Taxation in China

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Taxation in China Taxation in China I. Corporate Income Tax The long-awaited Corporate Income Tax (EIT) Law, passed by the National People's Congress in March 2007 and effective on January 1, 2008, brings the most significant change in China’s tax regime since the turnover tax reform in 1994. The new regime unifies two separate enterprise income tax regimes for domestic enterprises and foreign-invested enterprises (FIEs) into a single regime of 25% income tax rate. In addition, the law fundamentally changes China’s tax incentive scheme from one based largely on geography to one based on the country's latest industrial and economic development goals. 2009 was the year where the Chinese government spent more effort on EIT law enforcement. The new regime has a clear negative implication on FIEs. As most foreign investors enjoy preferential taxation rates of 24% or below, this will actually lead to increased EIT liabilities for foreign enterprises. Furthermore, tax reform will also mean the end of income tax “holidays” for foreign investors, and while preferential policies for those that invest in interior provinces or high-tech industries might remain, many foreign manufacturers along China’s coast will be impacted. Moreover, a new department, Large Enterprise Tax Administration Department ("LEAD"), was formed by the end of 2008 to focus on the tax administration of large enterprises, including many multinational companies which used to experience inconsistency in tax administration in different locations of China. Quick Glance • China’s new Enterprise Income Tax (EIT) Law stipulates a 25% income tax rate for both foreign and domestic enterprises. • The EIT Law eliminates many of the tax incentives available under the previous tax regime. • New incentives are largely based on preferences for certain industries. As the “grand-fathering” principle will apply, foreign investors that establish entities prior to the tax reform will continue to benefit from their preferential policies for another five years after the tax reform is implemented. These old FIEs will see their tax increasing in a phase-in schedule. Transition from Old to New Tax Rates Old rates New rates Transition 33% 25% Change took place on January 1, 2008 24% 25% Change took place on January 1, 2008 15% 25% The rates will gradually increase as follows: 2008 18% 2009 20% 2010 22% Taxation in China October 2009 | Page 1 2011 24% 2012 25% Under the old tax regime, FIEs could take advantage of several tax incentives, based on location, industry, size, and other criteria. The new regime eliminates many of these incentives and instead adopts a predominantly industry-oriented, limited geography-based tax incentive policy aimed at directing investments into industrial sectors and projects that the Chinese government encourages. The EIT Law clearly reflects the Chinese government’s focus on technological development, environmental protection, energy conservation, production safety, venture capital, and investment in agriculture, forestry, animal husbandry, fisheries, and infrastructure development. For the foreign invested High- and new-tech enterprises (HNTEs), for instance, there is a reduced tax rate of 15% instead of 25%. But, with the tightening of EIT, a set of working guidelines, detailing the six criteria for the assessment of NHTE was implemented in 2009. The NHTE, which used to be one of the key tax incentives established by China, was set with more hurdles and was much more difficult for foreign investors to get qualified than in previous years. Another key movement in the EIT regulatory system is that the tax authority is tightening control over cross-boarder transfer pricing activities in big multinational companies. Related party transactions with oversea parent company or intercompany are closely monitored by local tax bureau. Simple transfer of profit to tax saving vehicles in BVI or Hong Kong or other similar “tax heavens” (e.g. through payment of management fee) are far less effective and becoming costly when tax authority could charge double taxing on this type of activities. II. Withholding Tax (“WT”) FEs which obtain income through interest, rental (finance lease, operating lease), sales (land, buildings) royalties (trademarks, copyrights, patents) and other income are liable to Withholding Tax on that income at a rate of 10% (20% under the New Law). Gains on the sale or transfer of an investment in the PRC by an FE are also subject to withholding tax, and has implications for M&A. Dividends paid or profits distributed by an FIE to foreign investors are exempt from withholding tax. The Withholding Tax due should be identified on the invoice of the China based entity in order for them to “withhold” this tax and then remit it to the relevant tax authorities. FIEs should be careful when they are using sub-contractors: interests, rent or royalty charges payable to a FE pursuant to the related contracts or agreements that have been accrued in costs or expenses are considered to be a payment of the charges to the recipient for WT purposes. Accordingly, the liability of the FE to remit WT to the relevant tax authorities within the prescribed time limit would be triggered at that point, regardless of whether the amount of charges has actually been paid to the FE. WT is normally deductible against income in the home country based on double taxation treaties (Italy has a taxation treaty with China, signed on the 31st October 1986 and effective on the 1st January 1990). Taxation in China October 2009 | Page 2 III. Value Added Tax (“VAT”) In some more developed countries, Corporate and Individual Income Tax account for the majority of fiscal revenue. However, China relies heavily on indirect taxes, and thus FIEs, FEs and domestic enterprises pay either VAT or Business Tax depending on the nature of their business and the type of products involved. VAT is levied on the importation, production, distribution and retailing of “taxable goods”, and the provision of labor services in relation to the processing of goods and of repair and replacement of goods. “Taxable goods” refers to tangible goods and utilities (electricity, thermal power and gas), but excludes: equipment and machinery required to be imported under contract processing, contract assembly and compensation trade, certain products (contraceptive medicines and devices, self-produced agricultural products sold by agricultural producers, antique books), and imported materials and equipment directly used in scientific research, experiment and education. The normal VAT rate is 17%, but a reduced rate of 13% applies fro certain products. VAT payable is calculated on the basis of the value added to the taxable goods and services at each stage of a production chain, and equals the output VAT for the period minus the input VAT for the period, where output VAT refers to the VAT amount collected by the taxpayer from the buyer at the point of sale, and input VAT refers to the VAT amount paid by the taxpayer at the point of purchase, both calculated on the basis of price exclusive of VAT. If the output VAT for the period is less than, and insufficient to offset against the input VAT for the period, then the excess can be carried forward for setoff in the following period. One key development in China’s VAT system was the permission to credit VAT on capital investment against consumption VAT. Previously the capital investment such as purchase cost of fixed assets are excluded from the calculation of input VAT. The renewed VAT Interim Regulation was effective on 1 January 2009. Goods imported into China are subject to import VAT based on their combined CIF plus Customs Duty value. VAT liability arises on the date when import is declared, and collected by the customs office on behalf of the tax authorities. For the sales of “taxable goods” and “taxable services”, VAT liability arises on the date when the sales sum is received or the documented evidence of the sales sum obtained. Enterprises regarded as small businesses (annual production sales of less than RMB1 million or annual wholesale or retail sales of less than RMB1.8 million) are subject to VAT at the rate of 6%, but unlike other VAT payers, are not entitled to claim input tax credits for the VAT paid on their purchases. IV. Business Tax (“BT”) FIEs, FEs and domestic enterprises may be liable BT instead of VAT, depending on the business or assets involved. BT is payable by enterprises that provided taxable services, assign intangible assets, and sell real estate. Taxation in China October 2009 | Page 3 BT is levied on gross turnover at rates of between 3% and 20%. The most common rates are 3% (construction, cultural activities and sport, post and telecommunication, transportation) and 5% (assignment of intangible assets, sale of real estate, financial & insurance services, and other normal services). In addition, 10% is levied on some leisure services (dancing halls, bars, karaokes) and 15% on others (video game halls, billiard halls, bowling alleys, golf courses). In some areas (normally smaller towns), local government authorities may return part of the BT levied, similar to VAT. V. Consumption Tax (“CT”) CT is levied on manufacturers and importers of specified categories of consumer goods (tobacco, alcoholic beverages, ethyl alcohol, cosmetics, skin and hair care products, jewellery, fireworks, gasoline and diesel, automobile tyres, motorcycles and small automobiles) at rates ranging from 3% to 50%. CT is imposed in addition to applicable customs duties and VAT. In some areas (normally smaller towns), local government authorities may return part of the CT levied, similar to VAT and BT. VI. Customs Duties Products and raw materials imported into China are first subject to Customs Duties based on their CIF value. Duty rates vary depending on the classification of the goods, and these rates vary significantly, although they are normally between 10% and 20%.
Recommended publications
  • 1 Progressive Taxation in Developing Economies
    1 Progressive Taxation in Developing Economies: The Experience of China and India By Michael A. Livingston1 The concept of fairness in taxation is as old as the Bible, and applies to young or developing economies no less than large industrial democracies. Yet the debate on progressive (and especially progressive income) taxation has been conducted primarily in the wealthier countries. This results in part from experience: the most advanced and frequently studied progressive tax systems have been in developed countries, and the principal theoretical work was done in them. There is also a certain condescension here, a sense that poorer countries can perhaps not afford too much progressivity, and should content themselves with the collection of sufficient tax revenues—no small task in its own right—without indulging the “luxury” of a progressive or redistributive tax system. Yet tax equity is an issue that applies to all societies, and there is no inherent reason that it should be less important in a new or developing country than a more established nation. This paper considers the issue of progressive taxation and tax equity in younger, developing economies. The issue being extremely broad, it is necessary at the outset to impose some limitations. Thus I will limit myself to tax rather than spending policy and, within the tax system, provide special emphasis on progressive income taxes, although I am well aware that the income tax is only one of several revenue sources and, in many developing countries, is less important than other, less high-profile taxes. I will likewise eschew a statistical evaluation of progressivity, which I am in any case ill-equipped to do, in favor of an abstract but I hope engaging discussion of the issue in theoretical terms.
    [Show full text]
  • Ecotaxes: a Comparative Study of India and China
    Ecotaxes: A Comparative Study of India and China Rajat Verma ISBN 978-81-7791-209-8 © 2016, Copyright Reserved The Institute for Social and Economic Change, Bangalore Institute for Social and Economic Change (ISEC) is engaged in interdisciplinary research in analytical and applied areas of the social sciences, encompassing diverse aspects of development. ISEC works with central, state and local governments as well as international agencies by undertaking systematic studies of resource potential, identifying factors influencing growth and examining measures for reducing poverty. The thrust areas of research include state and local economic policies, issues relating to sociological and demographic transition, environmental issues and fiscal, administrative and political decentralization and governance. It pursues fruitful contacts with other institutions and scholars devoted to social science research through collaborative research programmes, seminars, etc. The Working Paper Series provides an opportunity for ISEC faculty, visiting fellows and PhD scholars to discuss their ideas and research work before publication and to get feedback from their peer group. Papers selected for publication in the series present empirical analyses and generally deal with wider issues of public policy at a sectoral, regional or national level. These working papers undergo review but typically do not present final research results, and constitute works in progress. ECOTAXES: A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF INDIA AND CHINA1 Rajat Verma2 Abstract This paper attempts to compare various forms of ecotaxes adopted by India and China in order to reduce their carbon emissions by 2020 and to address other environmental issues. The study contributes to the literature by giving a comprehensive definition of ecotaxes and using it to analyse the status of these taxes in India and China.
    [Show full text]
  • Taxation and Income Inequality in Nigeria
    http://afr.sciedupress.com Accounting and Finance Research Vol. 8, No. 3; 2019 Taxation and Income Inequality in Nigeria John Obiora Anyaduba1 & Praise Oghenefejiro Otulugbu1 1Department of Accounting, Faculty of Management Sciences, University of Benin, Nigeria. Correspondence: John Obiora Anyaduba, Department of Accounting, Faculty of Management Sciences, University of Benin, Nigeria. E-mail: [email protected] Received: July 4, 2019 Accepted: July 19, 2019 Online Published: July 25, 2019 doi:10.5430/afr.v8n3p118 URL: https://doi.org/10.5430/afr.v8n3p118 Abstract The study examined taxation and income inequality (GINI), specifically, it determined the impact of Value Added Tax (VAT), Custom and Excise Duties (CED), Petroleum Profit Tax (PPT) and Company Income Tax (CIT) on GINI in Nigeria from the year 1990 to 2016. The Cointegration and Error Correction Models (ECMs) were used to analyze the data. Augmented Dickey Fuller unit root was used to test for stationarity. Data were sourced from the Central Bank of Nigerian statistical bulletin, Federal Inland Revenue Service and the National Bureau of Statistics. The result revealed that VAT, CED and PPT had positive relationship with GINI when measured at 5% critical level, though VAT and CED were not significant. CIT had a negative but significant impact on GINI. Based on the findings, we conclude that only CIT was able to reduce income inequality. We therefore recommend that VAT should be imposed on goods and services consumed by high income earners. In respect of CED, government should address the level of tariffs; for PPT, there is need for adequate diversification of the economy; and for CIT, tax authority should harness corporate taxes to its fullness.
    [Show full text]
  • Conspicuous Compassion and Taxation: a Reality
    Asian Review of Social Sciences ISSN: 2249-6319 Vol.7 No.3, 2018, pp. 80-85 © The Research Publication, www.trp.org.in Conspicuous Compassion and Taxation: A Reality Mudaser Ahad Bhat1 and Binish Qadri2 1&2Research Scholar, Department of Economics, Central University of Kashmir, Jammu and Kashmir, India E-Mail: [email protected], [email protected] Abstract - In modern public-finance literature, many canons or development activities such as health, education, sanitation, principles have been followed for tax policies, ‘ability rural development, water supply etc. It has to be principle’ (Pigou, 1933), ‘benefit principle’ (Lindahl as cited by compensated for its own administration. All these functions Roberts, J, 1989). Under the benefit theory, tax levels are necessitate huge public finance. Taxes constitute the main automatically determined and therefore self-loaded, because source of public finance whereby government raises taxpayers pay proportionately for the government benefits they receive. In other words, the individuals who benefit the revenue for public expenditure. most from public services pay most of the taxes (Lindahl model,). The present paper highlights that conspicuous In the present-day world, taxation is not just a way to compassion and taxation go hand in hand especially in case of handover money to the government to meet the public rich people but not in case of poor people and as result in expenditures or raise revenue to the government, but have modern societies tax levels are not self-loaded, a claim made by become a potent tool to lessen demand in the private sector, benefit principle. Along with proportionate benefit principle redistribute income and wealth in the civilizations in the ‘conspicuous compassion in favour of rich people’ is also in countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Taxing Energy Use 2019: Country Note – China
    CHINA 1 │ Taxing Energy Use 2019: Country Note – China This note explains how China taxes energy use. The note shows the distribution of effective energy tax rates – the sum of fuel excise taxes, explicit carbon taxes, and electricity excise taxes, net of applicable exemptions, rate reductions, and refunds – across all domestic energy use. It also details the country-specific assumptions made when calculating effective energy tax rates and matching tax rates to the corresponding energy base. The note complements the Taxing Energy Use 2019 report that is available at http://oe.cd/TEU2019. The report analyses where OECD and G20 countries stand in deploying energy and carbon taxes, tracks progress made, and makes actionable recommendations on how governments could do better to use taxes to reach environmental and climate goals. The general methodology employed to calculate effective energy tax rates and assign tax rates to the energy base is explained in Chapter 1 of the report. The official energy tax profile for China can be found in Chapter 2 of the report. Chapter 3 additionally shows effective carbon tax rates per tonne of CO2, and presents the corresponding carbon tax profiles for all countries. The report also contains StatLinks to the official data. Structure of energy taxation in China In China, the Refined Oil Excise Tax (成品油消费税) applies to gasoline, naphtha, solvent and lubricating oil at a uniform rate of CNY 1.52 per litre, as well as to diesel, and fuel oil at a uniform rate of CNY 1.2 per litre. Revenues are earmarked for transport funding and green purposes.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal Federalism in Chinese Taxation Wei Cui Allard School of Law at the University of British Columbia, [email protected]
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Allard Research Commons (Peter A. Allard School of Law) The Peter A. Allard School of Law Allard Research Commons Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship 2011 Fiscal Federalism in Chinese Taxation Wei Cui Allard School of Law at the University of British Columbia, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://commons.allard.ubc.ca/fac_pubs Part of the Tax Law Commons Citation Details Wei Cui, "Fiscal Federalism in Chinese Taxation" (2011) 3 World Tax J 455. This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Allard Research Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of Allard Research Commons. Wei Cui* Fiscal Federalism in Chinese Taxation1 The recent policy literature on fiscal federalism in China has concentrated on the large “vertical fiscal gap” resulting in inadequate local provision of public goods and services. Thus there is an evident interest in giving local governments more taxing powers. After a brief historical survey, the article discusses a 1993 State Council directive that centralized taxing power. This has led local governments to make use of their control over tax administration to alter effective tax rates, and to the practice of “refund after collection”, whereby local governments disguise tax cuts as expenditures, following a logic opposite to tax expenditures. This study concludes, firstly, that the allocation of taxing power is still done outside the framework of the law, and secondly, that the government has not been able to settle on a stable allocation.
    [Show full text]
  • Development and Tax Policy: Case Study of China Jinyan Li Osgoode Hall Law School of York University, [email protected]
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by York University, Osgoode Hall Law School Osgoode Hall Law School of York University Osgoode Digital Commons Research Papers, Working Papers, Conference Comparative Research in Law & Political Economy Papers Research Report No. 27/2007 Development and Tax Policy: Case Study of China Jinyan Li Osgoode Hall Law School of York University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.osgoode.yorku.ca/clpe Recommended Citation Li, Jinyan, "Development and Tax Policy: Case Study of China" (2007). Comparative Research in Law & Political Economy. Research Paper No. 27/2007. http://digitalcommons.osgoode.yorku.ca/clpe/243 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Research Papers, Working Papers, Conference Papers at Osgoode Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Comparative Research in Law & Political Economy by an authorized administrator of Osgoode Digital Commons. CLPE RESEARCH PAPER 27/2007 Jinyan Li Development and Tax Policy: Case Study of China EDITORS: Peer Zumbansen (Osgoode Hall Law School, Toronto, Director, Comparative Research in Law and Political Economy, York University), John W. Cioffi (University of California at Riverside), Lindsay Krauss (Osgoode Hall Law School, Toronto, Production Editor) CLPE Research Paper 27/2007 Vol. 03 No. 04 (2007) Jinyan Li DEVELOPMENT AND TAX POLICY: CASE STUDY OF CHINA Abstract: This paper examines the role of tax policy in China’s economic, social and legal development. With respect to economic development, the author examines the use of tax incentives in attracting foreign direct investment to China and assesses its impact on the development of China’s market economy.
    [Show full text]
  • China Tax in the Digital Age
    China tax in the digital age Issue 1 – China’s digital economy becomes the economy itself kpmg.com/cn Contents Introduction 2 The state of the digital economy today 4 Key challenges to cross-border tax rules from the digital 10 economy - Nexus Key challenges to cross-border tax rules from the digital 14 economy – Digital form of products and characterisation of income Key challenges to cross-border tax rules from the digital 17 economy – Use of data/value creation How KPMG China can help 20 KPMG China contacts 21 © 2016 KPMG, a Hong Kong partnership and a member firm of the KPMG network of independent member firms affiliated with KPMG International Cooperative (“KPMG International”), a Swiss entity. All rights reserved. This is the first in a series of publications, referred to collectively as China tax in the digital age, from KPMG China’s Technology, Media and Telecommunications (TMT) division. This series will examine the existing and emerging tax implications of doing business in China’s digital economy. As the Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development (OECD) noted in its recent publication, ‘Addressing the tax challenges of the digital economy’: “the digital economy is increasingly becoming the economy itself.” Nowhere is this more apparent, and perhaps nowhere are the consequences more far-reaching for the rest of the world, than in China. The emergence of many new digital economy business models and their increasing use in cross- border activities has triggered a number of new and complex tax issues for companies operating in the TMT sectors. For direct taxes, as identified by the OECD, three key issues stand out: nexus, characterisation and data/value creation.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rise and Fall of Chinese Tax Incentives and Implications for International Tax Debates Jinyan Li Osgoode Hall Law School of York University, [email protected]
    Osgoode Hall Law School of York University Osgoode Digital Commons Research Papers, Working Papers, Conference Comparative Research in Law & Political Economy Papers Research Report No. 5/2008 The Rise and Fall of Chinese Tax Incentives and Implications for International Tax Debates Jinyan Li Osgoode Hall Law School of York University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.osgoode.yorku.ca/clpe Recommended Citation Li, Jinyan, "The Rise and Fall of Chinese Tax Incentives and Implications for International Tax Debates" (2008). Comparative Research in Law & Political Economy. Research Paper No. 5/2008. http://digitalcommons.osgoode.yorku.ca/clpe/179 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Research Papers, Working Papers, Conference Papers at Osgoode Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Comparative Research in Law & Political Economy by an authorized administrator of Osgoode Digital Commons. CLPE RESEARCH PAPER 05/2008 Jinyan Li The Rise and Fall of Chinese Tax Incentives and Implications for International Tax Debates Forthcoming in 2007 Florida Tax Review EDITORS: Peer Zumbansen (Osgoode Hall Law School, Toronto, Director, Comparative Research in Law and Political Economy, York University), John W. Cioffi (University of California at Riverside), Lindsay Krauss (Osgoode Hall Law School, Toronto, Production Editor) CLPE RESEARCH PAPER XX/2007 • VOL. XX NO. XX (2007) CLPE Research Paper 05/2008 Vol. 04 No. 01 (2008) Jinyan Li THE RISE AND FALL OF CHINESE TAX INCENTIVES AND IMPLICATIONS FOR INTERNATIONAL TAX DEBATES Abstract: China had no foreign direct investment (FDI) before 1979. Now, it is one of the world’s largest recipients of FDI.
    [Show full text]
  • Green Taxation in China: a Possible Consolidated Transport Fuel Tax to Promote Clean Air?
    Fordham Environmental Law Review Volume 21, Number 2 2010 Article 5 Green Taxation in China: A Possible Consolidated Transport Fuel Tax to Promote Clean Air? Xu Yan∗ ∗Fordham University School of Law Copyright c 2010 by the authors. Fordham Environmental Law Review is produced by The Berkeley Electronic Press (bepress). http://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/elr GREEN TAXATION IN CHINA: A POSSIBLE CONSOLIDATED TRANSPORT FUEL TAX TO PROMOTE CLEAN AIR? Xu Yan * I. INTRODUCTION In the 1960s, due to rapid industrial development, a series of grave environmental accidents occurred in a number of countries.' Man- made environmental harms, such as dangerous water and air pollution, destruction and depletion of irreplaceable resources, have posed a major threat to the existence and development of mankind.2 * Post-doctoral Fellow, Faculty of Law, The University of Hong Kong (HKU). The author would like to thank Professor Richard Cullen for his helpful comments. An earlier draft of this paper was presented at the Green Taxation Conference held by the Taxation Law Research Programme (of the HKU Faculty of Law's Asian Institute of International Financial Law) in January, 2010. Papers presented at the Conference will be published, in due course, as a book by Edward Elgar. The author also would like to thank the participants at the Conference for their comments. 1. See, e.g., Neil Gunningham, Environment Law, Regulation and Governance: Shifting Architectures, 21 J. ENVTL. L. 179, 182 (2009) (noting that America saw several environmental disasters in the 1960s, in particular oil spills in California, and the Cuyahoga River fire in 1969 (in Ohio)); Michael C.
    [Show full text]
  • How a Hong Kong Holding Company Can Benefit Foreign Enterprises Doing Business in China: Benefits to Seize and Pitfalls to Avoid
    How a Hong Kong Holding Company Can Benefit Foreign Enterprises Doing Business in China: Benefits to Seize and Pitfalls to Avoid China Business Alert | December 6, 2011 by: Kevin S. Koscil U.S. companies looking to expand internationally must consider complex legal and economic matters to ensure that the benefits of doing business in a foreign country are maximized. One of the primary concerns is to develop an investment structure that can minimize taxes not only on ongoing operations, but also on the repatriation of income to a domestic parent and the ultimate disposition of foreign operations in appropriate circumstances. Moreover, due to the complexity of the U.S. tax laws concerning foreign operations, including the foreign tax credit regime, and rules regarding controlled foreign corporations and personal foreign investment corporations, the choice of a particular legal and tax structure will depend on the specific characteristics of both the domestic company looking to expand overseas as well as the particular activities to be undertaken internationally. Given all of these considerations, we have nevertheless seen that an investment in mainland China is often best undertaken utilizing an intermediary holding company based in Hong Kong. Long regarded as a financial hub and free trade center in Asia, Hong Kong is often chosen by foreign investors as a gateway to investing in China due to Hong Kong’s favorable tax relationship with China, along with its historical, geographical and cultural connections with the mainland. THE IMPORTANCE OF THE CHINA-HONG KONG TREATY Many foreign-invested enterprises enjoyed preferential tax treatment before China enacted the Enterprise Income Tax Law (EITL) on March 16, 2007 (effective January 1, 2008).
    [Show full text]
  • A Global Compendium and Meta-Analysis of Property Tax Systems
    A Global Compendium and Meta-Analysis of Property Tax Systems Richard Almy © 2013 Lincoln Institute of Land Policy Lincoln Institute of Land Policy Working Paper The findings and conclusions of this Working Paper reflect the views of the author(s) and have not been subject to a detailed review by the staff of the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Contact the Lincoln Institute with questions or requests for permission to reprint this paper. [email protected] Lincoln Institute Product Code: WP14RA1 Abstract This report is a global compendium of significant features of systems for recurrently taxing land and buildings. It is based on works in English, many of which were published by the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Its aim is to provide researchers and practitioners with useful infor- mation about these sources and with facts and patterns of system features, revenue statistics, and other data. It reports on systems in 187 countries (twenty-nine countries do not have such taxes; the situation in four countries is unclear). Accompanying the report are an Excel workbook and copies of the works cited when available in digital form. Keywords: Tax on property, recurrent tax on immovable property, property tax, real estate tax, real property tax, land tax, building tax, rates. About the Author Richard Almy is a partner in Almy, Gloudemans, Jacobs & Denne, a US-based consulting firm that works exclusively in property tax administration, chiefly for governments and related insti- tutions. Mr. Almy began his career as an appraiser with the Detroit, Michigan, Board of Asses- sors. Later he served as research director and executive director of the International Association of Assessing Officers (IAAO).
    [Show full text]