The Formation of Prosociality: Causal Evidence on the Role of Social Environment

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Formation of Prosociality: Causal Evidence on the Role of Social Environment HCEO WORKING PAPER SERIES Working Paper The University of Chicago 1126 E. 59th Street Box 107 Chicago IL 60637 www.hceconomics.org The Formation of Prosociality: Causal Evidence on the Role of Social Environment Fabian Kosse1,2, Thomas Deckers1, Pia Pinger1,2, Hannah Schildberg-H¨orisch3 and Armin Falk*,1,2 ∗ Corresponding author, [email protected] 1 University of Bonn, Institute for Applied Microeconomics 2 Institute on Behavior and Inequality (briq) 3 University of D¨usseldorf,D¨usseldorfInstitute for Competition Economics (DICE) May 2018 Abstract This study presents descriptive and causal evidence on the role of social envi- ronment for the formation of prosociality. In a first step, we show that socio- economic status (SES) as well as the intensity of mother-child interaction and mothers' prosocial attitudes are systematically related to elementary school children's prosociality. In a second step, we present evidence on a randomly- assigned variation of the social environment, providing children with a mentor for the duration of one year. Our data include a two-year follow-up and reveal a significant and persistent increase in prosociality in the treatment relative to the control group. Moreover, enriching the social environment bears the potential to close the observed gap in prosociality between low and high SES children. A mediation analysis of the observed treatment effect suggests that prosociality develops in response to stimuli in the form of prosocial role models and intense social interactions. Keywords: Formation of preferences, prosociality, social preferences, trust, social inequality. JEL-Codes: D64, C90 ∗Financial support through the Leibniz Programme and the CRC TR 224 of the German Re- search Foundation (DFG), the European Research Council (ERC Advanced Grant 340950), and the Benckiser Stiftung Zukunft is gratefully acknowledged. 1 Introduction Prosociality is a particularly important aspect of human personality and it affects a wide range of economic decisions and outcomes, e.g., the provision of public goods, contract enforcement, management of commons, governmental and judicial effi- ciency or economic growth (Knack and Keefer, 1997; La Porta et al., 1997; Fehr and G¨achter, 2002; Henrich et al., 2004; Ostrom et al., 2002; Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales, 2009; Cooper and Kagel, 2009; Burks et al., 2016). Prosocial behavior is not only a crucial factor for the functioning of societies but also an important skill that affects health, well-being, and labor market success (Dohmen et al., 2009; Carpenter and Seki, 2011; Becker et al., 2012; Algan et al., 2016; Deming, 2017).1 The importance of prosociality in economic contexts is thus in line with findings from a vast body of empirical literature on the returns to non-cognitive skills (see, e.g., Heckman, Stixrud, and Urzua, 2006). It is also reflected in economic theory, which, pioneered by Becker's work on altruism (Becker, 1976), incorporates other- regarding preferences and beliefs as key components (e.g., Rabin, 1993; Fehr and Schmidt, 1999; Charness and Rabin, 2002; B´enabou and Tirole, 2006; Falk and Fischbacher, 2006; Fehr and Schmidt, 2006). Despite its fundamental importance, and significant advances in understanding the consequences of prosociality, little is known about how prosociality forms. This paper therefore provides evidence on the formation of prosociality in children with a particular focus on the role of the social environment. It documents that prosociality in children is malleable and how it can be enhanced. We identify prosocial attachment figures and intense social interactions as two main drivers of child prosociality.2 Prosocial attachment figures are highly prosocial individuals with a close social connection to the child. They enable children to observe and imitate a prosocial role model and thereby internalize prosocial beliefs, preferences and behaviors (Skinner, 1953; Williamson, Donohue, and Tully, 2013). Intense social interactions are joint activities that foster social reinforcement and feedback (Eisenberg, Fabes, and Spinrad, 2006; Eisenberg, Spinrad, and Knafo- Noam, 2015). In order to obtain exogenous variation in these stimuli, we randomly assigned a sample of elementary school children to an enriched social environment in form of a mentoring program. This mentoring program is a well-established non- 1Using data from the German Socio-Economic Panel (SOEP), we find for example that a one standard deviation increase in prosociality translates into 0.45 standard deviations improved sub- jective well-being, a two percentage point reduction in the probability of being unemployed, as well as higher wages, and better health (see Becker et al. (2012) and table B1). 2For biological and genetic determinants of prosociality, see e.g. Fehr and Fischbacher (2003), Kosfeld et al. (2005) and Cesarini et al. (2008, 2009). 1 profit program called \Balu und Du" (German for \Baloo and You"). It provides children with a volunteer mentor for the duration of one year. Conceptually, the idea of the program is to extend a child's horizon and foster the acquisition of new skills and experiences through intense social interactions between mentor and child. During the intervention, the child experiences an unrelated and highly prosocial attachment figure taking responsibility and devoting effort and time with him/her. Before and after the intervention, children and their mothers were interviewed by trained interviewers. Children participated in incentivized choice experiments and answered a short questionnaire. Mothers completed an extensive questionnaire covering socio-economic background information, interaction patterns and assess- ments of personality regarding their children and themselves. In order to yield a comprehensive measure of a child's prosociality, we collected data on three main facets: altruism, trust and other-regarding behavior in everyday life. Altruism reflects prosocial motivation, trust indicates prosocial beliefs, and other-regarding behavior in everyday life appraises prosocial behaviors. The corresponding facets have been shown to predict real-life societal and individual success (Becker et al., 2012; Falk et al., 2018). The respective measures combine information from in- centivized experiments and statements from questionnaires. Altruism summarizes children's choices in three incentivized dictator games. Trust is measured using a well-established, age-adapted and experimentally-validated three-item trust ques- tionnaire administered to the child. Moreover, we asked mothers to assess their child's other-regarding behavior in everyday life using the prosociality subscale of the widely used Strength and Difficulties Questionnaire (SDQ) (Goodman, 1997). Our measures thus provide a broad-ranging characterization of prosocial disposition using different data collection methods and statements from children and mothers. This approach reduces measurement error and potential demand effects (Hertwig and Ortmann, 2001). For the main analysis, we collapse all three facets into one joint measure of children's prosociality, but we also provide results for each facet separately. In addition, to understand the respective role of attachment figures, we elicit prosociality for mothers and mentors. As for children, this measure consists of the three facets altruism, trust and other-regarding behavior. Our sample was recruited using official registry data. It comprises families inter- ested in participating in the mentoring intervention and the interviews. We study three distinct groups that differ in terms of socio-economic and treatment status. Based on socio-demographic background information (household income, parental education and single-parent status), we classify families as either low or high SES. Among low SES families, we randomly assigned a subset of families to participate in 2 the intervention, reflecting the treatment group (Treatment Low SES). The remain- ing families with a low SES background form our intervention control group (Control Low SES). The third group comprises families with high SES background (Control High SES). Differences in social environment and child prosociality among Control Low SES and Control High SES families allow us to derive and test hypotheses regarding the two potential drivers of prosociality formation, prosocial attachment figures and intense social interaction, respectively. Comparing Control Low SES and Treatment Low SES provides causal evidence on how providing children with an enriched social environment can promote their prosociality. Overall, we collected three waves of data. After a baseline wave of interviews (wave 1), the treatment was randomly assigned and implemented. The one-year treatment period was closely followed by a post-treatment wave of interviews (wave 2) and a two-year follow-up wave (wave 3). In the main analysis, we focus on post-treatment wave 2 data, but also use wave 1 to study baseline balance and systematic attrition, as well as wave 3 data to investigate whether the observed effects are enduring. Our main findings can be summarized as follows. Using the Control High SES and Control Low SES groups, we first document a pronounced SES gap in prosocial- ity among elementary school children, amounting to 22.6% of a standard deviation. Moreover, we show that low and high SES families differ in their social environment and provide suggestive evidence that alterable stimuli in form of prosocial attach- ment figures and intense social interaction explain a substantial part of the observed SES
Recommended publications
  • Prof. Dr. Armin Falk Biographical Sketch 1998 Phd, University Of
    Prof. Dr. Armin Falk Biographical Sketch 1998 PhD, University of Zurich 1998 - 2003 Assistant professor, University of Zurich 2003 - 2005 Lecturer, Central European University (Budapest) 2003 - today Research Director, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) 2003 - today Professor of Economics, University of Bonn Affiliations with CESifo, CEPR Research Interests Labor Economics, Behavioral and experimental economics Selected Journal Publications “Fairness Perceptions and Reservation Wages - The Behavioral Effects of Minimum Wage Laws” (with Ernst Fehr and Christian Zehnder), Quarterly Journal of Economic, forthcoming. “Distrust - The Hidden Cost of Control” (with Michael Kosfeld), American Economic Review, forthcoming. “Clean Evidence on Peer Effects” (with Andrea Ichino), Journal of Labor Economics, forthcoming. “A Theory of Reciprocity” (with Urs Fischbacher), Games and Economic Behavior 54 (2), 2006, 293-315. “Driving Forces Behind Informal Sanctions” (with Ernst Fehr and Urs Fischbacher), Econometrica 73 (6), 2005, 2017-2030. “The Success of Job Applications: A New Approach to Program Evaluation” (with Rafael Lalive and Josef Zweimüller), Labour Economics 12 (6), 2005, 739-748. “Choosing the Joneses: Endogenous Goals and Reference Standards” (with Markus Knell), Scandinavian Journal of Economics 106 (3), 2004, 417-435. “Relational Contracts and the Nature of Market Interactions” (with Martin Brown and Ernst Fehr), Econometrica 72, 2004, 747-780. “On the Nature of Fair Behavior” (with Ernst Fehr and Urs Fischbacher), Economic Inquiry 41(1), 2003, 20-26. “Reasons for Conflict - Lessons From Bargaining Experiments” (with Ernst Fehr and Urs Fischbacher), Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 159 (1), 2003, 171-187. “Why Labour Market Experiments?” (with Ernst Fehr), Labour Economics 10, 2003, 399-406.
    [Show full text]
  • Armin Falk IZA and University of Bonn April 2004
    I. Introduction Armin Falk IZA and University of Bonn April 2004 Falk: Behavioral Labor Economics: Psychology of Incentives 1/18 This course • Study behavioral effects for labor related outcomes • Empirical studies •Overview – Introduction – Psychology of incentives • Reciprocity and contract enforcement • Dysfunctional effects of explicit incentives • Peer effects • Loss aversion, collusion and sabotage in the presence of tournament incentives – Labor supply – Market behavior • Monopsony and minimum wages • Fairness, efficiency wages and wage rigidities • Incomplete contracts, fairness and the functioning of markets Falk: Behavioral Labor Economics: Psychology of Incentives 2/18 Requirements 1. Take part in the lecture 2. Write a short paper • Either about a summary and discussion of 3 papers • List of topics and papers will be provided • Papers, which are not discussed in this course • Or about a labor economics experiment, which you design, conduct and analyze • Motivation, design, results, discussion • Few observations sufficient • Can also be a field experiment, a theoretical model or the analysis of an existing data set • You can see me and David Huffman to discuss your suggestions Falk: Behavioral Labor Economics: Psychology of Incentives 3/18 Information • Slides can be downloaded – www.iza.org/home/falk • Readers available at IZA Falk: Behavioral Labor Economics: Psychology of Incentives 4/18 Behavioral Economics: From the Nobel Prize laudation “Traditionally, economic theory has relied on the assumption of a "homo œconomicus", whose behavior is governed by self-interest and who is capable of rational decision-making. Economics has also been regarded as a non-experimental science, where researchers – as in astronomy or meteorology – have had to rely exclusively on field data, that is, direct observations of the real world.
    [Show full text]
  • Kranton Duke University
    The Devil is in the Details – Implications of Samuel Bowles’ The Moral Economy for economics and policy research October 13 2017 Rachel Kranton Duke University The Moral Economy by Samuel Bowles should be required reading by all graduate students in economics. Indeed, all economists should buy a copy and read it. The book is a stunning, critical discussion of the interplay between economic incentives and preferences. It challenges basic premises of economic theory and questions policy recommendations based on these theories. The book proposes the path forward: designing policy that combines incentives and moral appeals. And, therefore, like such as book should, The Moral Economy leaves us with much work to do. The Moral Economy concerns individual choices and economic policy, particularly microeconomic policies with goals to enhance the collective good. The book takes aim at laws, policies, and business practices that are based on the classic Homo economicus model of individual choice. The book first argues in great detail that policies that follow from the Homo economicus paradigm can backfire. While most economists would now recognize that people are not purely selfish and self-interested, The Moral Economy goes one step further. Incentives can amplify the selfishness of individuals. People might act in more self-interested ways in a system based on incentives and rewards than they would in the absence of such inducements. The Moral Economy warns economists to be especially wary of incentives because social norms, like norms of trust and honesty, are critical to economic activity. The danger is not only of incentives backfiring in a single instance; monetary incentives can generally erode ethical and moral codes and social motivations people can have towards each other.
    [Show full text]
  • Patience and Comparative Development*
    Patience and Comparative Development* Thomas Dohmen Benjamin Enke Armin Falk David Huffman Uwe Sunde May 29, 2018 Abstract This paper studies the role of heterogeneity in patience for comparative devel- opment. The empirical analysis is based on a simple OLG model in which patience drives the accumulation of physical capital, human capital, productivity improve- ments, and hence income. Based on a globally representative dataset on patience in 76 countries, we study the implications of the model through a combination of reduced-form estimations and simulations. In the data, patience is strongly corre- lated with income levels, income growth, and the accumulation of physical capital, human capital, and productivity. These relationships hold across countries, sub- national regions, and individuals. In the reduced-form analyses, the quantitative magnitude of the relationship between patience and income strongly increases in the level of aggregation. A simple parameterized version of the model generates comparable aggregation effects as a result of production complementarities and equilibrium effects, and illustrates that variation in preference endowments can account for a considerable part of the observed variation in per capita income. JEL classification: D03, D90, O10, O30, O40. Keywords: Patience; comparative development; factor accumulation. *Armin Falk acknowledges financial support from the European Research Council through ERC # 209214. Dohmen, Falk: University of Bonn, Department of Economics; [email protected], [email protected]. Enke: Harvard University, Department of Economics; [email protected]. Huffman: University of Pittsburgh, Department of Economics; huff[email protected]. Sunde: University of Munich, Department of Economics; [email protected]. 1 Introduction A long stream of research in development accounting has documented that both pro- duction factors and productivity play an important role in explaining cross-country income differences (Hall and Jones, 1999; Caselli, 2005; Hsieh and Klenow, 2010).
    [Show full text]
  • Walrasian Economics in Retrospect
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Bowles, Samuel; Gintis, Herbert Working Paper Walrasian Economics in Retrospect Working Paper, No. 2000-04 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts Suggested Citation: Bowles, Samuel; Gintis, Herbert (2000) : Walrasian Economics in Retrospect, Working Paper, No. 2000-04, University of Massachusetts, Department of Economics, Amherst, MA This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/105719 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu WALRASIAN ECONOMICS IN RETROSPECT∗ Department of Economics University of Massachusetts Amherst, Massachusetts, 01003 Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis February 4, 2000 Abstract Two basic tenets of the Walrasian model, behavior based on self-interested exogenous preferences and complete and costless contracting have recently come under critical scrutiny.
    [Show full text]
  • Did We Overestimate the Role of Social Preferences? the Case of Self-Selected Student Samples
    Did we overestimate the role of social preferences? The case of self-selected student samples Armin Falk,∗ Stephan Meier,y and Christian Zehnderz July 13, 2010 Abstract Social preference research has fundamentally changed the way economists think about many important economic and social phenomena. However, the em- pirical foundation of social preferences is largely based on laboratory experiments with self-selected students as participants. This is potentially problematic as students participating in experiments may behave systematically different than non-participating students or non-students. In this paper we empirically inves- tigate whether laboratory experiments with student samples misrepresent the importance of social preferences. Our first study shows that students who ex- hibit stronger prosocial inclinations in an unrelated field donation are not more likely to participate in experiments. This suggests that self-selection of more prosocial students into experiments is not a major issue. Our second study com- pares behavior of students and the general population in a trust experiment. We find very similar behavioral patterns for the two groups. If anything, the level of reciprocation seems higher among non-students implying an even greater importance of social preferences than assumed from student samples. Keywords: methodology, selection, experiments, prosocial behavior JEL: C90, D03 ∗University of Bonn, Department of Economics, Adenauerallee 24-42, D-53113 Bonn; [email protected]. yColumbia University, Graduate School of Business, 710 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway, New York, NY 10027; [email protected]. zUniversity of Lausanne, Faculty of Business and Economics, Quartier UNIL-Dorigny, Internef 612, CH-1015 Lausanne; [email protected]. 1 1 Introduction Social preferences such as trust and reciprocity play an increasingly important role in economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Fairness in the Labour Market a Survey of Experimental Results
    Research Collection Working Paper Fairness in the labour market a survey of experimental results Author(s): Gächter, Simon; Fehr, Ernst Publication Date: 2002 Permanent Link: https://doi.org/10.3929/ethz-a-004375058 Rights / License: In Copyright - Non-Commercial Use Permitted This page was generated automatically upon download from the ETH Zurich Research Collection. For more information please consult the Terms of use. ETH Library Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich Working Paper Series ISSN 1424-0459 Forthcoming in: Friedel Bolle and Marco Lehmann-Waffenschmidt (eds.): Surveys in Experimental Economics. Bargaining, Cooperation and Election Stock Markets. Physica Verlag 2001. Working Paper No. 114 Fairness in the Labour Market – A Survey of Experimental Results Simon Gächter and Ernst Fehr April 2002 Fairness in the Labour Market – * A Survey of Experimental Results Simon Gächter Ernst Fehr University of St. Gallen University of Zurich FEW-HSG Institute for Empirical Economic Research Varnbüelstrasse 14 Blümlisalpstrasse 10 CH-9000 St. Gallen CH-8006 Zurich [email protected] [email protected] Forthcoming in: Friedel Bolle and Marco Lehmann-Waffenschmidt (eds.): Surveys in Experimental Economics. Bargaining, Cooperation and Election Stock Markets. Physica Verlag 2001. 7 November 2001 Abstract In this chapter we provide a selective survey of experiments to investigate the potential of social motivations in explaining labour market phenomena. We argue that laboratory experiments are a useful instrument to explore issues in labour market theory and personnel economics. Our starting point is the observation that employment relations are frequently governed by incomplete contracts. We show that the norm of reciprocity that leads to gift exchanges is an effective contract enforcement device under conditions of contractual incompleteness.
    [Show full text]
  • Davranişsal Iktisat
    Hatime Kamilçelebi DAVRANIŞSAL İKTİSAT IJOPEC PUBLICATION London ijopec.co.uk Istanbul DAVRANIŞSAL İKTİSAT Hatime Kamilçelebi Davranışsal İktisat Hatime Kamilçelebi IJOPEC PUBLICATION London ijopec.co.uk Istanbul IJOPEC Publication Limited www.ijopec.co.uk 60 Westmeade Close E-Mail: [email protected] Cheshunt, Waltham Cross Phone: (+44) 73 875 2361 (UK) Hertfordshire (+90) 488 217 4007 (Turkey) EN7 6JR London Davranışsal İktisat First Edition, December 2019 IJOPEC Publication No: 2019/20 ISBN: 978-1-912503-83-4 No part of this book may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, transmitted in any form or by any means electronically without author’s permission. No responsibility is accepted for the accuracy of information contained in the text, illustrations or advertisements. The opinions expressed in these haptersc are not necessarily those of the editors or publisher. A catalogue record for this book is available from Nielsen Book Data, British Library and Google Books. The publishing responsibilities of the chapters in this book belong to the authors. Printed in London. Composer: IJOPEC Art Design Cover illustrators are from Pinclipart & Freepik İçindekiler Tablolar Listesi ..................................................................................................... 5 Grafikler Listesi .................................................................................................... 6 Ön Söz ................................................................................................................. 7 Giriş ....................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Grand Experiment of Communism: Discovering the Trade-Off Between Equality and Efficiency
    NOTA DI LAVORO 70.2011 The Grand Experiment of Communism: Discovering the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency By Etienne Farvaque, Equippe - University of Lille 1, Faculté des Sciences Economiques et Sociales, France Alexander Mihailov, University of Reading and University of Warwick, Department of Economics, United Kingdom Alireza Naghavi, University of Bologna, Department of Economics, Italy Economy and Society Editor: Giuseppe Sammarco The Grand Experiment of Communism: Discovering the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency By Etienne Farvaque, Equippe - University of Lille 1, Faculté des Sciences Economiques et Sociales, France Alexander Mihailov, University of Reading and University of Warwick, Department of Economics, United Kingdom Alireza Naghavi, University of Bologna, Department of Economics, Italy Summary This paper aims to explain the rise and fall of communism by exploring the interplay between economic incentives and social preferences in different economic systems. We introduce inequality-averse and inefficiency-averse agents responding to economic incentives and transmitting their ideology as they are affected by evolving outcomes. We analyze their conflict through the interaction between leaders with economic power and followers with ideological determination. The socioeconomic dynamics of our model generate a pendulum- like switch from markets to a centrally-planned economy abolishing private ownership, and back to restoring market incentives. The grand experiment of communism is thus characterized to have led
    [Show full text]
  • CV Armin Falk
    Curriculum Vitae Professor Dr. Armin Falk Name: Armin Falk Born: 18 January 1968 Photo: J Henry Fair Research Priorities: Behavioral Economics, Neuroeconomics, Experimental Economics, Labour Economics Armin Falk is a German behavioural economist. His research aims on a better empirical foundation of the economic behaviour model. This is important for basic research as well as from an economic and sociopolitical point of view. Academic and Professional Career since 2016 Director of the Institute on Behavior and Inequality Research (briq), Bonn, Germany since 2016 Research Fellow, German Institute for Economic Research (DIW), Berlin, Germany 2009 - 2016 Director of the Center for Economics and Neuroscience, University of Bonn, Germany since 2006 Research Professor, German Institute for Economic Research (DIW), Berlin, Germany since 2004 Director of the Bonn Laboratory for Experimental Economics, Germany since 2003 Professor of Economics at University of Bonn, Germany 2003 - 2007 Research Director, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn, Germany 2003 - 2005 Lecturer, Central European University, Budapest, Hungary 2003 Habilitation and Venia legendi at the University of Zurich, Switzerland since 2000 Fellow at the Institute for Economic Research (CESifo), Munich, Germany since 1999 Research Fellow in the Labour Economics Programme of the Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) 1999 Ph.D. in Economics, University of Zurich, Switzerland Nationale Akademie der Wissenschaften Leopoldina www.leopoldina.org 1 1998 - 2003 Assistant Professor,
    [Show full text]
  • David Huffman 416 N
    DAVID HUFFMAN 416 N. Chester Rd., Apt. 2 Swarthmore, PA 19081 E-mail: [email protected] Webpage: http://www.swarthmore.edu/x28019.xml PERSONAL Birth Date: April 4th, 1974 Citizenship: USA EMPLOYMENT SINCE PH.D. Associate Professor (with tenure), Swarthmore College February 2012 – Present Assistant Professor, Swarthmore College January 2008 – February 2013 IZA Senior Research Associate 2006 – 2007 Deputy Director, Behavioral and Personnel Economics Program Area IZA Laboratory Coordinator IZA Research Associate 2003 – 2006 EDITORIAL POSITIONS Associate Editor for Management Science January 2013 – present EDUCATION University of California, Berkeley Ph.D. Economics 2003 Primary Fields: Behavioral economics, labor economics, applied microeconomics. Dissertation Advisor: Professor George Akerlof Oberlin College, Oberlin Ohio B.A., magna cum laude in Economics 1996 PUBLICATIONS “Implicit Contracts, Unemployment, and Market Segmentation” IZA Discussion Paper, No. 5001 (with Steffen Altmann, Armin Falk, and Andreas Grunewald), forthcoming in Review of Economic Studies. “When a Nudge isn’t Enough: A Field Test of the Power of Defaults to Influence Savings of Low- Income Tax Filers”, NBER Working Paper, No. 16887 (with Erin Bronchetti, Thomas Dee, and Ellen Magenheim), forthcoming in National Tax Journal. “Validating an Ultra-Short Survey Measure of Impatience”, forthcoming in Economics Letters (with Thomas Dohment, Armin Falk, Jürgen Schupp, Uwe Sunde, Thomas Vischer, and Gert Wagner). “Competition Between Organizational Groups: Its Impact on Altruistic and Antisocial Motivations”, Management Science, 2012, 58(5), 948–960 (with Lorenz Goette, Stephan Meier, and Matthias Sutter). “The Impact of Social Ties on Group Interactions: Evidence from Minimal Groups and Randomly Assigned Real Groups”, American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2012, 4(1), 101–115 (with Lorenz Goette and Stephan Meier).
    [Show full text]
  • Gift Exchange in the Field
    Gift Exchange in the Field Armin Falk* University of Bonn, IZA, CEPR, CESifo This version: May 2005 Abstract. This study reports evidence from a field experiment that was conducted to investigate the relevance of gift-exchange in a natural setting. In collaboration with a charitable organization we sent roughly 10,000 solicitation letters to potential donors. One third of the letters contained no gift, one third contained a small gift and one third contained a large gift. The treatment assignment was random. The results confirm the economic importance of gift-exchange. Compared to the no gift condition, the relative frequency of donations increased by 17 percent if a small gift was included and by 75 percent for a large gift. The study extends the current body of research on reciprocity, which is almost exclusively confined to laboratory studies. The results also add to the understanding of the motives behind charitable giving. Keywords: gift-exchange, reciprocity, field experiments, charitable giving JEL-classification: C93, D63, H41 * Address: Institute for the Study of Labor, P.O. Box 7240, D-53072 Bonn, Germany Email: [email protected] 1. INTRODUCTION In recent years numerous laboratory experiments have provided strong evidence in favor of social preferences and gift-exchange. In the so-called gift-exchange game, e.g., it has been shown that by paying generous prices, buyers induce sellers to provide (costly) quality levels above the contractually enforceable level. In particular, the higher the prices (the gift), the higher are the average quality levels (Fehr, Kirchsteiger and Riedl 1993; Fehr, Gächter and Kirchsteiger 1997; Gneezy 2003).
    [Show full text]