A Transatlantic History of the Social Sciences: Robber Barons, the Third Reich and the Invention of Empirical Social Research

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A Transatlantic History of the Social Sciences: Robber Barons, the Third Reich and the Invention of Empirical Social Research "In the Shadow of Nazi Rule: Two Generation Units of Social Scientists." A Transatlantic History of the Social Sciences: Robber Barons, the Third Reich and the Invention of Empirical Social Research. Fleck, Christian. London: Bloomsbury Academic, 2011. 111–164. Bloomsbury Collections. Web. 27 Sep. 2021. <http://dx.doi.org/10.5040/9781849662932.ch-004>. Downloaded from Bloomsbury Collections, www.bloomsburycollections.com, 27 September 2021, 03:03 UTC. Copyright © Christian Fleck 2011. You may share this work for non-commercial purposes only, provided you give attribution to the copyright holder and the publisher, and provide a link to the Creative Commons licence. 4 IN THE SHADOW OF NAZI RULE: TWO GENERATION UNITS OF SOCIAL SCIENTISTS At the end of the first third of the twentieth century, German-language sociology suffered a dramatic caesura. For a long time, René König’s dictum that after 1933 the discipline had been ‘brought to a brutal standstill’ (König 1958: 14) was accepted as the ultimate description of the impact of the Nazis’ rise to power on sociology. Helmut Schelsky’s contrary opinion, at the time, that ‘it was our sociol- ogy itself that had run out of subject matter, the melodies had all been played through, the fronts were consolidating, and little evolutionary momentum was left within the discipline itself’ (Schelsky 1959: 36), did not register. Decades later the debate resurfaced under the new heading of ‘sociology in National Socialism’ (Rammstedt 1985; Klingemann 1996). At the end of his life, König vehemently protested against what he felt to be an exculpation of Nazi sociologists (König 1987). The debate, fraught with polemics, criticism and counter-criticism, carried on for some time and ran dry without any consensus being reached. The present study is not aiming for consensus either, but proposes a new perspective. Analysing the career paths of the sociologists of the time may indeed shed new light on the repercussions of the year 1933 (or, for Austria, 1938). First of all, a collective biography of German-speaking sociologists should identify the commonalities as well as the differences that marked this genera- tion. Karl Mannheim’s concept of Generationseinheit (generation unit) seems the adequate tool for drawing a comparison between those who emigrated and those who did not. In his essay ‘The Problem of Generations’ (Mannheim 1952), first published in 1928, Mannheim distinguished between generation, social location of a generation and generation unit. Given the ‘similarity of location … within a social whole’, Mannheim came to the conclusion that a generation tends to show something like a ‘characteristic mode of thought and experience’ (Mannheim 1952: 291). Often, however, the similarity of location as such does not suffice as a basis for postulating a generational bond. For the latter to emerge, there must be something like a common destiny. Within a 111 FFleck.indbleck.indb 111111 003/02/113/02/11 55:56:56 PPMM A Transatlantic History of the Social Sciences generational bond constituted by certain political and historical facts, there may be contrasting generation units, differing in their way of coping with the same historical and political macro-event: ‘Youth experiencing the same con- crete historical problems may be said to be part of the same actual generation; while those groups within the same actual generation which work up the material of their common experiences in different specific ways, constitute separate generation units’ (Mannheim 1952: 304). In the present case, the con- cept of separate generations clearly suggests itself. Secondly, a comparison between two science cultures that can be identified in terms of nation states is also attempted here: situations in Germany and Austria were different, but the common language certainly made the inhabit- ants of these countries more similar to each other than to the inhabitants of other states. Table 4.1 gives a preliminary idea of these differences. While the number of universities and students is rather close to the base value of the population, the other ratios clearly differ. In Austria there were more univer- sity teachers, and the 1938 dismissal rate for Austria was slightly higher than the 1933 rate for Germany. There are remarkable differences in the last two cells, but one has allow for the fact that there have as yet been few – indeed, hardly any – contributions by Austrians to the editorial decisions of the pub- lications (Hagemann and Krohn 1999a; Hagemann and Krohn 1999b; Smelser and Baltes 2001) used to estimate the figures. Table 4.1 Ratios between Austria and Germany For every 100 Germans account for … Austrians Population (1930s) 10 Universities (1930s) 13 Students (1930s) 15 Teaching staff (1930s) 30 Dismissed professors (1933 and 1938, resp.) 34 Grantees of the Emergency Committee (1933–44) 20 Émigré Economists (1933–45) 43 Leading Social Scientists (20th Century) 77 Sources: Population: Mitchell 1992. Universities, Students and Teaching staff: Titze 1987; Völlmecke 1979. Dismissed professors: for Germany – A Crisis in the University World 1935; for Austria – Archive of the Society for the Protection of Science and Learning 1938. Grantees of the Emergency Committee: Files of the Emergency Committee in Aid of Displaced German Scholars, New York Public Library, Rare Book and Manuscript Division, New York; Duggan and Drury 1948; émigré economists – Krohn and Hagemann 1999; leading social scientists – Smelser and Baltes 2001. Author’s calculations. Third, to allow for the effects of the change of political regimes to show, and for individual career paths to be traced, a period spanning three decades from the mid-1920s to the mid-1950s was chosen for analysis here. The starting point is 112 FFleck.indbleck.indb 111212 003/02/113/02/11 55:56:56 PPMM In the Shadow of Nazi Rule: Two Generation Units of Social Scientists early enough, with respect to the handing over of power to the Nazis, to allow us to establish the positions held before change set in, and the end is late enough, with respect to the time when most of the emigrants had left the German-language area, to allow us to reconstruct their careers after displacement. It furthermore enables us to account for the dangers faced by non-emigrants, such as military service and imprisonment, likely to have caused breaks in their careers. Fourth, the following specifically concerns sociology. This is easier said than done, for while sociology as an intellectual project was not at all uncommon in the German-language area, it did not exist as a formal discipline, i.e. in an institution- alized form. One thus comes up against a number of difficulties when trying to establish the boundaries of sociology as a discipline-in-the–making. Doing so hor- izontally among the social sciences – delimiting sociology from other disciplines – is difficult since the latter were far from being clearly outlined. In the German-language area, the emergence of the ‘third science culture’ (Lepenies 1985) was different and slower than that of other countries. As for the date that marks the beginning of sociology as a scientific discipline, there is no consensus at all. WHO IS A SOCIOLOGIST? Right after the problem of how to delimit a discipline from its neighbours, there is the problem of whom to count among its members. Who makes up the very top of the status hierarchy is just as uncontroversial as the very bottom, the students. Full professors seldom become ignored, while the many gradu- ates of a discipline are rarely given any more room in its history than is needed for some statistics. But what about those in between? Limiting investigations to sociologists with a university affiliation or, even more restrictively, to those who were actually qualified as lecturers or professors, would be too narrow a definition of the population, since it means excluding a number of scholars who today are definitely considered part of the history of sociology. Nor does it help much to consult the ‘membership list’ of the Deutsche Gesellschaft für Soziologie (DGS, German Sociological Association, Austrians included) to identify German-speaking sociologists in the first half of the twen- tieth century. The DGS existed from 1910, but since it conceived of itself as an association of notables, eligibility for membership was severely restricted. And since there is no other membership list of the proto-discipline, the only way to establish the population is to reconstruct it on the basis of contemporaneous classifications and later delimitations. This may be done by (a) relying on self- reports; (b) using an independent definition as a basis for a reconstruction of the group; (c) referring to similar attempts by others; or (d) relying on reports by contemporary or latter-day peers. (a) Relying on Self-reports: Anyone Calling Him or Herself a Sociologist is a Sociologist One way of defining sociology is to say that it is what sociologists do. So, as an analogy, one way to count the membership of this discipline may be to label as 113 FFleck.indbleck.indb 111313 003/02/113/02/11 55:56:56 PPMM A Transatlantic History of the Social Sciences sociologists all those who claim to be so. An excellent contemporaneous source for this is Kürschners Deutscher Gelehrten Kalender . Between 1926 and 1950, six issues were published of this ‘Who’s Who’ of German-language scholars, and sociology is indeed included in the index of disciplines in the 1926 issue for the first time. A search of the indices of names in those six issues of the Kürschners results in a total of two hundred and seventy male and seven female (2 per cent) sociologists. Almost half of the names appear only once, one-fifth appear twice, and only thirty-five individuals (12 per cent) appear as often as four times or more within these twenty-five years.
Recommended publications
  • The Essential Von Mises
    The Essential von Mises The Essential von Mises Murray N. Rothbard LvMI MISES INSTITUTE Scholar, Creator, Hero © 1988 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute The Essential von Mises first published in 1973 by Bramble Minibooks, Lansing Michigan Copyright © 2009 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute and published under the Creative Commons Attribution License 3.0. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/ by/3.0/ New matter copyright © 2009 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute Ludwig von Mises Institute 518 West Magnolia Avenue Auburn, Alabama 36832 Mises.org ISBN: 978-1-933550-41-1 Contents Introduction by Douglas E. French . vii Part One: The Essential von Mises 1. The Austrian School. 3 2. Mises and “Austrian Economics”: The Theory of Money and Credit . .13 3. Mises on the Business Cycle . 21 4. Mises in the Interwar Period . 25 5. Mises on Economic Calculation and Socialism . 29 6. Mises on the Methodology of Economics. 31 7. Mises and Human Action . 35 8. Mises in America . .41 9. The Way Out . 45 Part Two: Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero 1. The Young Scholar . 51 2. The Theory of Money and Credit. 55 3. The Reception of Mises and of Money and Credit . 67 4. Mises in the 1920s: Economic Adviser to the Government . 73 5. Mises in the 1920s: Scholar and Creator . 79 6. Mises in the 1920s: Teacher and Mentor . 91 7. Exile and the New World . 99 8. Coda: Mises the Man . 115 v Introduction he two essays printed in this monograph were written by my Tteacher Murray N. Rothbard (1926–1995) about his teacher Ludwig von Mises (1881–1973).
    [Show full text]
  • Foundational Research in Accounting: Professional I Memoirs and Beyond ______
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics Richard Mattessich: Foundational research in accounting: professional I memoirs and beyond _____________________________________________________________________________________ FOUNDATIONAL RESEARCH IN ACCOUNTING: PROFESSIONAL MEMOIRS AND BEYOND Richard Mattessich Arthur Andersen & Co. Alumni Professor Emeritus Faculty of Commerce and Business Administration University of British Columbia Vancouver, B.C. Canada V6T 1Z2 _____________________________________________________________________________ DE COMPUTIS Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad Spanish Journal of Accounting History No. 5 Diciembre 2006 Richard Mattessich: Foundational research in accounting: professional II memoirs and beyond _____________________________________________________________________________________ Foundational research in accounting: professional memoirs and beyond. Mattessich, Richard - Accounting, autobiography, history, foundations, research. First edition (1995), published by Chuo University Press, Higashinakano 742-1/ Hachioji/ Tokyo 192-03/ Japan. ISBN (Canada) Copyright 8 1995 Richard Mattessich Second extended edition (until 2006), published by Asociación Española de Contabilidad y Administración de Empresas (AECA), Rafael Bergamín, 16-B, 28043 Madrid, in DE COMPUTIS, Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad (Spanish Journal of Accounting History), no. 5, December 2006. ISSN: 1886-1881 Copyright 2006 Richard Mattessich
    [Show full text]
  • The Nationalökonomische Gesellschaft from Its Foundation to the Postwar Period: Prosperity and Depression
    Empirica https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-019-09439-4 ORIGINAL PAPER The Nationalökonomische Gesellschaft from its foundation to the postwar period: prosperity and depression Hansjörg Klausinger1 © The Author(s) 2019 Abstract The Nationalökonomische Gesellschaft (NOeG) was founded in June 1918 by a group of young scholars, mostly based in Vienna, as a forum for theoretical debate. Despite the prominent economists involved (e.g. Schumpeter, Mises, Mayer, Spann, Amonn) its activities soon petered out. The relaunch of the NOeG in 1927 origi- nated from the necessity of the two strands of the Austrian school, led by Mayer and Mises, to fnd some tolerable arrangement; Spann and economists outside the University of Vienna were excluded. Around 1930 the NOeG and Vienna in gen- eral proved an attraction for many well-known economists from abroad, and many of the papers presented were printed and cited in frst-rate journals. Yet with the emigration of many Austrian economists during the 1930s the NOeG mirrored the general decline of academic economics in Austria and the number and quality of the papers presented decreased. After the Anschluss 1938 the NOeG and its president Mayer were quick in dismissing its Jewish members and in the following adhered to a strategy of inconspicuous adaptation; its formal existence did not lead to any substantial activities. The post-war period was characterized by the restoration of the situation before 1938, with Mayer’s continued presence at the university as well as at the NOeG a case in point. In the end, it led Austrian academic economics into a state of international isolation and “provincialization” much lamented by the émigré economists of the Austrian school.
    [Show full text]
  • Diplomarbeit
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by OTHES Diplomarbeit Titel der Diplomarbeit: Die historische Entwicklung der Politischen Bildung im Bereich der Volksschule Verfasserin: Barbara Steinacher angestrebter akademischer Grad: Magistra der Philosophie (Mag. phil.) Wien, April 2010 Studienkennzahl lt. Studienblatt: A 300 Studienrichtung lt. Studienblatt: Politikwissenschaft Matrikelnummer: 0200694 Betreuer: Univ.-Doz. Dr. Johann Dvo řák Inhalt 1) Einleitung 4 1.1) Zur Relevanz des Themas 4 1.2) Aufbau 5 1.3) Schwierigkeiten sowie Quellenlage 6 1.4) Methodik 7 1.5) Thesen und Fragestellungen 7 Teil I 2) Definitionen 9 2.1) Erklärungsmuster zur Politischen Bildung 9 2.2) Ziele 10 2.3) Politische Bildung in der Volksschule 15 2.4) Drei Ansätze der Politischen Bildung in der Volksschule 15 2.5) Unterrichtsprinzip 19 Teil II 3) Historischer Abriss 21 3.1) Monarchie 21 3.1.1) Allgemeine Schulordnung 1774 21 3.2) Reformversuche unter Joseph II. 23 3.3) Weitere Reformen 25 3.3.1) Vinzenz Eduard Milde 26 3.4) Zur Zeit Kaiser Franz Josephs I. 27 3.5) Das Reichsvolksschulgesetz 29 3.5.1) Die Maigesetze 30 3.6) Überblick: Die politische Situation in der Monarchie 31 3.7) Zusammenfassung 33 2 4) Ein neues Schulzeitalter 35 4.1) Otto Glöckel 35 4.2) Glöckels Schulreform 36 4.2.1) Trennung Schule und Kirche 37 4.2.2) Meinungen der Parteien zur Schulreform 42 4.3) Exkurs: Sozialistische Erziehung 44 4.4) Exkurs: Arbeiterverein Kinderfreunde 48 4.5) Schönbrunner Erzieherschule 52 4.6) Tätigkeiten der Kinderfreunde 52 4.7) Überblick: Die politische Sit.
    [Show full text]
  • Doc 11366.Pdf
    SE PROHIBE Subrayar y/o margina,- esta lb" en " sub.nyatia, SE CC r. E DE SU 11MOR f.t 41.1 n7:7, COPYRIGHT 1976 JOSEPH EDWARD KECKEISSEN Propleded de le 1.1111PERSIDAD FRANC15(0 MARIN1111 THE MEANINGS OF ECONOMIC LAW JOSEPH EDWARD KECKEISSEN " ‘\‘10 A thesis presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Business Administration, New York University, in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy. 1976 -76 3 10. PREFACE ZLI It is a distinct source of satisfaction to be able to present to New York University this dissertation entitled "The Meanings of Economic Law." It covers a subject, which though close to the heart of economic theory, has been long neglected in the journals. It presents, for the first time in a single work, an orderly compilation of the many notions that economists have held about law, and attempts to sound out the underlying reasons for and the logic behind such a variety of opinions, perhaps suggesting an answer to that tantalizing question as to whether there are economic laws after all. To accomplish this task it was necessary to research large samplings of the literature of two centuries, at least of that part that is available in English. Unfortunately, it was not possible to broaden this investigation to analyze terms other than law, which might be used to describe the generalizations of economics. Nor could a complete epistemo- logical study be made at this time of what economic law "should" really mean. Hopefully, such studies will not be long in forthcoming.
    [Show full text]
  • The University of Chicago Experimental Futures And
    THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO EXPERIMENTAL FUTURES AND IMPOSSIBLE PROFESSIONS: PSYCHOANALYSIS, EDUCATION, AND POLITICS IN INTERWAR VIENNA, 1918-1938 A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF THE DIVISION OF THE SOCIAL SCIENCES IN CANDIDACY FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY DEPARTMENT OF HISTORY BY PHILLIP J. HENRY CHICAGO, ILLINOIS AUGUST 2018 TABLE OF CONTENTS DISSERTATION ABSTRACT v ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS x INTRODUCTION 1 Red Vienna 6 Interwar Psychoanalysis 20 Psychoanalysis, Education, and Politics in Interwar Vienna 35 CHAPTER ONE Between Seduction and Sublimation: The Emergence of a Psychoanalytic Theory of Education, 1896-1914 44 Unstable Foundations 45 Verführung and its Vicissitudes 50 Erziehung zur Realität 65 The Possibilities for Prophylaxis and the Elusiveness of Sublimation 78 Psychoanalysis and the New Education 91 CHAPTER TWO Recasting Bourgeois Psychoanalysis: Education, Authority, and the Politics of Analytic Therapy in the Freudian Revision of 1918 99 Out of the Wilderness, Into the Wasteland 104 Suggestion and its Discontents 110 Forming a Class Body for Psychoanalysis 119 The Ways and Means of Psychoanalysis 123 Beyond the Classical Paradigm 135 ii CHAPTER THREE Fashioning a New Psychoanalysis: Exceptional States and the Crisis of Authority in Analytic Practice, 1919-1925 139 States of Exception 146 Analysis for the Masses 157 Ego Politics and the Pedagogy of Reconstruction 167 Psychoanalytisches Neuland 177 The Limits of Analytic Therapy 184 CHAPTER FOUR The Mass Psychology of Education: Freudian Experiments in Collective
    [Show full text]
  • Ludwig Von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero
    Murray N. Rothbard Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero Introduction The purpose of this essay is to discuss and celebrate the life and work of one of the great creative minds of our century. Ludwig von Mises was born on September 29, 1881, in the city of Lemberg (now Lvov), in Galicia, in the Austro-Hungarian Empire. His father, Arthur Edler von Mises, a Viennese construction engineer working for the Austrian railroads, was stationed in Lemberg at the time. Ludwig’s mother, Adele Landau, also came from a prominent family in Vienna: her uncle, Dr. Joachim Landau, was a deputy from the Liberal Party in the Austrian Parliament. The Young Scholar Though the pre-eminent theorist of our time, Mises’s interest, as a teenager, centered in history, particularly economic and administrative history. But even while still in high school, he reacted against the relativism and historicism rampant in the German-speaking countries, dominated by the Historical School. In his early historical work, he was frustrated to find historical studies virtually consisting of paraphrases from official government reports. Instead, he yearned to write genuine economic history. He early disliked the State orientation of historical studies. Thus, in his memoirs, Mises writes: “It was my intense interest in historical knowledge that enabled me to perceive readily the inadequacy of German historicism. It did not deal with scientific problems, but with the glorification and justification of Prussian policies and Prussian authoritarian government. The German universities were state institutions and the instructors were civil servants. The professors were aware of this civil-service status, that is, they saw themselves as servants of the Prussian king”.[1] Ludwig von Mises entered the University of Vienna at the turn of the twentieth century and his major professor was the economic historian Karl Grünberg, a member of the German Historical School and a statist who was interested in labor history, agricultural history, and Marxism.
    [Show full text]
  • TRYGVE HAAVELMO (ECONOMICS, 1989) Olav Bjerkholt
    Olav Njølstad (ed.) Norwegian Nobel Prize Laureates From Bjørnson to Kydland TRYGVE HAAVELMO (ECONOMICS, 1989) Olav Bjerkholt Translated from Norwegian by Chris Saunders Universitetsforlaget © Universitetsforlaget 2006 ISBN-13: 978-82-15-00698-7 ISBN-10: 82-15-00698-1 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical or photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior permission of Universitetsforlaget. Enquiries should be sent to the Rights Department, Universitetsforlaget, Oslo, at the address below. TRYGVE HAAVELMO Economics, 1989 Olav Bjerkholt INTRODUCTION Trygve Haavelmo was born at Skedsmo in 1911 and grew up in Strømmen. His antecedents were farmers in Hallingdal, but his father had left the family farm to pursue a career in teaching. Haavelmo sat his university entrance exam (“artium”) in 1930, studied economics and graduated in 1933 with a cand.oecon degree. During his last two years at university he attended lectures by Ragnar Frisch, who had recently returned from the US. Haavelmo’s time at university coincided with the worst years of the Depression. According to what he divulged many years later, he was initially attracted to philology or some form of engineering, but opted for economics because the course’s brevity meant it could be completed in three years. Frisch probably recognised Haavelmo’s talent for research at the statistics seminars which formed part of his studies. After graduating, Haavelmo was offered a research assistant job at Frisch’s Institute of Economics. This was the start of an apprenticeship from 1933 to 1937 at Frisch’s statistical laboratory.
    [Show full text]
  • Deaf-Blind Education
    1 Chapter 3: The development of education for deaf-blind people The development of education for deaf-blind people Legacy of the Past The book Legacy of the Past (Some aspects of the history of blind educa- tion, deaf education, and deaf-blind education with emphasis on the time before 1900) contains three chapters: Chapter 1: The development of education for blind people Chapter 2: The development of education for deaf people Chapter 3: The development of education for deaf-blind people In all 399 pp. An internet edition of the whole book in one single document would be very unhandy. Therefore, I have divided the book into three documents (three inter- netbooks). In all the three documents contain the whole book. Legacy of the Past. This Internetbook is Chapter 3: The development of education for deaf-blind people. Foreword In his Introduction the author expresses very clearly that this book is not The history of blind education, deaf education and deaf-blind education but some aspects of their history of education with emphasis on the time before 1900. Nevertheless - having had the privilege of reading it - my opinion is that this volume must be one of the most extensive on the market today regarding this part of the history of special education. For several years now I have had the great pleasure of working with the author, and I am not surprised by the fact that he really has gone to the basic sources trying to find the right answers and perspectives. Who are they - and in what ways have societies during the centuries faced the problems? By going back to ancient sources like the Bible, the Holy Koran and to Nordic Myths the author gives the reader an exciting perspective; expressed, among other things, by a discussion of terms used through our history.
    [Show full text]
  • Oskar Morgenstern and the Viennese Economists in the 1930’S Abstract
    e i g o l o n h c e t a l t NOTE DE RECHERCHE e e c n From Austroliberalism to e i c Anschluss : s a l Oskar Morgenstern and r u s the Viennese Economists e h in the 1930’s c r e h c e r e d e r i a t i s r e v i n a u c r . e m t a q n i u . t s e r r i Robert Leonard t c . n w e w C 2006-03 w UNIVERSITÉ DE Université du Québec à Montréal SHERBROOKE Adresse postale CIRST Université du Québec à Montréal C.P. 8888, Succursale Centre-ville Montréal (Québec) Canada, H3C 3P8 Adresse civique CIRST Université du Québec à Montréal Pavillon Thérèse-Casgrain, 3e étage 455, boul. René-Lévesque Est, Bureau W-3042 Montréal (Québec) Canada H2L 4Y2 Pour nous joindre Téléphone : (514) 987-4018 Télécopieur : (514) 987-7726 Courrier électronique : [email protected] Site Internet : www.cirst.uqam.ca Conception graphique : Marie-Andrée Desgagnés et Lysanne Lessard Révision linguistique: Jocelyne Raymond ISBN-13 978-2-923333-20-5 ISBN-10 2-923333-20-9 Dépôt légal Bibliothèque et Archives nationales du Québec, 2006 Bibliothèque et Archives Canada, 2006 Table of Contents ABSTRACT.................................................................................................................................................................. 1 INTRODUCTION........................................................................................................................................................ 1 THE LIMITS OF MATHEMATICAL REPRESENTATION................................................................................ 3 SOCIAL PLANNING AND CONTEMPORARY CIVILIZATION......................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Haberler, Machlup, and Morgenstern and the Post- Emigration Elaboration of Austrian Economics1 (Preliminary Draft—Please Do Not Cite)
    “Un-Austrian” Austrians? Haberler, Machlup, and Morgenstern and the Post- Emigration Elaboration of Austrian Economics1 (Preliminary Draft—Please Do Not Cite) ABSTRACT: Historians of economic thought have begun to reintegrate “un-Austrian” Austrians back into discussions of Austrian Economics, yet many scholars have argued that the Austrian School dissolved “in the wilderness” of emigration. This paper argues that a renewed focus on the networks established by the Austrians themselves, before and after emigration, reveals a distinctly different picture of Austrian Economics. Focusing on their shared interest in international economics, we see the émigré Austrians continuing “traditional” Austrian ideas while also reconstituting and elaborating new Austrian affiliations. Ultimately, we find ourselves in agreement with Herbert Furth that Austrian Economics is far broader than Hayek, Mises, and their acolytes would have it, and that it is vital to understand and preserve this more diverse tradition. You know that I consider Hayek the ‘Dean’ of the Austrian School; nevertheless, he still is only one of many members, and has no authority to excommunicate those who are not fully in agreement with his views. Moreover, the sentences you quote don’t contradict my opinion about Auspitz, Lieben, and Schumpeter: sure, they can be included in the school only ‘with qualifications’ or ‘not wholly’ – but that is very different from calling them ‘un-Austrian’! Incidentally – would you deny that you, too – like every original thinker – has absorbed ‘many
    [Show full text]
  • Journal for the History of Analytical Philosophy Volume 3, Number 3
    Journal for the History of American Pragmatism and the Vienna Circle: Analytical Philosophy The Early Years Volume 3, Number 3 Thomas Uebel Discussions of the relation between pragmatism and logical em- Editor in Chief piricism tend to focus on the period when the logical empiricists Sandra Lapointe, McMaster University found themselves in exile, mostly in the United States, and then Editorial Board attempt to gauge the actual extent of their convergence. My con- Gary Ebbs, Indiana University Bloomington cern lies with the period before that and the question whether Greg Frost-Arnold, Hobart and William Smith Colleges pragmatism had an earlier influence on the development of logical Henry Jackman, York University empiricism, especially on the thought of the former members of Kevin C. Klement, University of Massachusetts the “first” Vienna Circle. I argue for a substantially qualified af- Lydia Patton, Virginia Tech firmative answer. Marcus Rossberg, University of Connecticut Mark Textor, King’s College London Richard Zach, University of Calgary Audrey Yap, University of Victoria Review Editors Juliet Floyd, Boston University Chris Pincock, Ohio State University Assistant Review Editor Sean Morris, Metropolitan State University of Denver Editorial Assistant Daniel Harris, Hunter College ©2015 Thomas Uebel American Pragmatism and the Vienna Circle: er”—meaning personal interaction—and “chiefly”—for not all members of the Circle were so affected. I will also do so without The Early Years contradicting Feigl: the proposed revision does not require of the members concerned a significant knowledge of American philos- Thomas Uebel ophy as such. This does not mean, however, that according to the proposed revision there was only negligble impact from pragma- tism on the Vienna Circle.
    [Show full text]