Back in the Fast Lane

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Back in the Fast Lane Back in the Fast Lane The Indonesian capital bustles at night. As members N 1997-98, a financial crisis brought The per capita GDP of high-income countries three East Asian middle-income rose by about 50 percent between 1980 and of the middle- countries—Indonesia, Korea, and Thai- 2000, that of low-income countries increased income Iland—to their knees. It also affected more than 150 percent, and the income ratio Malaysia and the Philippines, which had dif- between high- and low-income countries has country club, ficulty sustaining growth. Many predicted that been halved. In contrast, average real per cap- East Asian the structural weaknesses that the crisis laid ita incomes of middle-income countries grew bare—corruption, cronyism, and nepotism— by less than 20 percent over this period, wid- nations may would condemn the region to stagnation, as ening the gap between them and high-income need to update they had in Latin America after its debt cri- countries by about 20 percent. Middle-income sis in the mid-1980s. Emerging East Asia was countries, it is argued, are squeezed between their growth expected to lose years of growth. Instead, its low-wage competitors in poor countries, which strategy growth record since 1998 has been remark- dominate mature industries, and innovators able: GDP has almost doubled, growing by in rich countries, which dominate industries more than 9 percent a year, to reach $4 trillion undergoing rapid technological change. Indermit S. Gill in current dollar terms by 2005. Despite the This line of reasoning suggests that East setback in the 1990s, growth during the past Asian middle-income countries must update and Homi Kharas 40 years has been consistent (see table). their strategies. What permits countries to Now, almost a decade later, Korea is a high- grow fast from a per capita income of $1,000 income country, and the other four are grow- to $10,000—the current challenge for most ing fast. China has joined the middle-income East Asian countries—is different and more club. Once Vietnam achieves middle-income difficult than what helped them grow from status, possibly as early as 2010, more than a per capita income of $100 to $1,000—the 95 percent of East Asians will inhabit a middle- challenge they successfully faced in the past. income country. Economic research suggests that two oppos- Should East Asia expect to continue these ing forces are at work. On the one hand, as high growth rates? The reality is that middle- countries get richer, they demand a greater vari- income countries (those with per capita ety of goods, many of which can be produced incomes of $826-$ 10,665) have grown less domestically. This creates a force toward sec- rapidly than either rich or poor countries. toral diversification. On the other hand, coun- 38 Rnance & Development March 2007 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution tries get richer only if they specialize in what they do best. Which tendency dominates is an empirical question. Researchers have Consistent performance found that a switch to specialization happens during middle East Asia has grown rapidly despite the 1997-98 crisis. income and depends critically on the extent of economies of (per capita GDP growth, 1966-2004; percent) scale in production (see box). Region/country Growth Number of years in which the rate was What did the Asian leaders in the first wave do to success- 0-2 Above fully transit through middle-income stages of development? Negative percent 2 percent East Asia and Pacific 5.8 2 3 34 And what can today's middle-income countries in East Asia China 7.0 3 3 33 do to ensure that they do not suffer the same fate as Latin Indonesia 4.0 4 3 32 America's middle-income countries, which have struggled Thailand 4.8 3 5 31 unsuccessfully to grow into rich countries? This article Philippines 1.3 6 21 12 Malaysia 4.0 5 3 31 explores the challenges facing middle-income East Asia today. Latin America and Caribbean 1.5 10 15 14 Middle East and North Africa1 1.2 8 13 9 Recognizing economies of scale South Asia 2.6 1 12 26 In addressing these questions, policymakers in the region Sub-Saharan Africa 0.2 14 20 5 OECD 2.5 0 18 21 can learn from recent advances in thinking about economic Sources: World Bank, World Development Indicators, and Global Development growth, industrial organization, international trade, and eco- Finance central databases. nomic geography. 'Data are from 1975 to 2004. Renewed interest in economic growth since the late 1980s has been triggered by the observation that income levels across countries have not been converging in line with tradi- move from places where they are abundant to where they are tional economic theory. This theory predicted that efforts to scarce, bringing with them the latest and best products, pro- accumulate physical and human capital, improve efficiency of cesses, and technologies. production, and use the latest technologies would pay off in a But this has not happened. With few exceptions—primarily narrowing of income gaps between developed and developing East Asia's strong performers—income gaps have widened. countries. Its fundamental implication was that, in seeking the This does not mean the market has not worked at all: most highest possible returns, financial and human capital would countries have become richer and poverty has fallen. But both between and within countries, human and financial capital appear to move from places where they are scarce to How to get richer where they are abundant. This makes good sense in a world Although economic development requires constant learning of economies of scale in which factors of production tend to and adjustment, recent findings suggest that countries with cluster in cities. per capita incomes between $1,000 and $10,000 should make The main driver of economies of scale, in modern growth several major changes in their strategy. theory, is ideas. Unlike goods and factors, ideas can be used • From diversification to specialization. Countries gener- repeatedly, as well as by many people at the same time—that ally appear to diversify initially as they grow, but this trend is is, they are "nonrival." And an idea, once formed, can be used reversed after per capita incomes reach about $5,000-$8,000, as a starting point for new ideas. However, it requires effort to after which countries begin to specialize. At what stage they come up with useful ideas. And people can be prevented from reach this tipping point depends on their size and export ori- using ideas to improve products or production processes entation, but it implies that, in addition to worrying about through secrecy or enforcement of intellectual property the general investment climate, policymakers may also need rights, even if temporarily. Because of such "excludability," to develop sector-specific strategies. knowledge confers on its creators some monopoly power and • From investment to innovation. As firms in a country generates what economists call "economic rents." approach the technological frontier, regulatory policies that By bringing knowledge into formulations of economic favored investment by incumbent firms should give way growth, economists can recognize the centrality of ideas and to regulations that encourage entry of new firms and exit increasing returns, but they must also recognize that ideas do of those whose products or technologies are obsolete. This not always flourish under perfect competition. Some compe- switch has to be timed right and will be difficult to imple- tition can give firms an incentive to innovate, but too much ment because of vested interests. can reduce the value firms get from each idea and thus reduce • From basic to higher education. As countries exploit their effort to create new ideas. By the late 1980s, explana- economies of scale, skill premiums will rise rapidly and poli- cymakers must plan for an adequate supply of new graduates tions of international trade routinely discussed imperfect to mitigate the increase in income inequality. In such econo- competition to understand the rise of intra-industry trade. mies, knowledge spillovers are important and merit public By the early 1990s, growth theorists had accepted the need subsidies for higher education. to incorporate scale economies into aggregate formulations of the economy. By the mid-1990s, theorists had shown how Sources: Imbs and Wacziarg (2003), Aghion and Howitt (2005), and Romer(1994). these concepts could also be used to understand where eco- nomic activity became concentrated. Finance & Development March 2007 39 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Insights for middle-income countries and between cities and the countryside. The outcomes may How can modern growth economics help middle-income not be egalitarian, but policymakers should at least try to countries? At the risk of oversimplification, we classify the provide equal access to education and other social services. insights into two groups: the role of private enterprise in • Modern growth theory predicts that there will be eco- exploiting economies of scale, and the role of governments nomic rents, and how they are distributed is vital for growth. in ensuring a fair distribution of income. Both are needed to If economic rents are reinvested in public infrastructure sustain rapid growth. and social services, the foundations of economic growth The formal recognition of economies of scale, which are strengthened. If they are dissipated in ineffective cities, brings economic theory closer to the world of policymakers, social strife, or corruption, they may even slow growth. Thus, has three implications for middle-income countries: governments must tax economic rents in ways that are least • Trade can take place between all kinds of economies.
Recommended publications
  • Understanding Development and Poverty Alleviation
    14 OCTOBER 2019 Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2019 UNDERSTANDING DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel THE ROYAL SWEDISH ACADEMY OF SCIENCES, founded in 1739, is an independent organisation whose overall objective is to promote the sciences and strengthen their influence in society. The Academy takes special responsibility for the natural sciences and mathematics, but endeavours to promote the exchange of ideas between various disciplines. BOX 50005 (LILLA FRESCATIVÄGEN 4 A), SE-104 05 STOCKHOLM, SWEDEN TEL +46 8 673 95 00, [email protected] WWW.KVA.SE Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2019 Understanding Development and Poverty Alleviation The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel October 14, 2019 Despite massive progress in the past few decades, global poverty — in all its different dimensions — remains a broad and entrenched problem. For example, today, more than 700 million people subsist on extremely low incomes. Every year, five million children under five die of diseases that often could have been prevented or treated by a handful of proven interventions. Today, a large majority of children in low- and middle-income countries attend primary school, but many of them leave school lacking proficiency in reading, writing and mathematics. How to effectively reduce global poverty remains one of humankind’s most pressing questions. It is also one of the biggest questions facing the discipline of economics since its very inception.
    [Show full text]
  • Philippe Aghion
    CURRICULUM VITAE (last updated March 2018) Name: Philippe Aghion Address: College de France 3 rue d Ulm 75005 Paris France Email: [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] Date of Birth: August 17, 1956 Place of Birth: Paris, France Education: 1976-80 Ecole Normale Supérieure de Cachan, Mathematics Section 1981 Diplome d’Etudes Approfondies d’Economie Mathématique, Université de Paris I 1983 Doctorat de 3éme cycle d’Economie Mathématique, Université de Paris I- Pantheon-Sorbonne 1987 Ph.D. Harvard University (Economics) Professional Experience: 1986-87 Sloan Foundation Dissertation Fellowship 1987-89 Assistant Professor, Massachusetts Institute of Technology 1989- Chargé de Recherches au Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique 1990-1992 Deputy Chief Economist, EBRD (London) 1992-96 Official Fellow, Nuffield College (Oxford) 1992-2000 Research Co-ordinator, EBRD (London) 1996-2002 Professor of Economics, University College London (UCL) 2000-2002 Professor of Economics, Harvard University 2002- 2015 Robert C. Waggoner Professor of Economics, Harvard University 2015- Professor at College de France, Chair entitled “Institutions, Innovation, et Croissance” 2009-2015 Invited Professor, Institute of International Economic Studies, Stockholm 2015- Centennial Professor of Economics, London School of Economics 2018-2020 Visiting Professor, Department of Economics, Harvard University Other Professional Positions or Appointments: 1991-97 Associate Editor, Review of Economic Studies 1992- Managing Editor,
    [Show full text]
  • Escaping the Climate Trap? Values, Technologies, and Politics∗
    Escaping the Climate Trap? Values, Technologies, and Politics Tim Besleyyand Torsten Perssonz November 2020 Abstract It is widely acknowledged that reducing the emissions of green- house gases is almost impossible without radical changes in consump- tion and production patterns. This paper examines the interdependent roles of changing environmental values, changing technologies, and the politics of environmental policy, in creating sustainable societal change. Complementarities that emerge naturally in our framework may generate a “climate trap,”where society does not transit towards lifestyles and technologies that are more friendly to the environment. We discuss a variety of forces that make the climate trap more or less avoidable, including lobbying by firms, private politics, motivated scientists, and (endogenous) subsidies to green innovation. We are grateful for perceptive comments by Philippe Aghion, David Baron, Xavier Jaravel, Bård Harstad, Elhanan Helpman, Gilat Levy, Linus Mattauch, and Jean Tirole, as well as participants in a Tsinghua University seminar, and LSE and Hong Kong University webinars. We also thank Azhar Hussain for research assistance. Financial support from the ERC and the Swedish Research Council is gratefully acknowledged. yLSE, [email protected]. zIIES, Stockholm University, [email protected] 1 1 Introduction What will it take to bring about the fourth industrial revolution that may be needed to save the planet? Such a revolution would require major structural changes in production as well as consumption patterns. Firms would have to invest on a large scale in technologies that generate lower greenhouse gas emissions, and households would have to consume goods that produce lower emissions. Already these observations suggest that the required transformation can be reinforced by a key complementarity, akin to the one associated with so- called platform technologies (Rochet and Tirole 2003).
    [Show full text]
  • Endogenous Preferences: the Political Consequences of Economic Institutions
    Endogenous Preferences: The Political Consequences of Economic Institutions Jan-Emmanuel De Neve∗y November 5, 2009 Abstract This paper attempts to explain cross-national voting behavior in 18 West- ern democracies over 1960-2003. A new data set for the median voter is intro- duced that corrects for stochastic error in the statistics from the Comparative Manifesto Project. Next, the paper finds that electoral behavior is closely re- lated to the salience of particular economic institutions. Labour organization, skill specificity, and public sector employment are found to influence individual voting behavior. At the country level, this paper suggests that coordinated market economies move the median voter to the left, whereas liberal market economies move the median voter to the right. The empirical analysis employs cross-sectional and panel data that are instrumented with the level of eco- nomic structure circa 1900 to estimate the net effect of economic institutions on the median voter. Significant results show that revealed voter preferences are endogenous to the economic institutions of the political economy. This paper places political economy at the heart of voting behavior and implies the existence of institutional advantages to partisan politics. Keywords: Comparative Political Economy, Median Voter, Voting Behav- ior, Panel Data, Instrumental Variables JEL Classification Numbers: C23, D72, H5, J24, J51, O57, P51 . ∗London School of Economics and Political Science, Department of Government, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, United Kingdom (email: [email protected]). yFor their time and generous data sharing, the author would like to thank Simon Hix, Jonathan Hopkin, Peter Hall, Torben Iversen, Lane Kenworthy, Duane Swank, Daniel Gingerich, Pepper Culpepper, Piero Stanig, Slava Mikhaylov, Johannes Spinnewijn, and Richard Fording.
    [Show full text]
  • Employee Representation and Corporate Governance: a Missing Link
    EMPLOYEE REPRESENTATION AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE: A MISSING LINK Sanford M. Jacobyt The publication of Freeman and Rogers' What Workers Want' is a major contribution to the debate over employee representation in America. The authors have answered the basic question of what workers and manag- ers want. Now we must reconsider how public policy can be designed to help these preferences be realized. Although Freeman and Rogers have on other occasions contributed ideas for closing the representation gap,2 the present study maintains a curious silence on solutions. Most of the recent policy proposals on employee representation at- tempt to tweak the National Labor Relations Act to permit greater experi- mentation with nonunion employee participation plans. For example, the so-called Dunlop Commission of the mid-1990s outlined the following four principal policy options, all of which focused on labor law: (1) to retain the law in its present form; (2) to revise section 8(a)(2) to permit employers to create employee involvement plans and even company unions, so long as they do not bargain collectively with the employer (the approach contained in the so-called TEAM Act); (3) to modify the TEAM approach to permit employers to establish employee involvement plans but require that they meet certain standards for employee selection, access to information, and protection against reprisals; and (4) to legally require the establishment of employee participation committees,3 as in the plan put forth in 1990 by Professor Paul Weiler to require every company above a certain size to es- tablish elected committees to address the firm's human resource policies t Professor of Management, Policy Studies and History, UCLA; A.B.
    [Show full text]
  • October 2004
    ROBIN BURGESS CONTACT INFORMATION LSE Department of Economics Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK Tel: (020) 7955 6676, Fax: (020) 7955 6951 [email protected] http://econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/rburgess/index_own.html PERSONAL Marital Status: Married to Bronwen Burgess Children: Isla Macbeth Burgess (d.o.b. August 03, 2005) Citizenship: UK PROFESSIONAL EXPERIENCE POSITIONS 2007 – present Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, LSE 2004 – 2007 Reader in Economics, Department of Economics, LSE 1999 – present Co-Director, Economic Organization and Public Policy Programme, STICERD, LSE 2005 Visiting Associate Professor, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, Fall Semester 2003 Visiting Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Harvard University and National Bureau for Economic Research, Fall Semester 2002 Visiting Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University College London, Fall Semester 2001 Visiting Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, MIT, Fall Semester 2000 – 2004 Lecturer in Economics, Department of Economics, LSE 1998 – 1999 Lecturer in Development Economics, Development Studies Institute and Department of Economics, LSE 1991 – 1995 Consultant Economist, Chief Economists Office, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development 1989 – 1991 Consultant Economist, World Development Report and Research Department, World Bank AFFILIATIONS 2006 – present Program Director, CEPR Development Economics Program (with Esther Duflo) 2005 – present Senior Fellow, Bureau for Research in the Economic
    [Show full text]
  • Artificial Intelligence and Economic Growth
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARTIFICIAL INTELLIGENCE AND ECONOMIC GROWTH Philippe Aghion Benjamin F. Jones Charles I. Jones Working Paper 23928 http://www.nber.org/papers/w23928 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 October 2017 We are grateful to Ajay Agrawal, Mohammad Ahmadpoor, Adrien Auclert, Sebastian Di Tella, Patrick Francois, Joshua Gans, Avi Goldfarb, Pete Klenow, Hannes Mahlmberg, Pascual Restrepo, Chris Tonetti, Michael Webb, and participants at the NBER Conference on Artificial Intelligence for helpful discussion and comments. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2017 by Philippe Aghion, Benjamin F. Jones, and Charles I. Jones. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Artificial Intelligence and Economic Growth Philippe Aghion, Benjamin F. Jones, and Charles I. Jones NBER Working Paper No. 23928 October 2017 JEL No. O3,O4 ABSTRACT This paper examines the potential impact of artificial intelligence (A.I.) on economic growth. We model A.I. as the latest form of automation, a broader process dating back more than 200 years. Electricity, internal combustion engines, and semiconductors facilitated automation in the last century, but A.I. now seems poised to automate many tasks once thought to be out of reach, from driving cars to making medical recommendations and beyond.
    [Show full text]
  • The Flotilla Effect Europe’S Small Economies Through the Eye of the Storm
    The Flotilla Effect Europe’s small economies through the eye of the storm A Report for Jill Evans MEP by Adam Price with Ben Levinger The Flotilla Effect Europe’s small economies through the eye of the storm Adam Price with Ben Levinger Page 2 Today, Europe consists solely of small countries. The only relevant distinction that remains is that some countries understand this, while others still refuse to acknowledge it. Paul-Henri Spaak Page 3 Acknowledgements The authors would like to acknowledge the following for their help and support: Professor Michael Landesmann, Dr Eurfyl ap Gwilym and Dr. Rhys ap Gwilym for their comments and suggestions and David Linden, Iain Wallace and Daniel Wylie for their extremely valuable research input. Lastly we would like to put on record our heartfelt thanks to Jill Evans MEP (Plaid Cymru) and Alyn Smith MEP (Scottish National Party) for their financial support without which this research project would not have been possible. The views expressed and any inadequacies, inaccuracies or omissions are exclusively our own. Page 4 Biographies Adam Price was the Plaid Cymru Member of Parliament for Carmarthen East and Dinefwr between 2001 and 2010. He has published widely on politics, history and economic development, and is the former Managing Director of an economics consultancy. He is currently a Research Fellow at the Center for International Development at Harvard‟s John F. Kennedy School of Government. He can be contacted via email on [email protected]. Benjamin Levinger is currently conducting research at the Brookings Institution and studying for a Master in Public Policy at the Kennedy School.
    [Show full text]
  • Digital Economics†
    Journal of Economic Literature 2019, 57(1), 3–43 https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20171452 Permission to make digital or hard copies of part or all of American Economic Association publications for personal or classroom use is granted without fee provided that copies are not distributed for profit or direct commercial advantage and that copies show this notice on the first page or initial screen of a display along with the full citation, including the name of the author. Copyrights for components of this work owned by others than AEA must be honored. Abstracting with credit is permitted. The author has the right to republish, post on servers, redistribute to lists and use any component of this work in other works. For others to do so requires prior specific permission and/or a fee. Permissions may be requested from the American Economic Association Administrative Office by going to the Contact Us form and choosing "Copyright/Permissions Request" from the menu. Copyright © 2019 AEA Digital Economics† Avi Goldfarb and Catherine Tucker* Digital technology is the representation of information in bits. This technology has reduced the cost of storage, computation, and transmission of data. Research on digital economics examines whether and how digital technology changes economic activity. In this review, we emphasize the reduction in five distinct economic costs associated with digital economic activity: search costs, replication costs, transportation costs, tracking costs, and verification costs. (JEL D24, D83, L86, O33, R41) 1. What Is Digital Economics? economic models change as certain costs fall substantially and perhaps approach zero. igital technology is the representation We emphasize how this shift in costs can be Dof information in bits.
    [Show full text]
  • Faculty Research Working Papers Series
    Faculty Research Working Papers Series Inequality, Redistribution, and Population Filipe Campante John F. Kennedy School of Government – Harvard University Quoc-Anh Do Department of Economics – Harvard University October 2007 RWP07-046 This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://ksgnotes1.harvard.edu/Research/wpaper.nsf/rwp/RWP07-046 or The Social Science Research Network: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1083714 The views expressed in the KSG Faculty Research Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the John F. Kennedy School of Government or of Harvard University. Faculty Research Working Papers have not undergone formal review and approval. Such papers are included in this series to elicit feedback and to encourage debate on important public policy challenges. Copyright belongs to the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use only. Inequality, Redistribution, and Population∗ Filipe R. Campante† and Quoc-Anh Do‡ June 2007 Abstract We document a negative relationship between population size and inequality in the cross-country data. We propose an explanation built on the existence of a size effect in the political economy of redistribution, particularly in the presence of different channels of popular request for redistribution, e.g. “institutional” channels and “revolutions”. Based on the assumption that the threat of revolution is directly related to the number of people that may attempt to revolt, the theory predicts that the stylized fact initially uncovered by the paper can be refinedasfollows:thereisanegative relationship between population size, and its geographical concentration, and post-tax inequality in non-democracies. We subject these predictions to extensive empirical scrutiny in a cross-country context, and the data robustly confirm these patterns of inequality, population, and the interaction with democracy.
    [Show full text]
  • Good Economics for Hard Times Notes Explore Book Giveaways, Sneak Peeks, Deals, and More
    Copyright Copyright © 2019 by Abhijit V. Banerjee and Esther Duflo Cover design by Pete Garceau Cover copyright © 2019 Hachette Book Group, Inc. Hachette Book Group supports the right to free expression and the value of copyright. The purpose of copyright is to encourage writers and artists to produce the creative works that enrich our culture. The scanning, uploading, and distribution of this book without permission is a theft of the author’s intellectual property. If you would like permission to use material from the book (other than for review purposes), please contact [email protected]. Thank you for your support of the author’s rights. PublicAffairs Hachette Book Group 1290 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10104 www.publicaffairsbooks.com @Public_Affairs First Edition: November 2019 Published by PublicAffairs, an imprint of Perseus Books, LLC, a subsidiary of Hachette Book Group, Inc. The PublicAffairs name and logo is a trademark of the Hachette Book Group. The Hachette Speakers Bureau provides a wide range of authors for speaking events. To find out more, go to www.hachettespeakersbureau.com or call (866) 376-6591. The publisher is not responsible for websites (or their content) that are not owned by the publisher. Editorial production by Christine Marra, Marrathon Production Services. www.marrathoneditorial.org Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data has been applied for. ISBN 978-1-61039-950-0 (hardcover), ISBN 978-1-5417-6287-9 (ebook) E3-20191019-JV-NF-ORI CONTENTS Cover Title Page Copyright Dedication Preface 1 MEGA: Make Economics Great Again 2 From the Mouth of the Shark 3 The Pains from Trade 4 Likes, Wants, and Needs 5 The End of Growth? 6 In Hot Water 7 Player Piano 8 Legit.gov 9 Cash and Care Conclusion: Good and Bad Economics Acknowledgments Discover More About the Authors Praise for Good Economics for Hard Times Notes Explore book giveaways, sneak peeks, deals, and more.
    [Show full text]
  • Proquest Dissertations
    Winning the Peace: Canadian Economic and Political Security, 1943-1948 by Philippe Lagasse A thesis submitted to the Faculty of Graduate Studies and Research in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Department of Political Science Carleton University Ottawa, Ontario December 2007 © 2007 Philippe Lagasse Library and Bibliotheque et 1*1 Archives Canada Archives Canada Published Heritage Direction du Branch Patrimoine de I'edition 395 Wellington Street 395, rue Wellington Ottawa ON K1A0N4 Ottawa ON K1A0N4 Canada Canada Your file Votre reference ISBN: 978-0-494-40527-7 Our file Notre reference ISBN: 978-0-494-40527-7 NOTICE: AVIS: The author has granted a non­ L'auteur a accorde une licence non exclusive exclusive license allowing Library permettant a la Bibliotheque et Archives and Archives Canada to reproduce, Canada de reproduire, publier, archiver, publish, archive, preserve, conserve, sauvegarder, conserver, transmettre au public communicate to the public by par telecommunication ou par Plntemet, prefer, telecommunication or on the Internet, distribuer et vendre des theses partout dans loan, distribute and sell theses le monde, a des fins commerciales ou autres, worldwide, for commercial or non­ sur support microforme, papier, electronique commercial purposes, in microform, et/ou autres formats. paper, electronic and/or any other formats. The author retains copyright L'auteur conserve la propriete du droit d'auteur ownership and moral rights in et des droits moraux qui protege cette these. this thesis. Neither the thesis Ni la these ni des extraits substantiels de nor substantial extracts from it celle-ci ne doivent etre imprimes ou autrement may be printed or otherwise reproduits sans son autorisation.
    [Show full text]