Is Globalization Causing a 'Race to the Bottom' in Environmental Standards? (Part 4 of a Four Part Series)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Is Globalization Causing a 'Race to the Bottom' in Environmental Standards? (Part 4 of a Four Part Series) Is Globalization Causing A 'Race To The Bottom' In Environmental Standards? (Part 4 of a four part series) If globalization promotes growth, won't that mean more environmental degradation? Some critics argue that since increased trade and foreign direct investment stimulate higher growth in developing countries, this must lead to more industrial pollution and environmental degradation. Some pollutants such as acid emissions or particulate matter are empirically observed to have an 'inverted U curve' relation with income: pollution first rises as countries advance from low to middle level incomes, before falling again as countries attain high incomes. Is pollution an inevitable price for economic development? It should be noted in passing that this is an argument against economic growth in general, rather than against globalization specifically. Is it true, however, that growth in developing countries must necessarily be accompanied by severe environmental degradation? Recent evidence suggests a more subtle and complex relationship between economic development and environmental protection. Empirical observation of an 'inverted U' in some instances says little about the environmental policies underlying the observation, or the potential for better policies to 'flatten' or eliminate it. Thus it is striking that many developing countries have already turned or are turning the corner in the fight against pollution at much lower levels of income than the rich countries did in their day. A 1998 World Bank study of organic water pollution found that pollution intensity fell by 90 per cent as per capita income rose from $500 to $20,000, with the fastest decline occurring before the country reached middle income status (Figure 6. Hettige, Mani and Wheeler, 1998). Average air quality in China has stabilized or improved since the mid- 1980s in monitored cities, especially large ones - the same period during which China has experienced both rapid economic growth and increased openness to trade and investment. It seems there is no hard and fast rule that a certain level of development will be associated with a certain level of pollution. Much depends on the environmental policies countries pursue. Indeed, many developing countries appear to have found that the benefits of pollution control outweigh the costs and are adopting innovative, low-cost strategies to limit pollution while also expanding economic growth. For example, new pilot projects based on public disclosure of information about factory pollution have had significant success in reducing pollution in Indonesia and the Philippines. Moreover, openness to trade and investment can provide developing countries with both the incentive to adopt, and the access to, new technologies, which may provide a cleaner or greener way of producing the good concerned. For example, much foreign investment is for export markets. The quality requirements in those markets encourage use of the latest technology, which is typically cleaner than old technologies. A World Bank study of steel production in 50 countries found that open economies led closed economies in the adoption of cleaner technologies by wide margins, resulting in the open economies being 17 percent less pollution-intensive in this sector than closed economies (Wheeler, Huq and Martin 1993). This discussion suggests that developing countries may be able to achieve high levels of economic growth and high levels of environmental performance long before they reach the income levels of the industrialized countries. This is not to say that there are no tradeoffs between growth and the environment. Even with good environmental policies and clean technologies, continued increases in output may tend to increase the total volumes of various kinds of pollutants in many cases. Every society has to decide for itself on the relative value it places on economic output and the environment. The point about international openness, though, is that in general it appears to make this tradeoff less painful for developing countries, allowing more environmental protection for the same amount of growth, or more growth for the same amount of environmental protection. Will liberalization devastate sensitive environmental sectors? A second related concern is that trade and investment liberalization in environmentally- sensitive sectors such as forestry and fishing will exacerbate existing overuse of resources. Over-use of a natural resource may occur when there is a policy regime of open access and the overall costs to society of its use are not fully reflected in the price paid by private users (for example individual fishermen do not consider the impact of their activities on global fishing stocks). Opening the activity to international trade and investment may then exacerbate the irreversible loss of environmental resources. An important question here is that if one's concern is to protect a scarce environmental resource then why tax or regulate only international trade in the product? In the ideal case, taxing or regulating both international and domestic trade in the product without discrimination will usually be a more efficient or effective way of protecting it. Often, however, developing countries do not have the institutional capacity to put in place these more ideal, non-discriminatory environmental protection policies. In some cases, then, not opening the sector for the time being may turn out to be the only realistic 'second-best' policy, while the institutional and regulatory capacity for better quality environmental protection is built up. Will competition for investment cause developing countries to become 'pollution havens'? Another concern relates less to environmental outcomes and more to environmental regulation. It is argued that increased international competition for investment will cause countries to lower environmental regulations (or to retain poor ones), a "race to the bottom" in environmental standards as countries fight to attract foreign capital and keep domestic investment at home. However there is no evidence that the cost of environmental protection has ever been the determining factor in foreign investment decisions. Factors such as labor and raw material costs, transparent regulation and protection of property rights are likely to be much more important, even for polluting industries. Indeed, foreign-owned plants in developing countries, precisely the ones that according to the theory would be most attracted by low standards, tend to be less polluting than indigenous plants in the same industry. Most multinational companies adopt near-uniform standards globally, often well above the local government-set standards (Dowell, Hart and Yeung 2000; Schot and Fischer 1993). This suggests that they relocate plants to developing countries for reasons other than low environmental standards. Paradoxically, the pollution haven effect may be more important within the national boundaries of a developed country than between rich and poor countries. Within a national boundary many of the other locational factors are less important, and so local environmental regulations might matter more. (Globalization, Growth, and Poverty, World Bank, 2001) In East Asia in the 1970s, . the fast growing "Tigers" (Korea, Taiwan (China), Singapore and Hong Kong) began to export more of certain highly polluting sectors, while Japan began to reduce its exports in these sectors. However, this trend diminished in the 1980s, and a stable pattern emerged with the Tigers importing somewhat more than they export in the highly-polluting sectors. A similar pattern occurred in trade of polluting sector products between North America and Latin America. In China the share of the five dirtiest industries in total industrial output has fallen, while imports of pollution intensive products have actually increased. (World Bank, 1997). Two recent empirical studies (Wheeler 2001; Jaffe and others 1995) do not find that countries have lowered their standards to attract foreign investment or to increase exports. Wheeler analyzes data on air quality in the industrial heartlands of three major new globalizing countries; Brazil, China and Mexico. He finds that far from experiencing a race to the bottom, all three have registered improvements in air quality. Countries do not become permanent pollution havens because along with increases in income come increased demands for environmental quality and a better institutional capacity to supply environmental regulation. One World Bank study of 145 countries identified a strong positive correlation between income levels and the strictness of environmental regulation (Figure 7. Dasgupta, Mody, Roy and Wheeler, 1995). Indeed the so-called "California Effect" in the US demonstrates that there is nothing inevitable about a 'race to the bottom.' After the passage of the US 1970 Clean Air Act Amendments, California repeatedly adopted stricter emissions standards than other US states. Instead of a flight of investment and jobs from California, however, other states began adopting similar, tougher emissions standards. A self-reinforcing "race to the top" was thus put in place in which California helped lift standards throughout the US. Vogel (1995) attributes this largely to the "lure of green markets" - car manufacturers were willing to meet California's higher standards to avoid losing such a large market and once they had met the standard in one state, they could easily meet it in every state. Openness and environment friendly policies It seems
Recommended publications
  • Multi-Page.Pdf
    POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1458 Public Disclosure Authorized Credit Policies Directed credit programs should be small, narrowly focused, and of limited Lessons from East Asia duration fwith clear sunset provisions).They should be Public Disclosure Authorized Dimitri Vittas financedby long-term funds Yoon Je Cho to preventinflation and macroeconomic instability. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized The World Bank FinancialSector Development Department May 1995 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1458 Summary findings Directed credit programs were a major tool of * Credit programs must be financed by long-term development in the 1960s and 1970s. In the 1980s, their funds to prevent inflation and macroeconomic instabilitv. usefulness was reconsidered. Experience in most Recourse to central bank credit should be avoided except countries showed that they stimulated capital-intensive in the very early stages of development when the central projects, that preferential funds were often (mis)used for bank's assistance can help jump-start economic growth. nonpriority purposes, that a decline in financial * They should aim at achieving positive externalities discipline led to low repayment rates, and that budget (or avoiding negative ones). Any help to declining deficits swelled. Moreover, the programs were hard to industries should include plans for their timely phaseour. remove. * They should promote industrialization and export But Japan and other East Asian countries have long orientation in a competitive private sector with touted the merits of focused, well-managed directed internationally competitive operations. credit programs, saying they are warranted when there is * They should be part of a credible vision of economic a significant discrepancy between private and social development that promotes growth with equity and benefits, when investment risk is too high on certain should involve a long-term strategy to develop a sound projects, and when information problems discourage financial system.
    [Show full text]
  • REP21 December 1974
    World Bank Reprint Series: Number Twenty-one REP21 December 1974 Public Disclosure Authorized V.V. Bhatt Some Aspects of Financial Policies and Central Banking in Developing Countries Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Reprinted from World Development 2 (October-December 1974) World Development Vol.2, No.10-12, October-Deceinber 1974, pp. 59-67 59 Some Aspects of Financial Policies and Central Banking in Developing Countries V. V. BHATT Economic Development Institute of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development mechanism and agency as provided by the existence of a Central Bank. What needs special emphasis at an international level is the rationale and urgency of evolving a sound financial structure through the efficient performance of the twin interrelated functions-as promoters and as regulators of the financial system-by Central Banks. 1. SOME ASPECTS OF FINANCIAL POLICIES .. ~~~The main object of this Section is to show the Economic development is not only facilitated but its . pace is quickened by the appropriate development of the significance of saving and flow-of-funds analysis as an financial system--structure of financial institutions, indicator of a set of financial policies-policies relating instruments and interest rates.1 to the structure of financial institutions, instruments and Instrumentsand interest rates.r interest rates-essential for resource mobilization and In any strategy of development, therefore, it is allocation consistent with a country's development essential to emphasize the evolution of a sound and . 6 c well-integrated financial system from the point of view objectives. In a large number of developing countries, the only both of resource mobilization and efficient allocation.2 reliable data available for understanding the trends in the In Section I of this paper, an attempt is made to economy and for policy purposes relate to monetary delineate the broad contours of a set of financial policies flows and the balance of payments.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Is There No Race to the Bottom in Capital Taxation? Tax Competition Between Countries Of
    International Studies Quarterly (2009) 53, 761–786 Why is There No Race to the Bottom in Capital Taxation? Thomas Plu¨mper and Vera E. Troeger University of Essex Hannes Winner University of Innsbruck This article explains the absence of a race to the bottom in capital taxa- tion by analyzing fiscal competition under budget rigidities and tax equity constraints (fairness norms). We outline a political economic model of tax competition that treats the outcome of tax competition as one argu- ment in the governments utility function, the others being public expen- diture and tax equity. In accordance with previous theoretical research, tax competition tends to cause a reduction in taxes on mobile capital and an increase in the tax rates on relatively immobile labor in our model. Yet, our model predicts that governments do not fully abolish taxes on mobile capital. Instead, the government being least restricted by budget constraints and equity norms cuts tax rates to levels slightly below the low- est tax rates of those countries, in which governments are more con- strained, where effective constraints are country size, budget rigidities and fairness norms. Analyzing data from 23 Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development countries between 1975 and 2004 we find empirical support for the hypotheses derived from our theoretical model. A striking feature of international tax competition is the fact that independent jurisdictions share a mobile tax base. As a consequence, a country lowering its capital tax rate attracts an immediate inflow of capital, thereby reducing the tax base of other countries. These respond to the shrinking tax base and to declin- ing tax revenues by lowering their capital tax rate to competitive levels.
    [Show full text]
  • Profit Maximizing Goes Global: the Race to the Bottom David Kiefer Codrina Rada
    DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES Profit maximizing goes global: the race to the bottom David Kiefer Codrina Rada Working Paper No: 2013-05 March 2013 University of Utah Department of Economics 260 S. Central Campus Dr., Rm. 343 Tel: (801) 581-7481 Fax: (801) 585-5649 http://www.econ.utah.edu Profit maximizing goes global: the race to the bottom David Kiefer Department of Economics, University of Utah [email protected] Codrina Rada Department of Economics, University of Utah [email protected] Abstract We explore four decades of cyclical and long-run dynamics in income distribution and economic activity for a panel of thirteen OECD countries, as measured by the wage share and the output gap. When modeled as a Goodwin model, our results suggest that economic activity is weakly profit-led and that the wage share is pro-cyclical. Our estimated model is dynamically stable and has a long-run equilibrium in distribution- utilization space. An extension of the model suggests that this equilibrium has been shifting south-west towards a lower wage share and a loss of economic activity. This finding is suggestive of a coordination failure among industrialized nations; it could be that the governments of these countries are engaging in a race to the bottom in terms of the wage share; it may even be that this race has the undesirable consequence of decreasing economic efficiency. Keywords: predator-prey models; distributive-demand dynamics; panel data estimation; JEL Classification: D3; C23; C61; Profit maximizing goes global: the race to the bottom David Kiefer ∗ Codrina Rada y Abstract We explore four decades of cyclical and long-run dynamics in income distribution and economic activity for a panel of thirteen OECD countries, as measured by the wage share and the output gap.
    [Show full text]
  • Goals for the Rich Indispensible for a Universal Post-2015 Agenda Discussion Paper Civil Society Reflection Group on Global Development Perspectives
    Advance Unedited Version | 4 March 2015 1 Goals for the rich Indispensible for a universal Post-2015 Agenda Discussion Paper Civil Society Reflection Group on Global Development Perspectives 1. Introduction: Context and Principles After many years of focusing on the symptoms of extreme poverty with the pursuit of the Millennium Development Goals (MDG), the UN system is finally picking up a universal sustainability agenda, enshrined in the Sustainable Development Goals (SDG), that address sustainability and causes of poverty and inequality. The Open Working Group of the UN General Assembly on Sustainable Development Goals has proposed a list of 17 goals and 169 targets.1 The consensus outcome of this group, endorsed by the UN General Assembly in September 2014 as the “main basis” of the post-2015 development agenda, goes far beyond the narrow scope of the MDGs. The MDGs provided an international framework for the advancement of social development for the poor in the global South with a little help from the rich in the global North. Unlike the MDGs, the Post-2015 Agenda with the SDGs as a pivotal building block is intended to be truly universal and global. SDGs will be for everybody, rich countries, countries with emerging economies and poor countries. If it succeeds, this new global sustainability agenda would not only take forward the unfinished business of the MDGs, by ending poverty in all its forms everywhere, but add important dimensions. Apart from the potential to tackle inequalities and injustices worldwide, it would trigger decisive action to protect the integrity of our planet, to combat climate change, and put an end to the overuse of resources and ecosystems by acknowledging planetary boundaries and promoting the respect for nature.
    [Show full text]
  • U World Bank Discussion Papers
    Public Disclosure Authorized UWorld Bank DiscussionPapers Public Disclosure Authorized Credit Policies and the Industrialization of Korea Public Disclosure Authorized YoonJe Cho Joon-Kyung Kim Public Disclosure Authorized Recent World Bank Discussion Papers 1 N L' 2 1$ ( :1.'.*;.rifi au. te111,c,gt k p 1 IiatjC A iJ.luauritt,) Pa reiw :17a,.'entual IPirplctliver .irid I rnij'iu.dl l:'de t.e. KlamsuXV I )CIItiger Nt i. 2 I' I )cvelopruirnvof' Rgirj I,,.nai.a 1 .la ukrt,, irn S,.I,-Sa,ira,n Sah.upathwThil lirajah Nto. 224) '17li .A .litimre 'I iaPs, popOt 1i Ha. J. I'eLers Na I221 l'.l lia.r.l 1Fiu,uucr7iic Iixl'ertretr .4 l'oniat j.m. Tle Jap.inesc D)evelopimentBlank .indITlih J.ql.anEcnninntntc IResearch IiStEtute N.a 222 .1 a, ', r,'uimnnL .I tFclairrct al C lana:Plrn. cilint. ol.a Confim r--ineh liarD, .June 1993. Edited 1v Petcr Harrold. E. C. 1-twa.Jnidt Lou jtiet No'.223 1lie DrioloitentVY o0rIa 11,1 1nate .Soat,' an .1 Sall luior,OinMil 'lan.nsi:on:Ile Caw .in'.ionloli.3 Hotiaiijti Hahn; N i 224 ii;,,vgJ uIaEtirzrontpracn:l Stlral qj-,t, .',ita. CLarter lBrandoa andcilUi iesi; RtatJIaiakuctv Ntia22i E"orties.Irollpc"a.sad OIthir .Alythit abmout*hade: 110oii to. rorf Alerahandeiise pIportsin thir lt ,and()ilaer Mlalor IFdltrriltYlliu1n1,'tnu1. ;.n 1d lita '17W)'.Aleanj ilr evrhlo'pmnCuileutr,ij-).]ean alna etli Nit 226 .\ Olk.l.i Fr1l,8liartI: EdicatilollOII dtritg Ei,c'noniac lianist1o11. Kin Bling Wu NO. 227 Cjtaut' U'ilitna I.aidn bMarkerS;.rsn,.ri of the Iauild Socali,r lExpennmiert.Alain lBertaudi anid Bertrand Relnaud No.
    [Show full text]
  • The State of the Poor: Where Are the Poor and Where Are They Poorest?1
    The State of the Poor: Where are the Poor and where are they Poorest?1 Extreme poverty in the world has decreased considerably in the past three decades (figure 1). In 1981, more than half of citizens in the developing world lived on less than $1.25 a day. This rate has dropped dramatically to 21 percent in 2010. Moreover, despite a 59 percent increase in the developing world’s population, there were significantly fewer people living on less than $1.25 a day in 2010 (1.2 billion) than there were three decades ago (1.9 billion). But 1.2 billion people living in extreme poverty is still a extremely high figure, so the task ahead of us remains herculean. To accelerate poverty reduction and end extreme poverty by 2030, we need to know who are the poor, where do they live, and where poverty is deepest. How have the different regions of the developing world performed in terms of extreme poverty reduction? Extreme poverty headcount rates have fallen in every developing region in the last three decades. And both Sub‐Saharan Africa (SSA) and Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) seem to have turned a corner entering the new millennium. After steadily increasing from 51 percent in 1981 to 58 percent in 1999, the extreme poverty rate fell 10 percentage points in SSA between 1999 and 2010 and is now at 48 percent— an impressive decline of 17 percent in one decade. In LAC, after remaining stable at approximately 12 percent for the last two decades of the 20th century, extreme poverty was cut in half between 1999 and 2010 and is now at 6 percent.
    [Show full text]
  • Democracy and Inequality: a Resource Guide
    Democracy and Inequality A Resource Guide www.idea.int © 2017 International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance International IDEA publications are independent of specific national or political interests. Views expressed in this publication do not necessarily represent the views of International IDEA, its Board or its Council members. References to the names of countries and regions in this publication do not represent the official position of International IDEA with regard to the legal status or policy of the entities mentioned. Applications for permission to reproduce or translate all or any part of this publication should be made to: International IDEA Strömsborg SE–103 34 STOCKHOLM SWEDEN Tel: +46 8 698 37 00 Email: [email protected] Website: <http://www.idea.int> International IDEA encourages dissemination of its work and will promptly respond to requests for permission to reproduce or translate its publications. This publication has received support from International IDEA’s Member States through the Institute’s core funding. Grateful acknowledgement is made to the governments of Norway and Sweden, whose generous support made this publication possible. Text editing: Andrew Mash Layout: International IDEA Original design concept: Phoenix Design Aid Democracy and Inequality Fletcher D. Cox* This Resource Guide is part of a series designed for readers, including students and practitioners, interested in exploring further some of the themes and issues raised in The Global State of Democracy 2017: Exploring Democracy's Resilience (International IDEA 2017). The contents of the series reflect the topics of each chapter in the larger report, presenting current and past debates and key concepts related to each topic.
    [Show full text]
  • the Wto, Imf and World Bank
    ISSN: 1726-9466 13 F ULFILLING THE MARRAKESH MANDATE ON COHERENCE: ISBN: 978-92-870-3443-4 TEN YEARS OF COOPERATION BETWEEN THE WTO, IMF AND WORLD BANK by MARC AUBOIN Printed by the WTO Secretariat - 6006.07 DISCUSSION PAPER NO 13 Fulfi lling the Marrakesh Mandate on Coherence: Ten Years of Cooperation between the WTO, IMF and World Bank by Marc Auboin Counsellor, Trade and Finance and Trade Facilitation Division World Trade Organization Geneva, Switzerland Disclaimer and citation guideline Discussion Papers are presented by the authors in their personal capacity and opinions expressed in these papers should be attributed to the authors. They are not meant to represent the positions or opinions of the WTO Secretariat or of its Members and are without prejudice to Members’ rights and obligations under the WTO. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. Any citation of this paper should ascribe authorship to staff of the WTO Secretariat and not to the WTO. This paper is only available in English – Price CHF 20.- To order, please contact: WTO Publications Centre William Rappard 154 rue de Lausanne CH-1211 Geneva Switzerland Tel: (41 22) 739 52 08 Fax: (41 22) 739 57 92 Website: www.wto.org E-mail: [email protected] ISSN 1726-9466 ISBN: 978-92-870-3443-4 Printed by the WTO Secretariat IX-2007 Keywords: coherence, cooperation in global economic policy making, economic policy coordination, cooperation between international organizations. © World Trade Organization, 2007. Reproduction of material contained in this document may be made only with written permission of the WTO Publications Manager.
    [Show full text]
  • The Age of Economists: Globalization, Growth and Inequalities
    SYLLABUS THE AGE OF ECONOMISTS: GLOBALIZATION, GROWTH AND INEQUALITIES Professor: David DUHAMEL Session: January Language of instruction: English Number of hours of class: 30 Objective of the Course The course is an overview of how economic thought has risen over the centuries, and how, since WWII, it has influenced neighboring disciplines such as political philosophy, common law, political science, sociology and psychology. Each class will be devoted to a theme and a select number of authors. Economic news and current events in the largest sense will be mobilized to emphasize the longevity of our subject. We will use case studies, whether historical, experimental or empirical, to engage discussion and show how the history of economic thought shaped - if not totally constructed - some of our most important contemporary debates (the undesirability of inequalities, the value of globalization, the commodification of human interaction, etc.). Dialogue will be encouraged. Teamwork and innovation will be put at a premium during the collective assignments. Each group of five students will research a given subject. Form and substance will both be graded. A list of subjects can be found at the bottom of the syllabus. Summary “The age of chivalry is gone… now is the age of economists; and the glory of Europe is extinguished forever.” (Burke, 1790). Globalization, free trade, growth and its possible end, the crisis, inequalities, the rise of AI and its impact on the labor market, populism, demographic trends… all those subjects will be studied. From Gilgamesh and Aristotle to neuroeconomics and high frequency trading, this course aims to contextualize contemporary debates and underline how an economic “way of thinking” is now one of, if not the, dominant scheme in our lives, whether it is at the individual, societal or planetary levels.
    [Show full text]
  • Growth and Economic Thought Before and After the 2008-09 Crisis1
    WPS5752 Policy Research Working Paper 5752 Public Disclosure Authorized Learning from Developing Country Experience Growth and Economic Thought Before and After Public Disclosure Authorized the 2008–09 Crisis Ann Harrison Claudia Sepúlveda Public Disclosure Authorized The World Bank Public Disclosure Authorized Development Economics Vice Presidency August 2011 Policy Research Working Paper 5752 Abstract The aim of this paper is twofold. First, it documents the Second, it explores what these global economic changes changing global landscape before and after the crisis, and the recent crisis imply for shifts in the direction of emphasizing the shift towards multipolarity. In particular, research in development economics. The paper places it emphasizes the ascent of developing countries in the a particular emphasis on the lessons that developed global economy before, during, and after the crisis. countries can learn from the developing world. This paper is a product of the Development Economics Vice Presidency. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted may be contacted at [email protected] and [email protected]. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly.
    [Show full text]
  • Who Needs the Nation-State.Pdf
    ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY Roepke Lecture in Economic Geography— Who Needs the Nation-State? Dani Rodrik The nation-state has long been under attack from Kennedy School of liberal economists and cosmopolitan ethicists alike. Government But it has proved remarkably resilient and remains Harvard University the principal locus of governance as well as the 79 John F. Kennedy Street primary determinant of personal attachments and Cambridge, MA 02138 identity. The global financial crisis has further under- [email protected] abstract scored its centrality. Against the background of the globalization revolution, the tendency is to view the nation-state as a hindrance to the achievement of desirable economic and social outcomes. Yet it remains indispensable to the achievement of those 1 Key words: goals. nation-state globalization global governance 89(1):1–19. © 2012 Clark University. www.economicgeography.org ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY Acknowledgments The nation-state has few friends these days. It is roundly viewed as an archaic construct that is at This is the revised version of odds with twenty-first century realities. It has the Roepke Lecture in neither much relevance nor much power, analysts Economic Geography say. Increasingly, it is nongovernmental organiza- delivered to the Association tions, global corporate social responsibility, or of American Geographers on global governance on which pundits place their faith February 25, 2012. A version to achieve public purpose and social goals. It is of this article was also common to portray national politicians as the sole presented as the Arrow beneficiaries of the nation-state, on which their Lecture in Ethics and privileges and lofty status depend.
    [Show full text]