Lecture 4 Chapter 4 Public Goods

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Lecture 4 Chapter 4 Public Goods Lecture 4 Chapter 4 Public Goods What we are going to do ◦ Definitions ◦ Examples Rivalry – If someone consumes a good, then no one else can Excludability – If you don’t pay, you don’t get the good. Private Goods: Goods that are rival and Excludable Result in no Externalities Public Goods Public Good ◦ you can’t stop people from consuming it (nonexcludeable) ◦ Your consumption doesn’t affect other’s consumption (nonrivalrous) Public goods are associated with externalities because no one has a property right to a public good. Public goods lead to free riding Benefiting from a good without paying for it. Public Goods Examples of Rivalry ◦ Is Satellite TV rivalrous? No, it is nonrivalrous ◦ Is it Satellite TV exludable? Yes, they can turn off your service ◦ Is it a public good then? No, a good has to be both nonrivalrous and nonexcludable. Public Goods Example of Excludability ◦ Is fishing international waters excludable? No, who is going to enforce? Think Whale Wars ◦ Is it rivalrous? Yes, there are only so many fish in the ocean? ◦ Is it a public good? No, because it is rivalrous Public Good Examples National Defense ◦ Rivalrous? Excludable? ◦ No. It is a public good because it is nonrivalrous and nonexcludable Fireworks show ◦ Rivalrous? Excludable? ◦ No, it is a public good because it is nonrivalrous and nonexcludable Public vs. Private Bread Heat Purely Private Purely Public Total consumed = sum Everyone feels the same of individual temp consumption Impossible for one to A market could form consume more heat and and people could adjust exclude the others their consumption Individuals will not be according to their able to adjust according preferences to their preferences Everyone Consumes the same amount IfIce a creamgood is is both rival,also rival excludable,because and excludable, my SomeCableIt is excludable, TVgoods is non are -since rival,“impure” thebecause cablepublic my Tableitconsumptionbecause is a1 private I can good.of simply it precludes not share yougoodsconsumptioncompany myfrom because can ofsimply theyit in no arerefuse way non to-rival, hook consumingiceOtherForYet creamitexample, is goods non with the-excludable are a you. samecrowded “impure” ice because sidewalkcream. publicbutdiminishesupFinally,NationalIt is itThe the they isalsois system.pure arenondefense your (to-publicexcludable, someconsumption. is goodsa classicextent) becauseare both onlygoodsrivalclearly waybecause becausevery Definingfor difficult you your they to enjoyment consumeto are prohibitpure rival, it isbutexcludable.nonexample.once andis to -notrival an impure area and It is nonis non protected,- excludable.-publicrival because everyone goods my makeexcludable.reducedpedestrians more as moreicefrom cream. usingpedestrians theIs sidewalk. alsoconsumption“consumes”the good that of rival national protection. in defense consumption? use the same sidewalk. protection does not diminish your consumptionYes of it. No Yes Ice cream Cable tv Is the good excludable? No Crowded city sidewalk National defense Marginal Cost of allowing additional consumers to consume a public good Once a public good has been provided, what is the additional cost of allowing an additional person to enjoy the good? Don’t confuse distribution with production Think of the marginal cost of allowing an additional person watch a fireworks display. Marginal Cost of Producing A Public Good Let’s think production: Does the fact that a good is “public” alter how much it costs to produce another unit of the good? Main Point: The marginal cost of producing a public good is positive for each unit (the constant marginal cost curve is for simplicity of explanation) Good Classification Goods vary in their levels of excludability and Rivalry Provision of Public and Private Goods What is the traditional way that we believe private goods are provided to consumers? Public Goods? What are examples of goods that are both provided privately and by the government? ◦ Tennis Courts, Education, Golf Courses Congestible Public Goods Def: Goods for which crowding or congestion reduces the benefits to existing consumers when more consumers are accommodated ◦ Marginal cost of accommodating an additional consumer is not zero after the point of congestion is reached Example: a user of a congested road decreases the benefits to existing users by slowing traffic, increasing accident risk Other Examples? Congestible Public Goods How do we graphically present a congestible public good? Price-Excludable Public Goods Def: Goods with benefits that can be priced Can be individually consumed and are subject to exclusion, but their production and consumption is likely to generate externalities ◦ Membership rights to private clubs ◦ Schools, hospitals, transportation Is higher education a pure public good? Why Does the Government fund Higher Education then? Annotated Bibliography Def: An annotated bibliography is a list of citations to books, articles, and documents. Each citation is followed by a brief (usually about 150 words) descriptive and evaluative paragraph, the annotation. The purpose of the annotation is to inform the reader of the relevance, accuracy, and quality of the sources cited. Alphabetical Order by last name of first author Citation Style Notes are what you need to write your paper At least six total references, two from peer reviewed journal articles Due Date: October 20th Where to find peer reviewed journal articles? Market Demand for a Purely Private good – Think Horizontal Each Individual chooses how much they want at each price Demand for a purely Private good is the horizontal summation of the individual demand curves. ◦ Make sure demand is solved as Q a function of P, then add. For Example Q= 20 – 2P Price S=SMC of ice cream $3 $2 D DJERRY BEN SMB =DBEN+JERRY 0 QJERRY QBEN QTOTAL Quantity of ice Notice cream MBJerry = MBBen = MSC Efficiency Demand for Pure Private Good •Notice how the marginal conditions for efficiency are met: •MBA = MBB = MBC = MC •Also notice that these are prices per loaf Demand for Pure Public Goods – Think Vertical All consumers must consume the same quantity of the good ◦ Pure public goods cannot be divided into individual units Demand for public good is the maximum individuals are willing to pay for the amount of the good that is available Demand for public good is the vertical summation. Think Price as a function of quantity, P = 10 - .5Q Price of missiles $6 S=SMC $4 DJERRY $3 $2$2 SMB=DBEN+JERRY DBEN $1 0 1 5 Quantity of missiles Notice: the sum of the marginal benefits equal the marginal social cost. Demand for Pure Public Goods For one Guard: ◦ Person A is willing to pay $300, ◦ person B $250 ◦ person C $200 ◦ Total for one guard = $750 You Try Bill’s demand for hamburgers (a private good) is Q = 20- 2P and Ted’s demand is Q = 10 – P 1. Write down an equation for the social marginal benefit of the consumption of the hamburger 2. Now suppose that hamburgers are a public good. Write down an equation for the social marginal benefit of hamburger consumption. Quantity Alice Ben Carolyn Don You Try 1 1000 800 600 400 2 800 600 400 200 3 600 400 200 100 4 400 200 100 50 The table shows how the marginal benefit of a service varies for four consumers. a) Suppose the service is a pure private good and is sold in a competitive market with only buyers being the four in the table. If the market price of the product is $400, what is the quantity demanded? b) Suppose the service is a pure public good. What is the marginal social benefit of two units of service? c) If the MSC of the good is $2,000 what is the efficient output assuming that it is a pure private good? d) If the MSC of the good is $2,000 what is the efficient output assuming that it is a pure public good? Efficiency of a Pure Public Good Review: The marginal social benefit of any given amount of a pure public good is the sum of the individual marginal benefits received by all consumers. Efficient quantity per time period corresponds to the point at which output is increased so that the sum of marginal benefits to consumers equals marginal social cost of the good. Efficiency conditions are: i i •From the perspective of Society •Is one security guard efficient? •Are two security guards efficient? •Are three security guards efficient? How to finance public goods Lindhal Pricing: When each person pays an amount equal to their marginal benefit. ◦ The government provides the public good and finances its provision through each person paying what it is worth to them Examples International View ◦ When Iraq invaded Kuwait in 1990, which countries were at risk? ◦ Estimates of the cost of the war = $61 billion ◦ $54 billion came from other nations $17 billion from Saudi Arabia $16 billion from Kuwait $11 billion from Japan ◦ US left with $7 billion of the incremental costs of fighting the war. How is this like a Lindahl equilibrium? PROBLEM: ◦ If people know that they are required to pay a share of the cost of a public good dependent on their marginal benefits, they have an incentive to understate their true marginal benefits. The Free Rider Problem Def – A person who seeks to enjoy the benefits of a public good without contributing anything to the cost of financing. This strategy almost guarantees that the equilibrium amount of a pure public good will be less than the efficient amount. Problem becomes more acute in large groups where a free rider reasons that their contribution is less likely to be needed or missed Our government provides lots of public goods, how do they overcome the free rider problem? ANS: Compulsory finance! Taxes! Examples WNYC has an estimated listening audience of 1 million people, but only 7.5% of their listeners support the station. In the United Kingdom, the BBC charges an annual licensing fee to anyone who owns and operates a TV.
Recommended publications
  • From Material Scarcity to Arti8cial Abundance – the Case of Fablabs and 3D Printing Technologies Primavera De Filippi, Peter Troxler
    From material scarcity to arti8cial abundance – The case of FabLabs and 3D printing technologies Primavera de Filippi, Peter Troxler To cite this version: Primavera de Filippi, Peter Troxler. From material scarcity to arti8cial abundance – The case of FabLabs and 3D printing technologies. van den Berg B. & van der Hof S. 3D Printing : Legal, philosophical and economic dimensions., T.M.C. Asser Instituut pp. 65-83, 2015. hal-01265229 HAL Id: hal-01265229 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01265229 Submitted on 31 Jan 2016 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Primavera De Filippi & Peter Troxler [4] From material scarcity to arti8cial abundance – The case of FabLabs and 3D printing technologies Primavera De Filippi & Peter Troxler 1. Introduction Digital media allowed for the emergence of new artistic practices and innovative modes of production. In particular, the advent of Internet and digital technologies drastically enhanced the ability for multiple au- thors to collaborate towards the creation of large-scale collaborative works, which stand in contrast to the traditional understanding that artistic production is essentially an individual activity. The signi6cance of these practices in the physical world is illustrated by the recent deployment of FabLabs (Fabrication Laboratories), that employ innovative technologies – such as, most notably, 3D printing, which is recently gaining the most interest – to encourage the development of new methods of artistic production based on participation and interaction between peers.
    [Show full text]
  • Explain Externalities and Public Goods and How They Affect Efficiency of Market Outcomes.”
    Microeconomics Topic 9: “Explain externalities and public goods and how they affect efficiency of market outcomes.” Reference: Gregory Mankiw’s Principles of Microeconomics, 2nd edition, Chapters 10 and 11. The Efficiency of Private Exchange A private market transaction is one in which a buyer and seller exchange goods or services for money or other goods or services. The buyers and sellers could be individuals, corporations, or both. Voluntary private market transactions will occur between buyers and sellers only if both parties to the transaction expect to gain. If one of the parties expected to end up worse off as a result of the transaction, that transaction would not occur. Buyers and sellers have an incentive to find all the voluntary, private market transactions that could make them better off. When they have found and made all such possible transactions, then the market has achieved “an efficient allocation of resources.” This means that all of the resources that both buyers and sellers have are allocated so that these buyers and sellers are as well off as possible. For these reasons, private market transactions between buyers and sellers are usually considered to be “efficient” because these transactions result in all the parties being as well off as possible, given their initial resources. A more precise way of defining efficient production of a good is that we should produce more of a good whenever the added benefits are greater than the added costs, but we should stop when the added costs exceed the added benefits. Summary of conditions for efficient production (1) all units of the good are produced for which the value to consumers is greater than the costs of production, and (2) no unit of the good is produced that costs more to produce than the value it has for the consumers of that good.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Goods* by Matthew Kotchen† December 8, 2012
    Public Goods* By Matthew Kotchen† December 8, 2012 Pure public goods have two defining features. One is ‘non‐rivalry,’ meaning that one person’s enjoyment of a good does not diminish the ability of other people to enjoy the same good. The other is ‘non‐excludability,’ meaning that people cannot be prevented from enjoying the good. Air quality is an important environmental example of a public good. Under most circumstances, one person’s breathing of fresh air does not reduce air quality for others to enjoy, and people cannot be prevented from breathing the air. Public goods are defined in contrast to private goods, which are, by definition, both rival and excludable. A sandwich is a private good because one person’s consumption clearly diminishes its value for someone else, and sandwiches are typically excludable to all individuals not willing to pay. (This scenario does, of course, assume the proverbial no free lunch.) Many environmental resources are characterized as public goods, including water quality, open space, biodiversity, and a stable climate. These examples stand alongside the classic public goods of lighthouses, national defense, and knowledge. In some cases, however, it is reasonable to question whether environmental resources (and even the classic examples) are public goods in a fully pure sense. With open space, for example, congestion among those enjoying it may cause some degree of rivalry, and all open spaces are not accessible to everyone. Nevertheless, many environmental resources come close to satisfying the definition of pure public goods, and even when not exact (possibly closer to an impure public good), the basic concept is useful for understanding the causes of many environmental problems and potential solutions.
    [Show full text]
  • ECONOMICS Public Goods and Common Resources
    10/22/2017 N. GREGORY MANKIW Look for the answers to these questions: PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS • What are public goods? Eight Edition • What are common resources? Give examples of each. • Why do markets generally fail to provide the CHAPTER Public Goods and efficient amounts of these goods? • How might the government improve market 11 Common Resources outcomes in the case of public goods or common resources? Premium PowerPoint Slides by: V. Andreea CHIRITESCU Modified by Joseph Tao-yi Wang Eastern Illinois University © 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use © 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use 2 as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning 1 as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management system for classroom use. management system for classroom use. Introduction The Different Kinds of Goods • We consume many goods without paying: • Excludability – Parks, national defense, clean air & water – Property of a good whereby a person can be prevented from using it – When goods have no prices, the market – Excludable : MOS rice burgers, Wi-Fi access forces that normally allocate resources are Not excludable absent – : radio signals, national defense • Rivalry in consumption – The private market may fail to provide the socially efficient quantity of such goods – Property of a good whereby one person’s use diminishes other people’s use • ‘Governments can sometimes improve – Rival : MOS rice burgers market outcomes’ – Not rival : An MP3 file of David Tao’s latest single © 2018 Cengage Learning®.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economics of Climate Change 3
    Module 3 The economics of climate change 3 The economics of climate change 1 Introduction gives rise to climate change, considered to be the biggest market failure in human history. module Module 1 showed that economic activities can influence the climate because the economy and Since markets have failed, policy interventions are the environment are interdependent. Module needed to mitigate climate change. Even though 2 explained the climate science behind climate it has been known for some time how policy in- change and showed how human activities con- terventions could mitigate climate change, the tribute to change the climate. This module shows international community has been struggling how economic theory explains the occurrence of for decades to solve the issue. Section 4 investi- transboundary environmental problems, such as gates how economic theory explains the inability climate change, and clarifies why it can be so dif- of governments and societies to mitigate climate ficult to implement solutions to these problems change. It shows that climate change mitiga- even though those solutions are well known. tion is a global “public good” that has non-rival and non-excludable benefits (see Section 3.1). As Neoclassical economic theory stipulates that no country can single-handedly take actions to markets allocate resources in an optimal, i.e. ef- eliminate the threat of climate change, interna- ficient, way. At the same time, however, economic tional cooperation is needed. However, such co- behaviour leads to important negative effects operation is extremely difficult to achieve when on the environment such as climate change. If dealing with a global public good.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tragedy of the Commons (002)
    *For an expanded version of this article with video and more links go to this website: https://www.investopedia.com/terms/t/tragedy-of-the-commons.asp#:~:text=The%20tragedy%20 of%20the%20commons%20is%20a%20problem%20in%20economics,common%20resource%2 C%20to%20everybody's%20detriment. The Tragedy of the Commons INVESTOPEDIA STAFF Reviewed by MICHAEL J BOYLE Updated Oct 23, 2020 What is Tragedy Of The Commons? The tragedy of the commons is an economics problem in which every individual has an incentive to consume a resource, but at the expense of every other individual -- with no way to exclude anyone from consuming. Initially it was formulated by asking what would happen if every shepherd, acting in their own self-interest, allowed their flock to graze on the common field. If everybody does act in their apparent own best interest, it results in harmful over-consumption (all the grass is eaten, to the detriment of everyone) The problem can also result in under investment (since who is going to pay to plant new seed?), and ultimately total depletion of the resource. As the demand for the resource overwhelms the supply, every individual who consumes an additional unit directly harms others -- and themselves too -- who can no longer enjoy the benefits. Generally, the resource of interest is easily available to all individuals without barriers (i.e. the "commons"). KEY TAKEAWAYS ● The tragedy of the commons is a problem in economics that occurs when individuals neglect the well-being of society in the pursuit of personal gain. ● This leads to over-consumption and ultimately depletion of the common resource, to everybody's detriment.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Public Goods: Critique of a UN Discourse Author(S): David Long and Frances Woolley Source: Global Governance, Vol
    Global Public Goods: Critique of a UN Discourse Author(s): David Long and Frances Woolley Source: Global Governance, Vol. 15, No. 1 (January–March 2009), pp. 107-122 Published by: Brill Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/27800741 Accessed: 19-09-2019 14:45 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms Brill is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Global Governance This content downloaded from 143.107.26.62 on Thu, 19 Sep 2019 14:45:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Global Governance 15 (2009), 107-122 Global Public Goods: Critique of a UN Discourse David Long and Frances Wool ley The concept of global public goods has been advanced as a way of under standing certain transborder and global problems and the need for a coor dinated international response. It has been used to describe everything from global environment, international financial stability, and market effi ciency, to health, knowledge, peace and security, and humanitarian rights. Using an internal critique, this article finds that the concept is poorly de fined, avoids analytical problems by resorting to abstraction, and masks the incoherence of its two central characteristics.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Goods Microeconomics 2
    Public goods Microeconomics 2 Bernard Caillaud Master APE - Paris School of Economics February 2, 2017 (Lecture 4) Bernard Caillaud Public goods I. The nature of goods { I.1. Examples and definitions Suppose I grow rare flowers.... ... I can sell them to you: rivalry and exclusion ... I can open a flower exhibition and charge you an entry fee for the delightful view: non-rivalry but exclusion ... I can keep them but it improves the chances that these rare seeds continue to exist, i.e. I contribute to biodiversity: non-rivalry and non-exclusion In the first case, there is a market that "works" probably well enough In the second case, there is some sort of a market that works differently In the third case, there is (yet) no market: if I stop incurring the cost, we (on earth) will all become "poorer" ! Bernard Caillaud Public goods I.1. Examples and definitions Definitions - A good is rival (in consumption) if the same unit of the good cannot be consumed by more than one person at the same time. - A good is excludable if it is technologically or/and institution- ally feasible to prevent some people to consume the good. Rival and excludable goods: private consumption goods... we know that ! Rival and non-excludable goods: common resources, e.g. red tuna in the sea Non-rival and excludable goods: pay-TV, computer soft- ware, patented knowledge - ideas Non-rival and non-excludable goods: pure public goods, e.g. national defense, scientific knowledge - ideas, public TV Bernard Caillaud Public goods I.1. Examples and definitions In fact, a matter of degree of rivalry and exclusion A public good makes collective consumption possible But the satisfaction from consuming it may depend on others consuming it (e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • Biodiversity and Soil As Global Commons International Governance and the Role of Germany
    Hintergrundstudie Biodiversity and Soil as Global Commons International Governance and the Role of Germany Dr. Uta Eser, Büro für Umweltethik Im Auftrag der Wissenschaftsplattform Nachhaltigkeit 2030 2019 Zur Studie Hintergrund Wie können Global Commons besser geschützt und nachhaltiger genutzt werden, insbesondere im Rahmen der Deutschen Nachhaltigkeitsstrategie: Unter anderem diese Frage bearbeitet die Wissenschaftsplattform Nachhaltigkeit 2030 mit dem Ziel, wissenschaftlich basierte Handlungsempfehlungen für politi- sche Akteure zu entwickeln. Zu diesem Zweck hat sich 2017 über die Plattform die Arbeitsgruppe „Global Commons“ formiert, geleitet von Prof. Martin Visbeck (Co-Vorsitzender der Wissenschaftsplattform) und Prof. Aletta Bonn (Deutsches Zentrum für integrative Biodiversitätsforschung). In diesem Rahmen wurden unter anderem vier Hintergrundstudien zu vier Global-Commons-Bereichen von der Plattform in Auftrag gegeben (Süßwasser, Meere, Wälder, Biodiversität/Böden). Das vorliegende Papier „Biodiversity and Soil as Global Commons International Governance and the Role of Germany“ ist eine von ihnen. Maßgeblich für die weitere AG-Arbeit ist ein breiter interdisziplinärer Austausch mit der Wissenschaft sowie transdisziplinärer Austausch mit Politik, Wirtschaft und Zivilgesellschaft in mehreren Schritten. Zitierhinweis Eser, U. (2019): Biodiversity and Soil as Global Commons International Governan- ce and the Role of Germany“. Report to the Science Platform Sustainability 2030. Tübingen: Büro für Umweltehtik. DOI 10.2312/iass.2019.038
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Health Economics Health As (A Shared) Investment This Work Is Licensed Under a Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Sharealike License
    Introduction to Health Economics Health as (a shared) Investment This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike License. Your use of this material constitutes acceptance of that license and the conditions of use of materials on this site Copyright 2018, Teaching Vaccine Economics Everywhere. Use of these materials permitted only in accordance with license rights granted. Materials provided “AS IS”; no representations or warranties provided. User assumes all responsibility for use, and all liability related thereto, and must independently review all materials for accuracy and efficacy. May contain materials owned by others. User is responsible for obtaining permissions for use from third parties as needed. Outline • Health markets differ from other markets • Staying healthy can take a lot of our time • Health services like vaccines can be a mixed public private good • The free rider problem • Rationale for public (or private or mixed ) provision • Communication and advocacy issues to increase demand Investing in Health Care Health Production Inputs Outputs Capital Stock of Health Over Health Care Time Healthy Days Diet Physical Health Exercise Mental Health Environment Activity Income Limitation Time Time Period A Model for Money Spent Producing Health A Model for Time Spent Producing Health An analysis of 365 days or 100% Time Improving Health 20% Working 45% Producing Home Goods 25% Lost to illness 10% Issues that emerge: (a) Time spent producing health, reduces time spent on other activities. (b) Time spent on health investment increases health stock, and reduces time lost on ill health. (c) Time costs mean that even free services like vaccines have a cost (d) Choice to spend time getting vaccinated implies that the time spent is rewarded by health benefits and more earnings Rationale for government involvement 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Goods and Public Choices
    Public Goods and Public Choices Vincent Ostrom and Elinor Ostrom Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Indiana University Summary A new mode of analysis for dealing with the organization and delivery of public goods and services has developed over the last two decades. This mode of analysis, identified with public choice theory, involves the application of economic reasoning to nonmarket decisionmaking. A key element in the analysis turns upon the nature of goods and services. Characteristics which pertain to exclusion and jointness of use can be arrayed to define different types of goods and services. A public good is defined as one which is not subject to exclusion and is subject to jointness in its consumption or use. Characteristics of nonexclusion and jointness of consumption or use, create situations in which market arrangements may fail to meet individual demands for public goods. Special forms of governmental or quasi-governmental organization are required to deal with these contingencies. The problems, however, occur largely in relation to the organi- zation of collective consumption. As long as appropriate collective consumption units are organized, several alternative options can be used for the production and delivery of public goods and services. These options include private [8] suppliers as well as governmental agencies serving as suppliers. Where collective consumption is organized apart from production in a public economy, market-like arrangements can exist among producers and collective consumption units. Relations among such units can be conceptualized as forming public service industries in which multiple units coordinate their efforts to supply a particular type of good or service to a community of users.
    [Show full text]
  • ECONOMICS and MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman | Robin Wells
    THIRD EDITION ECONOMICS and MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman | Robin Wells Chapter 17 Public Goods and Common Resources • A way to classify goods that predicts whether a good is a private good—a good that can be efficiently provided by free markets • What public goods are, and why markets WHAT YOU fail to supply them WILL LEARN • What common resources are, and why IN THIS they are overused • What artificially scarce goods are, and CHAPTER why they are underconsumed • How government intervention in the production and consumption of these types of goods can make society better off • Why finding the right level of government intervention is difficult Private Goods—and Others • What’s the difference between installing a new bathroom in a house and building a municipal sewage system? • What’s the difference between growing wheat and fishing in the open ocean? • In each case there is a basic difference in the characteristics of the goods involved. Bathroom appliances and wheat have the characteristics needed to allow markets to work efficiently; sewage systems and fish in the sea do not. • Let’s look at these crucial characteristics and why they matter. Characteristics of Goods • Goods can be classified according to two attributes: . whether they are excludable . whether they are rival in consumption • A good is excludable if the supplier of that good can prevent people who do not pay from consuming it. • A good is rival in consumption if the same unit of the good cannot be consumed by more than one person at the same time. Characteristics of Goods • A good that is both excludable and rival in consumption is a private good.
    [Show full text]