Aspects and Characteristics of State-Owned Land in West Africa 1 by Gérard Chouquer , January 2011

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Aspects and Characteristics of State-Owned Land in West Africa 1 by Gérard Chouquer , January 2011 BRIEFING NOTES to improve our understanding and “Land Tenure and Development” Technical Committee ability to ask the right questions and take effective action on land matters in West Africa Aspects and characteristics of State-owned land in West Africa 1 by Gérard Chouquer , January 2011 West African land regimes are W hen we talk about ‘State-owned goods assigned for individual pub- based on particular constructs of land’ we mean the regime for lic use (cemeteries, market places, State-owned land. This paper goods that belong to public bodies. metered parking, etc.); This regime has a long and very rich aims to clarify the different goods allocated for a public serv- history, and encompasses a wide vari- conceptions of State-owned land ice, provided they relate to the ety of realities on different continents. so that we can better assess their public service in question and are implications for land policies and In European countries and their former developed for this purpose (such as understand the nature of this colonies, State-owned land has taken the land needed to build and de- various forms according to the nature velop railways, gas pipelines, elec- type of land in Africa. of the rights held by the public author- tric lines, etc.). ities: semi-feudal (seigneurial), coloni- al, public, private, and so on. But even Depending on the type of use for this historical typology could be im- which it is allocated or the type of proved, and the need for clarifi cation space concerned, public land is cat- is growing as new concepts emerge egorised as maritime, aerial, riverine, in Africa, since the existence of sev- terrestrial, personal or military. eral defi nitions can lead to ambiguity Public land is defi ned in contrast to State land, which refers to the State’s Public lands private assets: goods that belong to the State and which it holds and manag- In many countries, land assets that be- es under the same conditions as goods long to the State but are allocated for held by individuals. Unlike goods in the public use are known as public lands. public domain, those in the private do- Public land assets are covered by a par- main can be transferred, which means ticular regime of public law, which is that the State can rent or sell its own designed to protect and maintain their Production coordinated by: assets to individuals. This category also allocation for public use. Therefore, includes rural land that the State can goods in the public domain are inal- assign to individuals, or urban land that ienable (the State cannot sell them or communes can transfer to individuals transfer their ownership). by parcelling it up and selling it off for Public lands include: development (lotissement). goods designated for collective 1 Gérard Chouquer, Historian, CNRS and France public use, such as roadways and International Expertise Foncière (FIEF): sea shores; [email protected] 2 BRIEFING NOTES to improve our understanding and ability to ask the right questions and take effective action on land matters in West Africa Land monopolies Apparently not content with the clas- sic distinction between public and pri- vate State land, African countries have invented new concepts of State land. These need to be clarified and ex- plained, especially the concept of na- tional lands. The notion of national lands or pub- lic national lands that appeared in the legislation of numerous African coun- tries in the mid-1960s represented a major, but far from homogenous, in- novation. National lands amount to a State monopoly on land since the State holds all or some of the land in the country, not in its own name, but Fouta Djalon, Guinea. Diffuse land occupation creates an appearance of vacant lands. in the name of the nation that it rep- capture of Google earth resents. A. Rochegude and C. Plançon defi ne this kind of land as follows: >> National lands: “A new concept Examples of total State vate local government lands, and frequently used in Africa (or at least monopolies on land land held by other natural and le- francophone Africa), which can cov- gal bodies. Certain countries have opted for com- er a wide range of legal situations. For As in Mali, national lands in Mo- prehensive State ownership of land, example, in Mali national land consti- zambique constitute a broader cat- such as the Fundo Estatal de Terras in tutes a whole legal framework cover- egory than public lands, expressed Mozambique, the Património comun ing every status of land (which means in the concept of Fundo Estatal de de todo o Povo in Guinea Bissau, or that all land is included in this catego- Terras, (Domínio Público). There- the domaine national in Mali. A com- ry), while in Senegal it refers to the sta- fore, public lands should not be parison of the regimes in some of tus of all lands that are not part of the confused with the larger, overarch- these countries clearly illustrates the public domain or any legally appropri- ing category of national lands, to potential for ambiguity in the concept ated holding (that is to say titled pri- which the Mozambican State has of national lands. vate property).” a clear (and unusual) constitution- In Guinea Bissau, the law states If we take this defi nition as our starting al claim, and which encompasses that land is “the property of the point we can envisage two hypotheti- a public domain that is not funda- State and the common heritage cal situations. One where there is a to- mentally different to that of many of the entire population”. The tal monopoly on land, and all lands fall other countries. State may grant individuals private into the legal category of national land; use rights to facilitate productive and the other where there is a partial and social activities on land. This Examples of partial State monopoly, and only certain areas are is mainly done through common monopolies on land incorporated into national lands. This use or by assigning land. concept of national land is usually ac- In some countries certain lands are companied by a system of concessions Mali’s Land Code stipulates that classifi ed as national land (domaine or use rights which regulate the way all land is included in its nation- foncier national or domain national). that the State makes land available for al lands; that is to say, public and This category, which does not cover use by other, mainly individual, actors. private State lands, public and pri- all the land in the country and should Aspects and characteristics of State-owned land in West Africa 3 not be confused with public or private registry” when the law came into belong the State’s public or pri- State lands, includes any land that is force. Therefore, national lands in vate domain. In reality, this means not registered and is therefore consid- Senegal include lands formerly held that national lands are made up of ered vacant and ownerless. This type according to customary principles former customary lands (which are of regime exists in countries such as that the State holds in the name of not registered in the name of the Senegal, Togo, Cameroon and Gabon. the nation in order “to ensure that State or individuals). they are used judiciously and pro- Based on the principles of customary ductively, in accordance with de- land management, this approach to Ideas implicit in the State velopment plans (…)”. land management aims to establish monopoly on land some kind of ‘national land reserves’ With such use in mind, national by incorporating customary lands that lands are classifi ed in four catego- According to H. Ouedraogo, the no- are deemed to be unused or insuf- ries: urban areas, classifi ed areas, tion of ‘national lands’ is tied up with fi ciently used into a ‘national estate’ village lands and pioneer zones. the post-colonial history of the states that can be allocated for rural devel- This last category mainly relates to concerned. opment operations. land that can be developed in ac- >> “Emerging from independ- cordance with development plans; In Senegal, which was the first ence with dreams of economic de- land in these areas is allocated by West African country to enshrine velopment powered by an agricultur- decree to rural communities, co- this concept in law in 1964, na- al base, States in the [West African] operative associations or organisa- tional land automatically includes sub-region preferred to work with land tions created by the government. “all land that is not classifi ed as maps so that they could redistribute being in the public domain, is not In Togo, ‘national lands’ include all land to actors deemed capable of en- registered or whose ownership has land that has not been appropri- gaging with modern methods of ag- not been recorded in the mortgage ated by individuals and does not ricultural production”. The concept of State-owned land was originally unilateral, in that the State Impression of vacancy contradicts with the detailed study of land plots. capture of Google earth could use the notion of vacant lands to decide that it alone had the right Togo Togo to determine how such land is used. Designating land as vacant and incor- porating it into the national domain avoided the need to go through strict and restrictive procedures for expropri- ation on the grounds of public utility. These were the after-effects of coloni- al processes: reasoning based on the colonial regime of registration as the source of all legal land tenure. Every- thing was done as if this had regulat- ed the status of all land that was nor- mally occupied, while other land was deemed to be free and vacant.
Recommended publications
  • A New Politics of the Commons
    Published in Renewal magazine, December 17, 2007. Renewal is a Labour-oriented political journal dedicated to social democracy” published in London. A New Politics of the Commons By David Bollier One of the most stubborn problems in confronting the pathologies of the neoliberal political order is the limitations of our language. We do not have an adequate public vocabulary to describe the plunder of globalized markets. We have trouble highlighting the social inequities that are built into conventional economics and political discourse. We do not have a grand narrative with compelling sub-plots to set forth an alternative vision, one that can both stir the blood and show intellectual sophistication. That’s the bad news. The good news is that there is a brave, decentralized movement on the march that is addressing these problems with ingenuity and patience. The focus of this movement is the commons. The commons is still an embryonic vision. It will require time to evolve. But it is a vision with great potential, perhaps because it is not being advanced by an intellectual elite or a political party, but by a hardy band of resourceful irregulars on the periphery of conventional politics. (That’s always where the most interesting new things originate.) These commoners are now starting to find each other, a convergence that augurs great things. To be a bit more concrete: This proto-commons movement consists of environmentalists trying to protect wilderness areas and win fair compensation for the corporate use of public lands. It includes local communities trying to prevent multinational water companies from privatizing public water works and converting groundwater into over- priced, branded bottles of water.
    [Show full text]
  • The Politics of Indian Property Rights
    Property rights, selective enforcement, and the destruction of wealth on Indian lands Ilia Murtazashvili* University of Pittsburgh Abstract This paper reconceptualizes the nature of property institutions in the United States. Conventional economic analysis suggests that the U.S. established private property rights protection as a public good by the end of the nineteenth century. The experience of Indians suggests otherwise. During the mid-nineteenth century, the economic fortunes of settlers on public lands owned by the United States government and Indians diverged. Settlers secured legal property rights and self-governance, while members of Indian nations were forced into an inequitable property system in which the federal government established an institutionalized system to discriminate against reservation Indians. The property system is most appropriately described as a selective enforcement regime in which some groups enjoy credible and effective property rights at the expense of others who confront a predatory state and institutionalized property insecurity. The persistence of the selective enforcement regime explains the persistence of poverty among reservation Indians. * Email: [email protected]. Paper prepared for the Searle Workshop on “Indigenous Capital, Growth, and Property Rights: The Legacy of Colonialism,” Hoover Institution, Stanford University. Many thanks to Terry Anderson and Nick Parker for organizing the workshop. 1 2 Introduction The United States is often used as an example to illustrate the beneficial consequences of private property rights for economic growth and development. Sokoloff and Engerman (2000) use differences in land policy to explain the reversal of economic fortunes of the U.S. and Spanish America, which started with a similar per capita GDP around 1800 but diverged substantially by the twentieth century.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 4 Freedom and Progress
    Chapter 4 Freedom and Progress The best road to progress is freedom’s road. John F. Kennedy The only freedom which deserves the name, is that of pursuing our own good in our own way, so long as we do not attempt to deprive others of theirs, or impeded their efforts to obtain it. John Stuart Mill To cull the inestimable benefits assured by freedom of the press, it is necessary to put up with the inevitable evils springing therefrom. Alexis de Tocqueville Freedom is necessary to generate progress; people also value freedom as an important component of progress. This chapter will contend that both propositions are correct. Without liberty, there will be little or no progress; most people will consider an expansion in freedom as progress. Neither proposition would win universal acceptance. Some would argue that a totalitarian state can marshal the resources to generate economic growth. Many will contend that too much liberty induces libertine behavior and is destructive of society, peace, and the family. For better or worse, the record shows that freedom has increased throughout the world over the last few centuries and especially over the last few decades. There are of course many examples of non-free, totalitarian, ruthless government on the globe, but their number has decreased and now represents a smaller proportion of the world’s population. Perhaps this growth of freedom is partially responsible for the breakdown of the family and the rise in crime, described in the previous chapter. Dictators do tolerate less crime and are often very repressive of deviant sexual behavior, but, as the previous chapter reported, divorce and illegitimacy are more connected with improved income of women than with a permissive society.
    [Show full text]
  • Mill's "Very Simple Principle": Liberty, Utilitarianism And
    MILL'S "VERY SIMPLE PRINCIPLE": LIBERTY, UTILITARIANISM AND SOCIALISM MICHAEL GRENFELL submitted for degree of Ph.D. London School of Economics and Political Science UMI Number: U048607 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Dissertation Publishing UMI U048607 Published by ProQuest LLC 2014. Copyright in the Dissertation held by the Author. Microform Edition © ProQuest LLC. All rights reserved. This work is protected against unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code. ProQuest LLC 789 East Eisenhower Parkway P.O. Box 1346 Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 I H^S £ S F 6SI6 ABSTRACT OF THESIS MILL'S "VERY SIMPLE PRINCIPLE'*: LIBERTY. UTILITARIANISM AND SOCIALISM 1 The thesis aims to examine the political consequences of applying J.S. Mill's "very simple principle" of liberty in practice: whether the result would be free-market liberalism or socialism, and to what extent a society governed in accordance with the principle would be free. 2 Contrary to Mill's claims for the principle, it fails to provide a clear or coherent answer to this "practical question". This is largely because of three essential ambiguities in Mill's formulation of the principle, examined in turn in the three chapters of the thesis. 3 First, Mill is ambivalent about whether liberty is to be promoted for its intrinsic value, or because it is instrumental to the achievement of other objectives, principally the utilitarian objective of "general welfare".
    [Show full text]
  • Performance Differential Between Private and State-Owned Enterprises: an Analysis of Profitability and Leverage
    ADBI Working Paper Series PERFORMANCE DIFFERENTIAL BETWEEN PRIVATE AND STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES: AN ANALYSIS OF PROFITABILITY AND LEVERAGE Nguyet Thi Minh Phi, Farhad Taghizadeh-Hesary, Chuc Anh Tu, Naoyuki Yoshino, and Chul Ju Kim No. 950 May 2019 Asian Development Bank Institute Nguyet Thi Minh Phi is a Lecturer at the Academy of Finance, Ha Noi, Viet Nam and an associate researcher at Centre for Applied Economics and Business Research, Ha Noi, Viet Nam. Farhad Taghizadeh-Hesary is an Assistant Professor, Faculty of Political Science and Economics, Waseda University, Tokyo. Chuc Anh Tu is an Associate Professor, Academy of Finance, Ha Noi. Naoyuki Yoshino is Dean and CEO, ADBI, Tokyo. Chul Ju Kim is Deputy Dean, ADBI, Tokyo. The views expressed in this paper are the views of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of ADBI, ADB, its Board of Directors, or the governments they represent. ADBI does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this paper and accepts no responsibility for any consequences of their use. Terminology used may not necessarily be consistent with ADB official terms. Working papers are subject to formal revision and correction before they are finalized and considered published. The Working Paper series is a continuation of the formerly named Discussion Paper series; the numbering of the papers continued without interruption or change. ADBI’s working papers reflect initial ideas on a topic and are posted online for discussion. Some working papers may develop into other forms of publication. Suggested citation: Phi, N. T. M., F. Taghizadeh-Hesary, C.
    [Show full text]
  • John Stuart Mill (1806-1873)
    John Stuart Mill (1806-1873) • Principles of Political Economy, 1848 • Contributed to economics, logic, political science, philosophy of science, ethics and political philosophy. • A scientist, but also a social philosopher and a social reformer John Stuart Mill (1806-1873) Two social movements that influenced Mill 1. Socialism 2. Utilitarianism • Early (utopian) socialism (beginning of 19th century): – Very diverse movement – Insisted that capitalism is disharmonious – Objected to capitalism on ethical basis (capitalism is unjust, there is too much poverty and inequality) How to define capitalism, socialism and communism? • Capitalism: • Private ownership of economic resources • Market is an allocation and distribution mechanism • Socialism: • State or public ownership of resources (capital) • Market still serves to some extent as mechanism of allocation and distribution • Communism: • State ownership of resources • State (or central planner) decides on the allocation of resources and on the distribution of incomes (“from each according to his/her ability, to each according to her needs”) – Do you like this distributional principle? – What is wrong with it from the ethical perspective? From economic one? What is utilitarianism? • Leader of the movement – Jeremy Bentham (1748- 1832), economist and philosopher • Utilitarianism is an ethical view that the only standard by which moral rules, civil laws, and economic actions or outcomes should be evaluated is the principle of utility: maximization of the sum of the happiness (utility) of
    [Show full text]
  • Establishing Property Rights Is Therefore to a Large Extent Equivalent to Reducing Political Control
    144 i. MA4c4 14q5 EstablishingProperty Rights Andrei Shlezfer Public Disclosure Authorized Establishingsecure property rights hi transiton economies amounts to solvng two problems: inefficient structures of control rights over assets and poor contract enforce- ment. Politiciansand buraucrats still wield excessivecontrol over assets, which results in inefficient underinvestment by entreprneurs Cornption is one way of getting around political control, but the druvbacks are considerable,prticularly the limited enforceabilityof comiton contracts. More workable strategiesfor establshing prop- Public Disclosure Authorized erty nghts in transition economies are gving equity to the bureaucrats(and other par- ties that have control), eforming the civil servnce,and removing bureaucraic control rights through privataton Russia's experience shows how privatitr,on combied with eqity incentives for enterpriseinsides, transferscontrol rightsfrom the breau- crats and stimulates poltical and economic prsures to protect private property rig/a Poorly definedproperty rights are blamedfor many of the problemsof devel- oping countries and transition economies. But just what constitutes "poorly defined property rights" has eluded analysis. The classics of the property rights literature-Demsetz (1967), Alchian and Demsetz (1972), Jensen and Public Disclosure Authorized Meclding (1976), North and Thomas (1973), North (1981), and Barzel (1989)- offer revealing historical and contemporary examples of the importance of well- defined property rights for efficient resource allocation and economic growth. But they are not very specific in describing poorly defined property rights or in explain- ing how to establish well-defined property rights. Poorly defined property rights are usually discussed as a common pool problem: a resource gets overused because too many agents have the right to use it (North 1981; Ostrom 1990; Libecap 1989).
    [Show full text]
  • The Pope and Henry George: Pope Leo XIII Compared with Henry George, on the Ownership of Land and Other Natural Resources
    Solidarity: The Journal of Catholic Social Thought and Secular Ethics Volume 8 Issue 2 Article 2 2018 The Pope and Henry George: Pope Leo XIII compared with Henry George, on the ownership of land and other natural resources. A possible rapproachement? John Pullen uni, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://researchonline.nd.edu.au/solidarity ISSN: 1839-0366 COMMONWEALTH OF AUSTRALIA Copyright Regulations 1969 WARNING This material has been copied and communicated to you by or on behalf of the University of Notre Dame Australia pursuant to part VB of the Copyright Act 1969 (the Act). The material in this communication may be subject to copyright under the Act. Any further copying or communication of this material by you may be the subject of copyright protection under the Act. Do not remove this notice. Recommended Citation Pullen, John (2018) "The Pope and Henry George: Pope Leo XIII compared with Henry George, on the ownership of land and other natural resources. A possible rapproachement?," Solidarity: The Journal of Catholic Social Thought and Secular Ethics: Vol. 8 : Iss. 2 , Article 2. Available at: https://researchonline.nd.edu.au/solidarity/vol8/iss2/2 This Article is brought to you by ResearchOnline@ND. It has been accepted for inclusion in Solidarity: The Journal of Catholic Social Thought and Secular Ethics by an authorized administrator of ResearchOnline@ND. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Pope and Henry George: Pope Leo XIII compared with Henry George, on the ownership of land and other natural resources. A possible rapproachement? Abstract The encyclical, Rerum Novarum, issued by Pope Leo XIII in 1891 was interpreted by Henry George as a criticism of the views he had expressed in Progress and Poverty, 1879, and other writings.
    [Show full text]
  • State Ownership and Nationalization in Energy Sector: the Case of Kazakhstan's Oil Industry
    ADBI Working Paper Series STATE OWNERSHIP AND NATIONALIZATION IN ENERGY SECTOR: THE CASE OF KAZAKHSTAN’S OIL INDUSTRY Serik Orazgaliyev No. 1042 November 2019 Asian Development Bank Institute Serik Orazgaliyev is an assistant professor at the Graduate School of Public Policy of Nazarbayev University in Astana, Kazakhstan. The views expressed in this paper are the views of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of ADBI, ADB, its Board of Directors, or the governments they represent. ADBI does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this paper and accepts no responsibility for any consequences of their use. Terminology used may not necessarily be consistent with ADB official terms. Working papers are subject to formal revision and correction before they are finalized and considered published. The Working Paper series is a continuation of the formerly named Discussion Paper series; the numbering of the papers continued without interruption or change. ADBI’s working papers reflect initial ideas on a topic and are posted online for discussion. Some working papers may develop into other forms of publication. The Asian Development Bank refers to “China” as the People’s Republic of China. Suggested citation: Orazgaliyev, S. 2019. State Ownership and Nationalization in Energy Sector: The Case of Kazakhstan's Oil Industry. ADBI Working Paper 1042. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute. Available: https://www.adb.org/publications/state-ownership-nationalization-energy- sector-kazakhstan Please contact the authors for information about this paper. Email: [email protected] Asian Development Bank Institute Kasumigaseki Building, 8th Floor 3-2-5 Kasumigaseki, Chiyoda-ku Tokyo 100-6008, Japan Tel: +81-3-3593-5500 Fax: +81-3-3593-5571 URL: www.adbi.org E-mail: [email protected] © 2019 Asian Development Bank Institute ADBI Working Paper 1042 S.
    [Show full text]
  • Ownership and Governance of State-Owned Enterprises a Compendium of National Practices
    Ownership and Governance of State-Owned Enterprises A Compendium of National Practices Please cite this publication as: OECD (2018), Ownership and Governance of State-Owned Enterprises: A Compendium of National Practices This work is published on the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. The opinions expressed and arguments employed herein do not necessarily reflect the official views of the OECD or of the governments of its member countries or those of the European Union. This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. © OECD 2018 FOREWORD State-owned enterprises (SOEs) are an important element of most economies, including many more advanced economies. SOEs are most prevalent in strategic sectors such as energy, minerals, infrastructure, other utilities and, in some countries, financial services. The presence of SOEs in the global economy has grown strongly in recent years. Today they account for over a fifth of the world's largest enterprises as opposed to ten years ago where only one or two SOEs could be found at the top of the league table. This means that high standards of corporate governance of SOEs are critical to ensure financial stability and sustain global growth. The OECD Working Party on State Ownership and Privatisation Practices is the only international forum for government officials charged with the oversight of state-owned enterprises. The Working Party is responsible for the implementation of the OECD Guidelines on Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises (the “SOE Guidelines”).
    [Show full text]
  • A Contractual Analysis of State Versus Private Ownership1
    Preprint, forthcoming on China Economic Review A Contractual Analysis of State versus Private Ownership1 Kun Jiang2 and Susheng Wang3 January 2017 Abstract: We uniquely analyze the advantages and disadvantages of private ownership versus state ownership under various circumstances by focusing on three aspects: external risk, internal governance, and relative importance of owners versus managers. Our theoretical analysis indicates that private ownership is better than state ownership if the business envi- ronment is risky, corruption is limited, or the manager plays a more important role than the owner. Our empirical analysis supports our theoretical findings and reveals that better inter- nal governance, more external risk and greater importance of the manager will magnify the benefits of privatization. Keywords: contractual analysis, state ownership, private ownership, incentives, external risks, internal corruption. JEL Classification: D23, D73, P31 1 We gratefully acknowledge the helpful comments and suggestions from two referees and the funding support from the Research Grants Council and the Central Policy Unit of the Hong Kong SAR Government. 2 Roehampton University, UK. Email: [email protected]. 3 Hong Kong University of Science and Technology. Email: [email protected]. 1. Introduction The transformation of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) to private firms has been among the most important economic events in recent times. SOEs are generally considered as ineffi- cient and in the past 20 years, privatization has been the approach to their reform in more than 100 countries, including many Western countries such as the U.K., France and Canada, as well as Eastern Bloc countries and China. Privatization transforms a state-owned company to a privately owned one.
    [Show full text]
  • New Market Socialism: a Case for Rejuvenation Or Inspired Alchemy?
    NEW MARKET SOCIALISM: A CASE FOR REJUVENATION OR INSPIRED ALCHEMY? DIMITRIS MILONAKIS * ÍNDICE I. INTRODUCTION............................................................................................................................................. 2 I. EARLY MARKET SOCIALISM: THE LANGE MODEL ................................................................................... 4 II. MARKET SOCIALISM AND THE QUESTION OF KNOWLEDGE: THE AUSTRIAN CHALLENGE ............. 6 III. THE QUESTION OF INCENTIVES: MARKET SOCIALISM AND ‘NEW INFORMATION ECONOMICS’.... 7 IV. MODERN VERSIONS OF MARKET SOCIALISM ..................................................................................... 10 V. NEW MARKET SOCIALISM: A CRITIQUE FROM WITHIN........................................................................ 14 VI. TOWARDS A MORE RADICAL CRITIQUE ............................................................................................... 17 VII. BY WAY OF CONCLUSION...................................................................................................................... 21 VIII. REFERENCES ......................................................................................................................................... 22 *Department of Economics, University of Crete. I would like to thank Ben Fine for his painstaking critique of an earlier draft of this paper. My thanks also go to Costas Lapavitsas, George Argitis, the participants of the Fourth Annual Conference of the European Society for the History of Economic Thought,
    [Show full text]