low income earning households, small firms, local government) might be adversely affected by a shift away from their needs towards other segments of the market. In other words, savings banks in particular, and banks in general generate their own sets of constraints and incentives to which other actors are exposed; changes in banks’ behaviour lead to changes in those constraints and incentives.

261 9.3.3 Theoretical implications

The findings presented in the previous sections have theoretical implications as well, which might inform future research in the field of comparative political economy. First, as argued above, patterns of change are multiple and are not limited to the binary logic emphasised in the neo-institutionalist literature. It might be more useful to rely on broader and looser theories of change. Secondly, if the systemic congruence hypothesis does not hold, one might want to look at the dynamics at play within each national capitalism. This research agenda does not mean that any comparative perspective should be abandoned. Actually, one potentially interesting implication of the findings presented here is that internal differentiation processes helps explain cross-country differences. In other words, the various types of segmentation/fragmentation characterising each national financial system might constitute the central differentiating factor between national systems. Varieties within capitalism generate varieties of capitalism.

262 BIBLIOGRAPHY / REFERENCES

a. Sources

The study relies on descriptive statistical data on savings banks’ balance sheets. For Italy, all the data come from the Bilbank database compiled by the Italian Banking Association, available upon request. For France, balance sheet data has been collected from various sources: annual reports of the Commission Bancaire; annual reports of the CENCEP, later the CNCE. Balance sheet data were not manipulated since the research only uses rough indicators (such as the ratio of liabilities on own funds or the ratio of liabilities over assets). Balance sheet data for other categories of banks (mainly commercial banks) are aggregate data compiled from various central bank annual reports.

The study also uses data on various indicators, such as: the number of banks, the number of banking mergers and acquisitions, etc. Those data have been compiled from official publications by the regulatory authorities in each country. Those documents were consulted at the Banque de France library, at the Banca d’Italy library, and at the Italian Senate library.

Semi-structured interviews

The study draws on 52 semi-structured interviews conducted with key informants in both countries. Interviewees include: parliamentarians (former or current), one former Minister, savings banks managers, staff at the sector association, union members, and other stakeholders (such as experts involved in the various reforms). The table below recapitulates the number and quality of informants.

263 France Italy Total Savings banks association 11 5 16 Savings banks management 8 5 13 Savings banks union members 3 2 5 Parliamentarians 3 2 5 Ministers 0 1 1 Central Bank staff 1 5 6 Ministry of the Treasury staff 3 2 5 Total 29 23 52

Sampling was made on the basis of the role played by the informant in the policy/change process (key stakeholders) and on the informant’s experience with savings banks. The goal of such semi-structured interviews was, indeed, twofold: (i) gather first hand information concerning the dependent and independent variables; (ii) question informants on the meaning they gave to the changes under study. Various interview protocols, along with the list of interviewees, are included in the appendix.

Documents and archives

The study relies extensively on savings banks’ documents and archives, especially: (i) annual reports (in France, the annual reports of the CENCEP, later Caisse Nationale des Caisses d’Épargne; of the Caisse d’Épargne de Picardie; of the Caisse d’Épargne Provence Alpes Corse Réunion; in Italy: the annual reports of the Cassa di Risparmio delle Provincie Lombarde; of the Cassa di Risparmio di Roma; of the Cassa di Risparmio di Salerno) (ii) internal journal (in France: the Journal des Caisses d’Épargne, part of which became Culture Groupe); (iii) external journal (in France: the Journal des Caisses d’Épargne, later Épargne et Finance; in Italy, Il Risparmio); (iv) other documents (such as internal reports, transcripts of public interventions from major stakeholders – journal articles, speeches, interventions at conferences…). Most of this material was either obtained from savings banks themselves or consulted in savings banks’ documentation centres. In addition, relevant material and documents have been obtained from the main bank trade unions in both countries. Moreover, the research builds on the analysis of legal and regulatory texts, mostly published in the Journal Officiel in France and the Gazzetta Ufficiale in Italy, and in regulatory authorities’ various bulletins and annual reports.

264 Finally, the research draws from an extensive analysis of the parliamentary proceedings related to the major regulatory reforms in both countries, in particular: the 1983 and 1999 laws in France and the 1990 and 1998 laws in Italy. Those parliamentary proceedings were mostly consulted at the Senate library in Italy, and the library of the Assemblée Nationale in France. Part of these proceedings was also published, either in the Journal des Caisses d’Épargne or the book by Senator Cluzel (1984). b. Secondary Literature

- Acciaro, Adamo, Giorgio Giovando, Sandro Molinari and Giovanni Tommasini (1985), “Le Innovazioni Funzionali ed Operative Degli Enti della Categoria”, in Il Risparmio, vol.33 n.6 (November-December), pp.1053-1074. - Affinito, Massimiliano, Riccardo De Bonis and Fabio Farabullini (2003), “Concorrenza E convergenza tra i sistemi bancari dell’area dell’euro”, Ente Luigi Einaudi Quaderni di Ricerche n.40. - Aoki, Masahiko and Hugh Patrick (1994), "The Japanese Main Bank System: An Introductory Overview", in Aoki and Patrick (eds.), The Japanese Main Bank System, Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1-50. - Arrighetti, Alessandro and Gilberto Seravalli (1997), “Istituzioni e Dualismo Dimensionale dell’Industria Italiana”, in Barca (ed.), Storia del Capitalismo Italiano, 335-387. - Arthur Andersen (1993), European Banking and Capital Markets: A Strategic Forecast, London: The Economist Intelligence Unit. - Associazione fra le Casse di Risparmio Italiane (1996), Primo rapporto sulle fondazioni bancarie, Roma: Acri. - (1997a), Secondo rapporto sulle fondazioni bancarie, Roma: Acri. - (1997b), Atti del 17esimo Congresso Nazionale delle Casse di Risparmio, delle Banche dei Monti e delle Fondazioni Bancarie, Roma: Acri. - (1998), Terzo rapporto sulle fondazioni bancarie, Roma: Acri. - (1999), Quarto rapporto sulle fondazioni bancarie, Roma: Acri. - (2000), Quinto rapporto sulle fondazioni bancarie, Roma: Acri. - (2001), Sesto rapporto sulle fondazioni bancarie, Roma: Acri. - (2002), Settimoo rapporto sulle fondazioni bancarie, Roma: Acri. - Bagnasco, Angelo (1977), Tre Italie: la Problematica Territoriale dello Sviluppo Italiano, Bologna: Il Mulino. - Bagnasco, Angelo (1988), La Costruzione sociale del mercato, Bologna: Il Mulino.

265 - Bairoch, Paul (1996), “Globalization Myth and Realities: One Century of External Trade and Foreign Investment”, in Boyer and Drache (eds.), States vs. Markets. The Limits of Globalization, 173-192. - Baltensperger, E. and Jean Dermine (1990), “European banking: prudential and regulatory issues”, in Jean Dermine (ed.), European Banking in the 1990s (Oxford: Blackwell). - Banca d’Italia, Relazione Annuale, Assemblea Generale Ordinaria dei Partecipanti, various years. - Banca d’Italia, 1981, Ordinamenti degli enti pubblici creditizi: Analisi e prospettive, Roma: Banca d’Italia. - Banque de France, Rapport annuel, various years. - Banuri, Tariq and Juliet B. Schor (eds.) (1992), Financial Openness and National Autonomy, Oxford: Oxford University Press. - Barca, Fabrizio (ed.) (1997a), Storia del Capitalismo Italiano: dal dopoguerra a oggi, Roma: Donzelli Editore. - Barca, Fabrizio (1997b), “Compromesso senza Riforme nel Capitalismo Italiano”, in Barca (ed.), Storia del Capitalismo Italiano, 4-115. - Barca, Luciano and Gianni Vanghetti (1976), L’Italia delle Banche, Roma: Editori Riuniti. - Bauchard, Philippe 1986, La Guerre des Roses: du rêve à la réalité, 1981-1985, Paris: Grasset. - Baumol, William, Panzard, John C. and Robert D. Willig (1982), Contestable Markets: and the Theory of Industry Structure, San Diego: Harcourt-Brace-Jovanovich. - Bellon, Bertrand (1980), Le Pouvoir Financier et l’Industrie en France, Paris: Seuil. - Berger, Suzanne (1996), “Introduction”, in Berger and Dore (eds.), National Diversity…, 1-25. - Berger, Suzanne and Ronald Dore (eds.) (1996), National Diversity and Global Capitalism, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. - Berger, Suzanne and Michael Piore (1982), Dualism and Discontinuity in Industrial Societies, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Blyth, Mark, 2002, Great Transformations: Economic Ideas and Institutional Change in the Twentieth Century, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Boltho, Andrea (1996), “Has France Converged on Germany? Policies and Institutions since 1958”, in Berger and Dore (eds.), National Diversity…, 89-104. - Bongini, Paola and Rossella Locatelli (1998), “Un modello interpretativo della specificità delle casse di risparmio oggi in Italia”, in Locatelli (ed.), Le Casse di risparmio tra localismo e despecializzazione, Milano: Giuffré Editore, pp.195-240.

266 - Boyer, Robert (1996), “The Convergence hypothesis revisited: globalization but still the century of nations?”, in Berger and Dore (eds.), National Diversity…, 29-56. - Boyer, Robert (1997), “French Statism at the Crossroads”, in Crouch and Streeck (eds.), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 71-101. - Boyer, Robert and Daniel Drache (eds) (1996), States against Markets: the Limits of Globalization, London: Routledge. - Boyer, Robert and J. Rogers Hollingsworth (eds.), 1997, Contemporary Capitalism: The Embededness of Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Boyer, Robert and Michel Freyssinet (2000), Les modèles productifs, Paris: La Découverte. - Busch, Andreas (2002), “Divergence or convergence ? State regulation of the banking system in Western Europe and the United States”, Paper presented at the Workshop on theories of regulation, Nuffield College, Oxford, 25-26 May 2002. - Calcagnini, Giorgio (2003), “L’evoluzione del sistema bancario italiano negli anni novanta”, in Messori et al. (eds), Il Sistema Bancario Italiano, pp.15-46. - Calcagnini, Giorgio, Riccardo De Bonis and Donald D. Hester (2000), “Financial convergence in the European Monetary Union?”, SSRI Working Paper n. 2022, University of Wisconsin, Madison. - Calder, Kent E. (1998), “Assault on the Bankers’ Kingdom: Politics, Markets, and the Liberalization of Japanese Industrial Finance”, in Loriaux et al., Capital Ungoverned. Liberalizing Finance in Interventionist States, 17-56. - Capriglione, Federico (1977), “La caratteristica operativa delle Casse di risparmio ex art. 32 del T.U. del 1929”, in Banca, Borsa e Titoli di Credito, vol.1. - Carli, Guido, 1983, Communication to the Conference “Concorrenza, stabilità, efficienza nel sistema bancario. Ruolo delle Casse di Risparmio”, held in Bologna on March 9-10, 1984, published in Banca Impresa Società vol.3 n.3, pp.509-517 - Casper, Steven (2001), “The Legal Framework for Corporate Governance: The Influence of Contract Law on Company Strategies in Germany and the United States”, in Hall and Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism, 387-416. - Cassese, Sabino (1983), “Pubblico e Privato sono compatibili”, Bollettino del Risparmio (May special issue). - Cassou, Pierre-Henry (1997), La Réglementation bancaire et financière, Boulogne: SEFI.

267 - Cerny, Philip G. (1989), "The 'Little Big Bang' in Paris: Financial Market Deregulation in a Dirigiste System", European Journal of Political Research, Vol.17. - Cerny, Philip G. (1993), Finance and World Politics: Markets, Regimes and States in the Post-Hegemonic Era, Brookfield, USA: Edward Elgar. - Cerny, Philip G. (1995) "Globalization and the Changing Logic of Collective Action", International Organization Vol.49: pp.595-625. - Cerny, Philip G. (1997), “International Finance and the Erosion of Capitalist Diversity”, in Crouch and Streeck, Political Economy of Modern Capitalism. - Cerny, Philip C. and Martin A. Schain (eds.) 1985, Socialism, the State, and Public Policy in France, London: F. Pinter. - Cesari, Riccardo, Vittorio Conti and Marco Onado (1994), “Competition in banking markets: lessons from the Italian case”, in Jack Revell (ed.), The Changing Face of European Banks and Securities Market (New York: St. Martin’s Press). - Cesarini, Francesco (1979), “Despecializzazione delle Casse di Risparmio”, Il Risparmio, vol. 27, n.11 (November), pp.1426-1453. - Ciampi, Carlo Azeglio, 1982a, “Costi e Margini, Efficienza e Stabilità nelle Banche Italiane”, Intervention at the 1982 annual meeting of ABI, published in Bancaria, n.4 (April), pp.370-373. - Ciampi, Carlo Azeglio, 1982b, “Orientamenti per un disegno statutario finalizzato a sviluppare l’operatività delle CR”, Banca Impresa Società Vol.1 n.0, pp. 31-40. - Cieply, Sylvie and Bernard Paranque (1997), French Manufacturing Firms and the Capital Gap since 1985, Banque de France Working Paper D 97/98. - Clarich, Maurizio (1984), Le Casse di risparmio, Bologna: Il Mulino. - Cluzel, Jean, 1984, Les Pouvoirs Publics et les Caisses d’Épargne, Paris: LGDJ. - Coase, Ronald H. (1937), “The nature of the firm”, Economica n.4, 386-405. - Coleman, William (1993), "Reforming Corporatism: the French Banking Policy Community, 1941-1990", West European Politics Vol.16 No.2 (April 1993): pp.122-43 - Conti, Giuseppe and Giovanni Ferri (1997), “Banche locali e sviluppo economico decentrato”, in Barca (ed.), Storia del Capitalismo Italiano, op.cit., pp. 429-465. - Crouch, Colin (2005), “Complementarity and fit in the study of comparative capitalisms”, in Morgan, Whitley and Moen (eds.), Changing Capitalisms?, pp.167-189.

268 - Crouch, Colin and Henry Farrell (2002), “Breaking the path of institutional development? Alternatives to the new determinism”, Max-Planck-Institut fur Gesellschaftforschung Discussion Paper n.02/5 (June). - Crouch, Colin, Patrick Le Galès, Carlo Trigilia, and Helmut Voelzkow, 2002, Local Production Systems in Europe: Rise or Demise?, Oxford: Oxford University Press. - Crouch, Colin and Wolfgang Streeck (eds.) (1997a), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism. Mapping Convergence and Diversity, London: Sage. - Crouch, Colin and Wolfgang Streeck (1997b), “Introduction: the Future of Capitalist Diversity, by Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck”, in Crouch and Streeck (eds.), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 1-18. - Danthine, Jean-Pierre, Francesco Giavazzi and E. Ludwig von Thadden (2000), “European Financial Markets after EMU: a first assessment”, CEPR Discussion Paper n.2413. - De Boissieu, Christian (2000), “L’avenir des banques coopératives face aux restructurations bancaires”, Cahiers pour l’histoire de l’épargne, n.2 (June), pp.73-75. - De Bonis, Riccardo (2003), “Le concentrazioni bancarie: una sintesi”, in Messori et al. (eds), Il Sistema Bancario Italiano, pp.149-182. - De Cecco, Marcello (1997), “Splendore e crisi del sistema Benedice”, in Barca (ed.), Storia del Capitalismo Italiano, op. cit., pp. 389-404. - De Rosa, Luigi (2003), Storia delle Casse di Risparmio Italiane e della loro associazione, Bari: Laterza. - De Rosa, Luigi (1988), “Per la storiografia industriale” in Rassegna Economica vol. LII n.1: pp.79-90. - Deeg, Richard (1999), Finance Capitalism Unveiled: Banks and the German Political Economy, Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press. - Deeg, Richard (2000), Modell Deutschland Meets EMU: the Hybridization of German Political Economy, Paper presented at the University of Mississippi, September 2000. - Deeg, Richard, 2001, “Institutional change and the uses and limits of path dependency: the case of German finance”, Max-Planck-Institut fur Geselleschaftsforschung Discussion Paper n.01/06. - Deeg, Richard and Sofia Pérez (2000), “International capital mobility and domestic institutions: corporate finance and governance in four European cases”, Governance, vol.13 n.2, pp.119-142. - Dewatripont, Mathias and Jean Tirole (1994), The Prudential Regulation of Banks, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. - Dini, Lamberto, 1983, “Introduzione ai Temi del Convegno” in Banca Impresa Società vol.3 n.3, pp. 401-404.

269 - Djelic, Marie-Laure and Sigrid Quack (2005), “Rethinking path dependency: the crooked path of institutional ch’ange in post-war Germany”, in Morgan, Whitley and Moen (eds.), Changing Capitalisms?, pp.137-166. - Dore, Ronald (1997), “The Distinctiveness of Japan”, in Crouch and Streeck (eds.), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 19-32. - Dore, Ronald, (2000), Stock Market Capitalism: Welfare Capitalism: Japan and Germany versus the Anglo-Saxons, Oxford: Oxford University Press. - Doremus, Paul N., William W. Keller, Louis W. Pauly and Simon Reich (eds.) (1998), The Myth of the Global Corporation, Princeton: Princeton University Press. - Duet, Daniel (1986), La Métamorphose des Caisses d’Épargne, Paris: Éditions de l’Épargne. - Duet, Daniel (2000a), “Le Destin Coopératif des Caisses d’Épargne: Éléments pour une Critique des Conceptions Étatistes de la Situation Historique des Caisses d’Épargne Francaises”, in Les Cahiers pour l’Histoire de l’Épargne, 2 (June). - Duet, Daniel (2000b), “Les Caisses d’Épargne au Rendez-Vous de leur Histoire: de la Caisse Mono-Produit à la Banque Coopérative”, Revue Internationale de l’Économie Sociale, 277 (July). - Duet, Daniel (2001), Les Caisses d’Épargne, collection Que Sais-je?, Paris: Presses Universitaires de France (7th edition). - Duysters, Geert and John Hagedoorn 2001, “Do company strategies and structures converge in global markets? Evidence from the computer industry”, in Journal of International Business Studies vol.32 n.2: 347-356. - Emanuele, Emmanuele (2002), Il ruolo dell’impresa pubblica: un dibattito ancora aperto; le vicende dell’impresa bancaria, Roma: Luiss Edizioni. - Epstein, Gerald (1996), International Capital Mobility and the Scope for National Economic Management”, in Boyer and Drache (eds.), States vs. Markets. The Limits of Globalization, 211-224. - Esping-Andersen, Gøsta (1990), The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Princeton: Princeton University Press. - European Commission (1997), Credit Institutions and Banking: Impact on Services, vol.3, London: Kogan Page. - Evans, Peter (1995), Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation, Princeton: Princeton University Press. - Fair, Donald E. and Christian de Boissieu (eds.) (1990), Financial Institutions in Europe under New Competitive Conditions, Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

270 - Farabullini, Fabio & Giorgio Gobbi (1997), “Le banche nei sistemi locali di produzione”, in L. Federico Signorini (ed.), Lo Sviluppo Locale. Un’indagine della Banca d’Italia sui Distretti Industriali, Meridiana Libri. - Fenucci, Fulvio, 1996, Il Governo del Credito – negli Atti del CICR, Milano: Giuffré Editore. - Ferrari, Camillo (1981), “Per una critica degli ultimi trent’anni di storia dell’ICCRI”, Il Risparmio, n. , pp. 943- - Ferrari, Camillo (1985), “Le Casse di Risparmio e le Banche del Monte Italiane: Imprese Innovatrici nel Solco della Tradizione”, Il Risparmio, vol.33, n.6 (November-December), pp.1027-1052. - Ferri, Giovanni (1992), “Sugli effetti dell’instabilità finanziaria nella Grande Crisi in Italia”, in P. Ciocca (ed.), Il progresso economico dell’Italia: permanenze, discontinuità, limiti, Bologna: Il Mulino. - Ferri, Giovanni and Sandro Trento (1997), “La dirigenza delle grandi banche e imprese”, in Barca (ed.), Storia del Capitalismo Italiano, op.cit., pp. 405-427. - Fforde, J.S., (1983) "Competition, Innovation and Regulation in British Banking", Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Vol.23 No.3. - Figliolia, Luigi (1981), “Le Casse di Risparmio oggi”, Il Ponte, vol.37, n.10 (October), pp.1001-1034. - Flier, Bert, Frans A.J. Van der Bosch and Henk W. Volberda (2003), “Convergence and divergence in the European financial services sector: the pace of diffusion of banking technologies and regulations in European financial environments, and strategic behaviour of incumbent firms”, Institute for New Technologies, United Nations University, EIFC Consortium Working Paper n. 03-22. - Focarelli D., F.Panetta, C. Salleo (1999), “Determinanti e conseguenze delle acquisizioni e fusioni in Italia. Un’analisi empirica (1984-1996)”, Banca, Impresa e società, XVIII, 1. - Forsyth, Douglas and Ton Notermans (eds.) (1997), Regime Changes: Macroeconomic Policy and Financial Regulation in Europe from the 1930s to the 1990s, Providence, USA: Berghahn Books. - Forsyth, Douglad and Daniel Verdier (eds.) (2003), The Origins of National Financial Systems: Alexander Gerschenkron Reconsidered, London: Routledge. - Freeman, Richard B. 2000, "Single-Peaked vs. Diversified Capitalism: The Relation Between Economic Institutions and Outcomes", National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper n.7556. - Gardener, Edward P.M. (1994), “Bank marketing, organization and performance” in Jack Revell (ed.), The Changing Face of European Banks and Securities Market (New York: St. Martin’s Press).

271 - Gardener, Edward and Philip Molyneux, (1990), Changes in Western European Banking, London: Unwin Hyman. - Giannola, Adriano (2003), “Istituzioni, dualismo e mercati. Analisi e proposte operative”, In A. Giannola A., Imbriani C., (a cura di), Neo dualismo: istituzioni, mercati e politiche di intervento, Rubbettino, Soveria Mannelli. - Giannola, Adriano., Claudio Ricci, G. Scarfiglieri (1996a), “Size and Regional Aspects of Banking Efficiency: the Italian Puzzle”, Rivista di Politica Economica, 86. - Giannola, Adriano (1996b), “L’evoluzione della politica economica e industriale”, in Franco Barbagallo (ed.), Storia dell’Italia repubblicana, vol. 3, Torino: Einaudi, pp. 402-495. - Giddy, Ian (1985), “Assetless Banking”, in Paolo Savona and G. Sutija (eds.), Strategic Planning in International Banking, London: Macmillan. - Goldstein, Judith and Robert Keohane (eds.), 1993, Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions and Political Change, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. - Goldthorpe, John (ed.) (1984), Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Gorton, Gary, and Frank Schmid (2000), Universal Banking and the Performance of German Firms, Journal of Financial Economics n.58, pp.29-80 - Gourevitch, Peter A. (1986), Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. - Gourevitch, Peter A.., 1989, “Keynesian Politics: the Political Sources of Economic Policy Choices”, in Hall (ed.), The Political Power of economic Ideas. - Gourevitch, Peter A. (1996), “The Macropolitics of Microinstitutional Differences in the Analysis of Comparative Capitalism”, in Berger and Dore (eds.), National Diversity…, 239-259. - Granovetter, Mark (1985), “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness”, American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 91, No. 3 (November). - Graziani, Augusto (2000), Lo sviluppo dell’economia italiana. Dalla ricostruzione alla moneta unica, Torino: Bollati-Boringhieri. - Graziani, Augusto (ed.) (1989), L’economia italiana dal 1945 a oggi, Bologna: Il Mulino (3d ed.). - Gualandri, Elisabetta and Andrea Landri (1994), “Economies of Diversification and Conflicts of Interests: the Effects of the New Regulation in Italy”, in Revell (ed.), The Changing Face of European Banks, 144-173.

272 - Gurley, John G. and Edward S. Shaw (1960), Money in a theory of finance, Washington DC: The Brookings Institution Press. - Hall, Peter A. (1986), Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France, Cambridge: Polity. - Hall, Peter A. (ed.) (1989), The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism Across Nations, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. - Hall, Peter A. (1993), "Policy Paradigms, Social Learning and the State: the Case of Economic Policy-Making in Britain", Comparative Politics Vol. 25 No.3 (April). - Hall, Peter, 1997, “The role of interests, institutions and ideas in the comparative political economy of the industrialized nations”, in Mark Irving Lichbach and Alan S. Zuckerman (eds.), Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture and Structure, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Hall, Peter A. (1999), “The Political Economy of Europe in an Era of Interdependence”, in Kitschelt et al. (eds.), Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, 135-163. - Hall, Peter A. and David Soskice (eds.) (2001a), Varieties of Capitalism. The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press. - Hall, Peter A. and David Soskice (2001b), “An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism”, in Hall and Soskice (eds.), op. Cit.,1-70. - Hall, Peter A. and Rosemary C. R. Taylor (1996), “Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms”, Political Studies, XLIV, 936-957. - Hancké, Bob (2002), Large Firms and Institutional Change. Industrial Renewal and Economic Restructuring in France, Oxford: Oxford University Press. - Hancké, Bob (2001), “Revisiting the French Model: Coordination and Restructuring in French Industry”, in Hall and Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism, 307-334. - Hancké, Bob and Steven Casper (1999), “Reproducing Diversity. ISO 9000 and Work Organization in the French and German Car Industry”, in Quack et al. (eds.), National Capitalisms, Global Competition and Economic Performance, 173-188. - Hancké, Bob and Michel Goyer (2005), “Degrees of freedom: rethinking the institutional analysis of economic change”, in Morgan, Whitley and Moen (eds.), Changing Capitalisms?, pp.53-77. - Hautcoeur, Pierre-Cyrille (1996), “Le système financier français depuis 1945 », Risques, 25 (January).

273 - Hay, Colin and Ben Rosamond (2001), “Globalization, European integration and the discursive construction of economic imperatives: a question of convergence?”, Queen’s Papers on Europeanisation, n.1/2001. - Hayward, Jack (1986), The State and the Market Economy, Industrial Patriotism and Economic Intervention in France, New York: New York University Press. - Helleiner, Eric (1994), States and the Reemergence of Global Finance: From Bretton-Woods to the 1990s, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. - Hertner, Peter (1996), “Italy”, in Mura (ed.), History of European Savings Banks, pp.193-228. - Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1998) ‘Evolutionary and Competence-Based Theories of the Firm’, Journal of Economic Studies, 25(1), pp. 25-56. - Hollingsworth, J. Rogers (1997), “The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism”, in Crouch and Streeck (eds.), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 133-147. - Hollingsworth, J. Rogers and Robert Boyer (1997), “Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production”, in Boyer and Hollingsworth (eds.), Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47. - Institute of European Finance (1999), Challenges and the Future of Savings Banks in the Single Financial Market of the European Union, Bangor, UK: Institute of European Finance. - Inzerillo U, M. Messori (2000), “Le privatizzazioni bancarie in Italia”, Centro Studi Confindustria, Working Paper, 25. - Jobert, Bruno (ed.) (1994), Le Tournant Néo-Libéral en Europe, Paris: L'Harmattan. - Kassim, Hussein and Menon, Anand (eds.) (1996), The European Union and National Industrial Policy, London: Routledge. - Katz, Harry C., and Owen Darbishire, 2000, Converging Divergences: Worldwide Change in Employment Systems, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. - Katzenstein, Peter J. (ed.) (1978), Between Power and Plenty, Madison, WI: Wisconsin University Press. - Katzenstein, Peter J. (1984), Corporatism and Change, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. - Katzenstein, Peter J. (1985), Small States in World Markets, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. - Kester, W. Carl (1996), “American and Japanese Corporate Governance: Convergence to Best Practice?”, in Berger and Dore (eds.), National Diversity…, 107-137.

274 - King, Gary, Robert O. Keohane and Sidney Verba (1994), Designing Social Inquiry, Social Inference in Qualitative Research, Princeton: Princeton University Press. - Kitschelt, Herbert (1991), “Industrial Governance Structures”, International Organization (Autumn), 453-94. - Kitschelt, Herbert, Peter Lange, Gary Marks and John D. Stephens (eds.) (1999a), Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Kitschelt, Herbert, Peter Lange, Gary Marks and John D. Stephens (1999b), “Conclusion: Convergence and Divergence in Advanced Capitalist Democracies”, in Kitschelt et al. (eds.), Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, 427-460. - Knight, Jack (1992), Institutions and Social Conflicts, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Labye, Agnès and Françoise Renversez (2000), “Intermédiation financière et marchés financiers en France et en Allemagne: Un essai d’analyse comparative” Paper presented at the 17th International Meeting of Banking and Finance Economics in Lisbona, June 2000. - Lacoue-Labarthe, Dominique (2001), Les Banques en France. Privatisation, Restructuration, Consolidation, Paris: Economica. - Laurent, René (1976), “La longue marche des Caisses d’épargne”, Journal des Caisses d’Épargne n.5 & 6 (May-June). - Lazonick, William (1991), Business Organization and the Myth of the Market Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Lee, Bradford A., 1989, “The miscarriage of necessity and invention: proto-keynesianism and democratic states in the 1930s”, in Peter Hall (ed.), The Political Power of Economic Ideas. - Lehrer, Mark (2001), “Macro-varieties of Capitalism and Micro-varieties of Strategic Management in European Airlines”, in Hall and Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism, 361-386. - Lehrer, Mark, and Owen Darbishire (1999), “Comparative Managerial Learning in Germany and Britain. Techno-Organizational Innovation in Network Industries”, in Quack et al. (eds.), National Capitalisms, Global Competition and Economic Performance, 79-104. - Léonard de Juvigny, François (1990), “Les Pouvoirs Publics Français et les Résistances à la Création d’un Marché Bancaire Intérieur Unifié”, in Fair and De Boissieu (eds.), Financial Institutions in Europe, 83-94. - Lévy-Lang, André (1990), “Banking Strategies for the 1990s”, in Fair and de Boissieu (eds.), Financial Institutions in Europe, 39-46. - Lieberman, Robert C. 2002, “Ideas, Institutions, and Political Order: explaining Political Change”, American Political Science Review vol.96 no.4 (December), 697-712.

275 - Lisanti, Vittorio (1981), “Considerazioni sul convegno delle Casse di Risparmio a La Spezia”, Il Risparmio, vol.29 n.4 (Aprile), pp.442-452. - Locatelli, Rossella (ed.), 1998a, Le Casse di Risparmio tra Localismo e Delocalizzazione, Milano: Giuffré Editore. - Locatelli, Rossella, 1998b, “Casse di risparmio e territorio”, in Locatelli (ed.), Le Casse di risparmio tra localismo e despecializzazione, pp.157-194. - Locke, Richard (1994), Remaking the Italian Economy: Local Politics and Industrial Change in Contemporary Italy, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. - Loriaux Michael, (1991) France After Hegemony: International Change and Financial Reform, Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press. - Loriaux, Michael (1998a), “The End of Credit Activism in Interventionist States”, in Loriaux et al., Capital Ungoverned. Liberalizing Finance in Interventionist States, 1-16. - Loriaux, Michael (1998b), “Socialist Monetarism and Financial Liberalization in France”, in Loriaux et al., Capital Ungoverned. Liberalizing Finance in Interventionist States, 120-161. - Loriaux, Michael (2003), “Developmentalism and Liberalization in France”, in Linda Weiss (ed.), States in the Global Economy: Bringing Domestic Institutions Back In, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Loriaux, Michael, Meredith Woo-Cummings, Kent E. Calder, Sylvia Maxfield, Sofià Pérez (1998), Capital Ungoverned. Liberalizing Finance in Interventionist States, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. - Lubochinsky, Catherine and Joel Métais (1990), “La Banque à Géométrie Variable: un Nouveau Facteur de Compétitivité”, in Fair and De Boissieu (eds.), Financial Institutions in Europe, 65-81. - Lütz, Suzanne (1998), "The Revival of the Nation-State? Stock Exchange Regulation in an Eve of Globalized Financial Markets", Journal of European Public Policy, Vol.5 No.1: pp.153-168. - Lütz, Suzanne (2003), “Convergence within national diversity: a comparative perspective on the regulatory state in finance”, Max-Planck- Institut für Gesellschaftsfortschung Discussion Paper 3/07 (December). - Machin, Howard and Vincent Wright, 1985, Economic Policy and Policy Making under the Mitterrand Presidency, London: Pinter. - Mazzocchi, Giancarlo (1983), “Alcune riflessioni su problemi vecchi e nuovi delle “casse””, Il Risparmio, vol.31, n.1 (January-February), pp.1-18. - McNamara, Kathleen R., 1998, The Currency of Ideas: Monetary Politics and the European Union, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. - Melitz, Jacques, (1990) "Financial Deregulation in France", European Economic Review, Vol.34.

276 - Mentré, Paul and Antoine Mérieux (2002), Les Institutions d’Épargne en Europe et en France: le Secteur Public et Mutualiste, Paris: Association d’Économie Financière - Caisse des Dépôts et Consignations. - Merusi, Franco (1984), “Sulla riforma delle Casse di risparmio e dei Monti di credito su pegno”, Bancaria, p.633. - Merusi, Franco (1993), “Sulla natura giuridica dei cosidetti enti- fondazione”, Diritto Amministrativo, pp.491. - Messori, Marcello, Roberto Tamborini and Alberto Zazzaro (eds.) (2003), Il Sistema Bancario Italiano. Le Occasioni degli Anni Novanta e le Sfide dell’Euro, Roma: Carocci editore. - Messori, Marcello and Roberto Tamburini (2003), “Assetti bancari, efficienza operativa e efficienza economica”, in Messori et al. (eds.), Il Sistema Bancario Italiano, pp.47-98. - Messori, Marcello and Alberto Zazzaro (2003), “Aggregazioni bancarie, riassetti proprietari e modelli di governo. Come sono cambiate le banche italiane negli anni novanta”, in Messori et al. (eds.), Il Sistema Bancario Italiano, pp.99-148. - Ministère de l’Économie, des Finances et de l’Industrie (2003), Rapport sur l’équilibre des fonds d’épargne (by Philippe Nasse and Christian Noyer). - Molyneux, Phil (1996), ‘Banking and Financial Services’, in Kassim and Menon (eds), op.cit. - Molyneux, Phil, Yener Altunbas and Edward Gardener, (1996) Efficiency in European Banking, Wiley: Chichester, England. - Molyneux, Phil, D.M. Lloyd-Williams and John Thornton (1994), “European Banking – an Analysis of Competitive conditions”, in Revell (ed.), The Changing Face of European Banks”, 3-29. - Moran, Michael (1984), The Politics of Banking, London: Macmillan. - Moran, Michael (1994), "The State and the Financial Services Revolution: a Comparative Analysis", in Wolfgang C. Mueller and Vincent Wright (eds), The State in Western Europe: Retreat or Redefinition?, Portland. - Morgan, Glenn (2005), “Introduction: changing capitalisms? Internationalization, institutional change and systems of economic organization”, in in Morgan, Whitley and Moen (eds.), Changing Capitalisms?, pp.1-20. - Morgan, Glenn, Richard Whitley and Eli Moen (eds.) (2005), Changing Capitalisms? Internationalization, Institutional Change, and Systems of Economic Organization, Oxford: Oxford University Press. - Morgan, Glenn and Sigrid Quack (1999), “Confidence and Confidentiality. The Social Construction of Performance Standards in Banking”, in Quack et al. (eds.), National Capitalisms, Global Competition and Economic Performance, 131-157.

277 - Morison, Ian (1994), “Organisational Change in UK Clearing Banks: The Causes and Consequences”, in Revell(ed.), The Changing Face of European Banks, 79-92. - Moster, Antoine, 2000, “L’évolution des Caisses d’épargne depuis 1945”, Cahiers pour l’histoire de l’épargne, n. 3 (October), pp.39-54. - Moster, Antoine and Bernard Vogler (1996), « France », in Mura (ed.), History of European Savings Banks, pp.75-103. - Mura, Jurgen (ed.), 1996, History of European Savings Banks, Stuttgart : Wissenshaftsforderung der Sparkassenorganisation e.V. - Murinde, Victor, Juda Agung and Andy Mullineux (2004), “Patterns of corporate financing and financial system convergence in Europe“, Review of International Economics, vol.12 n.4 (September), 693-705. - Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G. (1982) An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. - Notermans, Ton, 1998, “Policy continuity, policy change, and the political power of economic ideas”, Advanced Research on the Europeanization of the Nation-State Working Paper n. 17/98. - Ogata, Shijuro (1996), “Financial Markets in Japan”, in Berger and Dore (eds.), National Diversity…, 171-178. - Ohmae, Kenichi (1991), The Borderless World: Power and Strategy in the Interlinked Economy, New York: Harper Perennial. - Onado, Marco (1990), “Competition in Banking Services and its Implications: the Italian Case”, in Fair and De Boissieu (eds.), Financial Institutions in Europe, 94-106. - Paranque, Bernard (1997), Financial Constraints and Economic Behavior: The Specificities of Small Manufacturing Firms From 1985 to 1995, Banque de France Working Paper. - Patat, Jean-Pierre and Lutfalla, Michel (1986), Histoire monétaire de la France au XXème siècle, Paris: Economica. - Peluffo, Paolo (1997), Storia del Mediocredito Centrale, Bari: Laterza. - Pérez, Sofia A. (1997a), "’Strong’ States and ’Cheap’ Credit: Economic Policy Strategy and Financial Regulation in France and Spain", in Forsyth and Notermans (eds), op.cit.: pp.169-220. - Pérez, Sofia A. (1997b), Banking on Privilege: The Politics of Spanish Financial Reform, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. - Pierson, Paul (2004), Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Political Analysis, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. - Pierson, Paul (2000a), “Increasing returns, path dependence, and the study of politics”, American Political Science Review, vol.94 n.2 (June), 251-267

278 - Pierson, Paul (2000b), “Not Just What, but When: Timing and Sequence in Political Process”, Studies in American Politcal Development, vol.14 (Spring). - Pin, Antonio (1984), “La Riforma in Atto nelle Casse di Risparmio Italiane”, Il Risparmio vol.32 n.6. - Pontusson, Jonas (1997), “Between Neo-Liberalism and the German Model: Swedish Capitalism in Transition”, in Crouch and Streeck (eds.), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 55-70. - Prowse, Stephen, (1995) "Corporate Governance in an International perspective: A Survey of Corporate Control Mechanisms Among Large Firms in the United States, the United Kingdom, Japan and Germany", Financial Markets, Institutions & Instruments 4 (1): 1-63. - Quack, Sigrid and Glenn Morgan (1999a), “National Capitalisms, Global Competition and Economic Performance: An Introduction”, in Quack et al. (eds.), National Capitalisms, Global Competition and Economic Performance, 3-24. - Quack, Sigrid and Glenn Morgan (1999b), “Institutions, Sector Specialization and Economic Performance Outcomes”, in Quack et al. (eds.), National Capitalisms, Global Competition and Economic Performance, pp.27-52. - Quack, Sigrid, Glenn Morgan and Richard Whitley (eds.) (1999), National Capitalisms, Global Competition, and Economic Performance, Amsterdam: John Benjamins Publishing. - Räsänen, K and R Whipp (1992), “National Business Recipes: a Sector Perspective”, in Whitley (ed.), European Business Systems. Firms and Markets in their National Contexts, 46-60. - Regini, Marino (1997), “Social Institutions and Production Structure: the Italian Variety of Capitalism in the 1980s”, in Crouch and Streeck (eds.), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 102-116. - Revell, Jack (ed.) (1994a), The Changing Face of European Banks and Securities Market, St. Marin’s Press: London. - Revell, Jack (1994b), “Strategies of Major British Banks since the Big Bang”, in Revell (ed.), The Changing Face of European Banks, 93-129. - Revell, Jack (1989), “The future of savings banks: a study of Spain and the rest of Europe”, Institute of European Finance Research Monograph in Banking and Finance n.8, Bangor, UK: University of Wales. - Rhodes, Martin, and Bastiaan van Apeldoorn, (1997), "Capitalism vs. Capitalism in Western Europe", in Rhodes et al. (eds.), Developments in Western European Politics, New York: St. Martins, 171-89. - Rodrick, Dani (1997), Has Globalization Gone Too Far?, NBER Working Paper no.

279 - Rose, Henry (1998), “Le role clé des intermediaries financiers”, in l’Art de la finance, Les Echos, pp. 10-11. - Ruggieri, Ernesto (1992), Cassa di Risparmio di Calabria e di Lucania: un po’ di storia e un po’ di cifre, Cosenza: Benito Patitucci Editore. - Ruozi, Roberto (1981), “Prospettive dell’attività bancaria in Italia con particolare riferimento alle Casse di risparmio”, Il Risparmio, vol.29 n.4. - Sabel, Charles F. (1989), "Flexible Specialisation and the Re-emergence of Regional Economies", in: Paul Hirst and Jonathan Zeitlin (eds.), Reversing Industrial Decline? Industrial Structure and Policy in Britain and Her Competitors, New York: St. Martin's Press: 17-70. - Sabel, Charles F. and Jonathan Zeitlin (eds.) (1997), Worlds of Possibility, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Sacchi Morsiani, Gianguido, 1984, “Problemi giuridici della concorrenza bancaria. Casse di Risparmio e dimensioni di impresa.” in Banca Impresa Società vol.3 n.3, pp. 437-454. - Salomon, Danielle (1999), “Changing Performance Standards in the French Banking System, in Quack et al. (eds.), National Capitalisms, Global Competition and Economic Performance, 159-171. - Scharpf, Fritz (1997), Games Real Actors Play: Actor-Centered Institutionalism in Policy Research, Boulder, CO: Westview Press. - Schena, Cristiana, 1998, “I riflessi della despecializzazione normativa sulla struttura del bilancio delle casse di risparmio. Un analisi su dati aggregati”, in Locatelli (ed.), Le Casse di risparmio tra localismo e despecializzazione, Milano: Giuffré Editore, pp.135-156. - Schmidt, Vivien A. (1996), From State to Market? The Transformation of French Business and Government, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press. - Schmitter, Philippe C. and Gerhard Lembruch (eds.) (1979), Trends Towards Corporatist Intermediation, London: Sage. - Schmitter, Philippe C. and Wolfgang Streeck (1985), Private Interest Government: Between Market and State, London: Sage. - Shonfield, Andrew (1965), Modern Capitalism. The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power, Oxford: Oxford University Press. - Skocpol, Theda, Marshall Ganz and Ziad Munson (2000), “A nation of organizers: the institutional origins of civic voluntarism in the United States”, American political science Review 94 (3) (September): 527-46. - Skocpol, Theda and Margaret Weir, 1985, “State Structures and the Possibilities for Keynesian Responses to the Depression in Sweden, Britain and the United States”, in Peter B. Evans, Dietrich - Rueschemeyer, Theda Skocpol (eds.), Bringing the State Back In, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

280 - Sorge, Arndt (2005), “systemic perspectives on business practices and institutions. A plea beyond comparative statics”, in Morgan, Whitley and Moen (eds.), Changing Capitalisms?, pp.110-136. - Soskice, David (1999), “Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s”, in Kitschelt et al. (eds.), Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, 101-134. - Stark, David and Laszlo Bruszt (1998), Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Steinherr, Alfred (1990), “Financial Innovation, Internationalization, Deregulation and Market Integration in Europe: Why does it all Happn Now?”, in Fair and De Boissieu (eds.), Financial Institutions in Europe, 49-63. - Steinmo, Sven, Kathleen Thelen and Frank Longstreth (eds.) (1992), Structuring Politics. Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Stoffaes, Christian (1978), La Grande Menace Industrielle, Paris: Calmann-Lévy. - Story, Jonathan and Ingo Walter (1997), Political Economy of Financial Integration in Europe: The Battle of Two Systems, Cambridge, Massachusetts (USA): MIT Press. - Strange, Susan (1997), “The Future of Global Capitalism; or, Will Divergence Persist Forever?”, in Crouch and Streeck (eds.), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 182-191. - Streeck, Wolfgang (1992), Social Institutions and Economic Performance: Studies of Industrial Relations in Advanced Capitalist Economies, London: Sage. - Streeck, Wolfgang (1996), “Lean Production in the Automobile Industry: A Test Case for Convergence Theory”, in Berger and Dore (eds.), National Diversity…, 138-170. - Streeck, Wolfgang (1997), “German Capitalism: Does it exist? Can it survive?”, in Crouch and Streeck (eds.), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, pp.33-54. - Streeck, Wolfgang and Kathleen Thelen (eds.) (2005a), Beyond Continuity. Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies, Oxford: Oxford University Press. - Streeck, Wolfgang and Kathleen Thelen (2005b), “Introduction” in Streeck and Thelen (eds.), Beyond Continuity: 1-39. - Sylla, Richard (1999) Financial Revolution – Industrial Revolution, Paper presented at the World Bank working seminar on the 2000 World Development Report, Washington, December 1999.

281 - Thatcher, Mark (1994), "Regulatory Reform in Britain and France: Organizational Structure and the Extension of Competition", Journal of European Public Policy Vol.1 No.3: pp.441-464 - Thelen, Kathleen (2004), How Institutions Evolve. The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States and Japan, New York: Cambridge University Press. - Thelen, Kathleen (2001), “Varieties of Labor Politics in Developed Democracies”, in Hall and Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism, 71-103. - Thiolon, Jean-Pierre (1971), Les Caisses d’Épargne, Éditions Berger- Levrault: Paris. - Thompson, Grahame (1999), “Where Do Multinational Corporations Conduct Their Business and What Are the Consequences for National Systems?”, in Quack et al. (eds.), National Capitalisms, Global Competition and Economic Performance, 191-212. - Tilly, Charles (1984), Big Structures, Large Processes, and Huge Comparisons, New York: Russell Sage Foundation. - Upham, Frank K. (1996), “Retail Convergence: The Structural Impediments Initiative and the Regulation of the Japanese Retail Industry”, in Berger and Dore (eds.), National Diversity, 263-297. - Vanthemsche, Guy (1996), “Belgium”, in Mura (ed.), History of European Savings Banks, pp.27-52. - Verdier, Daniel (2000), “The rise and fall of state banking in OECD countries”, in Comparative Political Studies, vol.33, n.3, April; pp.283-318. - Verdier, Daniel (2002), “How and why financial systems differ: a review of the literature”, European University Institute SPS Working Paper 2/2002. - Verdier, Daniel (2003), “Explaining cross-national variations in universal banking in nineteenth-century Europe, North America and Australasia”, in Forsyth and Verdier (eds.), The Origins of National Financial Systems, London: Routledge, pp.23-42. - Vitols, Sigurt (1997), "Financial Systems and Industrial Policy in Germany and Great Britain: The Limits of Convergence", in Forsyth and Notermans (eds), op.cit.: pp. 221-255. - Vitols, Sigurt (2001), “Varieties of Corporate Governance: Comparing Germany and the UK”, in hall and Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism, 337-360. - Vitols, Sigurt (2004), “Changes in Germany’s bank-based financial system: a varieties of capitalism perspective”, Wissenschaftzentrum Berlin Discussion Paper SP II 2004/3 (March). - Vogel, David (1986), National Styles of Regulation: Environmental Policy in the UK and the United States, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

282 - Vogel, Stephen K. (1996), Freer Markets, More Rules. Regulatory Reform in Advanced Insutrial Countries, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. - Wade, Robert (1996), “Globalization and Its Limits: Reports of the Death of the National Economy are Greatly Exaggerated”, in Berger and Dore (eds.), National Diversity…, 60-88. - Weir, Margaret, 1989, “Ideas and Politics: the Acceptance of Keynesianism in Great Britain and the United States”, in Hall (ed.), The Political Power of Economic Ideas. - Weiss, Linda (1988), Creating Capitalism, Oxford: Blackwell. - Weiss, Linda (1998), The Myth of the Powerless State, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. - Whitley, Richard (1987), “Taking Firms Seriously as Economic Actors: Towards a Sociology of Firm Behavior”, Organization Studies, 8: 125-47. - Whitley, Richard (1991), “The Social Construction of Business Systems in East Asia”, Organization Studies, 12 (1): 1-28. - Whitley, Richard (ed.) (1992a), European Business Systems: Firms and Markets in their National Contexts, London: Sage. - Whitley, Richard (1992b), “Societies, Firms and Markets: the Social Structuring of Business Systems”, in Whitley (ed.), European Business Systems: Firms and Markets in their National Contexts, 5-45. - Whitley, Richard, (1999), Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems, Oxford: Oxford University Press. - Whitley, Richard, and Peer Hull Kristensen (eds.) (1996), The Changing European Firm: Limits to Convergence, London: Routledge. - Whitley, Richard (2005), “How national are business systems? The role of States and complementary institutions in standardizing systems of economic coordination and control at the national level”, in Morgan, Whitley and Moen (eds.), Changing Capitalisms?, pp.190-234. - Williamson, Oliver E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, New York: Free Press. - Womack, Jones and Roos (1991), The Machine that Changed the World: The Story of Lean Production, New York: Harper. - Wysocki, Josef (1996), “Introduction”, in Mura (ed.), History of European Savings Banks, pp.9-25. - Zevin, Robert (1992), “Are World Financial Markets More Open? If So, Why and With What Effects”, in Banuri and Schor (eds.), Financial Openness and National Autonomy. - Zysman, John (1983), Governments, Markets and Growth: Financial Systems and the Politics of Industrial Change, Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press. - Zysman, John, (1994) "How Institutions Create Historically-Rooted Trajectories of Growth", Industrial and Corporate Change 3 (1): 243-283.

283 284 285 286

About WSBI (World Savings Banks Institute) and ESBG (European Savings Banks Group)

WSBI (World Savings Banks Institute) is one of the largest international banking associations and the only global representative of savings and retail banks. Founded in 1924, it represents savings and retail banks and associations thereof in 86 countries of the world (Asia-Pacific, the Americas, Africa and Europe – via the European Savings Banks Group). It works closely with international financial institutions and donor agencies and facilitates the provision of access to finance worldwide – be it in developing or developed regions.

ESBG (European Savings Banks Group) is an international banking association that represents one of the largest European retail banking networks, comprising about one third of the retail banking market in Europe. It represents the interests of its members vis-à-vis the EU Institutions and generates, facilitates and manages high quality cross-border banking projects.

WSBI-ESBG members are typically savings and retail banks or associations thereof. They are often organised in decentralised networks and offer their services throughout their region. WSBI and ESBG member banks have reinvested responsibly in their region for many decades and are one distinct benchmark for corporate social responsibility activities throughout Europe and the world.

Rue Marie-Thérèse, 11 B-1000 Brussels Tel: +32 2 211 11 11 Fax: +32 2 211 11 99 [email protected] www.savings-banks.com Published by WSBI/ESBG. Copyright January 2007 ISSN 1782-396X