Reflections on Work Addiction As a Symptom of Contemporary Social Unrest

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Reflections on Work Addiction As a Symptom of Contemporary Social Unrest MOJ Addiction Medicine & Therapy Review Article Open Access Reflections on work addiction as a symptom of contemporary social unrest Abstract Volume 4 Issue 1 - 2017 The main objective of this paper is to present a set of reflections on the addiction to Néstor Raúl Porras Velásquez,1 Laura Camila work as a symptom of the social unrest of our post-industrial era. The methodology 2 used was the documentary analysis of recent publications on work addiction. The Parra D’aleman 1National University of Colombia, Colombia results show that the personal, organizational, job position (tasks and responsibilities) 2Los Libertadores University Foundation, University in Bogotá, and employment in general, as well as the process of organizational socialization Colombia and the management of interpersonal relationships with managers are triggers of addictive behavior. The partial conclusions indicate that the addictive behavior of Correspondence: Néstor Raúl Porras Velásquez, Psychologist salaried workers is configured as a coping strategy to the anxiety, stress, anxiety and at the National University of Colombia, Currently a professor psychological suffering generated by the fear of losing the work manifested in the and researcher at the faculty of psychology of the Libertadores perception of high contemporary labor instability. University Foundation, Bogotá. Member of the Free Association in Colombia, Email [email protected], Keywords: addiction to work, occupational health, work psychology, labor malaise [email protected] and social symptom Received: October 10, 2017 | Published: November 08, 2017 Introduction tolerance of unpleasant physical or psychological stimuli such as pain or sadness, depressed mood or dysphoria and the search for strong “Addiction is a compulsive behavior that seeks immediate feelings increase the predisposition and vulnerability for a subject to satisfaction but not a mental illness”, “Addictions are the substitute for develop an addiction. a primary satisfaction. That is, they are a compulsion to repetition”. Néstor Raúl Porras Velásquez. Finally, a behaviour becomes addictive, when the subject loses control before the beginning or cessation of behaviour, develops a At present and based on the studies and scientific literature dependency (it is not easy to stop thinking about such behaviour), consulted we can say that the addiction to work is part of this set of new the interest in other activities that previously disappeared was addictions. That in psychological terms is a psychological addiction pleasurable, maintains the behaviour despite being aware of its of the cognitive-behavioural order. In other words behavioural/ negative consequences and experiences a feeling of discomfort when emotional, which unlike chemical addiction to a drug, the addiction to it cannot perform such behaviour (abstinence syndrome). With these work does not have a “substance”. For this reason, when we talk about introductory elements to the subject in question, we next address the addiction from clinically/social perspective, the outlook is very broad particular aspects of adding to work in contemporary work contexts. and we delimit according to the types of addiction that have been proposed so far by the investigators of this phenomenon. In a nutshell, General aspects of addiction to work addiction to work is more of a compulsive behaviour than a mental The addiction to work is a topic that today draws attention not illness. The concept of workaholism may also be associated with a only to professionals and researchers of human behaviour at work but priori behaviours or behaviour that are healthy and not dangerous. to the staff dedicated to health in general. The interest in studying, These behaviours can become addictive, depending on the intensity, understanding and explaining this labour phenomenon has to do frequency or amount of time and money that the person invests in not only with the implications but also with the personal, social carrying them out and seriously interfere with the functioning of the and organizational repercussions that such behaviour entails as a subject. We refer, for example, to repetitive and excessive behaviours psychosocial risk factor intra and extra labour for the health of the such as: internet use, sex, work, shopping, food, gambling, among working population. At present, the world of work has undergone others. a series of changes not only at the technological level, but also in It is evident that the human being tends to repeat the behaviours the conditions of employment that directly affect a large number of that produce satisfactory or pleasant consequences, that is why people who are currently working, and indirectly, those who aspire certain behaviours can generate behaviours addictive. In short, a to enter the labour market. The companies in their eagerness to adapt behaviour becomes addictive, when the subject loses control before to the new demands of the global market generate new demands and the beginning or cessation of behaviour, develops a dependence (it is demands for the employees that translate into increasingly complex not easy to stop thinking about such behaviour), the interest in other transformations of the labour activities. Both the emotional work and activities that disappear previously it was pleasurable, maintains the more frequent social interactions with a greater number of people in the behaviour despite being aware of its negative consequences and their daily tasks (peers, bosses, suppliers, clients, etc.), affect both the experiences a feeling of discomfort when it cannot perform such health and well-being of workers and negatively affect the efficiency behaviour (abstinence syndrome). To the above, it is necessary to of productive organizations, since they become agents that generate initially add a set of risk factors to develop an addiction: difficulty in work stress, emotional exhaustion and job exhaustion. On the other coping with everyday problems, low self-esteem, impulsivity, non- hand, both flexibilization and job insecurity show in many regions Submit Manuscript | http://medcraveonline.com MOJ Addict Med Ther. 2017;4(1):217‒222 217 © 2017 Velásquez et al. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and build upon your work non-commercially. Copyright: Reflections on work addiction as a symptom of contemporary social unrest ©2017 Velásquez et al. 218 of the world new labour market conditions, where formalization of political, economic, scientific and technological changes have had a informal work becomes the norm and workers are forced to accept significant impact both on the role, responsibilities and roles assigned worse conditions in their workplaces. to the work psychologist, as well as on models and techniques that this as a social agent uses in his professional activity interventora Finally, among the new realities of contemporary work, we can and investigativa. However, however drastic those changes may mention the following: the merger and disappearance of large and have been, according to the authors mentioned: Psychology, with its especially small enterprises, which generate labour instability and scientific methods and theories remains the conceptual basis of work uncertainty about the future of the work, as well as loss of control psychology, and yet the psychologist has had to expand his activity over personal life projects and family that are reflected in a kind of to aspects related to other disciplines such as economics, labour law, existential vacuum because of the lack of meaning of the work done. occupational medicine, etc., both when working individually and For this reason, Marx’s phrase is included at the beginning of the text, when doing it as part of multidisciplinary teams.10 The warning is which can guide those who legislate or direct the areas of human talent directed mainly towards those psychologists and psychologists who management in companies in our country, in matters of decent and assume occupational psychology as an administrative practice of decent working conditions. This paper initially addresses the concepts human resources. of work psychology and occupational health psychology as a frame of reference for analyzing psychosocial risk factors and work addiction. On the other hand, according to Blanch,3 the psychology of work as a discipline and as a profession aims to study “the psychosocial Psychology of work phenomena and processes involved in the interaction of the employed 3 According to Leplat & Cuny,1 the name industrial psychology is person with his working environment”. This author acknowledges perhaps the most common and used in many countries. However, that traditionally a purely personal-personal perspective has “the term” work psychology “is clearly being imposed against been taken to analyze how ordinary people think, feel and value the traditional term of industrial psychology, more identified with working in the employment system and what psychosocial impact Taylorism and the strict economic optimization of industrial labor”.1 their work situation produces (employment, underemployment or From the perspective of these two French psychologists, talking unemployment). For this reason, it proposes a broader sociocultural about work psychology is much more pertinent and adequate than study perspective where the rigorous look and critical analysis of industrial-organizational psychology,
Recommended publications
  • Main Economic Indicators: Comparative Methodological Analysis: Wage Related Statistics
    MAIN ECONOMIC INDICATORS: COMPARATIVE METHODOLOGICAL ANALYSIS: WAGE RELATED STATISTICS VOLUME 2002 SUPPLEMENT 3 FOREWORD This publication provides comparisons of methodologies used by OECD Member countries to compile key short-term and annual data on wage related statistics. These statistics comprise annual and infra-annual statistics on wages and earnings, minimum wages, labour costs, labour prices, unit labour costs, and household income. Also, because of their use in the compilation of these statistics, the publication also includes an initial analysis of hours of work statistics. In its coverage of short-term indicators it is related to analytical publications previously published by the OECD for indicators published in the monthly publication, Main Economic Indicators (MEI) for: industry, retail and construction indicators; and price indices. The primary purpose of this publication is to provide users with methodological information underlying the compilation of wage related statistics. The analysis provided for these statistics is designed to ensure their appropriate use by analysts in an international context. The information will also enable national statistical institutes and other agencies responsible for compiling such statistics to compare their methodologies and data sources with those used in other countries. Finally, it will provide a range of options for countries in the process of creating their own wage related statistics, or overhauling existing indicators. The analysis in this publication focuses on issues of data comparability in the context of existing international statistical guidelines and recommendations published by the OECD and other international agencies such as the United Nations Statistical Division (UNSD), the International Labour Organisation (ILO), and the Statistical Office of the European Communities (Eurostat).
    [Show full text]
  • Reproducing Low-Wage Labour: Capital Accumulation, Labour Markets and Young Workers
    This is a repository copy of Reproducing low-wage labour: capital accumulation, labour markets and young workers. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/138261/ Version: Accepted Version Article: Yates, E. orcid.org/0000-0001-9886-455X (2018) Reproducing low-wage labour: capital accumulation, labour markets and young workers. Industrial Relations Journal, 48 (5-6). pp. 463-481. ISSN 0019-8692 https://doi.org/10.1111/irj.12195 This is the peer reviewed version of the following article: Yates, E. (2017) Reproducing low‐ wage labour: capital accumulation, labour markets and young workers. Industrial Relations Journal, 48: 463–481, which has been published in final form at https://doi.org/10.1111/irj.12195. This article may be used for non-commercial purposes in accordance with Wiley Terms and Conditions for Self-Archiving. Reuse Items deposited in White Rose Research Online are protected by copyright, with all rights reserved unless indicated otherwise. They may be downloaded and/or printed for private study, or other acts as permitted by national copyright laws. The publisher or other rights holders may allow further reproduction and re-use of the full text version. This is indicated by the licence information on the White Rose Research Online record for the item. Takedown If you consider content in White Rose Research Online to be in breach of UK law, please notify us by emailing [email protected] including the URL of the record and the reason for the withdrawal request. [email protected] https://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/ Reproducing low wage labour: capital accumulation, labour markets, and young workers Edward Yates, University of Leicester Abstract: Drawing on evidence from Greater Manchester, this paper examines how structural changes in capital accumulation have created particular labour market outcomes which have led to young people becoming a source of cheap labour for the growing low-wage service economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Unfree Labor, Capitalism and Contemporary Forms of Slavery
    Unfree Labor, Capitalism and Contemporary Forms of Slavery Siobhán McGrath Graduate Faculty of Political and Social Science, New School University Economic Development & Global Governance and Independent Study: William Milberg Spring 2005 1. Introduction It is widely accepted that capitalism is characterized by “free” wage labor. But what is “free wage labor”? According to Marx a “free” laborer is “free in the double sense, that as a free man he can dispose of his labour power as his own commodity, and that on the other hand he has no other commodity for sale” – thus obliging the laborer to sell this labor power to an employer, who possesses the means of production. Yet, instances of “unfree labor” – where the worker cannot even “dispose of his labor power as his own commodity1” – abound under capitalism. The question posed by this paper is why. What factors can account for the existence of unfree labor? What role does it play in an economy? Why does it exist in certain forms? In terms of the broadest answers to the question of why unfree labor exists under capitalism, there appear to be various potential hypotheses. ¾ Unfree labor may be theorized as a “pre-capitalist” form of labor that has lingered on, a “vestige” of a formerly dominant mode of production. Similarly, it may be viewed as a “non-capitalist” form of labor that can come into existence under capitalism, but can never become the central form of labor. ¾ An alternate explanation of the relationship between unfree labor and capitalism is that it is part of a process of primary accumulation.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of Minimum Wage on Employment in Poland Investigaciones Regionales, Núm
    Investigaciones Regionales ISSN: 1695-7253 [email protected] Asociación Española de Ciencia Regional España Majchrowska, Aleksandra; Zólkiewski, Zbigniew The impact of minimum wage on employment in Poland Investigaciones Regionales, núm. 24, 2012, pp. 211-239 Asociación Española de Ciencia Regional Madrid, España Available in: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=28924660010 How to cite Complete issue Scientific Information System More information about this article Network of Scientific Journals from Latin America, the Caribbean, Spain and Portugal Journal's homepage in redalyc.org Non-profit academic project, developed under the open access initiative © Investigaciones Regionales, 24 – Pages 211 to 239 Section ARTICLES The impact of minimum wage on employment in Poland · Aleksandra Majchrowska *, Zbigniew Zółkiewski ** ABSTRACT: The purpose of this paper is to verify the hypothesis that minimum wage might have negative impact on employment in Poland, at least for some work- ers groups and regions. After having reviewed theoretical literature on minimum wage and having discussed stylized facts on labour market in Poland, the authors define econometric model to check the impact of minimum wage on employment in Poland and then discuss the results. The main conclusions of the study may be summarized as follows: i) minimum wage has had an adverse impact on employ- ment in 1999-2010; ii) the adverse effect of minimum wage on employment has been pronounced for the young workers during the period of substantial increase of the minimum wage (2005-2010), and iii) there is some evidence that a uniform national minimum wage may be particularly harmful to employment in poorest regions.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of the Minimum Wage on Employment: an EU Panel Data Analysis
    sustainability Article The Impact of the Minimum Wage on Employment: An EU Panel Data Analysis Cristian Valeriu Paun 1 , Radu Nechita 2, Alexandru Patruti 2,* and Mihai Vladimir Topan 2,* 1 Department of International Business and Economics, Bucharest University of Economic Studies, 010374 Bucharest, Romania; [email protected] 2 Department of European Studies and Governance, Babes-Bolyai University, 400090 Cluj Napoca, Romania; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] (A.P.); [email protected] (M.V.T.) Abstract: Minimum wage laws have become one of the most debated state interventions in the economy, being considered by many specialists as a very efficient tool used to correct certain labour market failures. The aim of this paper is to explore the relationship between minimum wage and employment dynamics, with a special focus on some vulnerable categories recognized in the literature (young people, female workers, the elderly, etc.). Thus, we analysed the relation between the dynamics of minimum wages and that of employment in 22 EU countries, panel data (1999–2016). The results suggest a negative impact of the minimum wage on total employment and on sensitive categories (youth, female workers, the elderly). The long-running negative impact holds for all but one group (55–64 years). The models were tested for random and fixed effects and the results were correspondingly adjusted with country and time and random and fixed effects. Cointegration tests and the tests using lagged minimum wage also confirm a robust relationship between the dynamics of the minimum wage and that of employment over time. Our findings are consistent with many previous studies and confirm the recommendations to prudently use this public policy tool.
    [Show full text]
  • The Employment Effects of Collective Bargaining
    The Employment Effects of Collective Bargaining∗ Bernardo Fanfani∗∗ Abstract This paper studies the wage and employment effects of Italian collective bargaining. For this purpose, it analyses monthly data derived from administrative archives on the population of private-sector employees, matched with extensive information on contractual pay levels settled in industry-wide agreements bargained by trade unions' and employers' representatives at the national level. The research design is based on a generalised differences-in-differences method, which exploits the numerous contrasts generated by the Italian wage setting rules and controls for space-specific sectoral unobserved time-varying disturbances in a fully non-parametric way. Results show that a growth in contractual wages produced sizeable increases in actual pay levels for all workers, determining at the same time strong and negative effects on employment. The resulting confidence interval of the implied own-price labour demand elasticity ranged between -0.4 and -1.2, and it was even slightly more negative among incorporated companies. Studying interactions of this parameter with firm-level outcomes {value added per worker, size, the labour share and capital intensity{ we found associations broadly consistent with Hicks-Marshall laws and with traditional models of centralized wage bargaining. Further analyses carefully document the presence of dynamic employment adjustments to contractual wage levels and assess the overall robustness of the results. Keywords: collective bargaining, labour
    [Show full text]
  • Minimum Wages and Productivity
    Minimum wages and labour productivity Recent studies have shown that minimum wages not only help to reduce wage dispersion and to channel productivity gains into higher wages, but they also can contribute to higher labour productivity – both at the enterprise level and at the aggregate economy-wide level. At the enterprise level, workers may be motivated to work harder. They may also stay longer with their employer, gaining valuable experience and also encouraging employers and employee to engage in productivity-enhancing training. At the aggregate level, minimum wages can result in more productive firms replacing least productive ones – and surviving firms becoming more efficient. These mechanisms can increase overall economy- wide productivity. (a) workers can be more motivated A large number of experimental studies have supported the hypothesis formulated by Akerlof in 1982 that employees consistently provide higher effort levels in response to higher wages, the so-called “efficiency wage” theory. Most of these studies have focused on pay levels of individual firms, showing that higher pay compared to elsewhere can attract more experienced and motivated applicants. Higher pay can also elicit greater commitment and productivity from existing employees (Ehrenberg and Smith, 2009). The effect of minimum wages - as opposed to higher wages in individual firms - on workers’ motivation has also been found to be positive. Using a standard natural experiment design Georgiadis (2013) for example found that the U.K. national minimum wage has operated as a kind of “efficiency wage” in the residential care homes sector, increasing motivation and leading to a reduction in the level of worker supervision required.
    [Show full text]
  • Basic Income Beyond Wage Slavery in Search of Transcending Political Aesthetics
    Basic Income beyond Wage Slavery In search of transcending political aesthetics Lasse Ekstrand, Monika Wallmon * University of Gävle, Uppsala University Key words: basic income BI, political aesthetics, post-industrialism, welfare theory * Corresponding author: Monika Wallmon [email protected] ABSTRACT This paper addresses the concept of Basic Income * – hereafter abbreviated as BI – and its use in the contexts of welfare theory and aesthetic philosophy. A case study of the German artist Joseph Beuys is presented. It is suggested that the concept of BI approached through a ‘Beuysian’ lens, opens to a distinctly political aesthetics. INTRODUCTION Substantial work has been done defining the idea of BI and positioning it in welfare theory (c.f. Baumann, 1998; Christensen, 2002; Gorz, 1999; Offe, 2001). Still, the relations between BI and political aesthetics have rarely been discussed. This paper elaborates with a post-industrial society requiring the payment of an unconditional BI to all society members; focusing the meaning of concepts such as ‘learned helplessness’, ‘social art’ and ‘liberation’. With the starting point in recent developments in welfare theory, and its attempts to understand changes in economic activity and in capitalism itself, we investigate the one of many proposed links to aesthetics (c.f. Agamben, 2000; 2005; Dewey, 2005; Ranciére, 2004). There exists already a managerial ‘test map’ on different ‘aesthetizations’, often proposed as models for business management; i.e. aesthetic marketing, aesthetic organizing etc. (c.f. Gibb, 2006; Strati and Guillet de Monthoux, 2002). But there are also suggestions that the aesthetics and artists increasingly will participate in the critic review and creativity aspects within the frames for new forms of capitalism (Ekstrand, 2004).
    [Show full text]
  • THE LABOR SUPPLY of the EARLY ROMAN EMPIRE Peter Temin
    Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series THE LABOR SUPPLY OF THE EARLY ROMAN EMPIRE Peter Temin Working Paper 01-45 November 2001 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=293397 The Labor Supply of the Early Roman Empire Peter Temin 07 December 2001 Abstract I argue that it makes sense to speak of a functioning labor market in the early Roman Empire where the supply and demand for labor were equilibrated by wages and other payments to workers, albeit in a rough way. The economy of the early Roman Empire therefore had a market in this critical factor of production that resembles the labor market in more recent market economies. Slaves were included in the general labor market because Roman slavery was very different from modern slavery in the Americas. In the early Roman Empire, frequent manumission provided incentives for slaves to cooperate with their owners and act like free laborers. My thanks for help and advice from Roger Bagnall, Alan Bowman, Richard Duncan- Jones, Peter Garnsey, Keith Hopkins, Dominic Rathbone, and Joshua Sosin. I also thank the Warden and Fellows of Nuffield College, Oxford, for research support. All errors remain mine alone. The Labor Supply of the Early Roman Empire Ancient Rome was a slave society. This view has become so common as to need no citation, although Moses Finley may have been the first to assert that Rome was one of only five slave societies in recorded history (Finley, 1980).
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of Working Time and Wages on Retention in the Health Workforce Stephanie Steinmetz1*, Daniel H De Vries1 and Kea G Tijdens2
    Steinmetz et al. Human Resources for Health 2014, 12:23 http://www.human-resources-health.com/content/12/1/23 RESEARCH Open Access Should I stay or should I go? The impact of working time and wages on retention in the health workforce Stephanie Steinmetz1*, Daniel H de Vries1 and Kea G Tijdens2 Abstract Background: Turnover in the health workforce is a concern as it is costly and detrimental to organizational performance and quality of care. Most studies have focused on the influence of individual and organizational factors on an employee’s intention to quit. Inspired by the observation that providing care is based on the duration of practices, tasks and processes (issues of time) rather than exchange values (wages), this paper focuses on the influence of working-time characteristics and wages on an employee’s intention to stay. Methods: Using data from the WageIndicator web survey (N = 5,323), three logistic regression models were used to estimate health care employee’s intention to stay for Belgium, Germany and the Netherlands. The first model includes working-time characteristics controlling for a set of sociodemographic variables, job categories, promotion and organization-related characteristics. The second model tests the impact of wage-related characteristics. The third model includes both working-time- and wage-related aspects. Results: Model 1 reveals that working-time-related factors significantly affect intention to stay across all countries. In particular, working part-time hours, overtime and a long commuting time decrease the intention to stay with the same employer. The analysis also shows that job dissatisfaction is a strong predictor for the intention to leave, next to being a woman, being moderately or well educated, and being promoted in the current organization.
    [Show full text]
  • Unemployment and Income Security
    Unemployment and Income Security by Guy Standing June, 2000, Geneva International Labour Organization Table of Contents 1. Introduction............................................................................................ 1 2. Unemployment and Income Security ........................................................... 3 3. Policy Frameworks for Unemployment ........................................................ 4 4. Unemployment Insurance Benefits .............................................................. 6 (i) The contributions issue...................................................................... 9 (ii) The incentive issue......................................................................... 10 (iii) The three crises of unemployment benefits........................................... 11 (iv) The Conditionality of Unemployment Benefit Schemes........................... 13 (v) Age test........................................................................................ 15 (vi) Employment record test................................................................... 15 (vii) Job departure test........................................................................... 17 (viii) Job-seeking test ............................................................................. 18 (ix) Available-for-work test.................................................................... 19 (x) Job refusal test .............................................................................. 20 (xi) Training refusal test.......................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • 10Ways Work Must Change.Pdf
    FOR GOOD DR. JIM STANFORD Economist and Director Centre for Future Work JUNE 2020 his research paper is published by the Centre for Future Work as part of its newPower Share project, to investigate workers’ collective voice and agency in the future of work. Work is T changing due to many forces: technology,business models,labour regulations and policies,and social attitudes.Will workers have a real sayin what work becomes? Will theyhave the voice and power to meaningfully shape the future of work, and protect their interests? PowerShare is a partnership between the Centre for Future Work, the Atkinson Foundation, and the Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives. The Centre for Future Work is a progressive research institute, founded in 2016, with operations in Canada and Australia.It is a unique centre of excellence on the economic issues facing working people: including the future of jobs, wages and income distribution, skills and training, sector and industry policies, globalization, the role of government, public services, and more. The Centre also develops timely and practical policy proposals to help make the world of work better for working people and their families. The Centre is independent and non-partisan. Learn more atcentreforfuturework.ca . ABOUT THE AUTHOR: Dr. Jim Stanford is Economist and Director of the Centre for FutureWork. He worked for many years as Economist and Director of Policy for Unifor (and before that the Canadian Auto Workers), before moving to Australia in 2016 to establish the Centre for Future Work at the Australia Institute. Jim returned to Canada and now resides in Vancouver, where the Centre has recently opened a Canadian office.
    [Show full text]