Production and Distribution in Political-Economic Systems: a Non-Atomic Game" (2017)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Production and Distribution in Political-Economic Systems: a Non-Atomic Game University of Massachusetts Amherst ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst Economics Department Working Paper Series Economics 2017 Production and Distribution in Political-Economic Systems: a Non- Atomic Game Alex Coram University of Massachusetts Amherst Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umass.edu/econ_workingpaper Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Coram, Alex, "Production and Distribution in Political-Economic Systems: a Non-Atomic Game" (2017). UMass Economics Working Papers. 236. https://doi.org/10.7275/10943155 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics at ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economics Department Working Paper Series by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Production and distribution in political-economic systems: a non-atomic game [Alex Coram. Economics. University of Massachusetts. Draft 3. September o17] Abstract Societies are often compared in terms of the relative shares of the domestic product controlled by govern- ment but we don’t have much by way of analytical tools to allow us to think about the ways in which changes in these shares affect the characteristics of production and distribution. This paper treats production and dis- tribution as a cooperative game with a continuum of players. Outcomes depend on politics and economics. It has a number of unexpected results. Among these are that relative shares do not depend on the majority rule the production function and that the characteristics of inegalitarian and egalitarian systems may converge. 1 Introduction Societies are often compared in terms of the relative shares of the total domestic product transferred through government action and there is extensive discussion of the effects of differences in these shares on things like output, economic participation and distribution. Obvious examples are debates about welfare payments and a universal income. So far this discussion has mostly been historical and empirical. Despite the progress made with these approaches it would also be useful if it were possible to construct some sort of analytical framework that would help understand the factors influencing these differences and their affects at a more abstract level. This might help serve as a reference point for discussion in the same way as abstract models of, say, economic growth help us talk about particular economies. For example we might want to ask: What would be the properties of an allocation if every agent had a share based on political power and productive capacities? How does participation in production change as the share of distribution controlled by the political system changes? What happens as political power and the allocation of resources changes? The purpose of this paper is to attempt to contribute to constructing at least one version of such a frame- work. Rather than starting with micro-foundations it looks at a distribution across large systems of political and economic interactions. I also undertake some comparative static analysis of systems with different levels of transfer. 1 The approach taken here is to treat the production and distribution problem as a cooperative game with an arbitrarily large number of agents thought of as a continuum. In contrast, most of the current theoretical literature on allocation through the political process concentrates on competitions between candidates or parties that offer resources to voters. Individual voters respond by trying to maximize their payoffs. This is usually done by making standard assumptions about utility functions and information and restricting the number of coalitions that form.1 These restrictions strengthen the analysis in some directions by allowing the tools of optimization theory to be used, but they weaken it in others. In particular they leave out the macro-effects produced by the possibility of shifting sets of possible coalitions. For example with 30 voters and a majoritarian voting rule there are about 150 million possibilities. It might be objected that the decision to ignore micro-foundations and use a model based on the value of the game is inconsistent with much contemporary practice in economics. This misses the point that the questions I am asking are different from micro-foundations questions. It also assumes that micro-foundations models are on a sound basis, or at least on a better basis than the approach used here.2 Many of the theoretical foundations for this paper have been developed by Aumann and Shapley [1], Aumann and Kurz [3], Shapiro and Shapley [17] and Milnor and Shapely [10]. In particular the second and third sections of the paper relies heavily on results in [1]. In the conclusion I summarise the characteristics of the systems studied and provide some answers to the questions in the first paragraph. Some results are reasonably obvious after the event. Others are less intu- itive. One example is that the proportion of votes required to make a winning coalition and the nature of the production function does not effect the relative distribution. Another is that participation in production is similar in systems with equal distribution of endowments and systems with unequal distribution of political power. I do not claim that these results map into the real world. On the other hand some of the results on the characteristics of systems with different shares of transfer are striking and, perhaps, should not be ignored in attempting to understand more specific cases. I set out the paper as follows. In §.2 the problem and the model are presented. §.3 gives the main theorem. This is analyzed in §.4. 2 The model 2.1. Statement of the model Suppose we have a social system made up of an economy and a political process. The problem presented 1See Roemer [14] for an example of a two party model and good recent discussion of the literature on vote competition. Osborne and Slivinski [12] give a model where the number of candidates is not restricted but voter preferences are linear. 2There is a large literature which questions whether voters and economic agents behave in the way required for a micro- foundations approach. See for example Shapiro and Green [18]. 2 in the introduction might be restated as that of determining how the total product would be distributed across all the members of a given system when everyone gets a share that is related to its political and economic capacities. The economy is described in terms of a production function, endowments of capital and labour capacity, and the political process represented by a voting mechanism. The total value for an individual is the sum of returns from participating in the political and production processes. The economy might be thought of as either capitalist in which each individual has an initial endowment of resources and skills, or a system in which all resources are collectively owned and workers have different skills. Although the model is written in terms of capitalism it holds for both cases. It is assumed that individuals do not extracts rent and everyone has to work with their endowments. The system might be thought of as some sort of lemonade stand capitalism. There is full employment and everyone who wants to work has a job. The collective choice rule says that any coalition with a weight greater than half is winning. A winning coali- tion can distribute some portion of the produced goods to its members. This portion is fixed in the short run. In many cases discussions of the effect of transfers from government on participation in the economy assume that there is a loss of utility associated with work. A similar assumption is made in this paper. The size of a set, or coalition, of agents is defined by the Lebesque measure µ on the interval I = [0, 1]. This means µ(I)= inf i νi = i µi = 1 where vi is a sequence of intervals covering I. Let S be a coalition of agents. The measureP of S is µP(S)= µ(S ∩ I). The majority rule is given by the number θ. A coalition is 1 winning when µ(S) ≥ θ ≥ 2 . Each individual i is represented by an infinitesimally small sub-interval written dt or µ(i) or µ depending on the point to be made. To begin let µ(i)= µ(j) for all i,j. I will change this assumption later in the paper. There is a single all purpose produced good and utilities in this good are linear. Utility of work is ex- pressed in the same units as utilities of the produced good. Individuals have different productive capacities depending on their endowments of resources and skills. Without worrying too much about measurement it is assumed that these endowments are substitutable. They can be thought of either as a vector or as a simple function g that takes on a finite number of values (g1,...,gk) on the interval I. Write the set of individuals with endowments gr as Gr and think of grdt as the endowments of an individual in Gr. Since g is Lebesque integrable define a vector γ(S):=( g1dt, g2dt,..., gkdt) ZG1∩S ZG2∩S ZGq ∩S r r with γ (S) := Gr ∩S g dt. It will be useful to express pendowments as a measure by defining R r r γ (S) w (S) := j j γ (I) P where j = (1,...,k). This means that wr(S) is the endowments of type r in S expressed as a proportion of the total. It follows that 3 wr(I)=1= µ(I) (1) Xr It is assumed, for the time being, that w is a non-trivial partition of I. In other words there is no r : wr(I)=1 and wj (I)=0 for j 6= r.
Recommended publications
  • Political Ideas and Movements That Created the Modern World
    harri+b.cov 27/5/03 4:15 pm Page 1 UNDERSTANDINGPOLITICS Understanding RITTEN with the A2 component of the GCE WGovernment and Politics A level in mind, this book is a comprehensive introduction to the political ideas and movements that created the modern world. Underpinned by the work of major thinkers such as Hobbes, Locke, Marx, Mill, Weber and others, the first half of the book looks at core political concepts including the British and European political issues state and sovereignty, the nation, democracy, representation and legitimacy, freedom, equality and rights, obligation and citizenship. The role of ideology in modern politics and society is also discussed. The second half of the book addresses established ideologies such as Conservatism, Liberalism, Socialism, Marxism and Nationalism, before moving on to more recent movements such as Environmentalism and Ecologism, Fascism, and Feminism. The subject is covered in a clear, accessible style, including Understanding a number of student-friendly features, such as chapter summaries, key points to consider, definitions and tips for further sources of information. There is a definite need for a text of this kind. It will be invaluable for students of Government and Politics on introductory courses, whether they be A level candidates or undergraduates. political ideas KEVIN HARRISON IS A LECTURER IN POLITICS AND HISTORY AT MANCHESTER COLLEGE OF ARTS AND TECHNOLOGY. HE IS ALSO AN ASSOCIATE McNAUGHTON LECTURER IN SOCIAL SCIENCES WITH THE OPEN UNIVERSITY. HE HAS WRITTEN ARTICLES ON POLITICS AND HISTORY AND IS JOINT AUTHOR, WITH TONY BOYD, OF THE BRITISH CONSTITUTION: EVOLUTION OR REVOLUTION? and TONY BOYD WAS FORMERLY HEAD OF GENERAL STUDIES AT XAVERIAN VI FORM COLLEGE, MANCHESTER, WHERE HE TAUGHT POLITICS AND HISTORY.
    [Show full text]
  • A Sociological Perspective Aviv Pichhadze
    Osgoode Hall Law School of York University Osgoode Digital Commons Research Papers, Working Papers, Conference Comparative Research in Law & Political Economy Papers Research Report No. 15/2010 Corporate Governance and First-Best Solutions: A Sociological Perspective Aviv Pichhadze Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.osgoode.yorku.ca/clpe Recommended Citation Pichhadze, Aviv, "Corporate Governance and First-Best Solutions: A Sociological Perspective" (2010). Comparative Research in Law & Political Economy. Research Paper No. 15/2010. http://digitalcommons.osgoode.yorku.ca/clpe/83 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Research Papers, Working Papers, Conference Papers at Osgoode Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Comparative Research in Law & Political Economy by an authorized administrator of Osgoode Digital Commons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orporate Governance and First-Best Solutions: A Sociological Perspective Aviv Pichhadze Abstract: Drawing on insights from social science methodology and systems analysis, the article adopts a holistic view of the equity markets and highlights how market forces have been driving the evolution in the equity markets towards a first-best corporate governance model.
    [Show full text]
  • Judicial Autonomy in a Political Environment
    University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Journal Articles Faculty Scholarship 2006 Judicial Autonomy in a Political Environment Richard A. Posner Follow this and additional works at: https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/journal_articles Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Richard A. Posner, "Judicial Autonomy in a Political Environment," 38 Arizona State Law Journal 1 (2006). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Chicago Unbound. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal Articles by an authorized administrator of Chicago Unbound. For more information, please contact [email protected]. JUDICIAL AUTONOMY IN A POLITICAL ENVIRONMENT Richard A. Posnert Thank you very much, Randy, for a most generous introduction. It is a pleasure to be here to talk about judicial autonomy. Of course, judges are biased in favor of judicial autonomy, so you will have to be critical as you listen to me. Actually, I'm not as strong a proponent of judicial autonomy as some judges are, and I don't think I would have titled my talk, as the organizers suggested, "maintaining judicial autonomy in a hostile climate," although I certainly agree that there are serious issues concerning judicial autonomy. And I know that it is a very timely issue for Arizona, making this a very good time and place to be talking about the subject. It is important in the state court system of Arizona because there is pressure, I understand, to alter your system of selecting judges, either by requiring confirmation by the Arizona Senate or by having judges elected rather than appointed; we have elected state judges in Illinois and Wisconsin, two of the Seventh Circuit states, which is my domain.
    [Show full text]
  • WHY COMPETITION in the POLITICS INDUSTRY IS FAILING AMERICA a Strategy for Reinvigorating Our Democracy
    SEPTEMBER 2017 WHY COMPETITION IN THE POLITICS INDUSTRY IS FAILING AMERICA A strategy for reinvigorating our democracy Katherine M. Gehl and Michael E. Porter ABOUT THE AUTHORS Katherine M. Gehl, a business leader and former CEO with experience in government, began, in the last decade, to participate actively in politics—first in traditional partisan politics. As she deepened her understanding of how politics actually worked—and didn’t work—for the public interest, she realized that even the best candidates and elected officials were severely limited by a dysfunctional system, and that the political system was the single greatest challenge facing our country. She turned her focus to political system reform and innovation and has made this her mission. Michael E. Porter, an expert on competition and strategy in industries and nations, encountered politics in trying to advise governments and advocate sensible and proven reforms. As co-chair of the multiyear, non-partisan U.S. Competitiveness Project at Harvard Business School over the past five years, it became clear to him that the political system was actually the major constraint in America’s inability to restore economic prosperity and address many of the other problems our nation faces. Working with Katherine to understand the root causes of the failure of political competition, and what to do about it, has become an obsession. DISCLOSURE This work was funded by Harvard Business School, including the Institute for Strategy and Competitiveness and the Division of Research and Faculty Development. No external funding was received. Katherine and Michael are both involved in supporting the work they advocate in this report.
    [Show full text]
  • Rethinking the International System As a Complex Adaptive System
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive A New Taxonomy for International Relations: Rethinking the International System as a Complex Adaptive System Scartozzi, Cesare M. University of Tokyo, Graduate School of Public Policy 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/95496/ MPRA Paper No. 95496, posted 12 Aug 2019 10:50 UTC 1SFQVCMJDBUJPOJournal on Policy and Complex Systems • Volume 4, Number 1 • Spring 2018 A New Taxonomy for International Relations: Rethinking the International System as a Complex Adaptive System Cesare Scartozzi Graduate School of Public Policy, University of Tokyo [email protected] 7-3-1, Hongo, Bunkyo, Tokyo 113-0033, Japan ORCID number: 0000-0002-4350-4386. Abstract The international system is a complex adaptive system with emer- gent properties and dynamics of self-organization and informa- tion processing. As such, it is better understood with a multidis- ciplinary approach that borrows methodologies from the field of complexity science and integrates them to the theoretical perspec- tives offered by the field of international relations (IR). This study is set to formalize a complex systems theory approach to the study of international affairs and introduce a new taxonomy for IR with the two-pronged aim of improving interoperability between differ- ent epistemological communities and outlining a formal grammar that set the basis for modeling international politics as a complex adaptive system. Keywords: international politics, international relations theory, complex systems theory, taxonomy, adaptation, fitness, self-orga- nization This is a prepublication version of: Scartozzi, Cesare M. “A New Taxonomy for International Relations: Rethinking the International System as a Complex Adaptive System.” Journal on Policy and Complex Systems 4, no.
    [Show full text]
  • Bio-Inspired Political Systems: Opening a Field
    Bio-inspired Political Systems: Opening a Field Nathalie Mezza-Garcia Universidad del Rosario La Candelaria, Bogotá, Colombia [email protected] Abstract. In this paper we highlight the scopes of engineering bio-inspired political systems: political systems based on the properties of life that self- organize the increasing complexity of human social systems. We describe bio- inspired political systems and conjecture about various ways to get to them – most notably, metaheuristics, modeling and simulation and complexified topologies. Bio-inspired political systems operate with nature-based dynamics, inspired on the knowledge that has been acquired about complexity from natural social systems and life. Bio-inspired political systems are presented as the best alternative for organizing human sociopolitical interactions as computation and microelectronics-based technology profoundly modify the ways in which humans decide. Therefore, weakening classical political systems. For instance, dwindling top-down power structures, modifying the notion of geographical spatiality and augmenting the political granularity. We also argue that, more than a new theoretical proposal, bio-inspired political systems are coming to be the political systems of the future. Keywords: metaheuristics, modeling and simulation, non-classical topologies, complex network structures, political granularity, sociopolitical self- organization, political regimes. 1 Introduction Human social systems are complexifying and it is becoming more difficult to frame and control them. At least, not through the traditional models of classical science. Bio-inspired political systems (BIPS) are an evolution of classical political systems. They are political systems based on the properties of life that self-organize the increasing complexity of the interactions among individuals and human social systems.
    [Show full text]
  • Transformations)
    TRANSFORMACJE (TRANSFORMATIONS) Transformacje (Transformations) is an interdisciplinary refereed, reviewed journal, published since 1992. The journal is devoted to i.a.: civilizational and cultural transformations, information (knowledge) societies, global problematique, sustainable development, political philosophy and values, future studies. The journal's quasi-paradigm is TRANSFORMATION - as a present stage and form of development of technology, society, culture, civilization, values, mindsets etc. Impacts and potentialities of change and transition need new methodological tools, new visions and innovation for theoretical and practical capacity-building. The journal aims to promote inter-, multi- and transdisci- plinary approach, future orientation and strategic and global thinking. Transformacje (Transformations) are internationally available – since 2012 we have a licence agrement with the global database: EBSCO Publishing (Ipswich, MA, USA) We are listed by INDEX COPERNICUS since 2013 I TRANSFORMACJE(TRANSFORMATIONS) 3-4 (78-79) 2013 ISSN 1230-0292 Reviewed journal Published twice a year (double issues) in Polish and English (separate papers) Editorial Staff: Prof. Lech W. ZACHER, Center of Impact Assessment Studies and Forecasting, Kozminski University, Warsaw, Poland ([email protected]) – Editor-in-Chief Prof. Dora MARINOVA, Sustainability Policy Institute, Curtin University, Perth, Australia ([email protected]) – Deputy Editor-in-Chief Prof. Tadeusz MICZKA, Institute of Cultural and Interdisciplinary Studies, University of Silesia, Katowice, Poland ([email protected]) – Deputy Editor-in-Chief Dr Małgorzata SKÓRZEWSKA-AMBERG, School of Law, Kozminski University, Warsaw, Poland ([email protected]) – Coordinator Dr Alina BETLEJ, Institute of Sociology, John Paul II Catholic University of Lublin, Poland Dr Mirosław GEISE, Institute of Political Sciences, Kazimierz Wielki University, Bydgoszcz, Poland (also statistical editor) Prof.
    [Show full text]
  • SS 12 Paper V Half 1 Topic 1B
    Systems Analysis of David Easton 1 Development of the General Systems Theory (GST) • In early 20 th century the Systems Theory was first applied in Biology by Ludwig Von Bertallanfy. • Then in 1920s Anthropologists Bronislaw Malinowski ( Argonauts of the Western Pacific ) and Radcliffe Brown ( Andaman Islanders ) used this as a theoretical tool for analyzing the behavioural patterns of the primitive tribes. For them it was more important to find out what part a pattern of behaviour in a given social system played in maintaining the system as a whole, rather than how the system had originated. • Logical Positivists like Moritz Schilick, Rudolf Carnap, Otto Von Newrath, Victor Kraft and Herbert Feigl, who used to consider empirically observable and verifiable knowledge as the only valid knowledge had influenced the writings of Herbert Simon and other contemporary political thinkers. • Linguistic Philosophers like TD Weldon ( Vocabulary of Politics ) had rejected all philosophical findings that were beyond sensory verification as meaningless. • Sociologists Robert K Merton and Talcott Parsons for the first time had adopted the Systems Theory in their work. All these developments in the first half of the 20 th century had impacted on the application of the Systems Theory to the study of Political Science. David Easton, Gabriel Almond, G C Powell, Morton Kaplan, Karl Deutsch and other behaviouralists were the pioneers to adopt the Systems Theory for analyzing political phenomena and developing theories in Political Science during late 1950s and 1960s. What is a ‘system’? • Ludwig Von Bertallanfy: A system is “a set of elements standing in inter-action.” • Hall and Fagan: A system is “a set of objects together with relationships between the objects and between their attributes.” • Colin Cherry: The system is “a whole which is compounded of many parts ..
    [Show full text]
  • Political Systems, Economics of Organization, and the Information Revolution (The Supply Side of Public Choice)
    Political Systems, Economics of organization, and the Information Revolution (The Supply Side of Public Choice) Jean-Jacques Rosa Independent Institute Working Paper Number 27 April 2001 100 Swan Way, Oakland, CA 94621-1428 • 510-632-1366 • Fax: 510-568-6040 • Email: [email protected] • http://www.independent.org European Public Choice Society Meeting Paris, April 18-21, 2001 Political Systems, Economics of organization, and the Information Revolution (The Supply Side of Public Choice) Jean-Jacques Rosa Institut d’Etudes Politiques de Paris March 2001 Abstract: The political history of the twentieth century was characterised by great variability in the social and political systems in both time and space. The initial trend was one of general growth in the size of hierarchical organizations (giant firms, internal and external growth of States) then reversed in the last third of the century with the universal return to the market mechanism, break-up of conglomerates, re-specialisation and downsizing of large firms, the privatization of the public sector, the lightening of the tax burden in a number of countries, the atomization of several States (U.S.S.R., Yugoslavia, and Czechoslovakia) and the triumph of democracy. This paper extends the Coase analysis to the field of Public Choice. It shows how the cost of information is the basic determinant of the choice between markets and hierarchies. The relative scarcity of information thus explains the great cycle of political organization which lead decentralized and democratic societies at the end of the XIXth century to the totalitarian regimes of the first part of the XXth century, and then brought back most countries towards democratic regimes and market economies by the end of the “second XXth century”.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Order in Changing Societies
    Political Order in Changing Societies by Samuel P. Huntington New Haven and London, Yale University Press Copyright © 1968 by Yale University. Seventh printing, 1973. Designed by John O. C. McCrillis, set in Baskerville type, and printed in the United States of America by The Colonial Press Inc., Clinton, Mass. For Nancy, All rights reserved. This book may not be reproduced, in whole or in part, in any form Timothy, and Nicholas (except by reviewers for the public press), without written permission from the publishers. Library of Congress catalog card number: 68-27756 ISBN: 0-300-00584-9 (cloth), 0-300-01171-'7 (paper) Published in Great Britain, Europe, and Africa by Yale University Press, Ltd., London. Distributed in Latin America by Kaiman anti Polon, Inc., New York City; in Australasia and Southeast Asia by John Wiley & Sons Australasia Pty. Ltd., Sidney; in India by UBS Publishers' Distributors Pvt., Ltd., Delhi; in Japan by John Weatherhill, Inc., Tokyo. I·-~· I I. Political Order and Political Decay THE POLITICAL GAP The most important political distinction among countries con­ i cerns not their form of government but their degree of govern­ ment. The differences between democracy and dictatorship are less i than the differences between those countries whose politics em­ , bodies consensus, community, legitimacy, organization, effective­ ness, stability, and those countries whose politics is deficient in these qualities. Communist totalitarian states and Western liberal .states both belong generally in the category of effective rather than debile political systems. The United States, Great Britain, and the Soviet Union have different forms of government, but in all three systems the government governs.
    [Show full text]
  • The Daily Show and Meta-Coverage by Michelle Newman — 5
    The Daily Show and Meta-Coverage by Michelle Newman — 5 The Daily Show and Meta-Coverage: How Mock News Covers the Political Communications System Michelle C. Newman* Strategic Communications Elon University Abstract This study examines the relationship between mock news coverage and Presidential approval. Specifically, it focuses on whether approval affects the volume and framing of mock news meta-coverage, or coverage of the political communications system. In contrast to other studies, which address either entertain- ment news programs or meta-coverage, this study combines the comedy of mock news and the democratic importance of meta-communications. Using a content analysis of The Daily Show episodes during the first term of former President George W. Bush and the current term of President Barack Obama, the research does not support a significant relationship between approval ratings and mock news meta-coverage. The research does identify key trends in meta-coverage themes and framing strategies. I. Introduction When the Pew Research Center released information on America’s most admired news figures in 2007, it probably surprised few to see Katie Couric, Dan Rather, and Tom Brokaw toward the top of the list. However, many were shocked to see one person’s name. Americans ranked comedian Jon Stewart among the top five most admired journalists. Stewart’s mock news program, The Daily Show, has become very popular since it premiered in 1996. The show is regarded as a fake news program, but it is structured much like a traditional news broadcast with an anchor, Stewart, giving news updates and interviewing guests. There are also news packages produced by fake correspondents on real or fake locations.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Capitalism
    07-037 The Political Economy of Capitalism Bruce R. Scott Copyright © 2006 by Bruce R. Scott Working papers are in draft form. This working paper is distributed for purposes of comment and discussion only. It may not be reproduced without permission of the copyright holder. Copies of working papers are available from the author. #07-037 Abstract Capitalism is often defined as an economic system where private actors are allowed to own and control the use of property in accord with their own interests, and where the invisible hand of the pricing mechanism coordinates supply and demand in markets in a way that is automatically in the best interests of society. Government, in this perspective, is often described as responsible for peace, justice, and tolerable taxes. This paper defines capitalism as a system of indirect governance for economic relationships, where all markets exist within institutional frameworks that are provided by political authorities, i.e. governments. In this second perspective capitalism is a three level system much like any organized sports. Markets occupy the first level, where the competition takes place; the institutional foundations that underpin those markets are the second; and the political authority that administers the system is the third. While markets do indeed coordinate supply and demand with the help of the invisible hand in a short term, quasi-static perspective, government coordinates the modernization of market frameworks in accord with changing circumstances, including changing perceptions of societal costs and benefits. In this broader perspective government has two distinct roles, one to administer the existing institutional frameworks, including the provision of infrastructure and the administration of laws and regulations, and the second to mobilize political power to bring about modernization of those frameworks as circumstances and/or societal priorities change.
    [Show full text]