Impact of Globalization on Monetary Policy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Impact of Globalization on Monetary Policy Impact of Globalization on Monetary Policy Kenneth S. Rogoff This paper aims to discuss a few core issues in the recent monetary policy and globalization debate.1 Are global factors becoming impor- tant drivers of domestic inflation—or disinflation? To what extent should terms of trade shocks play a larger role in central bank rules for deciding when and for how long to allow inflation to drift above or below target? Even if central banks are reluctant to react to perceived misalignments in asset price levels, how concerned should they be about the fact that thus far, equity, housing, and trade-weighted exchange rates have not yet demonstrated the enduring decline in volatility that output and inflation have experienced? I will argue that continuing asset price volatility is at least in part because of heightened asset price sensitivity to risk changes as risk levels fall, and the increas- ing ability of financial markets to diversify risk. Therefore, in the context of a long and successful campaign to reduce output and infla- tion volatility, it would be a mistake for central banks to obsess as much about asset price volatility as asset markets obsess about central bank volatility. The second section of the paper begins by exploring whether the popular view that “China exports deflation” has any real content, and other issues related to the effect of the global productivity boom on inflation. At some level, this view confuses terms of trade gains with deflation. Indeed, over the medium term, it would be more accurate to say that China is exporting inflation to the prices of other goods in the economy. Nevertheless, there is an important truth to the argument 265 266 Kenneth S. Rogoff also, in that central banks may reasonably choose to allow inflation to drift below target in response to favorable terms of trade shifts, just as they may choose to allow inflation to drift temporarily above target in response to adverse oil price shocks. More speculatively, some have argued that favorable trend terms of trade changes, combined with greater competitiveness and flexibility, allow central banks to target slightly lower trend inflation rates than they might otherwise. The second section also touches on the intriguing notion that central banks pay more attention to global excess capacity in predicting domes- tic inflation. Overall, I conclude that whereas global factors certainly help shape monetary decisions, domestic monetary authorities still retain extremely strong control over medium- and long-term inflation trends, even in very open economies. This is true despite the fact that, through both goods and asset price arbitrage, globalization is weaken- ing the grip of individual central banks over the trajectory of domestic real interest rates, except at relatively short horizons. The third section revisits the stunning decline in output and inflation volatility that most countries have experienced in recent years, and contrasts this with the continuing volatility in many asset markets, not least including equity prices, housing, and exchange rates. Economists have come to term the output volatility decline “The Great Modera- tion,” which in principle has been a great triumph for central banks though there remains a great deal of debate about how to apportion credit.2 Might the ever-expanding depth and liquidity of global asset markets, which are contributing to the general level of asset price infla- tion, also be exacerbating their volatility, partially offsetting the reduction that would otherwise come with more stable real economic activity? Why has exchange rate volatility been so slow to decline when, in principle, inflation and output volatility ought to be major drivers? There are many possible explanations for continuing asset price volatility. First, equities (should) reflect long horizon returns, and long- run risk does not necessarily diminish in proportion to reductions in short-run volatility. Second, as financial markets deepen, and as riskier parts of the global economy become securitized, aggregate measures of asset price volatility can rise even though the value of the global economy’s overall capital stock (including both securitized and nonse- curitized components) is not necessarily itself becoming more volatile. Deeper markets, of course, also allow greater diversification of risk, Impact of Globalization on Monetary Policy 267 lowering its price. Third, investors may still be engaged in a learning process on how to calibrate the effects of today’s considerably lower output volatility on asset prices, in which case some significant portion of current volatility may eventually pass. Fourth, I argue that to the extent higher asset prices are fueled by low-risk premia, and, therefore, low-risk adjusted interest rates, asset prices may become proportion- ately more sensitive to changes in perceived levels of risk. (This is in analogy to the fact that very long-lived assets become more sensitive to changes in the levels of interests rates as interest rates fall, which indeed also may be a factor in volatility.) In this case, the continuing volatility of many asset prices, not to mention their continuing sensitivity to monetary pronouncements, may reflect their inflated levels rather than, say, major failures in central bank communications policy. For completeness, in the final section before the conclusions, I briefly survey the burgeoning academic literature on whether, as economies become more open, the case becomes more compelling for including exchange rates or terms of trade shocks into inflation targeting rules. Whereas this relatively narrow issue is not our main focus, it, neverthe- less, concentrates a number of practical questions concerning how central banks might deal with increasing openness. In principle, exchange rates are naturally born schizophrenics that are both a relative goods price (for given price levels, the exchange rate is the relative price of two countries’ Consumer Price Index, CPI, baskets) and an asset price (the relative price of two countries’ currencies). Empirically, however, as we see again in the third section, exchange rates tend to behave much more like asset prices than goods prices. For countries with well-developed financial markets, the thin information content of exchange rates makes them of limited use in a monetary policy rule, although, of course, there can still be important information when movements are extreme and other variables to support the general direction of the signal exchange rates appear to be sending.3 A more open question is whether terms of trade shocks (for example, oil price shocks or an unexpectedly strong and sustained wave of low- cost manufactures) should play a larger role in monetary rules as economies become more open, despite the fact they are harder to measure. Although researchers have come up with special cases where central banks should not allow even large terms of trade shocks to cause deviations from a narrowly construed inflation targeting rule, these cases seem to be very much the exception rather than the rule. 268 Kenneth S. Rogoff For more generalized “flexible inflation targeting rules” that include inflation as only one argument, then any role for terms of trade shocks depends on whether its effects are already embodied in other variables such as output. The final section of the paper argues that the greatest challenge ahead for central banks is to make sure that their institutional mecha- nisms for preserving low-trend inflation are robust to possible setbacks in the future course of globalization. Whereas central banks should take care to avoid unnecessarily exacerbating asset price volatility (and, thereby, hindering financial deepening), continuing asset price volatil- ity after The Great Moderation can be explained by a number of other factors. Asset price volatility, including exchange rate volatility, should not distract central banks from their core mission of inflation and output stabilization. Globalization and low inflation A great deal already has been written about the broad implications of globalization on inflation, interest rates, and monetary policy. This includes both the surge of recent interest in policy discussions4 and, of course, academic analyses dating back at least to David Hume’s writings in the 18th century.5 In this section, I attempt to address a few issues that have been of particular concern in the recent policy debate, beginning with the increasingly prominent view that the forces of globalization have become the central drivers in domestic inflation trends. Is China exporting deflation—or inflation? Perhaps the idea that has gained the most traction is the “China is exporting deflation” theory. At one level, this paradigm is hopelessly naïve. It is certainly true that as China’s low-wage workers integrate into the global economy after decades of isolation (not to mention India, the former Soviet Bloc states, etc.), they place relentless down- ward pressures on wages and prices elsewhere. But hypercompetitive Chinese exports only affect relative prices. As long as the central bank targets inflation in the overall price level, which it can over sufficiently long horizons, cheap goods from China simply imply that other goods must become more expensive. From this perspec- tive, one might actually say that China is exporting inflation to the other sectors of the global economy. Impact of Globalization on Monetary Policy 269 However, on another level, the “China is exporting deflation” does have an important element of truth. The breathtaking speed and pace of China’s integration into the global economy during the past 20 years has been a continuing source of wonder, even for central bank oracles. Setting aside a number of nuances we will return to in the fourth section of the paper, optimal monetary policy in the face of favorable terms of trade shock will typically involve allowing inflation to temporarily drift below target. Thus, the continuing upside surprises in developing country growth during the past decade have translated into lower-than-expected inflation.
Recommended publications
  • Modern Monetary Realism by James K
    Modern Monetary Realism By James K. Galbraith March 15, 2019 – Project Syndicate Kenneth Rogoff’s criticism of Modern Monetary Theory assumes that MMT advocates don’t care about budget deficits or the independence of the US Federal Reserve. But these assumptions are wide of the mark, and Rogoff himself sometimes undermines his own arguments. Is Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) a would have predicted,” while “the US dollar potential boon to economic policymakers, or, has become increasingly dominant in global as Harvard’s Kenneth Rogoff recently argued, trade and finance.” Perhaps the US budget a threat to “the entire global financial system” deficit is not an immediate cause for panic after and the front line of the “next battle for central- all? bank independence”? For Rogoff, the threat MMT is not, as its opponents seem to think, seems to stem partly from the fear that MMT primarily a set of policy ideas. Rather, it is adherents may come to power in the United essentially a description of how a modern States in the 2020 elections. But he also makes credit economy actually works – how money is several substantive arguments, common to created and destroyed, by governments and by many critics of the MMT movement. banks, and how financial markets function. First, there is the claim that, as Rogoff puts it, Nor is MMT new: it is based on the work of MMT is all about “using the [US Federal John Maynard Keynes, whose A Treatise on Reserve’s] balance sheet as a cash cow to fund Money pointed out back in 1930 that “modern expansive new social programs.” Second, States” have functioned this way for thousands Rogoff and other MMT opponents strongly of years.
    [Show full text]
  • Download the Transcript
    FISCAL-2020/12/01 1 THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION WEBINAR FISCAL POLICY ADVICE FOR JOE BIDEN AND CONGRESS Washington, D.C. Tuesday, December 1, 2020 PARTICIPANTS: Welcome: ADAM POSEN President, Peterson Institute for International Economics DAVID WESSEL Senior Fellow and Director, Hutchins Center on Fiscal & Monetary Policy, The Brookings Institution COVID-19 and the Near Term: WENDY EDELBERG Senior Fellow and Director, The Hamilton Project The Brookings Institution DOUGLAS ELMENDORF Dean and Don K. Price Professor of Public Policy, Harvard Kennedy School MICHAEL STRAIN Director of Economic Policy Studies and Arthur F. Burns Scholar in Political Economy, American Enterprise Institute ADAM POSEN, Moderator President Peterson Institute for International Economics ‘What About the Federal Debt’ Presentation: JASON FURMAN Professor of the Practice of Economic Policy Harvard Kennedy School LAWRENCE SUMMERS Charles W. Eliot University Professor and President Emeritus, Harvard University Discussion: BEN BERNANKE Distinguished Fellow in Residence, Hutchins Center on Fiscal & Monetary Policy OLIVIER BLANCHARD C. Fred Bergsten Senior Fellow, Peterson Institute for International Economic ANDERSON COURT REPORTING 1800 Diagonal Road, Suite 600 Alexandria, VA 22314 Phone (703) 519-7180 Fax (703) 519-7190 FISCAL-2020/12/01 2 PARTICIPANTS (CONT’D): JASON FURMAN Professor of the Practice of Economic Policy, Harvard Kennedy School KENNETH ROGOFF Professor of Economics and Thomas D. Cabot Professor of Public Policy, Harvard University LAWRENCE SUMMERS Charles W. Eliot University Professor and President Emeritus, Harvard University LOUISE SHEINER, Moderator Senior Fellow and Policy Director, Hutchins Center on Fiscal & Monetary Policy The Brookings Institution * * * * * ANDERSON COURT REPORTING 1800 Diagonal Road, Suite 600 Alexandria, VA 22314 Phone (703) 519-7180 Fax (703) 519-7190 FISCAL-2020/12/01 3 P R O C E E D I N G S MR.
    [Show full text]
  • June 2020 Ph.D., Columbia University, New York, 1988. Advisor
    June 2020 CARMEN M. REINHART CURRICULUM VITAE EDUCATION Ph.D., Columbia University, New York, 1988. Advisor: Robert Mundell. Doctoral Dissertation: “Real Exchange Rates, Commodity Prices, and Policy Interdependence.” M. Phil., 1981 and M.A., Columbia University, New York, 1980. B.A., Florida International University, Miami, 1978. PROFESSIONAL POSITIONS Chief Economist and Vice President, World Bank, Washington DC, June 2020- Minos A. Zombanakis Professor of the International Financial System, Harvard Kennedy School, July 2012 – Dennis Weatherstone Chair, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington DC, 2011 – June 2012. Director, Center for International Economics, 2009-2010; Professor, School of Public Policy and Department of Economics, 2000 – 2010; Director, International Security and Economic Policy Specialization, 1998 – 2001; Associate Professor School of Public Policy, University of Maryland, 1996 – 2000. Senior Policy Advisor and Deputy Director, Research Department, 2001 – 2003. Senior Economist and Economist, 1988 - 1996, International Monetary Fund. Chief Economist and Vice President, 1985 – 1986; Economist, March 1982 - 1984, Bear Stearns, New York. AWARDS AND HONORS Karl Brunner Award, Swiss National Bank, planned September 2021. Mundell-Fleming Lecture, International Monetary Fund, planned November 2020. Economica, Coase-Phillips Lecture, London School of Economics, London, May 2020. FIMEF Diamond Finance Award, Instituto Mexicano de Ejecutivos de Finanzas, Mexico, August 2019. Homer Jones Memorial Lecture, St. Louis Federal Reserve, July 2019. Thomas Schelling Lecture, University of Maryland, April 2019. Carmen M. Reinhart Pa ge 1 King Juan Carlos Prize in Economics, December 2018. Wiki. Bernhard Harms Prize, Kiel Institute for the World Economy. October 2018. Adam Smith Award, National Association of Business Economists, September 2018. William F. Butler Award, New York Association for Business Economists, September 2017.
    [Show full text]
  • Deutsche Bank Prize in Financial Economics 2011
    Curriculum Vitae Kenneth Rogoff Kenneth Rogoff is Professor of Economics and Thomas D. Cabot Professor of Public Policy at Harvard University in Cambridge, USA. Rogoff has published numerous academic papers in the fields of international finance and macroeconomics. His research topics are exchange sovereign default and debt restructuring, exchange rate developments, global imbalances and the development of financial crises. The book he recently published jointly with Carmen M. Reinhart, “This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly” (2009), investigates the history of financial crises over the last eight centuries and was awarded the Paul A. Samuelson Award from the TIAA-CREF Institute. Prior to his time at Harvard, Kenneth Rogoff taught at the University of California, Berkeley and at Princeton University. He has taught as a visiting professor at institutes including the London School of Economics and New York University, and has worked as a guest researcher for the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. From 2001 to 2003 he was the Chief Economist and Director of Research at the International Monetary Fund (IMF). Kenneth Rogoff has been a member of the Group of Thirty (G30), an international committee made up of 30 leading current and former policy-makers, financiers and academics. Fellowships and Awards Recipient of the TIAA-CREF Paul A. Samuelson Award 2010 Member of the National Academy of Sciences Fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences Fellow of the World Economic Forum Fellow of the Econometric Society Grandmaster of Chess (life title awarded by the World Chess Federation (FIDE) in 1978) 1 Curriculum Vitae Kenneth Rogoff Selected Books This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly (with Carmen M.
    [Show full text]
  • Is Higher Debt an (Almost) Free Lunch?”
    Is Higher Debt an (Almost) Free Lunch?” By Kenneth Rogoff, Harvard University1 Abstract Faced with a global natural catastrophe, countries must spend to deal with the immediate crisis, and to reduce longer-term economic scarring. Sustained infrastructure and education spending can help counter headwinds to the long-term outlook. However, the fact that government borrowing rates are at extremely low levels does not imply that the very high debt, especially short-term borrowing, is a free lunch. Although real borrowing rates are on a gentle long-term declining trend, current levels are below trend. Massive underfunded old-age transfer and support programs are the most conspicuous form of hidden non-market “junior” debt, but as states cast ever-wider nets of implicit guarantees, they are far from the only ones. The fact that interest rates are below growth rates has long been the norm through advanced economies and emerging markets, but have not been a guarantee of safety. And it seems extremely likely that the rate of return on both public and private investment is comfortably above the growth rate, the world is probably not in an inefficient equilibrium where higher government debt is a free lunch. 1 Economics Department, Harvard University, Cambridge MA 02140 USA. [email protected] This paper was prepared for the European Fiscal Board annual meeting on February 26, 2021. An earlier version, Rogoff (2021), was presented at the American Economic Association meetings in January 2021. 1 I. Introduction The worldwide pandemic has already led a massive increase in government debt, especially in advanced economies.2 In the face of an extraordinary natural catastrophe, the cost/benefit/risk calculus gave few choices.
    [Show full text]
  • Reinhart and Rogoff Are Wrong About Austerity
    website: www.peri.umass.edu The following comment appeared in the April 17, 2013 print edition of the Financial Times. It is available online at http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/9e5107f8-a75c-11e2-9fbe-00144feabdc0.html#axzz2Qk3zV4ww. Reinhart and Rogoff are wrong about austerity Robert Pollin and Michael Ash In 2010, two Harvard economists published an academic paper that spoke to the world’s biggest policy question: should we cut public spending to control the deficit or use the state to rekindle economic growth? Growth in a Time of Debt by Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff has served as an important intellectual bulwark in support of austerity policies in the US and Europe. It has been cited by politicians ranging from Paul Ryan, the US congressman, to George Osborne, the UK chancellor. But we have shown that several critical findings advanced in this paper are wrong. So do we need to rethink austerity economics more broadly? Their research is best known for its result that, across a broad range of countries and periods, economic growth declines dramatically when a country’s level of public debt exceeds 90 per cent of gross domestic product. In their work with a sample of 20 advanced economies in the postwar period, they report that average annual GDP growth ranges between about 3 per cent and 4 per cent when the ratio of public debt to GDP is below 90 per cent. But it collapses to -0.1 per cent when the ratio rises above a 90 per cent threshold. In a new working paper, co-authored with Thomas Herndon, we found that these results were based on data errors and unsupportable statistical techniques.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 603 Does Excessive Sovereign Debt Really Hurt Growth? a Critique of This Time Is Different, by Reinhart and Ro
    Working Paper No. 603 Does Excessive Sovereign Debt Really Hurt Growth? A Critique of This Time Is Different, by Reinhart and Rogoff by Yeva Nersisyan L. Randall Wray June 2010 The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2010 All rights reserved ABSTRACT The worst global downturn since the Great Depression has caused ballooning budget deficits in most nations, as tax revenues collapse and governments bail out financial institutions and attempt countercyclical fiscal policy. With notable exceptions, most economists accept the desirability of expansion of deficits over the short term but fear possible long-term effects. There are a number of theoretical arguments that lead to the conclusion that higher government debt ratios might depress growth. There are other arguments related to more immediate effects of debt on inflation and national solvency. Research conducted by Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff is frequently cited to demonstrate the negative impacts of public debt on economic growth and financial stability. In this paper we critically examine their work.
    [Show full text]
  • Learning, Expectations Formation, and the Pitfalls of Optimal Control Monetary Policy
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Learning, Expectations Formation, and the Pitfalls of Optimal Control Monetary Policy Athanasios Orphanides Central Bank of Cyprus John C. Williams Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco April 2008 Working Paper 2008-05 http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/2008/wp08-05bk.pdf The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Learning, Expectations Formation, and the Pitfalls of Optimal Control Monetary Policy Athanasios Orphanides Central Bank of Cyprus and John C. Williams¤ Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco April 2008 Abstract This paper examines the robustness characteristics of optimal control policies derived un- der the assumption of rational expectations to alternative models of expectations. We assume that agents have imperfect knowledge about the precise structure of the economy and form expectations using a forecasting model that they continuously update based on incoming data. We ¯nd that the optimal control policy derived under the assumption of rational expectations can perform poorly when expectations deviate modestly from rational expectations. We then show that the optimal control policy can be made more robust by deemphasizing the stabilization of real economic activity and interest rates relative to infla- tion in the central bank loss function. That is, robustness to learning provides an incentive to employ a \conservative" central banker. We then examine two types of simple monetary policy rules from the literature that have been found to be robust to model misspeci¯cation in other contexts.
    [Show full text]
  • People in Economics
    ECONOMICS IN PEOPLE Economist as Crusader Arvind CONOMICS made Paul Krugman suasion, and through the shaping of historic famous. Punditry has made him a changes. This last is denied to all but those Subramanian celebrity, famous for being famous. who find themselves at the right place at an But Krugman aspires to be long re- epochal time. But on the first two scores, at interviews Emembered, and, in this respect, John May- least, Krugman may well become the first per- economist nard Keynes is the gold standard. Keynes left son outside the field of literature to win both his mark in three distinct ways: through the the Nobel and Pulitzer Prizes, the acme of Paul Krugman power of ideas, through the art of public per- achievement in academics and journalism. The dismal science has produced many versatile economists. Other giants of the 20th century, such as John Hicks, Ken Arrow, and Box 1 Paul Samuelson, sparkled in several fields. Sharp words Within international economics, though, Jagdish Bhagwati tells the story of Krugman’s first summer job as his research specialization has tended to be the rule. Bertil assistant at MIT. “I was in the middle of a paper on international migration. Ohlin, Eli Hecksher, Jagdish Bhagwati, and I gave Paul an outline of my thoughts—when he came back, he already had a Elhanan Helpman made seminal contri- finished paper, and I could not change even a comma! So I gave him the lead butions in the field of international trade. authorship.” Princeton’s Avinash Dixit has said that if Krugman were not so International macroeconomics has seen valuable to academics, “we should appoint him to a permanent position as the many that fall somewhere between the great translator of economic journals into English.” and the very good, including Robert Mundell, Indeed, Krugman is perhaps without peer among economists in the clarity Rudi Dornbusch, Michael Mussa, Maurice and sharpness of his prose.
    [Show full text]
  • FNCE 740: Central Banks, Macroeconomic Policy
    Central Banks, Macroeconomic Policy and Financial Markets FNCE 240/740 Fall 2021 This course will be co-taught by Professor Zvi Eckstein and Professor Joao F. Gomes. Professor Eckstein will teach most of Quarter 1 and Professor Gomes will teach during Quarter 2. Contact Information Professor Zvi Eckstein Email: [email protected] Office hours (Q1): Tuesday 1:30 – 3:00 pm and by appointment Professor Joao F. Gomes Email: [email protected] Office hours (Q2): Tuesday 3:00 – 4:30 pm and by appointment Teaching Assistants Luke Min: email: [email protected] Sergey Sarkisyan: Email: [email protected] Patrick John Shultz: Email: [email protected] Office hours: TBD Course Description Macroeconomic events and policies play a crucial role in driving financial market performance over time. This is an advanced course in applied macroeconomics that discusses both how macroeconomic policy works today and how it impacts the broad economy and financial markets. It is assumed that students have a good knowledge of intermediate undergraduate macroeconomic analysis and at least a basic understanding of the key financial markets indicators. The first half of the class focuses on understanding and predicting Central Banking (CB) decision making and how on monetary policy is conducted today. We provide the methods and knowledge on how central banks think and implement policies to reach the goals of price and financial stability as well as support of growth and employment. The core of this section connects economic knowledge, legal frameworks and the goals and methods followed by central banks. We explain the rationale for the policy prescriptions implemented today mainly by the Federal Reserve Bank (Fed) in the US as well as by the European Central Bank (ECB), Bank of Israel (BOI) and some other major countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Case and Shiller
    KARL E. CASE Wellesley College ROBERT J. SHILLER Yale University ANNE K. THOMPSON McGraw-Hill Construction What Have They Been Thinking? Homebuyer Behavior in Hot and Cold Markets ABSTRACT Questionnaire surveys undertaken in 1988 and annually from 2003 through 2012 of recent homebuyers in each of four U.S. metropoli- tan areas shed light on their expectations and reasons for buying during the recent housing boom and subsequent collapse. They also provide insight into the reasons for the housing crisis that initiated the current financial malaise. We find that homebuyers were generally well informed, and that their short- run expectations if anything underreacted to the year-to-year change in actual home prices. More of the root causes of the housing bubble can be seen in their long-term (10-year) home price expectations, which reached abnormally high levels relative to mortgage rates at the peak of the boom and have declined sharply since. The downward turning point, around 2005, of the long boom that preceded the crisis was associated with changing public understanding of speculative bubbles. etween the end of World War II and the early 2000s, the U.S. hous- Bing market contributed much to the strength of the macroeconomy. It was a major source of jobs, produced consistently rising home equity, and served as perhaps the most significant channel from monetary policy to the real economy. But starting with a drop in the S&P/Case-Shiller Home Price Index for Boston in September 2005, home prices began to fall in city after city. By the time the slump was over, prices were down almost 32 per- cent on a national basis, with many cities down by more than 50 percent, 265 266 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2012 wiping nearly $7 trillion in equity off household balance sheets.
    [Show full text]
  • Econ 2530B: International Finance
    Harvard University Economics Department Econ 2530b: International Finance, Spring 2015 Professor Gita Gopinath Logistics: My office: Littauer Center 206 Email: [email protected] Class Time and Place: Monday and Wednesday 8:30-10:00 a.m., Littauer M-17 Office hours: Monday 3:30-4:30 p.m. Teaching Fellow: Argyris Tsiaras, [email protected] Note: This is an advanced graduate level course in international macroeconomics designed for students in a Ph.D. program. There is no required text book for the course but several lectures will use chapters from the Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 4, co-edited by Gopinath, Helpman, and Rogoff, henceforth GHR. Individual copies of the chapters can be downloaded from the class website or found at the link for the textbook below. Handbook of International Economics,Volume 4. Edited by Gita Gopinath, Elhanan Helpman, Kenneth Rogoff, 1-740. Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2015. Course Requirements: There will be four problem sets and one class report. Problem sets: The problem sets will involve the use of computational software such as Matlab or any other program with which you are comfortable. You can work in groups of two at most on the problem sets. See the detailed problem set instructions on the course website. Report: Class participants will be asked to work through one paper. You can choose a paper from the list of readings below, or you can choose an unlisted reading from a leading journal. In either case, you will need to get it approved by me. I will be happy to discuss with each of you the topic in which you are interested and suggestions for a paper.
    [Show full text]