Financial Crises: a Focus on the Great Depression Economies Can Register ‘Boom’ and ‘Bust’

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Financial Crises: a Focus on the Great Depression Economies Can Register ‘Boom’ and ‘Bust’ Financial Crises: A Focus on the Great Depression Economies can register ‘boom’ and ‘bust’ Crises in History: Tulip mania - Netherlands 1637 South Seas Bubble, UK 1720 The Mississippi Bubble, France 1720 Panic of 1819 – USA The Long Depression 1876 – 1896 UK, USA, Europe Panic of 1907 Wall Street Crash – 1929, Great Depression 1930-45 Oil crisis 1973 (UK – IMF in 1976) Savings and Loan Scandal, USA, 1986-96, US$ 125 bn bailout Japanese asset bubble – 1986 - ? Mexico 1994 Asian financial crisis (“IMF crisis”) – Thailand, Indonesia, South Korea, Philippines, 1997-8 Russian financial crisis 1998 Dot-com bubble 2001 Argentina defaults – largest debt default in history - 2002 Background the United States Economy in the 1920’s The United States economy in the 1920’s was very strong The growth of the automobile industry had a positive impact on many other industries Unemployment was low Shorter working hours and higher wages gave Americans more spare time and more money for entertainment U.S. History is nicknamed the Roaring Twenties Life in the 1920s Moving Picture Shows (―movies‖) – all movies were silent films at first (had music but no talking) -Charlie Chaplin was the most famous silent film star -first ―talking‖ movie was The Jazz Singer (1927) staring Al Jolston -famous movie stars of the 20s: Rudolph Valentino, Clara Bow, Mary Pickford, Lillian Gish, Charlie Chaplin Life in the 1920s: The Jazz Age Music / Dance – the radio made music more popular -Jazz was the most popular music of the 20s – started in New Orleans -Louis Armstrong was the most popular jazz musician of the 20s -George Gershwin was a popular composer – wrote ―Rhapsody in Blue‖ -popular dances included: Charleston, Fox-trot, and Tango Life in the 1920s Literature – famous authors included: -F. Scott Fitzgerald – The Great Gatsby -Sinclair Lewis – Main Street -Ernest Hemingway – A Farewell to Arms Life in the 1920s Transportation *Henry Ford – ―made the 20s happen‖ -responsible for changing the automobile industry by using the assembly line – each worker had a specific job -1920 – 8 million cars on the road -1929 – 23 million -developed the Model T car 1920s GOOD TIMES ARE HERE TO STAY! • Gross National Product went up • All economic indicators showed increased prosperity • Consumption went up Installment Buying • In the 1920’s Americans began buying items they could not afford through the use of installment buying (buying on credit) • This increased the demand for goods • But it also increased consumers debt Consumer Goods Americans began to purchase large amounts of consumer goods, mostly on credit- Installment Plans – Washing machines – Radios – Vacuum cleaners – Refrigerators The Stock Market • The strength of the economy led many people to invest in the Stock Market in hopes of becoming rich Buying Stock on Margin • People who did not have money to purchase stock could buy stock on margin – Banks and stock brokers would loan people money to purchase stock – People had to pay back the bank/brokers with interest – Simple example with no interest rate Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario A Hello, sir. I would like to purchase 100 shares of stock in the Ford Motor Company. How much is it going to cost me? investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario A Well, Ford stock costs $10 per share. You want to buy 100 shares? Figure it out yourself, smart guy! investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario A Ummm… 100 shares x $10 per share = $1,000.00 Oh, well. I only have $100. I can’t afford 100 shares. investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario A No, problem! Just give me $100 and you can owe me the rest! investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario A Like, how much would that be? Let me think… $1,000 worth of stock - $100 paid = $900 owed Alright, it’s a deal!! investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario A Six months later, Ford stock doubles to $20 per share. My 100 shares are now worth... 100 shares x $20 per share $2,000 investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario A That’s great! Now pay me the $900 you owe me! investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario A No problemo! It was a pleasure doing business with you! investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario A Now let’s figure out how much money I made! $2,000 net worth - $900 owed $1,100 profit - $100 initial investment $1,000 net profit investor Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario B Six months later, Ford stock decreases to $1 per share. My 100 shares are now worth... 100 shares x $1 per share $100 investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario B Too bad, hotshot! You still owe me $900! investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario B But I’m broke! What am I going to do! investor stock broker Buying Stocks on Margin: Scenario B I don’t care what you do as long as you pay me back! investor stock broker Buying Stock Buying stock on margin can be very fruitful...but you have high risk….and you can register severe losses! Signs of Trouble But the ―Roaring Twenties‖ weren’t roaring for everyone... Although the economy of the 1920’s was very strong signs of trouble began to appear The Roots Causes (Signs of trouble) of the Great Depression 2.) Huge farm 1.) Over-production surpluses: and under- consumption -led to a drop in farm prices (failing DEMAND)… -many farmers lost their farms because no ↑ unemployment one needed their food The Great Depression 4.) Unequal 3.) Lack of distribution of diversification wealth ↓ variety of goods! The Roots Causes of the Great Depression 6.)High Tariffs 5.) Credit problems & Stock Market (Hawley-Smoot speculation Tariff)… ↓ competition ↑ prices of certain goods! The Great Depression 7.) Low Interest Rates (Federal Reserve) Signs of Trouble • Overproduction and huge farm surplus: Massive business inventories- --- Increased Supply Effects of Overproduction Farms and factories overproduced beyond the demand. Businesses cut production Workers suffered Demand for from wage cuts goods fell. and lay offs. People had little or no money to spend. Signs of Trouble • Lack of diversification in American economy--prosperity of 1920s largely a result of expansion of construction and automobile industries Signs of Trouble • Unequal distribution of wealth 1. people were very rich or very poor: 1% of Americans controlled 40% of the wealth in this country 2. 20% of the nation lived in poverty (late 1920s)! 3. Farm income declined 66% from 1920 to 1929 Signs of Trouble • Huge credit problems 1. Stream of bank failures in late 1920s as customers (many of them farmers) were unable to pay mortgages 2. Many bankers had invested money in the stock market 3. By October 1929, margin buying reached $8.5 billion in loans to stock purchasers 4. Low margins encouraged speculative investment on the part of banks, corporations, and individual investors Signs of Trouble • Decline in demand for American goods in international trade 1. High American protective tariffs discouraged trade • Hawley-Smoot Tariff 2. Some nations, particularly Germany, were experiencing financial crises and inflation and they could not afford to purchase American goods The Stock Market Crash Immediate Cause of the Great Depression – the Stock Market Crash: • Prices of stock rose throughout the 20s • By Sept. 1929, the Dow Jones average reached 381 The Great Depression • Thursday, October 24, 1929 – some stockholders began to pull out of the market – afraid of a crash • Tuesday, October 29, 1929: -―Black Tuesday‖ -the day the stock market crashed, and it largely symbolizes the start of the Great Depression Black Tuesday • Tuesday, October 29, 1929: investors panicked and started selling before their stock became worthless Dow Jones fell to 261 (41 in 1932) between $6 and $9 billion was lost The Stock Market Crash The Great Depression • Economic Downturn accelerated by stock market crash leads to the Great Depression • One of the most difficult periods in American history Consequences of the Stock Market Crash •People who had invested all their savings in stock lost everything •People that had bought stocks on margin could not pay back banks The Great Depression • Between 1929 and 1933, 100,000 businesses failed • Corporate profits fell from $10 billion to $1 billon • Between 1929 and 1933, over 6000 banks failed with over 9 million savings accounts lost ($2.5 billion) CROWD OUTSIDE A CLOSED BANK RUN ON BANK The Great Depression • By 1933, 13 million workers were unemployed (25% unemployment) and many were underemployed The Great Depression • Malnutrition increased, as did tuberculosis, typhoid and dysentery. – In 1932, 95 people died of starvation in New York City – Many turned to soup kitchens and breadlines for food The Great Depression • Children were forced to work • Many people became homeless -many of the homeless lived in small villages made of cardboard boxes and crates nicknamed ―hoovervilles‖ (named after Pres. Hoover who was blamed for the Depression) The Great Depression • Large numbers of homeless workers travelled the U.S., particularly the Southwest, seeking work Change in economic indicators 1929–32 United Great Germa France States Britain ny Industrial –46% –23% –24% –41% production Wholesale prices –32% –33% –34% –29% Foreign trade –70% –60% –54% –61% Unemployment +607% +129% +214% +232% President Hoover • President Herbert Clark Hoover and business leaders attempted to calm Americans by assuring them that the country's economy was fundamentally sound The Dust Bowl • An environmental disaster in the southern Great Plains during the 1930’s • Severe drought during 1931 caused the soil to dry out and swept the soil away – Farmers had cleared millions of acres of grassland – Grass had held the soil in place • Farmers went bankrupt and moved west President Hoover’s Response Did not believe that it was the role of the government to provide relief to Americans He believed in a limited role for government and worried that excessive federal intervention was a threat to capitalism Urged Americans to turn to community and church resources (Salvation Army, Community Chest, Red Cross) to meet needs of the poor Hoover’s Response Gradually used federal agencies to address issues 1.
Recommended publications
  • Friday, June 21, 2013 the Failures That Ignited America's Financial
    Friday, June 21, 2013 The Failures that Ignited America’s Financial Panics: A Clinical Survey Hugh Rockoff Department of Economics Rutgers University, 75 Hamilton Street New Brunswick NJ 08901 [email protected] Preliminary. Please do not cite without permission. 1 Abstract This paper surveys the key failures that ignited the major peacetime financial panics in the United States, beginning with the Panic of 1819 and ending with the Panic of 2008. In a few cases panics were triggered by the failure of a single firm, but typically panics resulted from a cluster of failures. In every case “shadow banks” were the source of the panic or a prominent member of the cluster. The firms that failed had excellent reputations prior to their failure. But they had made long-term investments concentrated in one sector of the economy, and financed those investments with short-term liabilities. Real estate, canals and railroads (real estate at one remove), mining, and cotton were the major problems. The panic of 2008, at least in these ways, was a repetition of earlier panics in the United States. 2 “Such accidental events are of the most various nature: a bad harvest, an apprehension of foreign invasion, the sudden failure of a great firm which everybody trusted, and many other similar events, have all caused a sudden demand for cash” (Walter Bagehot 1924 [1873], 118). 1. The Role of Famous Failures1 The failure of a famous financial firm features prominently in the narrative histories of most U.S. financial panics.2 In this respect the most recent panic is typical: Lehman brothers failed on September 15, 2008: and … all hell broke loose.
    [Show full text]
  • The Real Bills Views of the Founders of the Fed
    Economic Quarterly— Volume 100, Number 2— Second Quarter 2014— Pages 159–181 The Real Bills Views of the Founders of the Fed Robert L. Hetzel ilton Friedman (1982, 103) wrote: “In our book on U.S. mon- etary history, Anna Schwartz and I found it possible to use M one sentence to describe the central principle followed by the Federal Reserve System from the time it began operations in 1914 to 1952. That principle, to quote from our book, is: ‘Ifthe ‘money market’ is properly managed so as to avoid the unproductive use of credit and to assure the availability of credit for productive use, then the money stock will take care of itself.’” For Friedman, the reference to “the money stock”was synonymous with “the price level.”1 How did American monetary experience and debate in the 19th century give rise to these “real bills” views as a guide to Fed policy in the pre-World War II period? As distilled in the real bills doctrine, the founders of the Fed under- stood the Federal Reserve System as a decentralized system of reserve depositories that would allow the expansion and contraction of currency and credit based on discounting member-bank paper that originated out of productive activity. By discounting these “real bills,”the short- term loans that …nanced trade and goods in the process of production, policymakers ful…lled their responsibilities as they understood them. That is, they would provide the reserves required to accommodate the “legitimate,” nonspeculative, demands for credit.2 In so doing, they The author acknowledges helpful comments from Huberto Ennis, Motoo Haruta, Gary Richardson, Robert Sharp, Kurt Schuler, Ellis Tallman, and Alexander Wolman.
    [Show full text]
  • The Many Panics of 1837 People, Politics, and the Creation of a Transatlantic Financial Crisis
    The Many Panics of 1837 People, Politics, and the Creation of a Transatlantic Financial Crisis In the spring of 1837, people panicked as financial and economic uncer- tainty spread within and between New York, New Orleans, and London. Although the period of panic would dramatically influence political, cultural, and social history, those who panicked sought to erase from history their experiences of one of America’s worst early financial crises. The Many Panics of 1837 reconstructs the period between March and May 1837 in order to make arguments about the national boundaries of history, the role of information in the economy, the personal and local nature of national and international events, the origins and dissemination of economic ideas, and most importantly, what actually happened in 1837. This riveting transatlantic cultural history, based on archival research on two continents, reveals how people transformed their experiences of financial crisis into the “Panic of 1837,” a single event that would serve as a turning point in American history and an early inspiration for business cycle theory. Jessica M. Lepler is an assistant professor of history at the University of New Hampshire. The Society of American Historians awarded her Brandeis University doctoral dissertation, “1837: Anatomy of a Panic,” the 2008 Allan Nevins Prize. She has been the recipient of a Hench Post-Dissertation Fellowship from the American Antiquarian Society, a Dissertation Fellowship from the Library Company of Philadelphia’s Program in Early American Economy and Society, a John E. Rovensky Dissertation Fellowship in Business History, and a Jacob K. Javits Fellowship from the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Other People's Money: How Banking Worked in the Early American Republic
    Civil War Book Review Summer 2017 Article 14 Other People's Money: How Banking Worked In The Early American Republic Joshua Rothman Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.lsu.edu/cwbr Recommended Citation Rothman, Joshua (2017) "Other People's Money: How Banking Worked In The Early American Republic," Civil War Book Review: Vol. 19 : Iss. 3 . DOI: 10.31390/cwbr.19.3.19 Available at: https://digitalcommons.lsu.edu/cwbr/vol19/iss3/14 Rothman: Other People's Money: How Banking Worked In The Early American Re Review Rothman, Joshua Summer 2017 Murphy, Sharon Ann Other People’s Money: How Banking Worked in the Early American Republic. Johns Hopkins University Press, $19.95 ISBN 9781421421759 How Banks Worked (and Sometimes Did Not Work) in the Early Republic Trying to understand the workings of American banking and finance before the Civil War can be baffling. There was no central bank and no national currency, but rather a mostly decentralized system of banks of varying sorts that circulated thousands of different paper banknotes throughout the country. Counterfeiting was widespread, banknote values fluctuated wildly and varied from place to place, and chains of credit and debt created through promissory notes and bills of exchange easily became byzantine. Fundamental instability was endemic to the economy, and only the exigencies of the war itself led policymakers to craft an economic order that began to resemble that of the modern world. Anyone who has ever tried to convey the complexity of these circumstances in a survey lecture knows the looks of befuddlement and boredom on the faces of undergraduates, and when pressed more than a few historians would surely admit that they do not entirely understand how the economy worked in the early republic either.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Bank Activism Duke Law Journal, Vol
    Central Bank Activism Duke Law Journal, Vol. 71: __ (forthcoming) Christina Parajon Skinner † ABSTRACT—Today, the Federal Reserve is at a critical juncture in its evolution. Unlike any prior period in U.S. history, the Fed now faces increasing demands to expand its policy objectives to tackle a wide range of social and political problems—including climate change, income and racial inequality, and foreign and small business aid. This Article develops a framework for recognizing, and identifying the problems with, “central bank activism.” It refers to central bank activism as situations in which immediate public policy problems push central banks to aggrandize their power beyond the text and purpose of their legal mandates, which Congress has established. To illustrate, the Article provides in-depth exploration of both contemporary and historic episodes of central bank activism, thus clarifying the indicia of central bank activism and drawing out the lessons that past episodes should teach us going forward. The Article urges that, while activism may be expedient in the near term, there are long-term social costs. Activism undermines the legitimacy of central bank authority, erodes its political independence, and ultimately renders a weaker central bank. In the end, the Article issues an urgent call to resist the allure of activism. And it places front and center the need for vibrant public discourse on the role of a central bank in American political and economic life today. © 2021 Christina Parajon Skinner. Draft 2021-05-27 20:46. † Assistant Professor, The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania. This article benefited from feedback provided by workshop or conference participants at The Wharton School, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York .
    [Show full text]
  • The Growth of Political Factionalism and Sectionalism
    The Growth of Political Factionalism and Sectionalism Key Vocabulary Era of Good Feelings Bank of the United States Missouri Compromise Panic of 1819 Mason-Dixon Line Henry Clay The Era of Good Feelings began with a burst of nationalistic fervor. The economic program adopted by Congress, including a national bank and a protective tariff, reflected the growing feeling of national unity. The Supreme Court promoted the spirit of nationalism by establishing the principle of federal supremacy. Industrialization and improvements in transportation also added to the sense of national unity by contributing to the nation's economic strength and independence and by linking the West and the East together. But this same period also witnessed the emergence of growing factional divisions in politics, including a deepening sectional split between the North and South. A severe economic depression between 1819 and 1822 provoked bitter division over questions of banking and tariffs. Geographic expansion exposed latent tensions over the morality of slavery and the balance of economic power. It was during the Era of Good Feelings that the political issues arose that would dominate American politics for the next 40 years. The Panic of 1819 In 1819 a financial panic swept across the country. The growth in trade that followed the War of 1812 came to an abrupt halt. Unemployment mounted, banks failed, mortgages were foreclosed, and agricultural prices fell by half. Investment in western lands collapsed. The panic was frightening in its scope and impact. In New York State, property values fell from $315 million in 1818 to $256 million in 1820.
    [Show full text]
  • Destabilizing Entanglements
    Dael Norwood University of Delaware [email protected] Destabilizing Entanglements: How the Flow of Opium, Cotton, and Capital Restructured Americans’ Relationships with China, Britain, and Their Own Government in the Jacksonian Era Missouri Regional Seminar on Early American History February 1, 2019 Draft – Please do not share or cite Norwood / 2 When the ship Congress sailed from Boston harbor bound for Batavia in 1824, it went using some of the old habits of trade, and some of the new. Jacaob [sic] Caswell and Benjamin Brintnall entrusted “one Hundred Spanish milled Dollars” to an agent aboard the ship who promised to “Carey & Invest” it “from port to port.” This was a classic cabotage strategy, designed to make the most out of small capital resources – and used upon by American traders since the Revolution. William Gray, the Congress’s owner, chose a more sophisticated approach. Rather than simply sending a supercargo with specie, Gray instructed his captain, Nathaniel Kinsman, to communicated with trusted commission merchants, resident in Asia, to plot sales and purchases “calculated to promote my interest.” Gray’s cargo choices were finely reckoned, too. He packed the Congress with $7,786 worth of Western commodities (candles, beef, flour, seltzer water) that were readily salable at any European colonial port, and invested $19,318 in opium, a smokable narcotic with a large and growing market across Southeast Asia, and especially in China’s southern ports.1 Finally, he gave Kinsman access to a $50,000 line of credit with his London bankers at Baring Brothers & Co.. This would enable him to take advantage of low prices for return cargoes: teas at Canton, sugar in Manila, or cottons in Calcutta.
    [Show full text]
  • History2+Economics
    COMPUTER HISTORY and U.S. ECONOMIC CYCLES J. Wunderlich PhD, Created January, 2009; Updated January 11, 2019 On Oct 9, 2008, the DOW and NASDAQ sank to alarming lows (8,579.19 and 1,645.12) with the DOW dropping over 5000 points (from ~14,100) in one year despite urgent US government lowering of interest rates AND a 700 billion dollar bail-out plan to attempt to solve a credit crisis created by poor lending practices (primarily in Real Estate). Three months later the DOW and NASDAQ had not significantly changed despite even more bail-out money given to automobile manufacturers, and additional lowering of interest rates. This triggered what was termed “The Great Recession.” In 2018 the economy had almost fully recovered, with stock markets at all time highs with the exception of a typical “Correction” in February 2018 (overdue since 2013) Let’s frame this in a context relevant to our high-tech careers …….. Computer History Much of the following is from sources no longer available online: http://209.85.165.104/search?q=cache:t4gXKDRo518J:timelines.ws/subjects/Computer.HTML+%22history+of+the+personal+computer%22+powerpc+intel+motorola&hl=en&ct=clnk&cd=9&gl=us http://www.timelinesdb.com PRE -1900 History of the modern computer begins with two technologies - automated calculation and programmability. Early mechanical calculating devices included the abacus (2700–2300 BC), the slide rule (1600’s) ..... In 1837, Charles Babbage was first design a fully programmable mechanical computer "The Analytical Engine". 1914 Thomas J. Watson Sr. began the Computing-Tabulating-Recording Co., a predecessor to IBM.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rule of Law During Times of Economic Crisis
    THE RULE OF LAW DURING TIMES OF ECONOMIC CRISIS Todd J. Zywicki George Mason University School of Law George Mason University Legal Studies Research Paper Series LS 15-09 George Mason University Law & Economics Research Paper Series 15-27 This paper is available on the Social Science Research Network at ssrn.com/abstract=2651893 The Rule of Law During Times of Economic Crisis By Todd J. Zywicki1 George Mason University Foundation Professor of Law Abstract It is trite to observe that every economic crisis is unique and calls forth unique government responses. Still, it is possible to generalize from prior crises to anticipate government responses to future crises. Understanding patterns in governmental responses to crises is especially pressing in that the United States faces a looming and entirely predictable fiscal crisis caused by the seemingly irreversible nature of spending on entitlement programs and exploding government debt. Yet government responses to prior crises are not uniform—the economic crisis associate with the Articles of Confederation and the crisis of the Civil War produced strengthened constitutional structures. The crises of the Great Depression and recent financial crisis, by contrast, resulted permanent disfigurement of the Constitution that has produced a massive growth in rent-seeking and crony capitalist structures. This article explores these different constitutional responses to economic and national security crises and attempts to identify which factors may be crucial in determining whether the inevitable fiscal crisis results in strengthened or weakened constitutional government and the rule of law. Our next constitutional crisis is likely to differ from those that have come before.
    [Show full text]
  • Sabbatical Report, 2014 David Lehman Department of History And
    Sabbatical Report, 2014 David Lehman Department of History and Political Science October, 2014 Section 1: Copy of my original proposal, October, 2012 See attached proposal Long Beach City College SABBATICAL LEAVE PROPOSAL September 28, 2012 1. Briefly state the purpose of your sabbatical leave. I am requesting a sabbatical leave to work on a book project entitled “Explaining Hard Times: the Panic of 1819 in PHiladelpHia.” Last year I wrote an article with this title, publisHed by the Historical Society of Pennsylvania. Since that time, I Have received encouragement from several scHolars connected with the University of Pennsylvania Press and the McNeil Center for Early American Studies to consider turning this study into a book project. THis book would examine How the Panic of 1819—the nation’s first economic depression—was experienced and understood in one community, the city of PHiladelpHia. It would be based on researcH I conducted as a graduate student at UCLA and as a dissertation fellow at the McNeil Center for Early American Studies in PHiladelpHia. In recent years, scHolars of the Early National Period Have paid increasing attention to the significance of this event, and I feel that I Have something important to add to this examination. A sabbatical leave granted by Long BeacH City College would provide the generous gift of time and support needed to take on this project. 2. Give all pertinent details of your proposed plan. This should include all activities, projects, research, itinerary, study, employment, expected outcomes, relationships with current coursework, etc. connected with your proposed leave. My proposal will involve the following steps: • a review of recent literature, to be conducted at the UCLA University ResearcH Library and the Huntington Library.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Financial Regulation: Evidence from U.S
    American Finance Association The Political Economy of Financial Regulation: Evidence from U.S. State Usury Laws in the 19th Century Author(s): EFRAIM BENMELECH and TOBIAS J. MOSKOWITZ Source: The Journal of Finance, Vol. 65, No. 3 (JUNE 2010), pp. 1029-1073 Published by: Wiley for the American Finance Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/25656320 . Accessed: 16/02/2015 13:48 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Wiley and American Finance Association are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of Finance. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 128.135.212.41 on Mon, 16 Feb 2015 13:48:12 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXV, NO. 3 JUNE 2010 The Political Economy of Financial Regulation: Evidence from U.S. State Usury Laws in the 19th Century EFRAIM BENMELECH and TOBIAS J.MOSKOWITZ* ABSTRACT Financial regulation was as hotly debated a political issue in the 19th century as it is today. We study the political economy of state usury laws in 19th century America. Exploiting the wide variation in regulation, enforcement, and economic conditions across states and time, we find that usury laws when binding reduce credit and economic activity, especially for smaller firms.
    [Show full text]
  • The Governance of Firms and Budget Constraint
    The European Journal of Comparative Economics Vol. 15, n. 2, pp. 293-314 ISSN 1824-2979 Central Banking without Romance Thomas L. Hogan*, Daniel J. Smith**, Robin Aguiar-Hicks*** Abstract Many economists, including former Federal Reserve chairman Ben Bernanke, believe that the gold standard generates poor economic outcomes including output volatility, price instability, financial panics, the spread of recessions via the exchange rate, and speculation-induced collapse. These problems, however, do not by themselves demonstrate the superiority of central banks over the gold standard. Comparative institutional analysis requires demonstrating that the relevant alternative, in this case a central bank, can improve upon these outcomes in practice. We use this standard to compare central banking and the gold standard in the United States. Recent theoretical and empirical evidence suggests that the Fed has not been able to measurably improve upon the gold standard even when it comes to these deficiencies. JEL classification: E31, E32, E42, E58; N10 Keywords: Ben Bernanke; Federal Reserve; Gold standard; Public Choice; Stability 1. Introduction There is a broad consensus among economists that the gold standard suffers from major deficiencies. In a recent survey of prominent economists, none agreed with the proposition that a gold standard would improve price stability and employment (IGM 2012). In a series of lectures at George Washington University, former Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke (2012a; 2012b) surveyed the major theoretical and empirical problems with the gold standard. According to Bernanke (and most other economists), the gold standard prevents optimal monetary adjustment, leading to output and price instability, cannot prevent financial panics, transmits bad policies between countries, and can lead to speculation-induced collapse.1 These deficiencies certainly provide critiques of the gold standard that must be taken into consideration when comparing alternative monetary structures.
    [Show full text]