Coalition Manipulation of the Gale-Shapley Algorithm

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Coalition Manipulation of the Gale-Shapley Algorithm Coalition Manipulation of the Gale-Shapley Algorithm Weiran Shen and Pingzhong Tang Yuan Deng Institute for Interdisciplinary Information Sciences Department of Computer Science Tsinghua University Duke University Beijing, China Durham, NC 27708, USA femersonswr,[email protected] [email protected] Abstract him yet. Then each woman rejects all men but her favorite one. The algorithm terminates when no man can make any It is well-known that the Gale-Shapley algorithm is not truth- proposal. ful for all agents. Previous studies in this category concentrate on manipulations using incomplete preference lists by a sin- It is shown that the matching computed by the Gale- gle woman and by the set of all women. Little is known about Shapley algorithm is stable and the algorithm is guaranteed manipulations by a subset of women. to terminate for each legal input, which immediately implies In this paper, we consider manipulations by any subset of that every instance of the stable matching problem has a sta- women with arbitrary preferences. We show that a strong ble matching. There are many interesting structural results in Nash equilibrium of the induced manipulation game always the literature of stable matching theory. For example, among exists among the manipulators and the equilibrium outcome all stable matchings, the matching computed by the Gale- is unique and Pareto-dominant. In addition, the set of match- Shapley algorithm is preferred by all men to other match- ings achievable by manipulations has a lattice structure. We ings, and thus is called the M-optimal (W-pessimal) match- also examine the super-strong Nash equilibrium in the end. ing. Similarly, the W-optimal (M-pessimal) matching can be found by switching the roles of men and women. In fact, all Introduction men and women have opposite preferences over the set of stable matchings, i.e., for every two stable matchings µ1 and The stable matching theory was introduced by Gale and µ2, all men prefer µ1 to µ2, if and only if all women prefer Shapley (1962). Since then, stability has been a central µ2 to µ1. Moreover, the set of all stable matchings forms a concept in matching market design. The area has attracted lattice structure. intensive research attention, putting theory into practice through a large amount of important applications, such as Incentive Issue college admissions and school matchings (Abdulkadiroglu and Sonmez¨ 2003; Abdulkadiroglu,˘ Pathak, and Roth 2005; However, the Gale-Shapley algorithm suffers from the in- Gale and Shapley 1962), hospitals-residents matchings (Irv- centive issue, i.e., some agents have incentive to misreport ing and Manlove 2009; Irving, Manlove, and Scott 2000; their preference lists. Although it is shown that the Gale- Roth 1996), kidney exchange programs (Abraham, Blum, Shapley algorithm is group strategy-proof for all men (Du- and Sandholm 2007; Roth, Sonmez,¨ and Unver¨ 2004; 2005; bins and Freedman 1981)1, when the algorithm is adopted, Liu, Tang, and Fang 2014), and water right trading (Liu et the women may have incentives to misreport their pref- al. 2016; Zhan et al. 2017). erences. Moreover, a well-known impossibility result by We study the standard stable matching model, where two Roth (1982) states that no stable matching algorithm is truth- set of agents, namely men and women, have preferences ful for all agents. over each other. A matching is a one-to-one correspondence Gale and Sotomayor (1985) shows that if all women trun- between the two sets. A pair of a man and a woman, who cate their preference lists properly, the Gale-Shapley algo- are not matched together, but prefer each other to their des- rithm will output a matching that matches each of them to ignated partner, is said to be a blocking pair. A match- their partner in the W-optimal matching. Teo, Sethuraman, ing is called stable if there exists no blocking pair. The and Tan (2001) provide a polynomial time algorithm to find Gale-Shapley algorithm, which was first proposed by Gale the optimal single-agent truncation manipulation. However, and Shapley (1962), takes as input the preference lists of little is known when only a subset of players can misreport all agents, and computes a stable matching in O(n2) time. their preference lists. The algorithm simulates the procedure of men proposing to women. At each round of the procedure, each man proposes 1Precisely, group strategy-proof means no coalition manipula- to his favorite woman among those who have not rejected tion can make all men in the coalition strictly better off, in this context. If considering the case where no man is worse off and at Copyright c 2018, Association for the Advancement of Artificial least one man is strictly better off, the Gale-Shapley algorithm is Intelligence (www.aaai.org). All rights reserved. not group strategy-proof (Huang 2006). This paper is directly motivated by the recent reform of Dworczak (2016) put forward a new matching algorithm the college admissions process in China. In China, all stu- to find stable matchings, where all agents are allowed to dents are required to take the National College Entrance make proposals. Their algorithm is a natural generalization Exam before applying to the universities. The applications of the Gale-Shapley algorithm and they also characterize the are settled by the Ministry of Education using the Gale- set of stable matchings by showing that a matching is stable Shapley algorithm. However, besides the entrance exam, the if and only if it is a possible output of their algorithm. Teo, Ministry also has the independent admission program (aka Sethuraman, and Tan (2001) study a different type of ma- the university initiative admission plan). This program al- nipulation, where a woman can only permute her true pref- lows the universities to conduct independent exams to deter- erence list2. This is a natural constraint when all agents are mine their own ordering of the students. Starting from 2010, only allowed to report a complete preference list. They fo- these universities began to form leagues and determine their cus on the case where there is only a single manipulator and orderings together. Such leagues are widely believed to be give an algorithm to find the optimal manipulation that runs beneficial to their members, since they can cooperatively in polynomial time. Gupta et al. (2015) extends the algo- manipulate the admission results. However, these universi- rithm to the so-called P -stable (stable w.r.t preferences P ) ties are also faced with the problem of competition, since Nash equilibrium setting. they target for a similar set of students. Such leagues are With the impossibility result by Roth, it is clear that there urged to dissolve by the Ministry for the belief of unfairness. always exist some agents who have the incentive to manip- ulate the matching result, no matter what stable matching Our Results algorithm is applied. Nevertheless, Pini et al. (2009) design a stable matching mechanism and prove that it is computa- We analyze the manipulation problem in the stable matching tionally hard to find a manipulation, even for a single ma- problem, where agents can report a preference list over any nipulator. subset of the other sex. Contrary to most existing works, we allow any subset of women to be the manipulators. We show that a strong Nash equilibrium (i.e., no subset of manipula- Preliminaries tors can deviate and get strictly better off) always exists for In the standard stable matching problem, there are two sets any subset of women. Moreover, in the strong Nash equi- of agents: the men (denoted by M) and the women (denoted librium, each manipulator removes every man below her W- by W ). A preference profile P is the collection of the pref- optimal partner on her list and in the induced matching, all erence lists of all agents. The preference list P (m) of a man manipulators can be matched to their W-optimal partners. m 2 M is a strict total order over a subset of W , where This result generalizes the results by Teo, Sethuraman, m w1 m w2 denotes that m prefers w1 to w2. Similarly, the and Tan (2001) and Gale and Sotomayor (1985), which con- preference list P (w) of a woman w 2 W is a strict total sider manipulations by a single woman and the set of all P P order w over a subset of M. We will use m and w to women, respectively. Moreover, the equilibrium outcome is explicitly refer to the preference lists of m and w in profile unique and Pareto-dominant for all manipulators, i.e., all P , if multiple preference profiles are considered. However, manipulators reach a consensus on a single manipulation for simplicity, we always use m and m to denote the true profile. Furthermore, the set of all stable matchings attain- preferences of m and w. We slightly abuse notation and use able from general manipulations forms a join-semilattice. P (X) to denote the preference profile for a set of agents Finally, we show how to check whether such an unique X ⊂ M [ W . strong Nash equilibrium is a super-strong Nash equilibrium. A matching between men and women is a function µ : M [W ! M [W , that maps each agent to his or her partner Related Works in the matching. For example, µ(m) = w means that m is Knuth, Motwani, and Pittel (1990) show that the number of matched to w. Thus µ(m) = w if and only if µ(w) = m. In different partner that a woman can have in all stable match- any matching, a man should be matched with a woman and 1 vice versa.
Recommended publications
  • Stable Matching: Theory, Evidence, and Practical Design
    THE PRIZE IN ECONOMIC SCIENCES 2012 INFORMATION FOR THE PUBLIC Stable matching: Theory, evidence, and practical design This year’s Prize to Lloyd Shapley and Alvin Roth extends from abstract theory developed in the 1960s, over empirical work in the 1980s, to ongoing efforts to fnd practical solutions to real-world prob- lems. Examples include the assignment of new doctors to hospitals, students to schools, and human organs for transplant to recipients. Lloyd Shapley made the early theoretical contributions, which were unexpectedly adopted two decades later when Alvin Roth investigated the market for U.S. doctors. His fndings generated further analytical developments, as well as practical design of market institutions. Traditional economic analysis studies markets where prices adjust so that supply equals demand. Both theory and practice show that markets function well in many cases. But in some situations, the standard market mechanism encounters problems, and there are cases where prices cannot be used at all to allocate resources. For example, many schools and universities are prevented from charging tuition fees and, in the case of human organs for transplants, monetary payments are ruled out on ethical grounds. Yet, in these – and many other – cases, an allocation has to be made. How do such processes actually work, and when is the outcome efcient? Matching theory The Gale-Shapley algorithm Analysis of allocation mechanisms relies on a rather abstract idea. If rational people – who know their best interests and behave accordingly – simply engage in unrestricted mutual trade, then the outcome should be efcient. If it is not, some individuals would devise new trades that made them better of.
    [Show full text]
  • Matching with Externalities
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Pycia, Marek; Yenmez, M. Bumin Working Paper Matching with externalities Working Paper, No. 392 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, University of Zurich Suggested Citation: Pycia, Marek; Yenmez, M. Bumin (2021) : Matching with externalities, Working Paper, No. 392, University of Zurich, Department of Economics, Zurich, http://dx.doi.org/10.5167/uzh-204367 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/235605 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu University of Zurich Department of Economics Working Paper Series ISSN 1664-7041 (print) ISSN 1664-705X (online) Working Paper No. 392 Matching with Externalities Marek Pycia and M.
    [Show full text]
  • Kwanashie, Augustine (2015) Efficient Algorithms for Optimal Matching Problems Under Preferences
    Kwanashie, Augustine (2015) Efficient algorithms for optimal matching problems under preferences. PhD thesis. http://theses.gla.ac.uk/6706/ Copyright and moral rights for this thesis are retained by the author A copy can be downloaded for personal non-commercial research or study This thesis cannot be reproduced or quoted extensively from without first obtaining permission in writing from the Author The content must not be changed in any way or sold commercially in any format or medium without the formal permission of the Author When referring to this work, full bibliographic details including the author, title, awarding institution and date of the thesis must be given Glasgow Theses Service http://theses.gla.ac.uk/ [email protected] Efficient Algorithms for Optimal Matching Problems Under Preferences Augustine Kwanashie Submitted in fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy School of Computing Science College of Science and Engineering University of Glasgow September 2015 c Augustine Kwanashie 2015 Abstract In this thesis we consider efficient algorithms for matching problems involving pref- erences, i.e., problems where agents may be required to list other agents that they find acceptable in order of preference. In particular we mainly study the Stable Marriage problem (sm), the Hospitals / Residents problem (hr) and the Student / Project Allo- cation problem (spa), and some of their variants. In some of these problems the aim is to find a stable matching which is one that admits no blocking pair. A blocking pair with respect to a matching is a pair of agents that prefer to be matched to each other than their assigned partners in the matching if any.
    [Show full text]
  • Matching with Externalities
    Matching with Externalities Marek Pycia and M. Bumin Yenmez* June 2021 Abstract We incorporate externalities into the stable matching theory of two-sided markets. Ex- tending the classical substitutes condition to markets with externalities, we establish that stable matchings exist when agent choices satisfy substitutability. We show that substi- tutability is a necessary condition for the existence of a stable matching in a maximal- domain sense and provide a characterization of substitutable choice functions. In addition, we extend the standard insights of matching theory, like the existence of side-optimal sta- ble matchings and the deferred acceptance algorithm, to settings with externalities even though the standard fixed-point techniques do not apply. 1 Introduction Externalities are present in many two-sided markets. For instance, couples in a labor market pool their resources as do partners in legal or consulting partnerships. As a result, the pref- erences of an agent depend on the contracts signed by the partners. Likewise, a firm’s hiring *First online version: August 2, 2014; first presentation: February 2012. We would like to thank Peter Chen and Michael Egesdal for stimulating conversations early in the project. For their comments, we would also like to thank Omer Ali, Andrew Atkeson, David Dorn, Haydar Evren, James Fisher, Mikhail Freer, Andrea Gale- otti, Christian Hellwig, Jannik Hensel, George Mailath, Preston McAfee, SangMok Lee, Michael Ostrovsky, David Reiley, Michael Richter, Tayfun Sonmez, Alex Teytelboym, Utku Unver, Basit Zafar, Simpson Zhang, Josef Zweimüller, anonymous referees, and audiences of presentations at UCLA, Carnegie Mellon University, the University of Pennsylvania Workshop on Multiunit Allocation, AMMA, Arizona State University, Winter Econo- metric Society Meetings, Boston College, Princeton, CIREQ Montreal Microeconomic Theory Conference, and University of Zurich.
    [Show full text]
  • Seen As Stable Marriages
    This paper was presented as part of the Mini-Conference at IEEE INFOCOM 2011 Seen As Stable Marriages Hong Xu, Baochun Li Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering University of Toronto Abstract—In this paper, we advocate the use of stable matching agents from both sides to find the optimal solution, which is framework in solving networking problems, which are tradi- computationally expensive. tionally solved using utility-based optimization or game theory. Born in economics, stable matching efficiently resolves conflicts of interest among selfish agents in the market, with a simple and elegant procedure of deferred acceptance. We illustrate through (w1,w3,w2) (m1,m2,m3) one technical case study how it can be applied in practical m1 w1 scenarios where the impeding complexity of idiosyncratic factors makes defining a utility function difficult. Due to its use of (w2,w3,w1) (m1,m3,m2) generic preferences, stable matching has the potential to offer efficient and practical solutions to networking problems, while its m2 w2 mathematical structure and rich literature in economics provide many opportunities for theoretical studies. In closing, we discuss (w2,w1,w3) open questions when applying the stable matching framework. (m3,m2,m1) m3 w3 I. INTRODUCTION Matching is perhaps one of the most important functions of Fig. 1. A simple example of the marriage market. The matching shown is a stable matching. markets. The stable marriage problem, introduced by Gale and Shapley in their seminal work [1], is arguably one of the most Many large-scale networked systems, such as peer-to-peer interesting and successful abstractions of such markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Algorithms, Data Science, and Online Markets
    Algorithms, Data Science, and Online Markets Stefano Leonardi Department of Computer, Control, and Management Engineering Antonio Ruberti (DIAG) Sapienza University of Rome September 2-6, 2019 Data Science Summer School - Pisa Algorithms, Data Science, and Markets September 5, 2019 1 / 83 Stefano Leonardi Leader of the Research Group on Algorithms and Data Science at DIAG - Sapienza ERC Advanced Grant "Algorithms and Mechanism Design Research in Online MArkets" (AMDROMA) Chair of the PhD program in Data Science at Sapienza Past Chair of the Master's Research Interests: Degree in Data Science at Algorithmic Theory Sapienza Algorithmic Data Analysis Fellow of the European Association for Theoretical Economics and Computation Computer Science Algorithms, Data Science, and Markets September 5, 2019 2 / 83 Outline 1 Part I: Algorithms, Data Science and Markets 2 Part II: Internet, Equilibria and Games 3 Part III: Games and solution concepts 4 Part IV: The complexity of finding equilibria 5 Part V: The price of Anarchy 6 Part VI: Equilibria in markets 7 Conclusions Algorithms, Data Science, and Markets September 5, 2019 3 / 83 Algorithms, Data Science, and Markets Digital markets form an important share of the global economy. Many classical markets moved to Internet: real-estate, stocks, e-commerce, entarteinment New markets with previously unknown features have emerged: web-based advertisement, viral marketing, digital goods, online labour markets, sharing economy Algorithms, Data Science, and Markets September 5, 2019 4 / 83 An Economy of Algorithms In 2000, we had 600 humans making markets in U.S. stocks. Today, we have two people and a lot of software. One in three Goldman Sachs employees are engineers R.
    [Show full text]
  • Matchingandmarketdesign
    Matching and Market Design Theory and Practice Xiang Sun May 12, 2017 ii Contents Acknowledgement vii 1 Introduction 1 1.1 Matching and market design .......................................... 1 1.2 Time line of the main evolution of matching and market design ....................... 2 I Two-sided matching 9 2 Marriage 11 2.1 The formal model ............................................... 11 2.2 Stability and optimality ............................................ 12 2.3 Deferred acceptance algorithm ........................................ 14 2.4 Properties of stable matchings I ........................................ 16 2.5 Properties of stable matchings II ........................................ 21 2.6 Extension: Extending the men’s preferences ................................. 24 2.7 Extension: Adding another woman ...................................... 26 2.8 Incentive compatibility I ............................................ 29 2.9 Incentive compatibility II ........................................... 35 2.10 Non-bossiness ................................................. 38 3 College admissions 41 3.1 The formal model ............................................... 41 3.2 Stability ..................................................... 42 3.3 The connection between the college admissions model and the marriage model .............. 44 3.4 Deferred acceptance algorithm and properties of stable matchings ..................... 45 i Contents ii 3.5 Further results for the college admissions model ..............................
    [Show full text]
  • Unbalanced Random Matching Markets: the Stark Effect of Competition
    Unbalanced Random Matching Markets: The Stark Effect of Competition Itai Ashlagi Stanford University Yash Kanoria Columbia University Jacob D. Leshno Columbia University We study competition in matching markets with random heteroge- neous preferences and an unequal number of agents on either side. First, we show that even the slightest imbalance yields an essentially unique stable matching. Second, we give a tight description of stable outcomes, showing that matching markets are extremely competitive. Each agent on the short side of the market is matched with one of his top choices, and each agent on the long side either is unmatched or does almost no better than being matched with a random partner. Our results suggest that any matching market is likely to have a small core, explaining why small cores are empirically ubiquitous. I. Introduction Stable matching theory has been instrumental in the study and design of numerous two-sided markets. Two-sided markets are described by two dis- Part of the work was done when the last two authors were postdoctoral researchers at Microsoft Research New England. We thank Nittai Bergman, Gabriel Carroll, Yeon-Koo Che, Ben Golub, Uriel Feige, Ali Hortaçsu, Nicole Immorlica, Fuhito Kojima, SangMok Electronically published December 16, 2016 [ Journal of Political Economy, 2017, vol. 125, no. 1] © 2017 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-3808/2017/12501-0005$10.00 69 70 journal of political economy joint sets of men and women, where each agent has preferences over po- tential partners. Examples include entry-level labor markets, dating, and college admissions. The core of a two-sided market is the set of stable matchings, where a matching is stable if there are no man and woman who both prefer each other over their assigned partners.
    [Show full text]
  • Diversity.Pdf
    Published in the American Economic Review (2015) Vol. 105(8): 2679-94. doi:10.1257/aer.20130929 HOW TO CONTROL CONTROLLED SCHOOL CHOICE FEDERICO ECHENIQUE AND M. BUMIN YENMEZ Abstract. We characterize choice rules for schools that regard students as substitutes while expressing preferences for a diverse student body. The stable (or fair) assignment of students to schools requires the latter to re- gard the former as substitutes. Such a requirement is in conflict with the reality of schools' preferences for diversity. We show that the conflict can be useful, in the sense that certain unique rules emerge from imposing both considerations. We also provide welfare comparisons for students when different choice rules are employed. Date: October 22, 2014. Keywords: School choice, diversity, gross substitutes. We thank Estelle Cantillon, Lars Ehlers, Sean Horan, Mark Johnson, Juan Pereyra Barreiro, Ariel Rubinstein, Kota Saito, Yves Sprumont, and Utku Unver¨ for their helpful comments, as well as seminar audiences at multiple universities and conferences. We are particularly grateful to Scott Kominers, Parag Pathak and Tayfun S¨onmezfor their comments, and advise on existing controlled school choice programs. Karen Hannsberry, manager at the office of access and enrollment at Chicago Public Schools, very kindly answered all our questions about their program. Finally, we are very grateful to the editor, Debraj Ray, and three anonymous referees for their suggestions, which have led to a much improved version of the paper. Echenique is affiliated with the Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences, California Institute of Technology, Pasadena, CA 91125; Yenmez is with Tepper School of Business, Carnegie Mellon University, 5000 Forbes Ave, Pittsburgh, PA 15213.
    [Show full text]
  • Coalition Manipulation of Gale-Shapley Algorithm∗
    The Thirty-Second AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (AAAI-18) Coalition Manipulation of Gale-Shapley Algorithm∗ Weiran Shen, Pingzhong Tang Yuan Deng Institute for Interdisciplinary Information Sciences Department of Computer Science Tsinghua University Duke University Beijing, China Durham, NC 27708, USA {emersonswr,kenshinping}@gmail.com [email protected] Abstract women. At each round of the procedure, each man proposes to his favorite woman among those who have not rejected It is well-known that the Gale-Shapley algorithm is not truth- ful for all agents. Previous studies in this category concentrate him yet. Then each woman rejects all men but her favorite on manipulations using incomplete preference lists by a sin- one. The algorithm terminates when no man can make any gle woman and by the set of all women. Little is known about proposal. manipulations by a subset of women. It is shown that the matching computed by the Gale- In this paper, we consider manipulations by any subset of Shapley algorithm is stable and the algorithm is guaranteed women with arbitrary preferences. We show that a strong to terminate for each legal input, which immediately implies Nash equilibrium of the induced manipulation game always that every instance of the stable matching problem has a sta- exists among the manipulators and the equilibrium outcome ble matching. There are many interesting structural results in is unique and Pareto-dominant. In addition, the set of match- the literature of stable matching theory. For example, among ings achievable by manipulations has a lattice structure. We all stable matchings, the matching computed by the Gale- also examine the super-strong Nash equilibrium in the end.
    [Show full text]
  • The Complexity of Interactively Learning a Stable Matching by Trial and Error∗†
    The Complexity of Interactively Learning a Stable Matching by Trial and Error∗y Ehsan Emamjomeh-Zadehz Yannai A. Gonczarowskix David Kempe{ September 16, 2020 Abstract In a stable matching setting, we consider a query model that allows for an interactive learning algorithm to make precisely one type of query: proposing a matching, the response to which is either that the proposed matching is stable, or a blocking pair (chosen adversarially) indicating that this matching is unstable. For one-to-one matching markets, our main result is an essen- tially tight upper bound of O(n2 log n) on the deterministic query complexity of interactively learning a stable matching in this coarse query model, along with an efficient randomized algo- rithm that achieves this query complexity with high probability. For many-to-many matching markets in which participants have responsive preferences, we first give an interactive learning algorithm whose query complexity and running time are polynomial in the size of the market if the maximum quota of each agent is bounded; our main result for many-to-many markets is that the deterministic query complexity can be made polynomial (more specifically, O(n3 log n)) in the size of the market even for arbitrary (e.g., linear in the market size) quotas. 1 Introduction Problem and Background In the classic Stable Matching Problem (Gale and Shapley, 1962), there are n women and n men; each woman has a subset of men she deems acceptable and a strict preference order over them; similarly, each man has a subset of women he finds acceptable and a strict preference order over them.
    [Show full text]
  • Seen As Stable Marriages
    Seen As Stable Marriages Hong Xu, Baochun Li Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering University of Toronto Abstract—In this paper, we advocate the use of stable matching agents from both sides to find the optimal solution, which is framework in solving networking problems, which are tradi- computationally expensive. tionally solved using utility-based optimization or game theory. Born in economics, stable matching efficiently resolves conflicts of interest among selfish agents in the market, with a simple and elegant procedure of deferred acceptance. We illustrate through (w1, w 3, w 2) (m1, m 2, m 3) one technical case study how it can be applied in practical m1 w1 scenarios where the impeding complexity of idiosyncratic factors makes defining a utility function difficult. Due to its use of (w2, w 3, w 1) (m1, m 3, m 2) generic preferences, stable matching has the potential to offer efficient and practical solutions to networking problems, while its m2 w2 mathematical structure and rich literature in economics provide many opportunities for theoretical studies. In closing, we discuss (w2, w 1, w 3) open questions when applying the stable matching framework. (m3, m 2, m 1) m3 w3 I. INTRODUCTION Matching is perhaps one of the most important functions of Fig. 1. A simple example of the marriage market. The matching shown is a stable matching. markets. The stable marriage problem, introduced by Gale and Shapley in their seminal work [1], is arguably one of the most Many large-scale networked systems, such as peer-to-peer interesting and successful abstractions of such markets.
    [Show full text]