A Dual Approach to Contract Remedies Michael D

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A Dual Approach to Contract Remedies Michael D YALE LAW & POLICY REVIEW A Dual Approach to Contract Remedies Michael D. Knobler* INTRODUCTION ................................................................. 416 I. VALUE-BASED THEORY: THE CONTRACT AS OPTION...... ............... 418 A. Economic Efficiency. ............................ .......... 419 B. Contract-Law Rules....................................420 II. PERFORMANCE THEORY: THE CONTRACT AS COMMITMENT ...................... 424 A. How Performance Theorists React to Breach ............. ...... 425 B. Societal Expectations ................................... 427 C. The Deal to Which PartiesActually Consented, and Why That Matters ................................... ........ 433 D. The Search for a Middle Ground. ........................... 441 III. How COURTS TACKLE THE QUESTION .................................... 444 A. Bad-Faith Breach................ ..................... 444 B. Diminution in Value vs. Cost of Completion......................447 IV. POTENTIAL SOLUTIONS: WHY BIFURCATING REMEDIAL APPROACHES MAKES SENSE .............................................................. 448 A. Doing Nothing ....................................... 449 B. Notice .............................................. 449 C. Remedies Under a Performance Theory... ............................ 450 D. CreatingDual Systems.................................. 453 i. How Contract Law Already Tailors Itself to Parties' Needs.........453 2. Where To Apply the Option and Performance Theories.............456 3. Should the System of Remedies Be Contractible?.........................457 CONCLUSION ............................................ .......... ...................... 459 Yale Law School, J.D. expected 2012; Harvard University, A.B. 1985. I would like to thank Professors Rick Brooks, Greg Klass, and Daniel Markovits, Notes Editor Al- exandra Roth, and Daniel Hemel, Talia Kraemer, Robert Leider, Alex Platt, David Robinson, and Ellen Weis for their valuable comments. 415 YALE LAW & POLICY REVIEW 30:415 2012 INTRODUCTION Numerous disagreements in contract law stem from the answer to a straightforward definitional question: What is a contract? Is it a mutual com- mitment to perform, or is it merely a promise to deliver the agreed-upon per- formance or pay damages, with each choice treated as equally acceptable? Is a contract about the right to obtain an agreed-upon good or service at a given time, or is it about the right to obtain an agreed-upon value at a given time?' Most people answer those questions differently than the law does. People overwhelmingly view breach as immoral, favor specific performance if breach occurs, and consider exclusively economic damages undercompensatory.' In contrast, courts typically treat breach as a rational option and deny nonbreach- ing parties specific performance and both nonpecuniary and punitive damages.3 The courts' approach seems targeted to the needs of businesses rather than in- dividuals. 4 This disconnect between most people's beliefs and court enforcement un- dermines a foundational claim of contract law, that parties consent to a set of rules to guide their conduct and that courts enforce the parties' will.' Contract law zealously protects this consent principle in other areas, such as the statute of frauds, the doctrine of unconscionability, and the requirement for objective 1. Compare Louis KAPLOW & STEVEN SHAVELL, FAIRNESS VERSUS WELFARE 155-224 (2002) (arguing that the option to breach and pay damages maximizes social wel- fare), Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr., The Path of the Law, io HARV. L. REV. 457, 462 (1897) ("The duty to keep a contract at common law means a prediction that you must pay damages if you do not keep it-and nothing else."), and Richard Pos- ner, Let Us Never Blame a Contract Breaker, 107 MICH. L. REV. 1349 (2009) (sup- porting the option theory), with Bailey v. Alabama, 219 U.S. 219, 246 (1911) (Holmes, J., dissenting) ("Breach of a legal contract without excuse is wrong con- duct...."), Seana Shiffrin, Could Breach of Contract Be Immoral?, 107 MICH. L. REV. 1551 (2009) [hereinafter Shiffrin, Breach] (arguing for a perfor- mance-oriented approach), and Seana Valentine Shiffrin, The Divergence of Con- tract and Promise, 120 HARV. L. REV. 708 (2007) [hereinafter Shiffrin, Divergence] (same). 2. See infra Section II.B. 3. See infra Section I.B. 4. See infra Part I. 5. See Bidlack v. Wheelabrator Corp., 993 F.2d 603, 612 (7th Cir. 1993) (Cudahy, J., concurring) ("When the parties or the situation are such that those affected by the rule cannot bargain around it ... the rule may, in effect, supply terms to which the parties are bound but to which they have not explicitly agreed. In these cir- cumstances, courts should try to select the default rule that best reflects the course the parties would have taken had they bargained freely.") (citing FRANK H. EASTERBROOK & DANIEL R. FISCHEL, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF CORPORATE LAW 15 (1991); RICHARD POSNER, EcONOMic ANALYSIS OF LAW 372 (3d ed. 1986)). 416 A DUAL APPROACH TO CONTRACT REMEDIES manifestations of intent.6 It seems incongruous, therefore, to frustrate consent when choosing remedies for breach. This Note does not choose sides in the decades-old value versus perfor- mance dispute. Instead, it suggests a both-and answer for a question to which others have given an either-or response. Rather than saying that all contracts are mutual commitments to perform, or that all contracts are merely promises to deliver the agreed-upon performance or pay damages, why not recognize that the idea of "contract" embraces both definitions? Some contracts fit in one cat- egory, some in the other. Just as the Uniform Commercial Code (UCC) sets forth different rules for contracts among merchants and for those among other parties,7 so contract law in general should-and perhaps does-recognize the differing expectations and understandings of different contractors. If business people typically contract for value and consumers typically contract for perfor- mance, the law should be tailored to reflect that difference. This conclusion follows whether one wishes contract law to maximize au- tonomy or efficiency. Not only does an exclusively option-oriented approach to contracts frustrate the will of those who wish to contract for performance, it al- so creates party error, which is a gap between the contract as understood by at least one of the parties and the contract as enforced by the courts.9 Party error leads to inefficient contracts.o Only by abandoning the one-size-fits-all ap- proach can contract law maximize both efficiency and autonomy. I suggest two systems of remedies: a performance-oriented one for con- tracts to which at least one individual is a party and an option-oriented one for contracts involving only businesses. The performance-oriented approach would make more liberal use of specific performance and would make damages reme- dies more fully compensatory of both economic and nonpecuniary harms. The option-oriented approach would look much like current contract law, with its focus on compensating economic harms. 6. See infra notes 113-120 and accompanying text. 7. See, e.g., U.C.C. §§ 2-201(2), 2-205, 2-207(2), 2-209(2), 2-605(1)(b), 2-609(2) (1977). 8. See Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts:An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 99 YALE L.J. 87, 91 (1989) (defining a "tailored default" as a rule that attempts to provide parties "what they would have contracted for"); cf Hanoch Dagan, Pluralism and Perfectionism in Private Law 17 (Nov. 12, 2011) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with author) ("[D]espite the appeal of mon- ism's global coherence, value pluralism makes it reasonable and even desirable for law to adopt more than one set of principles and, therefore, more than one set of coherent doctrines."). 9. For a discussion of party error, see Ian Ayres, Regulating Opt-Out: An Economic Theory of Altering Rules, 121 YALE L.J. 2032 (2012). 10. See infra Section II.B. 417 YALE LAW & POLICY REVIEW 30:415 2012 This Note proceeds in four parts. Part I describes the efficiency justifica- tions for the option theory and shows that many rules of current contract law reflect this approach. Part II describes the theory that contracts constitute moral commitments, examines empirical data revealing how well that theory matches ordinary people's understandings, and argues that a law of contracts that ig- nores those understandings violates the fundamental requirement that con- tracts be consensual. Part III analyzes case law to show how this central ques- tion-is contract about performance or value?-plays out in the doctrine of bad-faith breach and in the choice of remedies between cost of completion and diminution in value. Part IV analyzes potential responses to the problems creat- ed by the duality of contract theory and suggests bifurcating contract-law reme- dies along the performance versus value divide. I. VALUE-BASED THEORY: THE CONTRACT AS OPTION The prevailing economic view of contract law focuses on its role as the fa- cilitator of voluntary exchanges, presumed to be welfare-enhancing." Transac- tions that result in gains from trade should be encouraged, according to this theory, as parties' self-interest will make contractual exchanges Pareto efficient, leaving at least one party better off and neither worse off." Sometimes, though, the parties will discover after formation that performance would be more costly to the promisor than value-producing for the promisee. In such a situation, performance would
Recommended publications
  • Paying for What You Get—Restitution Recovery for Breach of Contract
    Pace Law Review Volume 38 Issue 2 Spring 2018 Article 7 April 2018 Paying for What You Get—Restitution Recovery for Breach of Contract Jean Fleming Powers South Texas College of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.pace.edu/plr Part of the Contracts Commons Recommended Citation Jean Fleming Powers, Paying for What You Get—Restitution Recovery for Breach of Contract, 38 Pace L. Rev. 501 (2018) Available at: https://digitalcommons.pace.edu/plr/vol38/iss2/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the School of Law at DigitalCommons@Pace. It has been accepted for inclusion in Pace Law Review by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@Pace. For more information, please contact [email protected]. POWERS.DOCX (DO NOT DELETE) 5/8/18 10:33 PM Paying for What You Get—Restitution Recovery for Breach of Contract By Jean Fleming Powers* I. INTRODUCTION Many contracts casebooks, in dealing with contract remedies, include the case Sullivan v. O’Connor,1 a case dealing with an unsuccessful nose job.2 While a case about the results of surgery at first blush seems more fitting for a torts book, Sullivan, like its iconic counterpart Hawkins v. McGee3 uses a vivid fact pattern in an atypical contracts case4 to illustrate important points about contract remedies.5 Sullivan has the added benefit of providing a launching point for a discussion of the three contracts measures of recovery: expectation, reliance, and restitution.6 If the approach of the Restatement (Third) of Restitution and Unjust Enrichment7 [hereinafter referred to as “the Restatement of Restitution,” or just “the Restatement”] * Professor of Law, South Texas College of Law Houston; J.D., University of Houston Law Center, 1978; B.A.
    [Show full text]
  • Case 5:16-Cv-00137-HL Document 20 Filed 03/29/17 Page 1 of 31
    Case 5:16-cv-00137-HL Document 20 Filed 03/29/17 Page 1 of 31 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE MIDDLE DISTRICT OF GEORGIA MACON DIVISION BARBARA MORROW and BENNY MORROW, individually and on behalf of those similar situated, Civil Action No. 5:16-CV-137 (HL) Plaintiffs, v. ALLSTATE INDEMNITY COMPANY, ALLSTATE INSURANCE COMPANY, ALLSTATE FIRE & CASUALTY INSURANCE COMPANY, and ALLSTATE PROPERTY & CASUALTY INSURANCE COMPANY, Defendants. ORDER The Defendants have moved to dismiss the claims of Plaintiffs Barbara Morrow and Benny Morrow pursuant to Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6). (Doc. 13). The motion is GRANTED in part and DENIED in part. I. FACTUAL BACKGROUND1 Plaintiffs Barbara Morrow and Benny Morrow seek relief on behalf of themselves and others similarly situated for Defendants’ alleged refusal to assess and pay damages for diminished value for claims made under their homeowners’ insurance policies. As recognized by both parties, this case is part 1 The facts are taken from the allegations in the Complaint (Doc. 1) and are accepted as true for purposes of this motion. Case 5:16-cv-00137-HL Document 20 Filed 03/29/17 Page 2 of 31 of a series of cases seeking to certify in this district a class-action for diminished value in the real-property-insurance context. (See, e.g., Doc. 18, p. 15; Doc. 19, p. 8). Plaintiffs’ Complaint contains four counts: Count 1 (Doc. 1, ¶¶ 85–96), breach of contract for failure to assess diminished value; Count 2 (Doc. 1, ¶¶ 97– 106), breach of contract for failure to pay diminished value; Count 3 (Doc.
    [Show full text]
  • Compensation for Diminished Property Value Caused by Fear of Electromagnetic Fields
    Florida State University Law Review Volume 24 Issue 1 Article 5 1996 The Power Line Dilemma: Compensation for Diminished Property Value Caused by Fear of Electromagnetic Fields Andrew James Schutt [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.law.fsu.edu/lr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Andrew J. Schutt, The Power Line Dilemma: Compensation for Diminished Property Value Caused by Fear of Electromagnetic Fields, 24 Fla. St. U. L. Rev. (1996) . https://ir.law.fsu.edu/lr/vol24/iss1/5 This Comment is brought to you for free and open access by Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Florida State University Law Review by an authorized editor of Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. FLORIDA STATE UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW THE POWER LINE DILEMMA: COMPENSATION FOR DIMINISHED PROPERTY VALUE CAUSED BY FEAR OF ELECTROMAGNETIC FIELDS Andrew James Shutt VOLUME 24 FALL 1996 NUMBER 1 Recommended citation: Andrew James Shutt, Comment, The Power Line Dilemma: Compensation for Diminished Property Value Caused by Fear of Electromagnetic Fields, 24 FLA. ST. U. L. REV. 125 (1996). THE POWER LINE DILEMMA: COMPENSATION FOR DIMINISHED PROPERTY VALUE CAUSED BY FEAR OF ELECTROMAGNETIC FIELDS* ANDREW JAMES SCHUTT** I. INTRODUCTION................................................................................................... 125 II. THE THREE APPROACHES................................................................................... 130 A. The Minority View: Fear Can Never Be an Element of Damages .............. 130 1. In General............................................................................................. 130 2. The Minority View Applied: Alabama Power Co. v. Keystone Lime Co.......................................................................................................... 130 B. The Intermediate View: Award Permissible Where Fear Depresses Value, As Long as Fear is Reasonable........................................................ 133 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiduciary Remedy and Damages Survey
    ACTEC Fiduciary Litigation Committee Fiduciary Remedy and Damages Survey 50-STATE DAMAGES March 2018 In 2015, the Fiduciary Surcharge and Damages Sub-Committee distributed a twenty-six (26) question survey to ACTEC fellows regarding current case law, statutes and rules within each U.S. State on key issues relevant to financial remedies for trust and probate disputes. Separate topics related to damages and other remedies were presented to outline potential damage issues, followed by citations to language in Restatements, treatises, case law and other sources which may be followed by each State. Please direct any queries or comments regarding this 50-State Survey to Dom Campisi ([email protected]), Evans, Latham & Campisi, One Post Street, Suite 600, San Francisco, CA, 94104, (415) 421-0288. CONTRIBUTORS TO THE SURVEY Tracy Adamovich (Schiff Hardin)—New York Paul J. Barulich (Barulich Dugoni)—North Dakota, Oregon, South Dakota Kevin Bender (McGuire Woods)—Virginia David Benedetto (Vorys, Sater, Seymour and Pease)—Indiana Gerald Carp (Schiff Hardin)—New York T. Jack Challis (Polsinelli Shughart)—Missouri Patricia H. Char (K&L Gates)—Washington 2 William E. Davis (Jackson & Campbell)—District of Columbia Jane Gorham Ditelberg (Northern Trust)—Illinois W. Birch Douglas III (McGuire Woods)—Virginia Bruce K. Dudley (Wyatt, Tarrant & Combs)—Kentucky Danielle P. Ferrucci (Shipman & Goodwin)—Connecticut Lisa Forbes (Vorys, Sater, Seymour and Pease)—New Hampshire Lynn Foster (Univ. of Ark. at Little Rock School of Law)—Arkansas Stanbery Foster, Jr. (Williams, Kastner & Gibbs)—Washington Adam Gaslowitz (Gaslowitz Frankel)—Georgia Philip J. Halley (Husch Blackwell)—Wisconsin Bryon W. Harmon (Shipman & Goodwin)—Connecticut Frank N. Ikard, Jr.
    [Show full text]
  • Tort Law Review
    TORT LAW REVIEW Volume 23, Number 3 November 2015 ARTICLES Wilkinson v Downton: New work for an old tort to do? – Professor Anthony Gray The Supreme Court of the United Kingdom recently reconfirmed in Rhodes v OPO [2015] UKSC 32 the continued existence and viability of a claim for intentionally caused emotional injury, recognised in the classic case of Wilkinson v Downton. Previously, the continued existence of the principle had been doubted in that jurisdiction, as is currently the case in Australia. This article considers the recent UK decision in light of previous cases in that jurisdiction, considers the current position in Australia and North America, some parameter issues, and possible future uses of this tort. ............................................... 127 The normal measure of damages for tortious damage to chattels under English law – Dr John Ren In Coles v Hetherton [2015] 1 WLR 160; [2013] EWCA Civ 1704, the English Court of Appeal held that the normal measure of damages for tortious damage to chattels is diminution in value and reasonable cost of repair is simply evidence for the measure. This article argues that the decision departs from the previous law, which was, according to the weight of the authorities, that the normal measure be reasonable cost of repair. This article also argues that reasonable cost of repair is the better measure because it is a more reliable and direct way of carrying out restitutio in integrum than diminution in value, and it does not lead to the problems as a result of using diminution in value as the normal measure of damages.
    [Show full text]
  • A Survey of Approaches to Assessing Damages to Contaminated Private Property
    Fordham Environmental Law Review Volume 3, Number 2 2011 Article 4 A Survey of Approaches to Assessing Damages to Contaminated Private Property Kenneth F. McCallion∗ ∗ Copyright c 2011 by the authors. Fordham Environmental Law Review is produced by The Berkeley Electronic Press (bepress). http://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/elr A SURVEY OF APPROACHES TO ASSESSING DAMAGES TO CONTAMINATED PRIVATE PROPERTY by KENNETH F. McCALLION * INTRODUCTION WHENEVER a major oil or chemical spill occurs, the primary focus of attention is to ascertain how much of the oil or other contami- nant can be recovered as soon as possible, how much beach area can be cleaned, and how many sea mammals, birds and fish hatcheries can be protected.' After these initial steps are taken, attention is turned to sci- entific studies to determine the persistence of the pollutant and its impact on all aspects of the ecological system affected.2 Finally, economists, scientists and land appraisers seek to quantify all damages suffered as a result of the spill.' These damages may cover the full range of economic losses, from damages to commercial fisheries and fish processing compa- nies to quasi-economic damages relating to the losses sustained by native Americans and others who subsist off the natural resources in the af- fected lands and waters. In cases where wilderness or natural lands are contaminated, damages also may be assessed which flow from the impairment of the visual and scenic environment. Such an impairment adversely affects both the tour- ism industry and the aesthetic enjoyment of all users and non-users who suffer non-economic damages arising from the sense of loss and knowl- edge that a once pristine area has now been polluted.
    [Show full text]
  • Measure of Damages to Property
    (215) 864-6322 Nationwide Measures of Damages to Property Certain exceptions may apply and law is subject to change. Contact White and Weld, 747 P.2d 6 (Colo. App. 1987) (allowing consequential, loss of use Williams LLP for additional information, 215-864-6322. damages). Partial Loss: Diminution in fair market value from immediately before to immediately after the damage occurred. Goodyear Tire & Rubber Co. v. ALABAMA Holmes, 193 P.3d 821 (Colo. 2008). If fair market diminution does not adequately compensate the plaintiff, the courts may, at their discretion, award different Real Property: The difference between the fair market value of the property damages to ensure adequacy. Id. immediately before the damage and the fair market value immediately after the damage. Birmingham Coal & Coke Co., Inc. v. Johnson, 10 So.3d 993 (Ala. CONNECTICUT 2008). If the injury to real property is temporary, the plaintiff can recover the cost of repair plus rental value, if the total is less than the diminution in value. Borland Real Property: Generally, the diminution in fair market value from immediately v. Sanders Lead Co., 369 So.2d 523 (Ala. 1979). before to immediately after the damage occurred. However, the diminution in Personal Property: Generally, the difference between the reasonable market value value may be determined by the cost of repairing the damage provided that the of the property immediately before it was damaged and the reasonable market cost of repair does not exceed the pre-injury value of the property and does not value immediately after it was damaged. However, when the property had no enhance the value of the property over its pre-injury value.
    [Show full text]
  • July 1, 2013 John V. Fiorella, Jennifer L. Dering, ARCHER & G
    23@A?>. 5GA $% &$%' %$.),/7 219 9D<BE<=F@CB 41 )'$+%(,* 0<E? 8C# (-(,";06 IN THE COURT OF CHANCERY OF THE STATE OF DELAWARE UNIVERSAL ENTERPRISE GROUP, L.P.; 617 ) NORTH SALISBURY BOULEVARD, LLC; 176 ) FLATLANDS ROAD, LLC; 106 CEDAR STREET, ) LLC; 102 WEST CENTRAL AVENUE, LLC; 326 ) EAST DOVER STREET, LLC; 101 MAPLE ) AVENUE, LLC; 241 CYPRESS STREET, LLC; ) 28768 OCEAN GATEWAY HIGHWAY, LLC; 610 ) SNOW HILL ROAD, LLC; 5318 SNOW HILL ) ROAD, LLC; 302 MAPLE AVENUE, LLC; 177 OLD ) CAMDEN ROAD, LLC; 111 SOUTH WEST ) STREET, LLC; 1272 SOUTH GOVERNORS ) AVENUE, LLC; 505 BRIDGEVILLE HIGHWAY, ) LLC; 323 WEST STEIN HIGHWAY, LLC; 100 ) SOUTH MAIN STREET, LLC; 1104 SOUTH STATE ) STREET, LLC; 133 SALISBURY ROAD, LLC; ) UNIVERSAL DELAWARE, INC.; and DANIEL ) SINGH a/k/a DAMINDER S. BATRA; ) ) Plaintiffs, ) ) v. ) C.A. No. 4948-VCL ) DUNCAN PETROLEUM CORPORATION and ) ROBERT M. DUNCAN; ) ) Defendants. ) MEMORANDUM OPINION Date Submitted: April 4, 2013 Date Decided: July 1, 2013 John V. Fiorella, Jennifer L. Dering, ARCHER & GREINER, P.C., Wilmington, Delaware; Alan. S. Fellheimer, John J. Jacko, III, Susan M. O, FELLHEIMER & EICHEN LLP, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania; Attorneys for Plaintiffs. Daniel F. Wolcott, Jr., Ryan M. Murphy, Janine L. Hochberg, POTTER ANDERSON & CORROON LLP, Wilmington, Delaware; Attorneys for Defendants. LASTER, Vice Chancellor. The plaintiffs contend that the defendants made factual representations in a written agreement for the sale of a business that turned out to be wrong. They sued for fraud and breach of contract. At trial, the plaintiffs proved that the defendants knew their representations were false, but the plaintiffs failed to prove reliance and therefore could not establish fraud.
    [Show full text]
  • Retribution in Contract Law
    Retribution in Contract Law Marco J. Jimenez* For the last several centuries, there has been a powerful clash between two very different ways of understanding what contract law and contract remedies ought to accomplish. The older view, which found its most powerful philosophical expression in Kant and has been advanced by modern scholars like Charles Fried,1 is firmly rooted in the principle of respect for individual autonomy, and holds that parties have an obligation to keep their promises because they have invoked a convention (i.e., contract law) whose very purpose “it is to give grounds — moral grounds — for another to expect the promised performance.”2 According to this view of contract law, when a party invokes such a convention but nevertheless breaches their contract, not only do they wrong the other party by failing to properly value and respect them as autonomous agents, but their wrong frequently harms the other party as well, thereby creating a normative imbalance between the parties that seems to demand rectification on the ground of corrective justice.3 It is for this reason that, * Copyright © 2018 Marco J. Jimenez. Professor of Law, Stetson University College of Law; J.D., Yale Law School, 2000; B.A., B.S., University of Southern California, 1997. This Article was supported by a generous research grant from the Stetson University College of Law. I would like to thank Dean Chris Pietruszkiewicz and the Stetson University College of Law for their support of this project. Finally, I would like to take this opportunity to express my deep gratitude for the hard work and extraordinary research assistance of Rachelle Carnes and Catherine Selm, to thank the extraordinary editors at the UC Davis Law Review who made this Article better than it would otherwise have been by providing a number of helpful suggestions and catching several errors in the original text, and to express my enduring gratefulness for the love and understanding of my wife and son.
    [Show full text]
  • In the United States District Court for the Eastern District of Pennsylvania
    Case 2:16-cv-03604-JHS Document 43 Filed 03/30/17 Page 1 of 2 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA JERRY A. CONQUEST, Plaintiff, CIVIL ACTION v. NO. 16-03604 WMC MORTGAGE CORP., et al. Defendant. ORDER AND NOW, this 29th day of March 2017, upon consideration of Plaintiff’s Amended Complaint (Doc. No. 16), Defendants’ Motion[s] to Dismiss [the Amended Complaint] (Doc. Nos. 14, 17, 18, 19, 20, 28), Plaintiff’s Response in Opposition to the Motions to Dismiss (Doc. Nos. 22, 31, 32, 33, 35), Defendants’ Reply in Support of the Motions to Dismiss (Doc. Nos. 24, 25, 36, 37, 38, 39), and in accordance with the Opinion of the Court issued this day, it is ORDERED as follows: 1. Defendant American Modern Home’s Motion to Dismiss (Doc. No. 14) is GRANTED; 2. Defendant Southwest Business Corporation’s Motion to Dismiss (Doc. No. 17) is GRANTED; 3. Defendant Vanderbilt Mortgage and Finance, Inc.’s Motion to Dismiss (Doc. No 18) is GRANTED; 4. Defendant Mortgage Electronic Registration Systems, Inc.’s Motion to Dismiss (Doc. No 19) is GRANTED; Case 2:16-cv-03604-JHS Document 43 Filed 03/30/17 Page 2 of 2 5. Defendant MERSCORP Holding, Inc.’s Motion to Dismiss (Doc. No 19) is GRANTED; 6. Defendant HomeFirst Agency, Inc.’s Motion to Dismiss (Doc. No. 20) is GRANTED; 7. Defendant WMC Mortgage LLC’s Motion to Dismiss (Doc. No 28) is GRANTED; and 8. The Clerk of Court shall close this case for statistical purposes.
    [Show full text]
  • "Opportunistic" Breach of Contract: Its Fit in Rhode Island Kelsey A
    Roger Williams University Law Review Volume 22 Article 3 Issue 3 Vol. 22: No. 3 (Summer 2017) Summer 2017 Disgorgement of Defendant's Gains from "Opportunistic" Breach of Contract: Its Fit in Rhode Island Kelsey A. Hayward J.D. 2018, Roger Williams University School of Law Follow this and additional works at: http://docs.rwu.edu/rwu_LR Part of the Civil Law Commons, Contracts Commons, and the Legal Remedies Commons Recommended Citation Hayward, Kelsey A. (2017) "Disgorgement of Defendant's Gains from "Opportunistic" Breach of Contract: Its Fit in Rhode Island," Roger Williams University Law Review: Vol. 22 : Iss. 3 , Article 3. Available at: http://docs.rwu.edu/rwu_LR/vol22/iss3/3 This Notes and Comments is brought to you for free and open access by the School of Law at DOCS@RWU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Roger Williams University Law Review by an authorized editor of DOCS@RWU. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Comments Disgorgement of Defendant’s Gains from “Opportunistic” Breach of Contract: Its Fit in Rhode Island Kelsey A. Hayward* For breach of contract, should the plaintiff/non-breaching party be able to get a remedy based on any profit the defendant made from the breach? Contract law generally answers “no”: The norm is that the non-breaching party who seeks a monetary remedy is entitled to “compensation” for its losses resulting from the breach rather than “disgorgement” or “restitution” of the defendant’s gains resulting from the breach.1 But consider the following scenario from the Restatement (Third) of Restitution and Unjust Enrichment (2011): Farmer sells Buyer his entire crop of carrots for the coming season at a price of $500 per ton.
    [Show full text]
  • The Efficiency of a Disgorgement As a Remedy for Breach of Contract
    Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons Faculty Scholarship 1-1-1989 The Efficiency of a Disgorgement as a Remedy for Breach of Contract Sidney DeLong Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/faculty Part of the Law and Economics Commons, and the Legal Remedies Commons Recommended Citation Sidney DeLong, The Efficiency of a Disgorgement as a Remedy for Breach of Contract, 22 IND. L. REV. 737 (1989). https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/faculty/687 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Indiana Law Review Volume 22 1989 Number 3 THE EFFICIENCY OF A DISGORGEMENT AS A REMEDY FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT SIDNEY W. DELONO* Thesis: Economic analysis suggests that to give a contract promisee a general remedy that would require a breaching promisor to disgorge any benefit of breach would hinder the efficient post-contractual real- location of performance resources. This article explores certain situa- tions in which disgorgement appears to be an efficient remedy for breach of contract, including cases in which the breaching party refuses to pay contract damages at the time of breach. A rule permitting promisees to recover as "prejudgment interest" the breacher's benefit from withholding payment of damages would, in theory, be efficient in allocating the risk of the breacher's credit worthiness to the best risk bearer.
    [Show full text]