How to Measure Time Preferences: an Experimental Comparison of Three Methods

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

How to Measure Time Preferences: an Experimental Comparison of Three Methods Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 8, No. 3, May 2013, pp. 236–249 How to measure time preferences: An experimental comparison of three methods David J. Hardisty∗ Katherine F. Thompsony David H. Krantzy Elke U. Weberz Abstract In two studies, time preferences for financial gains and losses at delays of up to 50 years were elicited using three different methods: matching, fixed-sequence choice titration, and a dynamic “staircase” choice method. Matching was found to create fewer demand characteristics and to produce better fits with the hyperbolic model of discounting. The choice-based measures better predicted real-world outcomes such as smoking and payment of credit card debt. No consistent advantages were found for the dynamic staircase method over fixed-sequence titration. Keywords: time preference, discounting, measurement, method. 1 Introduction tial versus hyperbolic discounting models. The contin- uously compounded exponential discount rate (Samuel- Throughout life, people continually make decisions about son, 1937) is calculated as V = Ae−kD, where V is the what to do or have immediately, and what to put off un- present value, A is the future amount, e is the base of til later. The behavior of a person choosing an imme- the natural logarithm, D is the delay in years, and k is diate benefit at the cost of foregoing a larger delayed the discount rate. This is a normative model of discount- benefit (e.g., by purchasing a new car rather than sav- ing, which specifies how rational decision makers ought ing towards one’s pension) is an example of temporal to evaluate future events, but it has often been employed discounting (Samuelson, 1937). Similarly, choosing to as a descriptive model as well. The hyperbolic model avoid an immediate loss in favor of a larger, later loss (Mazur, 1987) is a descriptive model, calculated as V (e.g., by postponing a credit-card payment) is another ex- = A / (1+kD), where V is the present value, A is the ample of discounting. Laboratory measures of discount- future amount, D is the delay,1 and k is the discount ing predict many important real-world behaviors that in- rate. Although the hyperbolic and exponential models volve tradeoffs between immediate and delayed conse- are often highly correlated,2 the hyperbolic model often quences, including credit-card debt, smoking, exercise, fits the data somewhat better (e.g., Kirby, 1997; Kirby and marital infidelity (Chabris, Laibson, Morris, Schuldt, & Marakovic, 1995; Myerson & Green, 1995; Rachlin, & Taubinsky, 2008; Daly, Harmon, & Delaney, 2009; Raineri, & Cross, 1991). Because most recent psycho- Meier & Sprenger, 2010; Reimers, Maylor, Stewart, & logical studies of discounting have employed the hyper- Chater, 2009). At the same time, numerous studies have bolic model, our further analyses in this paper will focus established that time preferences are also determined by a on this model. number of contextual factors (for an overview, see Fred- In addition to these two popular discounting metrics, erick, 2003). others have been proposed and tested (for a recent review, Despite the growing popularity of research on tempo- see Doyle, 2013). In contrast, investigations of differ- ral discounting (Figure 1), there is relatively little consen- ent experimental procedures for eliciting discount rates sus or empirical research on which methods are best for are rare. A comprehensive review paper on discounting measuring discounting. Most of the theoretical and em- (Frederick, Loewenstein, & O’Donoghue, 2002) noted pirical efforts have been directed at testing rival exponen- the huge variability in discount rates among studies, and Support for this research was provided by National Science Foun- hypothesized that heterogeneity in elicitation methods dation grant SES-0820496. Supplementary material to this article is might be a major cause. Fifty-two percent of studies re- available through the table of contents of the journal, at the link on the top of each page. 1The units of delay in the hyperbolic model are unspecified, but in Copyright: © 2013. The authors license this article under the terms the experimental literature delay is often measured in days or years. of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 License. Measuring in years yields numbers that are easier to work with (e.g., ∗Graduate School of Business, Stanford University. Email: a yearly k of 0.3 rather than a daily k of 0.0008), so we will measure [email protected]. delay in years throughout this paper. yDepartment of Psychology, Columbia University. 2Researchers desiring to distinguish between hyperbolic and expo- zDepartments of Management and Psychology, Columbia Univer- nential models can design experimental stimuli to make them orthogo- sity nal, following the guidelines of Doyle, Chen, and Savani (2011). 236 Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 8, No. 3, May 2013 Time-preference measurement 237 directly. For example, it might ask the participant what Figure 1: Graph illustrating the rising popularity of amount “X” would make her indifferent between $10 im- temporal discounting as a research topic over the last mediately and $X in one year. twenty years. Results come from searching on ISI How do discount rates from these two elicitation meth- Web of Knowledge with Topic=(temporal discount*) OR ods compare? Several studies have concluded that match- Topic=(delay discount*) NOT Topic=(lobe) Search lan- ing yields lower discount rates than choice (Ahlbrecht guage=English Lemmatization=On Refined by: General & Weber, 1997; Manzini, Mariotti, & Mittone, 2008; Categories=( SOCIAL SCIENCES ), broken down by Read & Roelofsma, 2003). What are the reasons or year. mechanisms for this difference? One hypothesis is that, in choice, people are motivated to take the earlier re- ward, and pay relatively more attention to the delay (rather than the greater magnitude) of the later reward, whereas the matching methods, which typically ask for a match on the dollar dimension, focus them on the mag- nitude of the two rewards and thus results in a better at- tentional balance between the magnitude and delay at- tributes (Tversky, Sattath, & Slovic, 1988). This atten- tional hypothesis predicts order effects (specifically, that the first method will bias attention throughout the task), but unfortunately neither study investigated task order,3 so it is difficult to know whether participants’ experi- ence with one method influenced their answers on the other method. Frederick (2003) compared seven differ- ent elicitation methods (choice, matching, rating, “total”, sequence, “equity”, and “context”) for saving lives now or in the future. He also found that matching produced lower discount rates than choice, but again, order effects were not explored. He speculated that the choice task creates demand characteristics: offering the choice be- tween different amounts of immediate and future lives viewed used choice-based measures, 31% used matching, implies that one ought to discount them to some extent— and 17% used another method. “otherwise, why would the experimenter be asking the question” (Frederick, 2003, p. 42). In contrast, the match- ing method makes no suggestions as to which amounts 1.1 Measuring discount rates: Choice ver- are appropriate. sus matching Further evidence that characteristics of offered choice Choice-based methods often present participants with a options can bias discount rates comes from a pair of series of binary comparisons and use these to infer an in- studies that compared two variations on a choice-based difference point, which is then converted into a discount measure. One version presented repeated choices that rate. For example, suppose a participant, presented with a kept the larger-later reward constant with the amounts choice between receiving $10 immediately or $11 in one of the smaller-sooner reward presented in ascending or- year, chooses the immediate option, and subsequently, der, while the other version employed the same choice presented with a choice between $10 or $12 in one year, pairs, but with the smaller-sooner amounts presented in chooses the future option. This pattern of choices im- descending order. The order of presentation influenced plies that the participant would be indifferent between discount rates, such that participants were more patient $10 today and some amount between $11 and $12 in one (i.e., exhibited lower discount rates) when answering the year. For analytic convenience, we assign their indiffer- questions in descending order of sooner reward (Robles ence point as the average of the upper and lower bound, & Vargas, 2008; Robles, Vargas, & Bejarano, 2009). This which would be $11.50 in this case. This indifference suggests that observed discount rates are at least partly point can then be converted into a discount rate using one a function of constructed preference (Stewart, Chater, of the discounting models discussed above. For example, & Brown, 2006) and “coherent arbitrariness” (Ariely, using the continuously compounded exponential model, Loewenstein, & Prelec, 2003), rather than a stable in- this would yield a discount rate of 14%. The matching 3In Ahlbrecht & Weber (1997), participants always did matching method, in contrast, asks for the exact indifference point before choice. Read & Roelofsma (2003) does not state the task order. Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 8, No. 3, May 2013 Time-preference measurement 238 dividual preference. One explanation offered by Robles based discount rates predict consequential decisions and and colleagues is the
Recommended publications
  • The Role of Time Preference on Wealth
    THE ROLE OF TIME PREFERENCE ON WEALTH _______________________________________ A Thesis presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School at the University of Missouri-Columbia _______________________________________________________ In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Master of Science _____________________________________________________ by ANDREW MARK ZUMWALT Dr. Deanna L. Sharpe, Thesis Co-Supervisor Dr. Sandra J. Huston, Thesis Co-Supervisor December 2008 The undersigned, appointed by the dean of the Graduate School, have examined the thesis entitled THE ROLE OF TIME PREFERENCE ON WEALTH presented by Andrew Mark Zumwalt, a candidate for the degree of master of science, and hereby certify that, in their opinion, it is worthy of acceptance. Professor Deanna L. Sharpe Professor Sandra J. Huston Professor Thomas Johnson ad maiorem dei gloriam ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS All throughout my life, I have been supported by strong individuals. These people have been the pillars of my success, and without their influence and guidance, I would be nowhere near where I am now. I can only hope that I have, in turn, enriched their lives. I aspire to fulfill a similar role for the young men and women I meet. While I believe that my success has been caused by the cumulative efforts of many individuals, I would like to take this limited space to thank those that have helped with this part of my life. First, I would like to thank the members of my committee. Dr Thomas Johnson’s experience from agricultural economics provided insight into overlooked ideas in my research when viewed in a broader context. He has also been extremely understanding with regard to interesting timetables, and I’ve thoroughly enjoyed learning from him in both inside and outside the classroom.
    [Show full text]
  • The Geographies of Soft Paternalism in the UK: the Rise of the Avuncular State and Changing Behaviour After Neoliberalism
    The Geographies of Soft Paternalism in the UK: the rise of the avuncular state and changing behaviour after neoliberalism Rhys Jones, Jessica Pykett and Mark Whitehead, Aberystwyth University Forthcoming, Geography Compass Abstract Soft paternalism or libertarian paternalism has emerged as a new rationality of governing in the UK under New Labour, denoting a style of governing which is aimed at both increasing choice and ensuring welfare. Popularised in Thaler and Sunstein’s best-selling title, Nudge, the approach of libertarian paternalism poses new questions for critical human geographers interested in how the philosophies and practices of the Third Way are being adapted and developed in a range of public policy spheres, including the environment, personal finance and health policy. Focusing specifically on the case of the UK, this article charts how soft paternalism appeals to the intellectual influences of behavioural economics, psychology and the neurosciences, amongst others, to justify government interventions based on the ‘non-ideal’ or irrational citizen. By identifying the distinctive mechanisms associated with this ‘behaviour change’ agenda, such as ‘choice architecture’, we explore the contribution of behavioural geographies and political geographies of the state to further understanding of the techniques and rationalities of governing. 1 The Geographies of Soft Paternalism: the rise of the avuncular state and changing behaviour after neoliberalism 1. Introduction: The Chicago School comes to Britain Mark II. On March 24 2009, David Cameron stood next to the eminent behavioural economist Richard Thaler at the London Stock Exchange. David Cameron was in the City of London to deliver his keynote speech on banking reform and the Tory’s response to the credit crunch.
    [Show full text]
  • Variable-Time-Preference-He-Et-Al.Pdf
    Cognitive Psychology 111 (2019) 53–79 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Cognitive Psychology journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/cogpsych Variable time preference ⁎ T Lisheng Hea, , Russell Golmanb, Sudeep Bhatiaa,1 a University of Pennsylvania, United States b Carnegie Mellon University, United States ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT Keywords: We re-examine behavioral patterns of intertemporal choice with recognition that time pre- Decision making ferences may be inherently variable, focusing in particular on the explanatory power of an ex- Intertemporal choice ponential discounting model with variable discount factors – the variable exponential model. We Stochastic choice provide analytical results showing that this model can generate systematically different choice Preference variability patterns from an exponential discounting model with a fixed discount factor. The variable ex- Computational modeling ponential model accounts for the common behavioral pattern of decreasing impatience, which is typically attributed to hyperbolic discounting. The variable exponential model also generates violations of strong stochastic transitivity in choices involving intertemporal dominance. We present the results of two experiments designed to evaluate the variable exponential model in terms of quantitative fit to individual-level choice data. Data from these experiments reveal that allowing for a variable discount factor significantly improves the fit of the exponential model, and that a variable exponential model provides a better account of individual-level choice probabilities than hyperbolic discounting models. In a third experiment we find evidence of strong stochastic transitivity violations when intertemporal dominance is involved, in accordance with the variable exponential model. Overall, our analytical and experimental results indicate that exponential discounting can explain intertemporal choice behavior that was supposed to be beyond its descriptive scope if the discount factor is permitted to vary at random.
    [Show full text]
  • Time Preference and Economic Progress
    Alexandru Pătruți, 45 ISSN 2071-789X Mihai Vladimir Topan RECENT ISSUES IN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT Alexandru Pătruți, Mihai Vladimir Topan, Time Preference, Growth and Civilization: Economic Insights into the Workings of Society, Economics & Sociology, Vol. 5, No 2a, 2012, pp. 45-56. Alexandru Pătruti, PhD TIME PREFERENCE, GROWTH AND Candidate Bucharest University of Economic CIVILIZATION: ECONOMIC Science Department of International INSIGHTS INTO THE WORKINGS Business and Economics Faculty of International Business OF SOCIETY and Economics 6, Piata Romana, 1st district, ABSTRACT. Economic concepts are not mere ivory 010374, Romania tower abstractions disconnected from reality. To a +4.021.319.19.00 certain extent they can help interdisciplinary endeavours E-mail: [email protected] at explaining various non-economic realities (the family, education, charity, civilization, etc.). Following the Mihai Vladimir Topan, insights of Hoppe (2001), we argue that the economic PhD Lecturer concept of social time preference can provide insights – Bucharest University of Economic when interpreted in the proper context – into the degree Science Department of International of civilization of a nation/region/city/group of people. Business and Economics More specifically, growth and prosperity backed by the Faculty of International Business proper institutional context lead, ceteris paribus, to a and Economics diminishing of the social rate of time preference, and 6, Piata Romana, 1st district, therefore to more future-oriented behaviours compatible 010374, Romania with a more ambitious, capital intensive structure of +4.021.319.19.00 production, and with the accumulation of sustainable E-mail: [email protected] cultural patterns; on the other hand, improper institutional arrangements which hamper growth and Received: July, 2012 prosperity lead to an increase in the social rate of time 1st Revision: September, 2012 preference, to more present-oriented behaviours and, Accepted: Desember, 2012 ultimately, to the erosion of culture.
    [Show full text]
  • Time Preference and Its Relationship with Age, Health, and Survival Probability
    Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 4, No. 1, February 2009, pp. 1–19 Time preference and its relationship with age, health, and survival probability Li-Wei Chao∗1, Helena Szrek2, Nuno Sousa Pereira2,3 and Mark V. Pauly4 1 Population Studies Center, University of Pennsylvania 2 Center for Economics and Finance, University of Porto 3 Faculty of Economics, University of Porto 4 Health Care Systems Department, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Abstract Although theories from economics and evolutionary biology predict that one’s age, health, and survival probability should be associated with one’s subjective discount rate (SDR), few studies have empirically tested for these links. Our study analyzes in detail how the SDR is related to age, health, and survival probability, by surveying a sample of individuals in townships around Durban, South Africa. In contrast to previous studies, we find that age is not significantly related to the SDR, but both physical health and survival expectations have a U-shaped relationship with the SDR. Individuals in very poor health have high discount rates, and those in very good health also have high discount rates. Similarly, those with expected survival probability on the extremes have high discount rates. Therefore, health and survival probability, and not age, seem to be predictors of one’s SDR in an area of the world with high morbidity and mortality. Keywords: subjective discount rate; delay discounting; expected survival probability; health; age; South Africa. 1 Introduction diately, and the degree to which an individual discounts the future reward will be measured as the subjective dis- People generally prefer to receive a reward sooner rather count rate or SDR (which we define formally below).
    [Show full text]
  • Hyperbolic Discounting and the Time-Consistent Solution of Three Canonical Environmental Problems
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Strulik, Holger Working Paper Hyperbolic discounting and the time-consistent solution of three canonical environmental problems cege Discussion Papers, No. 319 Provided in Cooperation with: Georg August University of Göttingen, cege - Center for European, Governance and Economic Development Research Suggested Citation: Strulik, Holger (2017) : Hyperbolic discounting and the time-consistent solution of three canonical environmental problems, cege Discussion Papers, No. 319, University of Göttingen, Center for European, Governance and Economic Development Research (cege), Göttingen This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/170719 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten,
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper
    September 2014 136 Institut für Makroökonomie und Konjunkturforschung Macroeconomic Policy Institute Working Paper Thomas I. Palley1 The theory of global imbalances: mainstream economics vs. structural Keynesianism August 2014 Abstract Prior to the 2008 financial crisis there was much debate about global trade imbalances. Prima facie, the imbalances seem a significant problem. However, acknowledging that would question mainstream economics’ celebratory stance toward globalization. That tension prompted an array of explanations which explained the imbalances while retaining the claim that globalization is socially beneficial. This paper surveys those new theories. It contrasts them with the structural Keynesian explanation that views the imbalances as an inevitable consequence of neoliberal globalization. The paper also describes how globalization created a political economy that supported the system despite its proclivity to generate trade imbalances. Keywords global imbalances, saving glut, new Bretton Woods, asset shortage, structural Keynesianism. Jel references JEL references: F02, F32, F33. 1 Senior Economic Policy Advisor, AFL-CIO, Washington DC. [email protected] The theory of global imbalances: mainstream economics vs. structural Keynesianism1 Abstract Prior to the 2008 financial crisis there was much debate about global trade imbalances. Prima facie, the imbalances seem a significant problem. However, acknowledging that would question mainstream economics’ celebratory stance toward globalization. That tension prompted an array of explanations which explained the imbalances while retaining the claim that globalization is socially beneficial. This paper surveys those new theories. It contrasts them with the structural Keynesian explanation that views the imbalances as an inevitable consequence of neoliberal globalization. The paper also describes how globalization created a political economy that supported the system despite its proclivity to generate trade imbalances.
    [Show full text]
  • Neuroeconomics: How Neuroscience Can Inform Economics
    mr05_Article 1 3/28/05 3:25 PM Page 9 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLIII (March 2005), pp. 9–64 Neuroeconomics: How Neuroscience Can Inform Economics ∗ COLIN CAMERER, GEORGE LOEWENSTEIN, and DRAZEN PRELEC Who knows what I want to do? Who knows what anyone wants to do? How can you be sure about something like that? Isn’t it all a question of brain chemistry, signals going back and forth, electrical energy in the cortex? How do you know whether something is really what you want to do or just some kind of nerve impulse in the brain. Some minor little activity takes place somewhere in this unimportant place in one of the brain hemispheres and suddenly I want to go to Montana or I don’t want to go to Montana. (White Noise, Don DeLillo) 1. Introduction such as finance, game theory, labor econom- ics, public finance, law, and macroeconomics In the last two decades, following almost a (see Colin Camerer and George Loewenstein century of separation, economics has begun 2004). Behavioral economics has mostly been to import insights from psychology. informed by a branch of psychology called “Behavioral economics” is now a prominent “behavioral decision research,” but other fixture on the intellectual landscape and has cognitive sciences are ripe for harvest. Some spawned applications to topics in economics, important insights will surely come from neu- roscience, either directly or because neuro- ∗ Camerer: California Institute of Technology. science will reshape what is believed about Loewenstein: Carnegie Mellon University. Prelec: psychology which in turn informs economics. Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
    [Show full text]
  • A Social Time Preference Rate for Use in Long-Term Discounting
    THE OFFICE OF THE DEPUTY PRIME MINISTER, DEPARTMENT FOR TRANSPORT, AND DEPARTMENT OF THE ENVIRONMENT, FOOD AND RURAL AFFAIRS A SOCIAL TIME PREFERENCE RATE FOR USE IN LONG-TERM DISCOUNTING 17TH DECEMBER 2002 OXERA OXERA Consulting Ltd is registered in England, no. 2589629. Registered office: Blue Boar Court, Alfred Street, Oxford OX1 4EH, UK. Although every effort has been made to ensure the accuracy of the material and the integrity of the analysis presented herein, OXERA Consulting Ltd accepts no liability for any actions taken on the basis of its contents. OXERA Consulting Ltd is not licensed in the conduct of investment business as defined in the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000. Anyone considering a specific investment should consult their own broker or other investment adviser. OXERA Consulting Ltd accepts no liability for any specific investment decision which must be at the investor’s own risk. |O|X|E|R|A| Final report Executive Summary In the calculation of present values of costs and benefits of public sector projects and policies, future values are multiplied by a discount factor that is calculated from the social discount rate (social time preference rate). This practice is described in the Treasury’s Green Book. In the past it has always been the practice to use the same discount rate over short timescales as for long timescales. Yet, discounting at even a modest rate, such as 3.5%, reduces the value of costs (or benefits) several hundred years hence to almost zero. This disenfranchises future generations from consideration in today’s decisions. Recent work on discounting over the long term has now made it clear that constant rate discounting has only a limited justification, and that it is possible to make recommendations for better practice.
    [Show full text]
  • Time Preference and Health: an Exploratory Study
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Economic Aspects of Health Volume Author/Editor: Victor R. Fuchs, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-26785-7 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/fuch82-1 Publication Date: 1982 Chapter Title: Time Preference and Health: An Exploratory Study Chapter Author: Victor R. Fuchs Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c6546 Chapter pages in book: (p. 93 - 120) 3 Time Preference and Health: An Exploratory Study Victor R. Fuchs This paper reports the results of an exploratory effort in a new area- the relationship between intertemporal choice, health behavior, and health status. Intertemporal choice (or time preference) is, of course, a subject much discussed by economists and psychologists. (See Maital and Maitall978.) There is also a large literature on individual behavior (e.g., cigarette smoking, diet, exercise) and health status. This paper, however, seems to be the first to attempt to bring these subjects together and to test empirically for possible interrelations. In the first section of the paper I briefly review some of the considera- tions that suggest that an investigation of time preference might throw light on health behavior and health status. These include empirical stud- ies of the relation between schooling and health, epidemiological inves- tigations of the health effects of cigarette smoking, diet, exercise, and the like, and theoretical issues concerning investment in human capital, imperfections in capital markets, and optimizing behavior. The second section considers the critical problem of the measurement of time preference and reviews some recent efforts by other investigators to measure time preference in contexts other than health.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring Time Preferences
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURING TIME PREFERENCES Jonathan D. Cohen Keith Marzilli Ericson David Laibson John Myles White Working Paper 22455 http://www.nber.org/papers/w22455 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2016 We thank Steven Durlauf and five anonymous referees at the Journal of Economic Literature for thoughtful comments. We thank Layne Kirshon, Omeed Maghzian, Lea Nagel, and Kartik Vira for outstanding research assistance. We acknowledge financial support from the National Institutes of Health (NIA R01AG021650 and P01AG005842) and the Pershing Square Fund for Research in the Foundations of Human Behavior. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2016 by Jonathan D. Cohen, Keith Marzilli Ericson, David Laibson, and John Myles White. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Measuring Time Preferences Jonathan D. Cohen, Keith Marzilli Ericson, David Laibson, and John Myles White NBER Working Paper No. 22455 July 2016, Revised February 2019 JEL No. D03,D9 ABSTRACT We review research that measures time preferences—i.e., preferences over intertemporal tradeoffs. We distinguish between studies using financial flows, which we call “money earlier or later” (MEL) decisions and studies that use time-dated consumption/effort.
    [Show full text]
  • Time Discounting and Economic Decision-Making in the Older Population ⇑ David Huffman A, Raimond Maurer B, Olivia S
    The Journal of the Economics of Ageing xxx (2017) xxx–xxx Contents lists available at ScienceDirect The Journal of the Economics of Ageing journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jeoa Time discounting and economic decision-making in the older population ⇑ David Huffman a, Raimond Maurer b, Olivia S. Mitchell c, a Department of Economics, University of Pittsburgh, 4901 Wesley Posvar Hall, 230 South Bouquet Street, Pittsburgh, PA 15260, United States b Finance Department, Goethe University, Theodor-W.-Adorno Platz 3, 60323 Frankfurt am Main, Germany c The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania, Dept of Business Economics & Policy, 3620 Locust Walk, St 3000 Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, Philadelphia, PA 19104, United States article info abstract Article history: This paper examines heterogeneity in time discounting among a representative sample of elderly Available online xxxx Americans, as well as its role in explaining key economic behaviors at older ages. We show how older Americans evaluate simple (hypothetical) inter-temporal choices in which payments today are compared JEL classifications: with payments in the future. Using the indicators derived from this measure, we then demonstrate that D01 differences in discounting patterns are associated with characteristics of particular importance in elderly D03 populations. For example, cognitive deficits are associated with greater impatience, whereas bequest D12 motives are associated with less impatience. We then relate our discounting measure to key economic D14 outcomes and
    [Show full text]