An Engine, Not a Camera Studies of Science and the Institute for Scientific Information, for Career Contributions to the Field of Science Studies

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

An Engine, Not a Camera Studies of Science and the Institute for Scientific Information, for Career Contributions to the Field of Science Studies MacKenzie_jkt.qxd 3/30/06 1:27 PM Page 1 economics/science, technology, and society Donald MacKenzie is Professor of Sociology (Personal Chair) at the University of Edinburgh. He was the winner of the 2005 John Desmond Bernal Prize, awarded jointly by the Society for Social An Engine, Not a Camera Studies of Science and the Institute for Scientific Information, for career contributions to the field of science studies. His books “In one lifetime modern finance theory has revolutionized the arts of canny include Inventing Accuracy (1990), Knowing Machines (1996), and investing. MacKenzie knows this exciting story, and he tells it well.” How Financial Models Shape Markets Mechanizing Proof (2001), all published by The MIT Press. Portions Paul A. Samuelson, MIT, Nobel Laureate in Economic Sciences (1970) An Engine, Not a Camera of An Engine, Not a Camera won the Viviana A. Zelizer Prize in . economic sociology from the American Sociological Association. “Having returned from an audacious incursion into the black box of modern How Financial Models Shape Markets financial markets, Donald MacKenzie shows how economic theory has succeeded in capturing and shaping them. This book will be of substantial interest to specialists in a range of fields including economics, finance theory, Donald MacKenzie economic sociology, and science and technology studies. But MacKenzie’s tour An h de force is to make clear, even to nonspecialists, that through complex tech- Engine, DDoonnaallddMMaaccKKeennzziiee nical issues, alternative forms of economic organization can be imagined and Not a In An Engine, Not a Camera, Donald MacKenzie argues that the discussed.” Camera emergence of modern economic theories of finance affected Michel Callon, Ecole des Mines de Paris financial markets in fundamental ways. These new, Nobel Prize- Inside Technology series MacKenzie winning theories, based on elegant mathematical models of markets, were not simply external analyses but intrinsic parts of economic processes. “Donald MacKenzie has long been one of the world’s most brilliant social Paraphrasing Milton Friedman, MacKenzie says that economic and historical analysts of science and technology. Here he provides an original, models are an engine of inquiry rather than a camera to reproduce astute, and exhaustively researched account of the development of finance empirical facts. More than that, the emergence of an authoritative theory and the ways in which it is intertwined with financial markets. An theory of financial markets altered those markets fundamentally. Engine, Not a Camera is essential for anyone interested in markets and the For example, in 1970 there was almost no trading in financial forms of knowledge deployed in them.” derivatives such as “futures.” By June of 2004, derivatives contracts Karin Knorr Cetina, University of Konstanz and University of Chicago totaling $273 trillion were outstanding worldwide. MacKenzie suggests that this growth could never have happened without the “An Engine, Not a Camera is a compelling, detailed, and elegantly written explo- development of theories that gave derivatives legitimacy and ration of the conditions in which finance economists help to make the world explained their complexities. they seek to describe and predict. Donald MacKenzie has long been without MacKenzie examines the role played by finance theory in the equal as a sociologist of how late modern futures are brought into being and two most serious crises to hit the world’s financial markets in made authoritative. This is his best work yet.” recent years: the stock market crash of 1987 and the market Steven Shapin, Franklin L. Ford Professor of the History of Science, turmoil that engulfed the hedge fund Long-Term Capital Harvard University Management in 1998. He also looks at finance theory that is somewhat beyond the mainstream—chaos theorist Benoit The MIT Press | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Cambridge, Massachusetts 02142 Mandelbrot’s model of “wild” randomness. MacKenzie’s pioneering Cover image: Traders on the floor of work in the social studies of finance will interest anyone who the Chicago Board Options Exchange, http://mitpress.mit.edu | 0-262-13460-8 October 19, 1987. Photograph by wants to understand how America’s financial markets have John T. Gralak. © Corbis. All rights grown into their current form. reserved. An Engine, Not a Camera Inside Technology edited by Wiebe E. Bijker, W. Bernard Carlson, and Trevor Pinch A list of the series will be found on page 369. An Engine, Not a Camera How Financial Models Shape Markets Donald MacKenzie The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England © 2006 Massachusetts Institute of Technology All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form by any electronic or mechanical means (including photocopying, recording, or information storage and retrieval) without permission in writing from the publisher. This book does not constitute financial advice, and it is sold with the understanding that neither the author nor the publisher is engaged in rendering investing, legal, accounting, or other professional service. If investment advice or other expert assis- tance is required, the services of a competent professional person should be sought. MIT Press books may be purchased at special quantity discounts for business or sales promotional use. For information, please email [email protected] or write to Special Sales Department, The MIT Press, 55 Hayward Street, Cambridge, MA 02142. Set in Baskerville by SNP Best-set Typesetter Ltd., Hong Kong. Printed and bound in the United States of America. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data MacKenzie, Donald A. An engine, not a camera : how financial models shape markets / Donald MacKenzie. p. cm. — (Inside technology) Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0-262-13460-8 1. Capital market—Mathematical models. 2. Derivative securities—Mathematical models. 3. Financial crises—Mathematical models. 4. Financial crises—Case studies. I. Title. II. Series. HG4523.M24 2006 332'.01'5195—dc22 2005052115 10987654321 to Iain Contents Acknowledgements ix 1 Performing Theory? 1 2 Transforming Finance 37 3 Theory and Practice 69 4 Tests, Anomalies, and Monsters 89 5 Pricing Options 119 6 Pits, Bodies, and Theorems 143 7 The Fall 179 8 Arbitrage 211 9 Models and Markets 243 Appendix A An Example of Modigliani and Miller’s “Arbitrage Proof” of the Irrelevance of Capital Structure to Total Market Value 277 viii Contents Appendix B Lévy Distributions 279 Appendix C Sprenkle’s and Kassouf’s Equations for Warrant Prices 281 Appendix D The Black-Scholes Equation for a European Option on a Non- Dividend-Bearing Stock 283 Appendix E Pricing Options in a Binomial World 285 Appendix F Repo, Haircuts, and Reverse Repo 289 Appendix G A Typical Swap-Spread Arbitrage Trade 291 Appendix H List of Interviewees 293 Glossary 297 Notes 303 Sources of Unpublished Documents 331 References 333 Series List 369 Index 371 Acknowledgements To research and to write a book is to incur a multitude of debts of gratitude. For an academic, time is often the resource in shortest supply. The time needed to write this book and to complete the research that underpins it was provided by a professorial fellowship awarded by the U.K. Economic and Social Research Council (RES-051-27-0062). The funds for the trips required by all but the most recent interviews were provided by Edinburgh University and especially by the Interdisciplinary Research Collaboration on the Depend- ability of Computer-Based Systems (DIRC), which is itself supported by a grant awarded by the U.K. Engineering and Physical Sciences Research Council (GR/N13999). Behind that bald statement lies the generosity of DIRC’s overall director, Cliff Jones, and of the leaders of its Edinburgh center, Stuart Anderson and Robin Williams, in regarding an offbeat topic as relevant to DIRC. Robin, in particular, has been a good friend both to me and to this project. Ultimately, though, money was less important as a source of support than people. Moyra Forrest provided me, promptly and cheerfully, with the vast majority of the hundreds of documents that form this book’s bibliography. Margaret Robertson skillfully transcribed the bulk of the interviews: as anyone who has done similar work knows, the quality of transcription is a key matter. I am always amazed by Barbara Silander’s capacity to turn my voluminous, messy, handwritten drafts, heavily edited typescript, dictated passages, and file cards into an orderly word-processed text and reference list: I could not have written the book without her. I have also been lucky enough to find colleagues who have shared my enthu- siasm for “social studies of finance.” Yuval Millo was there at my project’s inception, and has contributed to it in a multitude of ways. James Clunie, Iain Hardie, Dave Leung, Lucia Siu, and Alex Preda have now joined me in the Edinburgh group, and it is my enormous good fortune to have them as collaborators. x Acknowledgements The work reported here draws heavily upon what I learned from the many interviewees from finance theory and the financial markets whose names are listed in appendix H (and by some additional interviewees who preferred anonymity). They gave their time to help me understand their world: if this book has virtues, it is largely as a result of their generosity in this respect. Peter Bernstein—who is both an investment practitioner and the author of the first overall history of finance theory (Bernstein 1992)—provided crucial advice and encouragement, as did Robert C. Merton. Particularly important in setting up in interviews for me and in putting me in touch with interviewees was Emily Schmitz of the Chicago Board Options Exchange: she is another person without whose help this book would have been much impoverished. Cathy Tawes Black kindly permitted me access to the papers of Fischer Black, held in the Institute Archives at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Several of the episodes discussed here have been controversial, some bitterly so.
Recommended publications
  • Myron Scholes Is the Frank E
    Myron Scholes is the Frank E. Buck Professor of Finance, Emeritus, called back to active duty at the Stanford Graduate School of Business. He is a Nobel Laureate in Economic Sciences, and co- originator of the Black-Scholes options pricing model. Scholes was awarded the Nobel Prize in 1997 for his new method of determining the value of derivatives. His research has focused on understanding uncertainty and its effect on asset prices and the value of options, including flexibility options. He has studied the effects of tax policy on asset prices and incentives. He studied the effects of the taxation of dividends on the prices of securities, the interaction of incentives and taxes in executive compensation, capital structure issues with taxation, and the effects of taxes on the optimal liquidation of assets. He wrote several articles on investment banking and incentives and developed a new theory of tax planning under uncertainty and information asymmetry which led to a book with Mark A. Wolfson called Taxes and Business Strategies: A Planning Myron Scholes Approach (Prentice Hall, 1991). Frank E. Buck Professor of Finance, Emeritus Scholes is currently the Chief Investment Strategist, Janus Capital Group. Previously he served as the Chairman of Platinum Grove Stanford University Asset Management and on the Dimensional Fund Advisors Board of Directors, formerly, American Century Mutual Fund Board of Directors and the Cutwater Advisory Board. He was a principal and Limited Partner at Long-Term Capital Management, L.P. and a Managing Director at Salomon Brothers. Other positions Scholes held include the Edward Eagle Brown Professor of Finance at the University of Chicago, Senior Research Fellow at the Hoover Institution, and Director of the Center for Research in Security Prices, and Professor of Finance at MIT’s Sloan School of Management.
    [Show full text]
  • F:\RSS\Me\Society's Mathemarica
    School of Social Sciences Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK Discussion Papers in Economics and Econometrics Mathematics in the Statistical Society 1883-1933 John Aldrich No. 0919 This paper is available on our website http://www.southampton.ac.uk/socsci/economics/research/papers ISSN 0966-4246 Mathematics in the Statistical Society 1883-1933* John Aldrich Economics Division School of Social Sciences University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ UK e-mail: [email protected] Abstract This paper considers the place of mathematical methods based on probability in the work of the London (later Royal) Statistical Society in the half-century 1883-1933. The end-points are chosen because mathematical work started to appear regularly in 1883 and 1933 saw the formation of the Industrial and Agricultural Research Section– to promote these particular applications was to encourage mathematical methods. In the period three movements are distinguished, associated with major figures in the history of mathematical statistics–F. Y. Edgeworth, Karl Pearson and R. A. Fisher. The first two movements were based on the conviction that the use of mathematical methods could transform the way the Society did its traditional work in economic/social statistics while the third movement was associated with an enlargement in the scope of statistics. The study tries to synthesise research based on the Society’s archives with research on the wider history of statistics. Key names : Arthur Bowley, F. Y. Edgeworth, R. A. Fisher, Egon Pearson, Karl Pearson, Ernest Snow, John Wishart, G. Udny Yule. Keywords : History of Statistics, Royal Statistical Society, mathematical methods.
    [Show full text]
  • BIS Papers No 95 Frontiers of Macrofinancial Linkages
    BIS Papers No 95 Frontiers of macrofinancial linkages by Stijn Claessens and M Ayhan Kose Monetary and Economic Department January 2018 The views expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS. This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2018. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISSN 1609-0381 (print) ISBN 978-92-9259-123-6 (print) ISSN 1682-7651 (online) ISBN 978-92-9259-124-3 (online) “…They [economists] turned a blind eye to the limitations of human rationality that often lead to bubbles and busts; to the problems of institutions that run amok; to the imperfections of markets – especially financial markets – that can cause the economy’s operating system to undergo sudden, unpredictable crashes …” Paul Krugman (2009a) ““Hello, Paul, where have you been for the last 30 years?”… Pretty much all we have been doing for 30 years is introducing flaws, frictions and new behaviors... The long literature on financial crises and banking … has also been doing exactly the same….” John H. Cochrane (2011a) “I believe that during the last financial crisis, macroeconomists (and I include myself among them) failed the country, and indeed the world. In September 2008, central bankers were in desperate need of a playbook that offered a systematic plan of attack to deal with fast evolving circumstances. Macroeconomics should have been able to provide that playbook. It could not…” Narayana Kocherlakota (2010)
    [Show full text]
  • An Intellectual History of Corporate Finance Theory
    Saint Louis University Law Journal Volume 54 Number 4 Remaking Law: Moving Beyond Article 11 Enlightenment Jurisprudence (Summer 2010) 2010 The Enlightenment and the Financial Crisis of 2008: An Intellectual History of Corporate Finance Theory James R. Hackney Jr. Northeastern University School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.slu.edu/lj Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation James R. Hackney Jr., The Enlightenment and the Financial Crisis of 2008: An Intellectual History of Corporate Finance Theory, 54 St. Louis U. L.J. (2010). Available at: https://scholarship.law.slu.edu/lj/vol54/iss4/11 This Childress Lecture is brought to you for free and open access by Scholarship Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Saint Louis University Law Journal by an authorized editor of Scholarship Commons. For more information, please contact Susie Lee. SAINT LOUIS UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW THE ENLIGHTENMENT AND THE FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2008: AN INTELLECTUAL HISTORY OF CORPORATE FINANCE THEORY JAMES R. HACKNEY, JR.* Professor powell paints a sweeping account of the relationship between the Enlightenment and law. I agree with the basic thrust of his argument, and I applaud his ability to make connections between the broad scope of intellectual history and developments in law.1 I have previously written about the interconnection between philosophical ideals and the development of legal- economic theory as it particularly relates to tort law theory.2 Through his extension of these ideas into other areas of law, Professor powell illustrates their wide implications. As Professor powell highlights, one of the principal tenets of the Enlightenment is the belief in rationality and the focus on the individual as the emphasis of analysis.3 This individualistic ideal is the foundation of neoclassical economics, which I have previously detailed.4 It is also the foundation for modern finance theory, which ascended with neoclassical economics and has a close relationship with it both theoretically and institutionally.
    [Show full text]
  • Myron S. Scholes [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Daniel B
    Myron S. Scholes [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Daniel B. Klein, Ryan Daza, and Hannah Mead Econ Journal Watch 10(3), September 2013: 590-593 Abstract Myron S. Scholes is among the 71 individuals who were awarded the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel between 1969 and 2012. This ideological profile is part of the project called “The Ideological Migration of the Economics Laureates,” which fills the September 2013 issue of Econ Journal Watch. Keywords Classical liberalism, economists, Nobel Prize in economics, ideology, ideological migration, intellectual biography. JEL classification A11, A13, B2, B3 Link to this document http://econjwatch.org/file_download/766/ScholesIPEL.pdf ECON JOURNAL WATCH Schelling, Thomas C. 2007. Strategies of Commitment and Other Essays. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Schelling, Thomas C. 2013. Email correspondence with Daniel Klein, June 12. Schelling, Thomas C., and Morton H. Halperin. 1961. Strategy and Arms Control. New York: The Twentieth Century Fund. Myron S. Scholes by Daniel B. Klein, Ryan Daza, and Hannah Mead Myron Scholes (1941–) was born and raised in Ontario. His father, born in New York City, was a teacher in Rochester. He moved to Ontario to practice dentistry in 1930. Scholes’s mother moved as a young girl to Ontario from Russia and its pogroms (Scholes 2009a, 235). His mother and his uncle ran a successful chain of department stores. Scholes’s “first exposure to agency and contracting problems” was a family dispute that left his mother out of much of the business (Scholes 2009a, 235). In high school, he “enjoyed puzzles and financial issues,” succeeded in mathematics, physics, and biology, and subsequently was solicited to enter a engineering program by McMaster University (Scholes 2009a, 236-237).
    [Show full text]
  • Robert Merton and Myron Scholes, Nobel Laureates in Economic Sciences, Receive 2011 CME Group Fred Arditti Innovation Award
    Robert Merton and Myron Scholes, Nobel Laureates in Economic Sciences, Receive 2011 CME Group Fred Arditti Innovation Award CHICAGO, Sept. 8, 2011 /PRNewswire/ -- The CME Group Center for Innovation (CFI) today announced Robert C. Merton, School of Management Distinguished Professor of Finance at the MIT Sloan School of Management and Myron S. Scholes, chairman of the Board of Economic Advisors of Stamos Partners, are the 2011 CME Group Fred Arditti Innovation Award recipients. Both recipients are recognized for their significant contributions to the financial markets, including the discovery and development of the Black-Scholes options pricing model, used to determine the value of options derivatives. The award will be presented at the fourth annual Global Financial Leadership Conference in Naples, Fla., Monday, October 24. "The Fred Arditti Award honors individuals whose innovative ideas created significant change to the markets," said Leo Melamed, CME Group Chairman Emeritus and Competitive Markets Advisory Council (CMAC) Vice Chairman. "The nexus between the Black-Scholes model and this Award needs no explanation. Their options model forever changed the nature of markets and provided the necessary foundation for the measurement of risk. The CME Group options markets were built on that infrastructure." "The Black-Scholes pricing model is still widely used to minimize risk in the financial markets," said Scholes, who first articulated the model's formula along with economist Fischer Black. "It is thrilling to witness the impact it has had in this industry, and we are honored to receive this recognition for it." "Amid uncertainty in the financial markets, we are pleased the Black-Scholes pricing model still plays an important role in determining pricing and managing risk," said Merton, who worked with Scholes and Black to further mathematically prove the model.
    [Show full text]
  • How the SEC Justified Its Decision to Require Registration of Hedge Fund Advisers
    Washington University Law Review Volume 83 Issue 2 2005 Looking Through the Hedges: How the SEC Justified Its Decision to Require Registration of Hedge Fund Advisers Laura Edwards Washington University School of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview Part of the Legislation Commons Recommended Citation Laura Edwards, Looking Through the Hedges: How the SEC Justified Its Decision ot Require Registration of Hedge Fund Advisers, 83 WASH. U. L. Q. 603 (2005). Available at: https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview/vol83/iss2/5 This Note is brought to you for free and open access by the Law School at Washington University Open Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Washington University Law Review by an authorized administrator of Washington University Open Scholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. LOOKING THROUGH THE HEDGES: HOW THE SEC JUSTIFIED ITS DECISION TO REQUIRE REGISTRATION OF HEDGE FUND ADVISERS I. INTRODUCTION In 1998, the infamous hedge fund, Long Term Capital Management (“LTCM”), collapsed, threatening to bring down the entire global economy.1 Although hedge funds had been dramatically growing in popularity since the early 1990s,2 this was the first major event in an industry that was, and still is, generally seen as an investment vehicle for the very rich and non-risk-averse.3 In the next five years, the hedge fund industry would be the focus of reports by the President’s Working Group on Financial Markets4 (“President’s Working
    [Show full text]
  • The New Market Wizards Conversations with America's Top Traders Jack D
    1 THE NEW MARKET WIZARDS CONVERSATIONS WITH AMERICA'S TOP TRADERS JACK D. SCHWAGER HarperBusiness 1 7700++ DDVVDD’’ss FFOORR SSAALLEE && EEXXCCHHAANNGGEE www.traders-software.com www.forex-warez.com www.trading-software-collection.com www.tradestation-download-free.com Contacts [email protected] [email protected] Skype: andreybbrv 2 This book was originally published in 1992 by HarperBusiness, a division of Harper-Coltins Publishers. THE NEW MARKET WIZARDS. Copyright © 1992 by Jack D. Schwager. All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. No part of this book may be used or reproduced in any manner whatsoever without written permission except in the case of brief quotations embodied in critical articles and reviews. For information address Harper-Collins Publishers, Inc., 10 East 53rd Street, New York, NY 10022. HarperCollins books may be purchased for educational, business, or sales promotional use. For information please write: Special Markets Department, HarpeiCollins Publishers, Inc., 10 East 53rd Street, New York, NY 10022. First paperback edition published 1994. Designed by Alma Hochhauser Orenstein The Library of Congress has catalogued the hardcover edition as follows: Schwager, Jack D., 1948- The new market wizards : conversations with America's top traders / Jack D. Schwager.- Isted-p. cm. Sequel to: Market wizards. ISBN 0-88730-587-3 1. Floor traders (Finance)-United States-Interviews. 2. Futures market-United States. 3. Financial futures- United States. 1. Schwager, Jack D., 1948- Market Wizards. H.
    [Show full text]
  • Second Draft
    Second Draft Risk, Financial Crises, and Globalization: Long-Term Capital Management and the Sociology of Arbitrage Donald MacKenzie March, 2002 Author’s address: School of Social and Political Studies University of Edinburgh Adam Ferguson Building George Square Edinburgh EH8 9LL Scotland [email protected] Word counts: main text, 16,883 words; notes, 1,657 words; appendix, 142 words; references, 1,400 words. Risk, Financial Crises, and Globalization: Long-Term Capital Management and the Sociology of Arbitrage Abstract Arbitrage is a key process in the practice of financial markets and in their theoretical depiction: it allows markets to be posited as efficient without all investors being assumed to be rational. This article explores the sociology of arbitrage by means of an examination of the arbitrageurs, Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM). It describes LTCM’s roots in the investment bank, Salomon Brothers, and how LTCM conducted arbitrage. LTCM’s 1998 crisis is analyzed using both qualitative, interview-based, data and quantitative examination of price movements. It is suggested that the roots of the crisis lay in an unstable pattern of imitation that had developed in the markets within which LTCM operated. As the resultant “superportfolio” began to unravel, arbitrageurs other than LTCM fled the market, even as arbitrage opportunities became more attractive. The episode reveals limits on the capacity of arbitrage to close price discrepancies; it suggests that processes of imitation can involve professional as well as lay traders; and it lends empirical plausibility to the conjecture that imitation may cause the distinctive “fat tails” of the probability distributions of price changes in the financial markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Interview with Jim Edgar # ISG-A-L-2009-019.23 Interview # 23: November 8, 2010 Interviewer: Mark Depue
    Interview with Governor Jim Edgar Volume V (Sessions 23-26) Interview with Jim Edgar # ISG-A-L-2009-019.23 Interview # 23: November 8, 2010 Interviewer: Mark DePue COPYRIGHT The following material can be used for educational and other non-commercial purposes without the written permission of the Abraham Lincoln Presidential Library. “Fair use” criteria of Section 107 of the Copyright Act of 1976 must be followed. These materials are not to be deposited in other repositories, nor used for resale or commercial purposes without the authorization from the Audio-Visual Curator at the Abraham Lincoln Presidential Library, 112 N. 6th Street, Springfield, Illinois 62701. Telephone (217) 785-7955 DePue: Today is Monday, November 8, 2010. My name is Mark DePue, the director of oral history with the Abraham Lincoln Presidential Library. This is my twenty-third session with Gov. Jim Edgar. Good afternoon, Governor. Edgar: Good afternoon. DePue: We’ve been at it for a little while, but it’s been a fascinating series of discussions. We are now getting close to the time when we can wrap up your administration. So without further ado in terms of the introduction, what we finished off last time was the MSI discussion. That puts us in the 1997 timeframe, into 1998. I wanted to start, though, with talking about some things in Historic Preservation. Obviously, with myself and our institution— Edgar: Let me ask you a question real quick. Did we do higher education reorganization? DePue: Oh yes. Edgar: We did? Okay. DePue: We did. Edgar: I can remember what I did twenty years ago; I can’t remember what I did two weeks ago.
    [Show full text]
  • JWM Losses Result in Job Cuts by Mark Ginocchio Staff Writer Article Launched: 05/03/2008 02:44:47 AM EDT
    JWM losses result in job cuts By Mark Ginocchio Staff Writer Article Launched: 05/03/2008 02:44:47 AM EDT Struggling Greenwich Hedge Fund JWM Partners LLC, run by ex-Long-Term Capital Management LP chief John Meriwether has terminated nearly 20 percent of its employees and has allowed investors to exit one of its funds, firm officials confirmed this week. At least 15 JWM employees across all departments were notified of their termination last week, according a spokesman at Rubenstein Associates, a firm that represents the hedge fund. A number of JWM's strategies have been hit hard with losses since the beginning of the year. The $1 billion Relative Value Opportunity fund is down about 24 percent since January, and the $300 million global macro fund has lost about 14 percent this year, according to published reports. In order to get "better knowledge of its investors intentions," JWM has accelerated the redemption rights of its global macro investors so the hedge fund could begin trading again, the Rubenstein spokesman said. Typically, hedge fund managers will lock up investors' money for long periods before allowing them to redeem. JWM's five-year-old global macro fund makes bets on currencies, stocks and bonds. Meriwether, who founded JWM, ran $4 billion Greenwich fund Long-Term Capital before it collapsed in 1998 after Russia defaulted and investors turned to the safety of U.S. treasuries, driving down the value of the fund's bets. Despite being associated with a manager that has now struggled with two different hedge funds, financial service recruiters said the laid-off JWM employees will likely get picked up.
    [Show full text]
  • Calibrated Bayes: a Bayes/Frequentist Roadmap
    Calibrated Bayes: A Bayes/Frequentist Roadmap Roderick LITTLE pects of the conflict are illustrated with basic and more general examples. In Sections 3 and 4, I provide my personal perspec- The lack of an agreed inferential basis for statistics makes life tive on strengths and weaknesses of the frequentist and Bayesian “interesting” for academic statisticians, but at the price of nega- approaches to statistics, and in Section5Iarguethat calibrated tive implications for the status of statistics in industry, science, Bayes is a compromise that capitalizes on the strengths of both and government. The practice of our discipline will mature only systems of inference. The calibrated Bayes compromise pro- when we can come to a basic agreement about how to apply vides a useful roadmap, but remains sketchy on the boundary statistics to real problems. Simple and more general illustrations between inference and model selection, suggesting areas of fu- are given of the negative consequences of the existing schism ture development. In Section 6, I discuss some implications of between frequentists and Bayesians. the proposed compromise for the future teaching and practice An assessment of strengths and weaknesses of the frequen- of statistics. tist and Bayes systems of inference suggests that calibrated Bayes—a compromise based on the work of Box, Rubin, and 2. THE BAYES/FREQUENTIST SCHISM: others—captures the strengths of both approaches and provides DOES IT MATTER? a roadmap for future advances. The approach asserts that infer- I was a student of statistics in London in the early 1970s, ences under a particular model should be Bayesian, but model when debates raged about alternative philosophies of statistics.
    [Show full text]