Organizing Democracy (Diss)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Organizing Democracy (Diss) FROM THE SOCIALISM OF INTELLIGENCE TO THE ARISTOCRACY OF KNOWLEDGE: ADMINISTRATIVE PRACTICE AND POLITICAL AUTHORITY IN AMERICAN DEMOCRACY, 1905–1921 A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE DEPARTMENT OF SOCIOLOGY AND THE COMMITTEE ON GRADUATE STUDIES OF STANFORD UNIVERSITY IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY AARON HORVATH JULY 2021 To Katey You were right: accounting is interesting. And I still can’t spell philanhropy on the first try. iv For forms of government let fools contest; Whate’er is best administered is best –Alexander Pope, An Essay on Man (1733) Early writings are full of assurances that we can adopt the administrative devices of autocracy without accepting its spirit and its ends. –Dwight Waldo, The Administrative State (1948) v Abstract “Government budgeting.” There is little in the phrase to arouse the passions or inspire excitement. And yet, beneath what sociologists have tended to regard as a relatively unremarkable set of bureaucratic procedures, one finds a history full of contingency and heated contestation. More than a mere means of allocating government funds, budgeting—and the specific procedural form it takes—is the financial embodiment of political authority. Budgets may determine who gets what; but budgetary practices determine who gets a say. As such, the history of this seemingly mundane administrative practice is the history of political power, one that centers on inclusion, exclusion, and the privileges of democratic voice. This dissertation chronicles the early career of government budgeting in the United States, tracing its emergence from New York municipal reform movements in 1905 to its codification into federal law in 1921. In its early days, budgeting was promoted as a device for shedding light on government activities, encouraging public debate about collective priorities, and empowering mass democracy. Annual municipal budgets were accompanied with well-attended public exhibits imploring citizens to “come see how your money is spent” and encouraging public participation in the budgetary process. As budgeting moved into federal government, however, proponents recast the practice as a tool for expanding executive authority and minimizing public “interference” in the policymaking process. The budget became, as one proponent put it, a “method of control without violence.” Although the new approach to public budgeting was initially rejected—seen as an instrument of despotism and oligarchic control—it was eventually institutionalized at the very heart of national government. Today, when an American President announces a national budget, our attention is drawn to the amount of vi money to be spent or what it will be spent on—not the fact that the task of determining a national agenda falls with the President and not the people themselves. In a country avowedly committed to the principles of egalitarianism and popular sovereignty, how did such an arrangement come to exist? Drawing on extensive archival materials from the New York Bureau of Municipal Research, the Rockefeller Foundation, the Taft Commission on Economy and Efficiency, and the Institute for Government Research (later incorporated as the Brookings Institution), I demonstrate how the emergence of the national budget was the result of political and cultural contestation over the meaning of democracy and the proper role of ordinary citizens within it. The ascendence of an aristocracy of knowledge was ultimately predicated on the invention of a unified national interest and a normative reconfiguration of the responsibilities of American citizenship. Contrary to a tradition in organizational sociology that views oligarchy as the natural byproduct of administrative rationalization, my account reveals that oligarchy is anything but inevitable. In the American case, it was the hard-won product of an elite social movement to redefine the character of political authority in democratic politics. vii Acknowledgements There is a ritual order to acknowledgment sections. Authors will typically remark on the loneliness of writing and credit the fellow scholars who had their back along the way. They’ll thank the funders without whom the work would have been impossible, and the research assistants without whom the work would have never gotten done. And at long last, usually in a final paragraph of gratitude, they’ll offer their deepest, sincerest thanks to their long-suffering spouses. I know the ritual well, but not nearly as well as my partner, my person, and my better half—Katey Webber—who, for eight years, has read the acknowledgements section of nearly every book I’ve brought home. She’s so familiar with the rigamarole that she’s probably instinctually flipped to the end to see what I’ve written about her. And sure, she’ll find something there. But it’ll be underwhelming; not at all commensurate with what she’s endured since we moved to California all those years ago. That’s because Katey shouldn’t have to wait until the end to be acknowledged. Katey has a patience and love for me that I’ve never had for myself. She’s proven that one really can blend the comic sensibilities of Rodney Dangerfield with the physical comedy of Charlie Chaplin and all the riot grrrl of Bikini Kill. I’ve been taught by her to stop using passive voice. Katey, through her selflessness, vulnerability, authenticity, and constant drive to build community, has taught me more about society—and what society ought to be—than any book or study ever could. Others who have kept me afloat include Woody Powell, a guy whose class I took because, it was either organizations or demography and, while I didn’t really know what “organizations” were or why anyone would want to study them, it sounded more viii interesting than demography. Best decision I made in grad school. After that first quarter, Woody took me under his wing, entertaining my simplistic pitchfork-and-torch politics while giving me a vocabulary for complexity and an ability to problematize big ideas. His mentorship, co-authorship, and friendship have been indispensable to my intellectual and personal growth over the last eight years. I also want to thank Sarah Soule who I first met in her class on organizations and social movements. Sarah is a constant source of energy and encouragement and a model of how to balance intellectual rigor with compassion and down-to-earth humanity. The many beers and bike rides to and from local watering holes that we’ve shared over the years have been some of my most cherished moments at Stanford. The first time I met John Meyer in 2014, he casually imparted wisdom that has stuck with me ever since. As I ranted about my disgust that powerful people and organizations were effectively granted carte blanche to perpetuate social inequities, John told me that this was a wonderful perspective to have “after five o’clock.” But “before five o’clock” I ought to focus sociologically on how such a systems came to be. John’s wisdom, kindness, and critical perspective have been essential to my education, even if work rarely ends at five. Thanks also go to Barbara Kiviat who, thanks to the pandemic, I have yet to actually meet in person. She has nevertheless been a vital source of encouragement both during the struggles of the 2020 academic job market and during the struggles of writing a dissertation. ix I am thankful to have a dissertation committee that understands, quite correctly, that the thing my dissertation most needs defending from is me. Thanks for helping me to keep it going. At Stanford, I have had the pleasure of existing in multiple worlds at once—both as a student in the Sociology Department and as a member of the Stanford Center on Philanthropy and Civil Society (PACS). In the Sociology Department, I am indebted to Mark Granovetter, Doug McAdam, and Cristobal Young whose support, encouragement, and critical attention were indispensable in my early years at Stanford. And without Natasha Newson and Randy Michaud in the front office, the University would have dispensed of me long ago. Thanks for keeping that from happening. At PACS, I have benefitted greatly from my interactions with Lucy Bernholz, Paul Brest, and Rob Reich. Rob is the consummate public scholar; his ability to speak truth to power and bridge between ivory tower and public relevance is something I seek to emulate in my own work. Also at PACS, I want to thank Kim Meredith, Priya Shanker, and Valerie Dao who have looked out for me, believed in me, and given me opportunities to pursue my various (and only occasionally sensible) intellectual interests. Although this dissertation only came together over the last few months, it is part of a larger project that has been several years in the making. At the end of 2017, the National Science Foundation was kind enough to support me with a Dissertation Improvement Grant (SES #1801678) and the funds were sufficient to allow me to visit archives around the country. I traveled to places as far apart as Syracuse, New York (where I got a crappy rental car stuck in a snowbank) and Santa Monica, California (where I drank at the bar where Daniel Ellsberg allegedly released the Pentagon Papers). x Between 2018 and the start of the pandemic, I was able to steal away enough time to visit 13 archives, pull material from 93 collections, and melt a hard drive with 160GB of archival images—only a fraction of which is used in this dissertation. It was one ski mask short of a smash and grab operation and were it not for the incredibly generous archivists, librarians, and historians who helped me along the way, all that smashing and grabbing would have been for naught. In particular, I want to thank the staff the Rockefeller Archive Center, the Columbia University Rare Book & Manuscript Library, the Newman Library Archives at CUNY’s Baruch College, and the Brookings Institution Archives.
Recommended publications
  • American Political Thought: Readings and Materials Keith E. Whittington
    American Political Thought: Readings and Materials Keith E. Whittington Index of Materials for Companion Website 2. The Colonial Era, Before 1776 II. Democracy and Liberty John Adams, Letter to James Sullivan (1776) John Cotton, The Bloudy Tenent Washed and Made White (1647) John Cotton, Letter to Lord Say and Seal (1636) Jacob Duche, The Duty of Standing Fast in Our Spiritual and Temporal Liberties (1775) Massachusetts Body of Liberties (1641) James Otis, Rights of the British Colony Asserted and Proved (1764) Elisha Williams, The Essential Rights and Liberties of Protestants (1744) Roger Williams, The Bloudy Tenent Yet More Bloudy (1652) John Winthrop, Arbitrary Government Described (1644) John Winthrop, A Defense of an Order of Court (1637) John Winthrop, Defense of the Negative Vote (1643) III. Citizenship and Community Agreement among the Settlers of Exeter, New Hampshire (1639) Combination of the Inhabitants of the Piscataqua River for Government (1641) Robert Cushman, The Sin and Danger of Self-Love (1621) Fundamental Agreement, or Original Constitution of the Colony of New Haven (1639) Fundamental Orders of Connecticut (1639) Patrick Henry, Give Me Liberty Speech (1775) William Livingston, “The Vanity of Birth and Titles” (1753) Oath of a Freeman in Massachusetts Bay (1632) Thomas Tryon, The Planter’s Speech to His Neighbors and Countrymen (1684) IV. Equality and Status Address of the Mechanics of New York City (1776) Jonathan Boucher, Sermon on the Peace (1763) Charles Inglis, The True Interest of America (1776) William Knox, Three Tracts Respecting the Conversion (1768) William Byrd, Letter to Lord Egmont (1736) Samuel Sewall, The Selling of Joseph (1700) John Saffin, A Brief and Candid Answer (1701) John Woolman Some Considerations on Keeping Negroes (1762) V.
    [Show full text]
  • Indiana Magazine of History
    INDIANA MAGAZINE OF HISTORY ’Volume XLV SEPTEMBER,1949 Number 3 The Heroic Age of the Social Sciences Robert S. Fletcher* History, political theory, and economics were not wholly neglected even in the colonial colleges. But history was chiefly treated as the handmaiden of theology and the Greek and Latin classics, while economic and political matters were dealt with in the courses in moral philosophy and ethics. The American Revolution and the experience of constitu- tion-making gave a great impetus to the study of politics. In 1779, Thomas Jefferson was instrumental in bringing about a notable revision of the curriculum of William and Mary College whereby more emphasis was placed upon political studies; by 1792 a knowIedge of “NationaI Law, Law of Nations, and the general principles of politics” was required for graduation. Other colleges followed this example. In the two succeeding generations the Federalist was listed as a text in many catalogs, and Locke, Rousseau, Montesquieu, and the Declaration of Independence were often included in required reading. New books on moral philosophy appeared with an ex- panded political emphasis. In 1795 a professor at Columbia published a Systematic Treatise on Moral Philosophy: Com- prehending the Law of Nature-Ethics-Natural Jurispru- dence-General Economy-Politics-and the Lnw of Nations which he optimistically hoped would “inflame the American youth with a true love for their country.”’ The first rumblings of the industrial revolution produced a greater emphasis on economics (or political economy, as it wag called). Adam Smith’s famous but wordy and difficult *Robert S. Fletcher is .a member of the history department at Oberlin College, Oberlin Oho.
    [Show full text]
  • PROFESSIONALIZING ECONOMICS: the 'Marginalist Revolution' in Historical Context Michael A. Bernstein Department of History 0
    PROFESSIONALIZING ECONOMICS: The ‘Marginalist Revolution’ in Historical Context Michael A. Bernstein Department of History 0104 University of California, San Diego 9500 Gilman Drive La Jolla, California 92093-0104 [USA] [Phone: 858-534-1070] [Fax: 858-534-7283] [[email protected]] 2 Economic analysis, serving for two centuries to win an understanding of the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, has been fobbed off with another bride -- a Theory of Value. There were no doubt deep-seated political reasons for the substitution but there was also a purely technical, intellectual reason. -- Joan Robinson [1956]i If the last years of the nineteenth century witnessed the first, genuine articulation of a professional self-consciousness among American economists, then they also demarcated the establishment of an altogether novel protocol for those experts. This new agenda, developed with increasing rigor and authority as the twentieth century beckoned, began a significant reorientation of the field's object of study while at the same time it reconfigured long-standing perceptions of the history of economic thought as a whole. Scientific sophistication necessarily involved a revision of practice, yet it also encouraged the articulation of new perceptions of its pedigree.ii Linking the object of study with particular and venerable authorities from the ages was of singular importance to the successful construction of a distinctly professional knowledge. Framing that understanding in a particular way was the result of both a social and an intellectual process. With their most apparent and seemingly immediate intellectual roots in the moral philosophy of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, modern economists were (and are) eager to invoke validation by impressive forebears and traditions.
    [Show full text]
  • Microfilmed 1996 Information to Users
    UMI MICROFILMED 1996 INFORMATION TO USERS This manuscript has been reproduced from the microfilm master. UMI films the text directly from the original or copy submitted. Thus, some thesis and dissertation copies are in typewriter face, while others may be from any type of computer printer. The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations and photographs, print bleedthrough, substandard margins, and improper alignment can adversely affect reproduction. In the unlikely event that the author did not send UMI a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized copyright material had to be removed, a note wilt indicate the deletion. Oversize materials (e.g., maps, drawings, charts) are reproduced by sectioning the original, beginning at the upper left-hand comer and continuing from left to right in equal sections with small overlaps. Bach original is also photographed in one exposure and is included in reduced form at the back of the book. Photographs included in the original manuscript have been reproduced xerographically in this copy. Higher quality 6" x 9" black and white photographic prints are available for any photographs or illustrations appearing in this copy for an additional charge. Contact UMI directly to order. UMI A Bell & Howell Information Company 300 North Zed> Road, Ann Aibor MI 48106-1346 USA 313/761-4700 800/321-0600 LESSONS FOR THE DESIGN OF INTERCONNECTION PRICING POLICY IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY: A POLICY LEARNING APPROACH DISSERTATION Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate School of The Ohio State University By Hyon Kun Kwok, B.A., M.P.A.
    [Show full text]
  • Walton Hamilton, Amherst, and the Brookings
    WALTON HAMILTON, AMHERST, AND THE BROOKINGS GRADUATE SCHOOL: INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS AND EDUCATION. Malcolm Rutherford University of Victoria (This Draft September 2001) The research for this paper made extensive use of the Brookings Institution Archives, and the Walton Hamilton papers at the Tarlton Law Library at the University of Texas. I also benefited from access to the Archives of the War Labor Policies Board at the National Archives, College Park, Maryland; the Morris A Copeland and Carter Goodrich papers at the Rare Book and Manuscript Library, Columbia University; the Clarence Ayres papers at the Center for American History at the University of Texas; the H. C. Adams and I. Leo Sharfman papers at the Bentley Historical Library, University of Michigan; the Isador Lubin, Rexford Tugwell, and Mordecai Ezekiel papers at the Franklin D. Roosevelt Library, Hyde Park, New York, and the Archives of the Laura Spelman Rockefeller Memorial at the Rockefeller Archive Center, Sleepy Hollow, New York. My thanks also to the Amherst College Archives and Special Collections for information on course offerings, to my research assistant, Cristobal Young, for biographical research, and to Mark Perlman, Robert Whaples, Sherry Kasper, Roger Backhouse, and Julian Reiss for useful information and comments. Any errors are my responsibility. This research has been supported by a Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada Research Grant (project # 410-99-0465). 1 1. Introduction This paper is a small part of a larger project concerning the
    [Show full text]
  • Religion and Evolution in Progressive Era Political Economy: Adversaries Or Allies? Thomas C
    Religion and Evolution in Progressive Era Political Economy: Adversaries or Allies? Thomas C. Leonard Of the several influences on early Progressive Era American political economy, two stand out, evangelical Protestantism and evolutionary sci- ence.1 Scholarly and popular accounts alike have tended to make sci- ence and religion antagonists, no more so than with the conflict they find between evangelical Protestantism and evolutionary science, as exem- plified by accounts of the 1925 Scopes trial.2 But evangelical Protestant- ism and evolutionary science comfortably coexisted in Progressive Era American political economy. Leading progressive3 economists, not least Correspondence may be addressed to Thomas C. Leonard, Department of Economics, Fisher Hall, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ 08544; e-mail: [email protected]. This essay benefited from the constructive criticism of several distinguished scholars. I especially wish to acknowledge the comments of Marie Griffith and Wallace Best, as well as those of the participants in the American Religious History seminar at Princeton University. 1. The term evangelical can be elusive. In the nineteenth-century American context it refers less to a specific group or church than to a set of widely held Protestant commitments: (1) the need for conversion (being “born again”), (2) the authority of the Bible, (3) an empha- sis on the sacrifice and resurrection of Jesus Christ, and (4) activism, in the form of mission- ary or social work (Bebbington 1989, 2–3). 2. The concept of religion and science in conflict can be found in late-Victorian-era books such as John William Draper’s History of the Conflict between Science and Religion (1875) and Andrew Dickson White’s A History of the Warfare of Science with Theology in Christen- dom (1896).
    [Show full text]
  • Progressive-Eva Economists and the Intellectual
    ENVISIONING THE MODERN AMERICAN FISCAL STATE: PROGRESSIVE-ERA ECONOMISTS AND THE INTELLECTUAL FOUNDATIONS OF THE U.S. INCOME TAX Ajay K. Mehrotra* At the turn of the twentieth century, the U.S. system of public finance underwent a dramatic, structural transformation. The late nineteenth-century system of indirect taxes, associated mainly with the tariff, was eclipsed in the early decades of the twentieth century by a progressive income tax. This shift in U.S. tax policy marked the emergence of a new fiscal polity-one that was guided not simply by the functional and structural need for government revenue but by concerns for equity and economic and socialjustice. This Article explores the paradigm shift in legal and economic theories that undergirded this dramatic shift in U.S. tax policy. More specifically, this Article contends that a particular group of academic economists played a pivotal role in supplanting the "benefits theory" of taxation, and its concomitant vision of the state as a passive protector of private property, with a more equitable principle of taxation based on one's "ability to pay"--a principle that promoted a more active role for the state in the dis- tribution of fiscal burdens. In facilitating this structural transformation, these theorists were able to use the growing concentration of wealth and the ascendancy of new economic ideas as justifications for using a progressive income tax to reallocate the burdens of financing the burgeoning American regulatory, administrative, and welfare state. INTRO D UC TION ........................................................................................................... 1794 I. THE OLD FISCAL ORDER AND ITS GRADUAL DEMISE ........................................... 1803 II. THE PROGRESSIVE PUBLIC FINANCE ECONOMISTS ..............................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Intellectual Legacy of Progressive Economics: a Review Essay of Thomas C
    Journal of Economic Literature 2017, 55(3), 1064–1083 https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20171436 The Intellectual Legacy of Progressive Economics: A Review Essay of Thomas C. Leonard’s Illiberal Reformers† Marshall I. Steinbaum and Bernard A. Weisberger* Thomas Leonard’s 2016 book Illiberal Reformers: Race, Eugenics, and American Economics in the Progressive Era argues that exclusionary views on eugenics, race, immigration, and gender taint the intellectual legacy of progressive economics and economists. This review essay reconsiders that legacy and places it in the context within which it developed. While the early generations of scholars who founded the economics profession in the United States and trained in its departments did indeed hold and express retrograde views on those subjects, those views were common to a broad swath of the intellectual elite of that era, including the progressives’ staunchest opponents inside and outside academia. Moreover, Leonard anachronistically intermingles a contemporary critique of early-twentieth-century progressive economics and the progressive movement writ large, serving to decontextualize those disputes—a flaw that is amplified by the book’s unsystematic approach to reconstructing the views and writing it attacks. Notwithstanding the history Leonard presents, economists working now nonetheless owe their progressive forebears for contributions that have become newly relevant: the “credibility revolution,” the influence of economic research on policy and program design, the prestige of economists working in and providing advice to government agencies and policy makers, and the academic freedom economists enjoy in modern research-oriented universities are all a part of that legacy. (JEL A11, B15, D82, J15, N31, N32) 1.
    [Show full text]
  • American Historical Association
    j '. j ~ '. " ANNUAL REPORT I If, " .... ' OF THE " :l AMERICAN HISTORICAL ASSOCIATION FOR THE YEAR 1904. WASHINGTON: GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE. 1905. , .. j ,~~ ;J"'. ·4. t If . .' .,~ LETTER OF SUB~lITTAL. SMITHSONIAN INSTI'l'UTION, lV ashington, D.O., i1l arch 18, 1905. To tlw Congress of the United States: In accordance with the act of incorporation of the Arneri­ can Historical AssociatioIl) approved'.Tanuary 4,1889, I have the honor to submit to Congress the annual report of that Association for the year 11.)0-1:. I have the honor to be, very respectfully, your obedient servant, S. P. LANGLEY, Secretm'y of the Smithsonian Institution. Hon. CHARLES 'lV. FAIRBANKS) Vice-President of the United States. 3 ., .. ;".. ACT OF INCORPORATION. Be -it enacted by tlw Senate and ilO1lse of Representatives of tile United States of America in Oongress assembled, That Andrew D. ,\Vhite, of Ithaca, in the State of New York; George Bancroft, of '\Yashington, in the District of Colum­ bia; Justin ,\Vinsor, of Cambridge, in the State of Massachu­ setts; William F. Poole, of Chicago, in the State of Illinois; Herbert B. Adams, of Baltimore, in the State of Maryland; Clarence 'V. Bowen, of Brooklyn, in the State of N ew York; their associates and successors, are hereby created, in the District of Columbia, a body corporate and politic, by the name of the American Historical Association, for the pro­ motion of historical studies, the collection and preservation of historical manuscripts, and for kindred purposes in the interest of American history and of history in America. Said Association is authorized to hold real and personal estate in the District of Columbia so tar ouly as may be nec­ essary to its lawful ends to an amount not exceeding five hundred thousand dollars, to adopt a constitution, and to make by-laws not inconsistent with law.
    [Show full text]
  • Fragmentation of Public Domain Law and Policy: an Alternative to the Shift-To-Retention Thesis
    Volume 39 Issue 4 Fall 1999 Fall 1999 Fragmentation of Public Domain Law and Policy: An Alternative to the Shift-to-Retention Thesis Leigh Raymond Sally K. Fairfax Recommended Citation Leigh Raymond & Sally K. Fairfax, Fragmentation of Public Domain Law and Policy: An Alternative to the Shift-to-Retention Thesis, 39 Nat. Resources J. 649 (1999). Available at: https://digitalrepository.unm.edu/nrj/vol39/iss4/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at UNM Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Natural Resources Journal by an authorized editor of UNM Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]. LEIGH RAYMOND & SALLY K. FAIRFAX" Fragmentation of Public Domain Law and Policy: An Alternative to the "Shift-to-Retention" Thesis" ABSTRACT Conventional wisdom asserts that after a century of disposition, Congress changed course and began retaining land in federal ownership during the Progressive Era. This "shift narrative" shapes our understandingof conservation history and federal land holdings in the Western United States. Unfortunately, it is largely incorrect. We propose an alternative narrative that emphasizes instead a fragmentationof policy. Fragmentationgrew in part out of changes in the nation'spolitical economy after the Civil War. Expanding centralgovernment power in some cases underwrote federal ownership of natural resources. However, the diverse priorities of increasingly effective corporate interests and scien- tific/professional groups assured a fragmentation of policy. Fragmentationalso blossomed when Progressive Era theories of property began to gain support. These more social and utilitarian views of ownership did not replace their Lockean antecedents, but simply supplemented and confused American ideas of ownership.
    [Show full text]
  • American Economic Reform in the Progressive Era: Its Foundational Beliefs and Their Relation to Eugenics Thomas C
    American Economic Reform in the Progressive Era: Its Foundational Beliefs and Their Relation to Eugenics Thomas C. Leonard It is a Whiggish temptation to regard progressive thought of a century ago as akin to contemporary progressivism.1 But, befi tting the protean nature of the American reform tradition, the original progressives enter- tained views that today’s progressives, if they knew of them, would reject as decidedly unprogressive (Gerstle 1994). In particular, the progressives of a century ago viewed the industrial poor and other economically mar- ginal groups with great ambivalence. Progressive Era economic reform saw the poor as victims in need of uplift but also as threats requiring social control, a fundamental tension that manifested itself most conspicu- ously in the appeal to inferior heredity as a scientifi c basis for distinguish- ing the poor worthy of uplift from the poor who should be regarded as threats to economic health and well-being. So, while progressives did advocate for labor, they also depicted many groups of workers as undeserving of uplift, indeed as the cause rather than the consequence of low wages (Leonard 2003b). While progressives did advocate for women’s rights, they also promoted a vision of economic and family life that would remove women from the labor force, the better to meet women’s obligations to be “mothers of the race,” and to defer to Correspondence may be addressed to Thomas (Tim) Leonard, Department of Economics, Princeton University, Fisher Hall, Princeton, N.J. 08544; e-mail: [email protected]. 1. In contemporary American political discourse, the label “progressive” is increasingly substituted for the label “liberal” (Nunberg 2006).
    [Show full text]
  • Progressive-Era Economists and the Intellectual Foundations of the U.S
    Maurer School of Law: Indiana University Digital Repository @ Maurer Law Articles by Maurer Faculty Faculty Scholarship 2005 Envisioning the Modern American Fiscal State: Progressive-Era Economists and the Intellectual Foundations of the U.S. Income Tax Ajay K. Mehrotra Indiana University Maurer School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/facpub Part of the Law and Economics Commons, and the Taxation-Federal Commons Recommended Citation Mehrotra, Ajay K., "Envisioning the Modern American Fiscal State: Progressive-Era Economists and the Intellectual Foundations of the U.S. Income Tax" (2005). Articles by Maurer Faculty. Paper 289. http://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/facpub/289 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Articles by Maurer Faculty by an authorized administrator of Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ENVISIONING THE MODERN AMERICAN FISCAL STATE: PROGRESSIVE-ERA ECONOMISTS AND THE INTELLECTUAL FOUNDATIONS OF THE U.S. INCOME TAX Ajay K. Mehrotra* At the turn of the twentieth century, the U.S. system of public finance underwent a dramatic, structural transformation. The late nineteenth-century system of indirect taxes, associated mainly with the tariff, was eclipsed in the early decades of the twentieth century by a progressive income tax. This shift in U.S. tax policy marked the emergence of a new fiscal polity-one that was guided not simply by the functional and structural need for government revenue but by concerns for equity and economic and socialjustice.
    [Show full text]