Women in Economics: a Lifelong Discouragement

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Women in Economics: a Lifelong Discouragement ESB Solutions ESB Solutions EXPOSITION Women in economics: a lifelong discouragement The gender gap in economics science is worse than in other Although understandable as an initial hypothesis, this disciplines. Are women treated differently than men, in does not do justice to existing knowledge, also in eco- nomics, about the influence of environmental factors school and during their careers? and prejudice as to preferences and behaviour. Three examples in economics can illustrate this bias. First, Huberman (2001), inspired by Merton HENRIËTTE n 1993, Hein Schreuder argued in ESB that (1987), explains the investor home bias as ‘familiarity’: PRAST in economics the difference between men and people more often opt for shares in companies that are Professor at Tilburg women would automatically disappear: the literally or figuratively close to home. As a consequence, University and number of female students was increasing, and not only do they diversify their financial capital insuf- member of the ‘fromI low to high’ this would result in more female doc- ficiently, they also place too many eggs in the basket in Senate for D66 toral students and academic staff. Eline van der Heijden which their human capital is invested. Secondly, in a (1993) had her doubts about this, and enumerated the Harvard Business Case, Avery (2012) shows that Coca structural obstacles that women faced when choosing Cola misjudged the use of the word Diet in Diet Coke: economics and making a career in it. men did not buy it, because the word ‘diet’ evokes a Ten years later Aart Jan de Geus, the Minister of realm unbefitting to the stereotypical man. However, Social Affairs at the time, also claimed that due to the Coke Zero does not have that problem. Thirdly, there is influx of female students, the difference between men a significant difference between men and women as to and women as to careers would disappear. As a result, their self-declared financial risk attitudes. Never theless, the Dutch newspaper Trouw wrote that the emancipa- when risk attitude is measured objectively, on the basis tion had been completed, and there was no role left of skin reaction, there is no difference and women are for the government in this respect (Prast, 2016). This just as risk-tolerant as men (Brighetti and Lucarelli, ‘pipeline idea’ of Schreuder and De Geus remains a 2015). Apparently, women fill out the questionnaire persistent misunderstanding, because there don’t seem in a way that is expected of them, which is due to the to be or have been any facts to support this. stereotyping effect. With a mere ten percent of female economics pro- To what extent can such factors contribute to the fessors in the Netherlands, economics is doing worse gender gap in economics science? First of all, a few facts. than any of the other disciplines. This craves an expla- nation. In this article, I will look into the influx in eco- ECONOMICS IN SECONDARY EDUCATION nomic studies and the careers of economic researchers. Over half of the university students in the Netherlands are women – but, with approximately 35 percent of PREFERENCES AND BEHAVIOUR female economics students, their share in economics is Economists traditionally assume that behaviour reveals a lot lower than that. Since almost all graduates with preferences, and they regard preferences as given facts. a pre-university education (vwo) meet the admission 52 Volume 103 (4767S) 1 November 2018 Solutions ESB requirements for studying economics, it is obvious to products not at all. Furthermore, football is mainly asso- attribute this diversity to a congenital or biological ciated with men as to sports (SCP, 2009; CBS, 2010). gender difference as to preference. Such an explanation The exams evoke an image of a world in which assumes that the context in which decisions are made men achieve a lot, and women little. In addition, being is neutral, though this is, as is shown by behavioural an economist is something for men, and also the spend- sciences, hardly ever the case. ing and use of time refers to men. In itself, this might In order to demonstrate this bias, Box 1a presents already influence the attitude of girls towards econom- the sexes and professions mentioned in the final exams ics negatively. Activating a stereotype, which these for economics in 2016–2018. These are the individuals exam questions seem to do, leads to people behaving explicitly indicated as being male or female (he/she, his/ accordingly, to wit stereotypically (Wheeler and Petty, her). If the gender is unclear, the person is not included. 2001), and lowers women’s self-confidence in areas that In these exams, 26 men and 6 women appear. The are associated with men. Stereotyping therefore influ- women include a welfare recipient, her girl friend, an ences performance, study choice and career (Carlana, economics teacher, a journalist, a spokeswoman for the 2018; Lavy and Sand, 2015). Nosek et al. (2009) com- Consumers’ Association, and a woman with a negative pare 34 countries and find that scientific gender bias – net return on her savings account. Most men in the measured by the extent to which people tend to asso- exams are economists, directors, ministers or governors ciate alpha-studies more with women and beta studies of central banks. more with men – is largest in the Netherlands. The products mentioned in the final exam also The stronger a teacher has a stereotypical notion evoke a man’s world. Men and women differ in their about pupils, the stronger her or his confirmation bias consumer expenditure (Figure 1). The biggest differ- will be – the degree to which he or she filters and weighs ence is cars (m >> f ), followed by personal care (f >> m), and computers and accessories (m >> f ). Box 1b gives an overview of the companies and BOX 1 products mentioned in the exams (not including finan- The vwo final economics exam (2016–2018) cial products). If we consider mobile telephony to be 1a. The sexes in the exam included in ‘computers and accessories’, men’s favourite products are mentioned five times and women’s favourite Men (26) • Economist (11×) • Investor • Director of a football club • Friend of investor • Director of a pension fund • Employee with an income of FIGURE 1 Spending for single men • Managing director of an online 50,000 euros and women, 2008 stock broker’s • Managing director of a theatre • Women (6) Veetbles • Manager multi-storey car park • Welfare recipient ruit • Manager of a telecom company • Friend of welfare recipient everes • Researcher (2×) • Journalist Etin in a resurnt • Governor of the Central Bank • Economics teacher • Saver with negative net return ren n loers • Minister of transport • Egg farmer • Spokeswoman of Consumers’ urniture • Journalist Association lotin Personl re Comuters n essories 1b. Companies and products in the exam io, TV, vieos, CDs etc. • Multi-storey car park • Football club Cars • Second-hand cars • Physiotherapy eminin (on) • Car manufacturer • Pharmaceuticals trnsorttion • Toll tunnel • Mobile telephony 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 In erente o totl eeniture • House (3×): renting, buying, • Eggs omen en mortgage • Airbnb Source: CBS Volume 103 (4767S) 1 November 2018 53 ESB Solutions up information about the pupil so that it confirms the parative advantages. Moreover, they used the example stereotype judgment (Bordalo et al., 2016). It seems of the man who marries his housekeeper to illustrate that the authors of these exam questions – economics that GDP is an imperfect measure. The evaluation of teachers – have a stereotypical image of the sexes. the VWO Economics Examination Programme (2011) Box 2 shows the composition of the committees does indeed include a chapter on the exam, but it does advising upon the final exam programme for eco- not include any mention of the sexes that crop up in nomics, and the external experts they have consult- the exam. In Van Dalen and Koedijk (2012), fourteen ed ( Teulings, 2002; Commissie-Teulings I, 2002; economists give their view on economics education. Commissie-Teulings II, 2005). Women are a minority Thirteen of them are Dutch males, the fourteenth is here, none of them have graduated in economics, and a non-Dutch author who has become a woman. The they have all adopted their husband’s name. illustration on the cover is a shirt and tie. The first committee (rightly) advocated a broad- ening of the economy’s domain, giving as an example STUDY CHOICE the division of tasks in the household. The second nar- By no means do all students who are able to study eco- rowed this down by explaining why women do more nomics take the vwo economics exam. That is why it household chores than men, using the theory of com- is also important to look at what students encounter when they orientate themselves towards economics studies. An inventory of the texts in which the univer- sities and economics faculties in our country describe Composition of advisory committees for the BOX 2 and recommend the economics studies shows that vwo economics programme they are generic, with terms such as ‘broad’, ‘social’, Teulings-1 (2002) Chiel Renique MSc Male ‘macro’, ‘meso’, ‘micro’, ‘current issues’, ‘many perspec- Prof. Coen Teulings Male Jan Klaver MSc Male tives’, or with specific emphasis on business, growth, Prof. Eric van Damme Male Marc Mittelmeijer MSc Male cost prices, stock exchange and market forces. Scarcity Prof. Hugo Keuzenkamp Male of raw materials, labour-market participation, climate, Dr Henk Don Male Teulings-2 (2005) unemployment, social security, income distribution Dr Sierk Keuning Male Prof. Coen Teulings Male and pensions are not included in these descriptions, Els Borghols MSc Female Prof. Eric van Damme Male Dorien Klarenbeek MSc Female Prof. Jules Theeuwes Male although they are not the least challenges as regards A.
Recommended publications
  • Optimal Taxation of Human Capital and the Earnings Function
    OPTIMAL TAXATION OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND THE EARNINGS FUNCTION BAS JACOBS Erasmus University Rotterdam A. LANS BOVENBERG Tilburg University Abstract This paper explores how the specification of the earnings function impacts optimal nonlinear taxes on human capi- tal under optimal nonlinear income taxation. If education is complementary to labor effort, education should be sub- sidized to offset tax distortions on labor supply. However, if education is complementary to ability, education should be taxed in order to redistribute income. If education is weakly separable from labor and ability in the earnings function, these two effects cancel and education should be neither taxed nor subsidized. 1. Introduction Should education be taxed or subsidized for redistributive reasons? Educa- tion subsidies are generally regressive due to the well-known ability bias in ed- ucation (Card 1999, Heckman, Lochner, and Todd 2006). In the absence of other instruments aimed at redistribution, the government may thus want to Bas Jacobs, Erasmus School of Economics, Erasmus University Rotterdam, Tinbergen Institute, Netspar and CESifo, P.O. Box 1738, 3000 DR Rotterdam, The Netherlands ([email protected]), URL: www.people.few.eur.nl/bjacobs. A. Lans Bovenberg, Tilburg University, CentER, Netspar, CESifo and CEPR, The Netherlands ([email protected]). Bas Jacobs gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Dutch Organization for Sciences (NWO Vidi Grant No. 452-07-013, “Skill Formation in Distorted Labor Markets”). Part of this research has been done while Jacobs was visiting scholar at the Center of Eco- nomic Studies of the Ludwig-Maximillians-Universitat¨ Munchen.¨ Comments and sugges- tions by seminar participants at the University of Konstanz and the 64th IIPF conference, August 22–25, 2008, Maastricht, the Netherlands, are gratefully acknowledged.
    [Show full text]
  • English, French, Hindi, Japanese, Europe and Central Asia 42 Portuguese, Russian, and Spanish
    THE WORLD BANK ANNUAL REPORT 2008 THE WORLD 46256 THE WORLD BANK ANNUAL REPORT 2008 YEAR IN REVIEW YEAR IN REVIEW Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized 1818 H St NW ISBN 978-0-8213-7675-1 Washington DC 20433 USA THE WORLD BANK Telephone: 202-473-1000 Facsimile: 202-477-6391 Internet: www.worldbank.org E-mail: [email protected] SKU 17675 THE WORLD BANK OPERATIONAL SUMMARY | FISCAL 2008 ANNUAL REPORT 2008 Offi ce of the Publisher, External Affairs IBRD MILLIONS OF DOLLARS 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 Team Leader Commitments 13,468 12,829 14,135 13,611 11,045 Richard A. B. Crabbe Of which development policy lending 3,967 3,635 4,906 4,264 4,453 Editor Number of projects 99 112 113 118 87 Cathy Lips Of which development policy lending 16 22 21 23 18 Assistant Editor Gross disbursements 10,490 11,055 11,833 9,722 10,109 Belinda Yong Of which development policy lending 3,485 4,096 5,406 3,605 4,348 Editorial Production Principal repayments (including prepayments) 12,610 17,231 13,600 14,809 18,479 Cindy A. Fisher Aziz Gökdemir Net disbursements (2,120) (6,176) (1,767) (5,087) (8,370) Mary C. Fisk Loans outstanding 99,050 97,805 103,004 104,401 109,610 Dina Towbin Undisbursed loans 38,176 35,440 34,938 33,744 32,128 Print Production Randi Park Operating incomea 2,271 1,659 1,740 1,320 1,696 Denise Bergeron Usable capital and reserves 36,888 33,754 33,339 32,072 31,332 Project Assistant Attiya Zaidi Equity-to-loans ratio 38% 35% 33% 31% 29% The World Bank Annual a.
    [Show full text]
  • FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORM in the NETHERLANDS Sijbren
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORM IN THE NETHERLANDS Sijbren Cnossen and Lans Bovenberg Abstract The Dutch Parliament has passed legislation for a new income tax that abolishes the current tax on personal capital income and substitutes it by a presumptive capital income tax, which is in fact a net wealth tax. This paper contrasts this wealth tax with a conventional realization-based capital gains tax, a retrospective capital gains tax which attempts to charge interest on the deferred tax, and a capital accretion tax which taxes capital gains as they accrue. None of the approaches meets all criteria for a 'good' income tax, i.e., equity, efficiency, and administrative feasibility. We thus conclude that the effective and neutral taxation of capital income can best be ensured through a combination of (a) a capital accretion tax to capture the returns on easy-to- value financial products, (b) a capital gains tax with interest to tax the returns on hard- to-value real estate and small businesses, and (c) a broad presumptive capital income tax, i.e., a net wealth tax, to account for the utility of holding wealth. We favor uniform and moderate proportional tax rates in the context of a dual income tax under which capital income is taxed separately from labor income. Keywords: capital income taxation, capital gains taxation, tax reform, wealth tax JEL Classification: H2 Sijbren Cnossen, Economics Faculty, Maastricht Universtiy, P.O. Box 616, 6200 MD, Maastricht, The Netherlands.
    [Show full text]
  • Nexus Conference 2009
    Nexus Conference 2009 Reflections on Man after the End of History Part i . Faith, Death, and Freedom Sunday 6 September 2009 9.15 am — 5.30 pm Muziektheater Amsterdam Speakers Jonathan Sacks - Zainab Al-Suwaij - John Gray Yossi Klein Halevi - Anne Applebaum - Ernst Hirsch Ballin Elisabeth Young-Bruehl - Marc Sageman - Slavoj Žižek - David Modell Ramin Jahanbegloo - Leon Wieseltier - Eva Hoffman - Pierre Audi Charles Rosen - Moshe Halbertal - Nina Khrushcheva Pratap Bhanu Mehta - Tariq Ramadan - John Ralston Saul Karim Wasfi - Ladan Boroumand In cooperation with the Netherlands Opera Attendance at Nexus Conference 2009 We would be happy to welcome you as a member of the audience, but advance reservation of an admission ticket is compulsory. Please register online at our website, www.nexus-instituut.nl, or contact Ms. Ilja Hijink at [email protected]. The conference admission fee is € 75. A reduced rate of € 50 is available for subscribers to the periodical Nexus, who may bring up to three guests for the same reduced rate of € 50. A special youth rate of € 25 will be charged to those under the age of 26, provided they enclose a copy of their identity document with their registration form. The conference fee includes lunch and refreshments during the reception and breaks. Only written cancellations will be accepted. Cancellations received before 21 August 2009 will be free of charge; after that date the full fee will be charged. If you decide to register after 1 September, we would advise you to contact us by telephone to check for availability. The Nexus Conference will be held at the Muziektheater Amsterdam, Amstel 3, Amsterdam (parking and subway station Waterlooplein; please check details on www.muziektheater.nl).
    [Show full text]
  • Bovenberg & Goulder
    OptimalEnvironmental Taxation in the Presence of Other Taxes: General-EquilibriumAnalyses By A. LANS BOVENBERG AND LAWRENCE H. GOULDER* Most economies feature levels of public The present paper contributes to the analyt- spending that require more tax revenues than ical and empirical literature in three ways. would be generated solely from the pollution First, it extends earlier analytical work on op- taxes set accordingto the Pigovianprinciple, that timal environmental taxation in a general- is, set equal to marginalenvironmental damages. equilibrium setting by considering pollution As a consequence,tax systems generallyrely on taxes imposed on intermediate inputs. This is both environmental(corrective) and othertaxes. a useful extension because many actual envi- However, economists typically have analyzed ronmental regulations and taxes affect the environmentaltaxes withouttaking into account costs of intermediate inputs.2 Second, the pa- the presence of other, distortionarytaxes. The per investigates second-best optimal environ- omission is significantbecause the consequences mental taxes numerically. Here we expand on of environmentaltaxes depend fundamentally the analytical work by employing a numerical on the levels of other taxes, including income general-equilibriummodel of the United States. and commodity taxes. The use of a numerical model enables us to This paper examines how optimal environ- employ a realistic specification of taxes and mental tax rates deviate from rates implied by adopt a fairly detailed representationof pro- the Pigovian principle in a second-best setting duction and demand. Our paper thus combines where other, distortionary taxes are present. the strengths of analytical and numerical ap- Previous investigationsof this issue include the proaches: a stylized analytical model uncovers partialequilibrium analyses of Dwight R.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics 230A Public Sector Microeconomics
    University of California, Berkeley Professor Alan Auerbach Department of Economics 525 Evans Hall Fall 2005 3-0711; auerbach@econ ECONOMICS 230A PUBLIC SECTOR MICROECONOMICS This is the first of two courses in the Public Economics sequence. It will cover core material on taxation, public expenditures and public choice, and conclude with a consideration of the effects of capital income taxation on the behavior of households and firms. Economics 230B, the second semester in the sequence, will extend the discussion of optimal income taxation and consider more fully the behavioral effects of government policy and the institutional characteristics of important U.S. federal taxes and expenditure programs Class meetings: Tuesdays 9-11, 639 Evans Hall Office hours: Mondays, 10:00-11:30, and by appointment Prerequisites: This course should normally be taken after the completion of first-year Ph. D. courses in economic theory and econometrics. Requirements: Problem sets (2) - 30% Paper (5 page review) - 20% Final examination - 50% There is no required textbook for this course. All starred readings below are required and are either included in the course reader or, where noted, available on the web. Non-starred material will be useful for further reading on topics of interest and preparation for the public economics field examination. The following texts and collections, selections from which appear on the reading list, are also useful for background reference: A. Atkinson and J. Stiglitz, Lectures on Public Economics, McGraw-Hill (1980) A. Auerbach and M. Feldstein, eds., Handbook of Public Economics, North-Holland, vol. 1 (1985), vol. 2 (1987), vol. 3 (2002) and vol.
    [Show full text]
  • Annual Report 2003
    TILEC ANNUAL REPORT 2003 Mailing address: TILEC Tilburg Law and Economics Center P.O. Box 90153 5000 LE Tilburg The Netherlands Phone: + 31-13-466 8789 Fax: + 31-13-466 8047 e-mail: [email protected] www: www.tilburguniversity.nl/tilec/ Visiting address: Warandelaan 2 Building Montesquieu Room Y122 5037 AB Tilburg The Netherlands TILEC - Tilburg University 3 Contents CONTENTS FOREWORD . 5 1. TILEC IN 2003 . 7 1.1. Overview . 7 1.2. TILEC and the outside world . 8 1.3. Highlights of 2003 . 12 1.1.1. Major Research efforts . 12 1.1.2. Workshops and Conferences . 14 1.1.3. Seminars . 15 2. PEOPLE . 17 2.1. Overview . 17 2.2. Management . 18 2.3. Faculty . 18 3. PUBLICATIONS . 20 4. ACTIVITIES . 23 5. COMMUNICATIONS . 24 APPENDIX A: PUBLICATIONS . 25 APPENDIX B: ACTIVITIES . 43 4 TILEC - Tilburg University TILEC - Tilburg University 5 Annual report 2003 Foreword FOREWORD On 29 and 30 January 2004, in Paris, the OECD organized a High-Level Ministerial Conference on Science, Technology and Innovation for the 21st Century. As noted in the background paper for that conference, 21st-century science systems face two major challenges: “pressures … to bet- ter respond to a more diverse set of stakeholders and the need to adapt to changes in the pro- cesses of knowledge creation and transfer. These have seen a shift from an organisational model based on scientific disciplines to one that places a premium on multidisciplinarity, institutional networking and a blurring between curiosity-driven and problem-oriented research.”1 As the Final Communiqué of the Conference makes clear, the participating Ministers of Education, Science and Technology and of Economics shared this vision.
    [Show full text]
  • Redistribution and Education Subsidies Are Siamese Twins
    Journal of Public Economics 89 (2005) 2005–2035 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Redistribution and education subsidies are Siamese twins A. Lans Bovenberga,T, Bas Jacobsb aUniversity of Tilburg, Netspar, and CEPR, The Netherlands bUniversity of Tilburg, Netspar, University of Amsterdam, and Tinbergen Institute, The Netherlands Received 17 October 2002; received in revised form 10 November 2004; accepted 13 December 2004 Available online 13 May 2005 Abstract We develop models of optimal linear and non-linear income taxation with endogenous human capital formation to explore optimal education subsidies. Optimal subsidies on education ensure efficiency in human capital accumulation and thus play an important role in alleviating the tax distortions on learning induced by redistributive policies. If the government cannot verify all investments in human capital, education policy offsets some but not all tax-induced distortions on learning. Non-pecuniary educational costs (benefits) may increase (decrease) subsidies on education, especially if they are complementary to work effort. D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: H2; H5; I2; J2 Keywords: Human capital; Education subsidies; Progressive taxation; Redistribution 1. Introduction Most OECD countries heavily subsidize higher education. These education subsidies are typically justified on the basis of perceived positive external effects of human capital T Corresponding author. CentER, Tilburg University, P.O. Box 90153, 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands. Tel.: +31 13 466 2912; fax: +31 13 466 3066. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (A. Lans Bovenberg)8 [email protected] (B. Jacobs). 0047-2727/$ - see front matter D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
    [Show full text]
  • Econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Jacobs, Bas; Bovenberg, Ary Lans Working Paper Optimal taxation of human capital and the earnings function CESifo Working Paper, No. 2250 Provided in Cooperation with: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Suggested Citation: Jacobs, Bas; Bovenberg, Ary Lans (2008) : Optimal taxation of human capital and the earnings function, CESifo Working Paper, No. 2250, Center for Economic Studies and ifo Institute (CESifo), Munich This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/26295 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Optimal Taxation of Human Capital and the Earnings Function BAS JACOBS A. LANS BOVENBERG CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO.
    [Show full text]
  • Reforming Dutch Occupational Pension Schemes LANS BOVENBERG Tilburg University RAYMOND GRADUS VU University Amsterdam and CDA R
    Reforming Dutch occupational pension schemes LANS BOVENBERG Tilburg University RAYMOND GRADUS1 VU University Amsterdam and CDA Research Institute Abstract Dutch occupational defined-benefit plans suffer from a number of serious weaknesses, including ambiguous ownership of the surplus, back-loading of benefits, and lack of tailor- made risk management. To address these weaknesses, we propose collective individual defined-contribution plans that are actuarially fair. These schemes maintain important strengths of collective schemes, such as mandatory saving, collective procurement and pooling biometric risks. At the same time, they eliminate intergenerational conflicts about risk management and distribution through transparent individual property rights and tailor-made risk profiles. We show how the transitional burden due to the phasing out the back-loading of pension benefits can be addressed without a substantial increase in contributions. Introduction The Dutch pension system consists of three pillars (see also Bovenberg and Gradus (2008)). The first pillar is the AOW, which is the basic minimum public pension provided by the government to all residents. It provides a flat-rate pension benefit, which is related to the net minimum wage. As a direct consequence. poverty under elderly is very low in the Netherlands. The second pillar involves occupational pension schemes, which are part of collective labor agreements. The first and second pillars currently account for similar shares in the average incomes of retirees (see Knoef et al. (2013)). The third pillar comprises individual pension provisions, the premiums of which are deductable for income taxation. The third pillar is relatively small in the Netherlands. It provides only 5% of the retirement income 1 Corresponding author: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Complete Dissertation
    VU Research Portal Worldviews and the Transformation to Sustainable Societies Hedlund-de Witt, A. 2013 document version Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record Link to publication in VU Research Portal citation for published version (APA) Hedlund-de Witt, A. (2013). Worldviews and the Transformation to Sustainable Societies: An exploration of the cultural and psychological dimensions of our global environmental chanllenges. General rights Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. • Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research. • You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain • You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal ? Take down policy If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim. E-mail address: [email protected] Download date: 04. Oct. 2021 to sustainable societies sustainable to and the transformation Worldviews Worldviews and the transformation to sustainable societies Worldviews and the transformation Worldviews and the transformation to sustainable societies addresses one of the most challenging questions of our time. Its unique vantage point is based on the recognition of the to sustainable societies crucial importance of worldviews vis-à-vis the urgently needed transformation to sustainable An exploration of the cultural and psychological societies.
    [Show full text]
  • Food (Safety) Policy in the Netherlands
    210 CHAPTER SIX: From ‘politics in the stable’ to stable politics: Food (safety) policy in the Netherlands 6.1 Introduction In his 1999 book De Virtuele Boer (‘The virtual farmer’), Jan Douwe van der Ploeg critically addressed the evolution of the Dutch ‘expertise-based’ intensive agriculture, which, according the author, had constructed an image of the farmer as focused on profit-maximizing and as virtually indifferent to the societal and environmental impact of intensive agriculture. Upon its publication, commentators referred to it as ‘not discussable’ (onbespreekbaar) at Wageningen University (Strijker 2000: 8), the long-standing agricultural university and breeding ground for the exceptional rate of success of Dutch agriculture - one of the largest exporters of agricultural products. What makes such criticism ‘not discussable’, and how does it compare to the desire to ‘remove the smell of stables’ from food (safety) policy in England and Germany, following the series of food scares during the 1990s? The present chapter explores the ways in which food (safety) has been taken up as a policy issue in the Netherlands and addresses the underlying contextual specificities in the following ways: Following this introduction, section 2 provides an account of the developments in the area of food (safety) policy in the Netherlands roughly over the past century in order to trace out some of the discursive-institutional foundations that still carry weight in today’s policy discourse. As in the previous two country-based chapters, section 3 recounts the range of food scares that occurred in the Netherlands over the past decade and highlights the key moments in which particular interpretations of ‘what food safety means’, and what the food scares stood for, were articulated.
    [Show full text]