Current Tax Reading Co-Editors: Robin Boadway, Kim Brooks, Jinyan Li, and Alan Macnaughton*

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Current Tax Reading Co-Editors: Robin Boadway, Kim Brooks, Jinyan Li, and Alan Macnaughton* canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2019) 67:4, 1319 - 39 https://doi.org/10.32721/ctj.2019.67.4.ctr Current Tax Reading Co-Editors: Robin Boadway, Kim Brooks, Jinyan Li, and Alan Macnaughton* Bev Dahlby, “Reforming the Federal Fiscal Stabilization Program” (2019) 12:18 SPP Briefing Papers [University of Calgary School of Public Policy] 1-20 (https://doi.org/10.11575/sppp.v12i0.68076) The federal-provincial fiscal transfer system both redistributes from high- to low- fiscal-capacity provinces and insures provinces against unexpected fiscal shocks. Fiscal redistribution in Canada is accomplished by (1) the equalization system, which is based on provinces’ revenue-raising capacities; and (2) federal health trans- fers and social transfers, which are given on an equal per capita basis. Insurance against fiscal shocks, which is the focus of Dahlby’s study, is provided by the equaliza- tion system and by the federal stabilization program (FSP). However, such insurance works better for some provinces than for others. Only those provinces that receive equalization can rely on it to cushion shocks to their revenue-raising capacity. The FSP augments equalization for provinces that suffer declines in their own-source revenues, but it does so only up to a cap of $60 per capita. Moreover, reductions in natural resource revenues trigger much less in FSP transfers than do reductions in non-resource revenues. Owing to a combination of these factors, Alberta gets virtually no fiscal insurance despite the fact that its revenues are very volatile relative to other provinces’. Equal- ization is of no insurance value to Alberta, since it is not an equalization recipient. In addition, as Dahlby points out, the FSP is of limited value to this province because (1) most of its volatility is caused by fluctuations in resource revenue, (2) the cap of $60 per capita precludes sizable insurance payouts when provincial revenues fall, and (3) FSP payments are based on single-year revenue reductions, so those sustained over several years are not covered. Dahlby proposes reforming the FSP so that it is based on standard insurance properties. A reformed program would be based on three core principles. First, only large unanticipated losses should be covered. Second, to preserve incentives to avoid losses, the program should cover only losses that are in excess of a deductible, and co-insurance should apply in such a way that only a proportion of eligible claims * Robin Boadway is of the Department of Economics, Queen’s University, Kingston, Ontario. Kim Brooks is of the Schulich School of Law, Dalhousie University, Halifax. Jinyan Li is of Osgoode Hall Law School, York University, Toronto. Alan Macnaughton is of the School of Accounting and Finance, University of Waterloo. 1319 1320 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2019) 67:4 are covered. Third, the reformed FSP should be based on simple contracts with streamlined claims-adjustment processes. Dahlby’s proposed FSP program would take the following form. Entitlements for FSP payments would be based on shortfalls of all current-year own-source revenues, as opposed to an average of own-source revenues in the previous five years, reduced by a deductible. The fiscal stabilization would be some proportion of the shortfall, referred to as the “coverage rate.” There would be no distinction between resource and non-resource revenues, and there would be no cap. The formula would include actual own-source revenues, not potential revenues as in the equalization program. Three alternative programs are considered: program A, with a deductible of 5 percent and coverage of 50 percent; program B, with a deductible of 5 percent and coverage of 75 percent; and program C, with a deductible of 3 percent and coverage of 66 percent. FSP payments would be received in the event of revenue shortfalls, but revenues in excess of previous years would not be taxed back, and there would be no analogue of an insurance premium. Dahlby illustrates his proposal by calculating what the annual FSP payouts would have been between 1986-87 and 2017-18 for Alberta, Saskatchewan, and Newfound- land and Labrador, and then comparing these payouts with what payouts would be from the existing system if the cap were not enforced. For Alberta, programs B and C would provide significantly more than would the current formula without a cap, and program A would provide roughly the same. For Saskatchewan, only program C would provide more than the current formula. For Newfoundland and Labrador, all three programs would provide a much larger payout than the current system does. Thus, while the existence of the cap is a significant problem with the current FSP, it is not the only problem. The discriminatory treatment of natural resource revenues is also a significant problem. R.B. Richard Eccleston and Ainsley Elbra, eds., Business, Civil Society and the “New” Politics of Corporate Tax Justice: Paying a Fair Share? (Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 2018), 318 pages (https://doi.org/10.4337/9781788114974) What constitutes paying a fair share of taxes and how to assess whether that share has, in fact, been paid are perennial concerns in tax policy. The growing interest of civil society groups in the tax collected from multinationals around the world is, perhaps, the old concern with a new flavour. This collection features work by various authors on the topic of citizen engage- ment and the role of civil society in the contribution that corporations should make to the fisc. The chief claim of the book is that much of the emerging pressure on multinational corporations to pay their “fair share” is driven not (as one might expect) by governments but, rather, by tax justice activists and non-governmental organiz- ations (NGOs) that have inspired the public to speak out about what they expect from multinationals. The authors’ way of framing that claim connects it with the current tax reading n 1321 literature on tax governance; they note that this book (1) contributes to debates about the effectiveness and legitimacy of private governance (that is, of a system in which private firms respond to marketplace pressures instead of to government legislation); (2) evaluates the effectiveness of civil-society groups in promoting international tax reform; and (3) assesses the likelihood that governments will be able to compel corporations to pay their fair share. The authors hail from Australia, the United States, the United Kingdom, and Canada (Allison Christians and Lynn Latulippe). The collection is divided into three parts and comprises 12 chapters, each of which should be relatively accessible to a non-technical audience. The first part (chapters 1 through 3) sets out the con- text for the problem. The authors begin with the early tax campaigns and end with the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development’s (OECD’s) base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS) project. The responses of civil-society groups are described within that historical context. The next part (chapters 4 through 7) explores the role of particular actors. To that end, the authors join forces with a growing body of scholarship that is inter- ested in the effects that a particular individual or group might have on global tax reform projects. The authors look at the role of, among other sources of influ- ence, the Tax Justice Network, the media, tax professionals, and the responses of corporations. Finally, in the third part, the collection offers five chapters (8 through 12) that put the previous discussions in a theoretical context. These chapters consider what we can learn by using concrete case studies (for example, those provided by the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative, the Fair Tax Mark, the Forestry Stewardship Council, and investigative journalism) of the consequences of emerg- ing modes of tax governance. Richard Eccleston and Ainsley Elbra’s thoughtful conclusion closes the volume. They attempt an assessment of whether the various civil-society initiatives have had a notable effect on the behaviour of firms (the short answer is sometimes yes, some- times no), and they speculate about whether other mechanisms might be more effective. Ultimately, they conclude that action by civil society alone is unlikely to result in transformative change; for that, political leadership will also be necessary. K.B. Mattia Anesa, Nicole Gillespie, A. Paul Spee, and Kerrie Sadiq, “The Legitimation of Corporate Tax Minimization” (May 2019) 75 Accounting, Organizations and Society 17-39 (https://doi.org/10.1016/j.aos.2018.10.004) Pierre Bourdieu probably did not imagine that his work would be used to inform a methodological framework for the analysis of how corporate tax-minimization strategies are legitimated, and yet that is precisely the authors’ aim in this article. Bourdieu’s work has inspired a generation of sociologists keen to understand the way in which power and social capital are transferred and maintained. 1322 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2019) 67:4 The central question in this article is how the practice of tax minimization is maintained in the face of threats to its legitimacy. The authors’ work was carried out between September 2014 (when the Australian chapter of the Tax Justice Network, together with the trade union United Voice, released a report offering a list of ef- fective tax rates paid by Australia’s largest 200 public companies) and the time, near the end of November 2017, when the Senate inquiry into corporate tax
Recommended publications
  • Is Panama Really Your Tax Haven? Secrecy Jurisdictions
    Is Panama really your tax haven? Secrecy jurisdictions and the countries they harm Petr Janský, Markus Meinzer, Miroslav Palanský1 Abstract Secrecy jurisdictions provide services that enable the residents of other countries to escape the laws and regulations of their home economies, evade tax, or hide their legally or illegally obtained assets. Recent offshore leaks offer only a limited and biased view of the world of financial secrecy. In this paper we quantify which secrecy jurisdictions provide secrecy to which countries and assess how successful countries are in targeting these jurisdictions with their policies. To that objective we develop the Bilateral Financial Secrecy Index (BFSI) and estimate it for 86 countries by quantifying the financial secrecy supplied to them by up to 100 secrecy jurisdictions. We then evaluate two major recent policy efforts by comparing them with the results of the BFSI. First, we focus on the blacklisting process of the European Commission and find that most of the important secrecy jurisdictions for EU member states have been identified by the lists. Second, we link the results to data on active bilateral automatic information exchange treaties to assess how well- aimed are the policymakers’ limited resources. We argue that while low-secrecy jurisdictions’ gains are maximized if a large share of received secrecy is covered by automatic information exchange, tax havens aim not to activate these relationships with countries to which they supply secrecy. Our results show that so far, some major secrecy jurisdictions successfully keep their most prominent relationships uncovered by automatic information exchange, and activating these relationships may thus be an effective tool to curb secrecy.
    [Show full text]
  • Fixing U.S. International Taxation
    DANIEL N. SHAVIRO FIXING U.S. INTERNATIONAL TAXATION 2 FIXING U.S. INTERNATIONAL TAXATION (forthcoming Oxford University Press, 2014) Daniel N. Shaviro June 2013 All Rights Reserved 2 1. INTRODUCTION AND OVERVIEW A Fork in the Road? Yogi Berra once offered the advice, “When you come to a fork in the road, take it.” He could almost have been speaking about the U.S. international tax rules, which govern how we tax cross-border or multinational investment. For “outbound” investment, or that earned abroad by U.S. companies, the U.S. rules, for almost a century, have muddled along in the netherworld between two sharply etched approaches that dominate the literature, each intuitively appealing but utterly inconsistent with the other. The first approach is called worldwide or residence-based taxation. Under it, the U.S. would impose tax at the same rate on U.S. companies’ foreign source income (FSI) as on their domestic income. The great apparent virtue of this approach is that it would prevent the companies from reducing their U.S. tax liability by investing (or reporting income) abroad rather than at home. The second approach is called source-based or territorial taxation. Under it, the U.S., recognizing that foreign companies pay no U.S. tax when they invest abroad, would extend this same U.S. tax exemption for FSI to its own companies. (This approach is therefore also called exemption). The great apparent virtue of this approach is that it would avoid placing U.S. companies under a competitive disadvantage, as compared to their foreign rivals, when they invest abroad.
    [Show full text]
  • EMERGING ISSUES in INTERNATIONAL TAXATION – CHALLENGES and WAY FORWARD by PATIENCE T
    EMERGING ISSUES IN INTERNATIONAL TAXATION – CHALLENGES AND WAY FORWARD By PATIENCE T. RUBAGUMYA COMMISSIONER LEGAL SERVICES AND BOARD AFFAIRS OUTLINE L 1 Introduction 2 Challenges in international taxation taxation 3 Proposed Way forward 4 Conclusion INTRODUCTION Structure of Budget Financing in Uganda and most African Countries: • Reliance on taxes to fund current and development expenditure • About 70% of the taxes are collected from domestic resources • Domestic resource mobilization is therefore key for sustainable development and thus the focus is now on international taxation and implementing strategies to enhance compliance with Transfer Pricing Regulations, Preventing Treaty Abuse and Policy redesign CHALLENGES Treaty Abuse: • This is a realistic challenge. Most treaties in developing countries are being abused due to inadequacy of the beneficial ownership anti provision. • Treaties are vulnerable to abuse and this is as a result of the way the provisions in those treaties are structured and as such the vice of treaty shopping is prevalent. CHALLENGES • Lack of information about worldwide activities and operations of multinational entities and finding comparable data for transfer pricing cases. • The MNEs create cash boxes in preferential tax regimes jurisdictions and these erode the tax base of developing countries through the payments of royalties and interest without substantial presence and value creation in such jurisdictions. CHALLENGES • Inadequate capacity of staff International taxation is complex, takes about four years to build expertise of tax official in international taxation matters. • Limited financing for capacity building programmes in the face of competing demands for resources which thus undermines domestic resource mobilization efforts. CHALLENGES- EXTRACTIVES • Some developing countries have significant oil reserves and other natural resources and often the right to tax income from the activities relating to exploitation of such resources is often an area of disputes that end up in costly international arbitration cases.
    [Show full text]
  • The Financial Secrecy Index: Shedding New Light on the Geography of Secrecy
    The Financial Secrecy Index: Shedding New Light on the Geography of Secrecy Alex Cobham, Petr Janský, and Markus Meinzer Abstract Both academic research and public policy debate around tax havens and offshore finance typically suffer from a lack of definitional consistency. Unsurprisingly then, there is little agreement about which jurisdictions ought to be considered as tax havens—or which policy measures would result in their not being so considered. In this article we explore and make operational an alternative concept, that of a secrecy jurisdiction and present the findings of the resulting Financial Secrecy Index (FSI). The FSI ranks countries and jurisdictions according to their contribution to opacity in global financial flows, revealing a quite different geography of financial secrecy from the image of small island tax havens that may still dominate popular perceptions and some of the literature on offshore finance. Some major (secrecy-supplying) economies now come into focus. Instead of a binary division between tax havens and others, the results show a secrecy spectrum, on which all jurisdictions can be situated, and that adjustment lfor the scale of business is necessary in order to compare impact propensity. This approach has the potential to support more precise and granular research findings and policy recommendations. JEL Codes: F36, F65 Working Paper 404 www.cgdev.org May 2015 The Financial Secrecy Index: Shedding New Light on the Geography of Secrecy Alex Cobham Tax Justice Network Petr Janský Institute of Economic Studies, Faculty of Social Sciences, Charles University in Prague Markus Meinzer Tax Justice Network A version of this paper is published in Economic Geography (July 2015).
    [Show full text]
  • The Relationship Between MNE Tax Haven Use and FDI Into Developing Economies Characterized by Capital Flight
    1 The relationship between MNE tax haven use and FDI into developing economies characterized by capital flight By Ali Ahmed, Chris Jones and Yama Temouri* The use of tax havens by multinationals is a pervasive activity in international business. However, we know little about the complementary relationship between tax haven use and foreign direct investment (FDI) in the developing world. Drawing on internalization theory, we develop a conceptual framework that explores this relationship and allows us to contribute to the literature on the determinants of tax haven use by developed-country multinationals. Using a large, firm-level data set, we test the model and find a strong positive association between tax haven use and FDI into countries characterized by low economic development and extreme levels of capital flight. This paper contributes to the literature by adding an important dimension to our understanding of the motives for which MNEs invest in tax havens and has important policy implications at both the domestic and the international level. Keywords: capital flight, economic development, institutions, tax havens, wealth extraction 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) from the developed world own different types of subsidiaries in increasingly complex networks across the globe. Some of the foreign host locations are characterized by light-touch regulation and secrecy, as well as low tax rates on financial capital. These so-called tax havens have received widespread media attention in recent years. In this paper, we explore the relationship between tax haven use and foreign direct investment (FDI) in developing countries, which are often characterized by weak institutions, market imperfections and a propensity for significant capital flight.
    [Show full text]
  • International Taxation Certificate
    International Taxation Certificate 1 Puerto Rico, and all U.S. states except California. Georgetown is also INTERNATIONAL TAXATION authorized separately to deliver online education to students residing in California. For more information on state authorization, including state CERTIFICATE complaint processes and refund policies the university is required to comply with, please visit Georgetown's office of Compliance and Ethics Georgetown offers a Certificate program in the increasingly important web page: https://compliance.georgetown.edu/student-consumer- field of international taxation. information/distance-education The Certificate is open to both U.S. and foreign-trained lawyers, as well as For more information on SARA please visit: https://www.nc-sara.org/ non-attorney tax professionals, and can be completed together with the Tax LL.M. degree (https://curriculum.law.georgetown.edu/llm/llm-llm- Disclosure Regarding Professional Licensure programs/llm-taxation) or on a stand-alone basis. Georgetown Law's online programs, which include the Executive LLM in Taxation, Executive LLM in Securities & Financial Regulation, MSL in The Certificate in International Taxation can also be completed entirely online Taxation, and Certificates in International Tax and State and Local Tax, (http://curriculum.law.georgetown.edu/llm/llm-online-parttime-options). will not lead to professional licensure and will not qualify a student to sit for any state bar exam. Requirements for U.S.-Trained Students and all Online Students: Search LL.M International Taxation Certificate Courses (http:// • All students must take a minimum of 10 specialization credits. curriculum.law.georgetown.edu/course-search/?program=program_89) • Prerequisites: All students must have successfully completed a course in basic federal income taxation or take Georgetown’s LAW 710 v00 Advanced International Taxation (http:// online course, Foundations of Federal Income Taxation, prior curriculum.law.georgetown.edu/course-search/?keyword=LAW to enrolling in the Certificate program.
    [Show full text]
  • The Inward Investment and International Taxation Review
    The Inward Investment and International Taxation Review Third Edition Editor Tim Sanders Law Business Research The Inward Investment and International Taxation Review THIRD EDITION Reproduced with permission from Law Business Research Ltd. This article was first published in The Inward Investment and International Taxation Review, 3rd edition (published in January 2013 – editor Tim Sanders). For further information please email [email protected] The Inward Investment and International Taxation Review THIRD EDITION Editor Tim Sanders Law Business Research Ltd The Law Reviews THE MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS REVIEW THE RESTRUCTURING REVIEW THE PRIVatE COMPETITION ENFORCEMENT REVIEW THE DISPUTE RESOLUTION REVIEW THE EMPLOYMENT LAW REVIEW THE PUBLIC COMPETITION ENFORCEMENT REVIEW THE BANKING REGUlatION REVIEW THE INTERNatIONAL ARBITRatION REVIEW THE MERGER CONTROL REVIEW THE TECHNOLOGY, MEDIA AND TELECOMMUNICatIONS REVIEW THE INWARD INVESTMENT AND INTERNatIONAL TAXatION REVIEW THE CORPORatE GOVERNANCE REVIEW THE CORPORatE IMMIGRatION REVIEW THE INTERNatIONAL INVESTIGatIONS REVIEW THE PROJECts AND CONSTRUCTION REVIEW THE INTERNatIONAL CAPItal MARKEts REVIEW THE REAL EstatE LAW REVIEW THE PRIVatE EQUITY REVIEW THE ENERGY REGUlatION AND MARKEts REVIEW THE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY REVIEW THE ASSET MANAGEMENT REVIEW THE PRIVATE WEALTH AND PRIVATE CLIENT REVIEW THE MINING laW REVIEW THE ANTi-BriBERY AND ANTi-CORRUPTION REVIEW THE EXECUTIVE REMUNERatION REVIEW www.TheLawReviews.co.uk Contents PUBLISHER Gideon Roberton BUSINESS DEVELOPMENT MANAGERS Adam Sargent, Nick Barette MARKETING MANAGER Katherine Jablonowska PUBLISHING ASSISTANT Lucy Brewer PRODUCTION CO-ORDINatOR Lydia Gerges HEAD OF EDITORIAL PRODUCTION Adam Myers PRODUCTION EDITOR Anne Borthwick SUBEDITOR Caroline Rawson EDITor-in-CHIEF Callum Campbell MANAGING DIRECTOR Richard Davey Published in the United Kingdom by Law Business Research Ltd, London 87 Lancaster Road, London, W11 1QQ, UK © 2013 Law Business Research Ltd No photocopying: copyright licences do not apply.
    [Show full text]
  • Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives
    Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives Jane G. Gravelle Senior Specialist in Economic Policy August 1, 2017 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov RL34115 Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives Summary A striking feature of the modern U.S. economy is its growing openness—its increased integration with the rest of the world. The attention of tax policymakers has recently been focused on the growing participation of U.S. firms in the international economy and the increased pressure that engagement places on the U.S. system for taxing overseas business. Is the current U.S. system for taxing U.S. international business the appropriate one for the modern era of globalized business operations, or should its basic structure be reformed? The current U.S. system for taxing international business is a hybrid. In part, the system is based on a residence principle, applying U.S. taxes on a worldwide basis to U.S. firms while granting foreign tax credits to alleviate double taxation. The system, however, also permits U.S. firms to defer foreign-source income indefinitely—a feature that approaches a territorial tax jurisdiction. In keeping with its mixed structure, the system produces a patchwork of economic effects that depend on the location of foreign investment and the circumstances of the firm. Broadly, the system poses a tax incentive to invest in countries with low tax rates of their own and a disincentive to invest in high-tax countries. In theory, U.S. investment should be skewed toward low-tax countries and away from high-tax locations.
    [Show full text]
  • JOURNAL of INTERNATIONAL TAXATION the Transfer of Shares by Non-U.S
    26 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL TAXATION The transfer of shares by non-U.S. individuals of an existing U.S. corporation owning U.S. real estate to a newly formed foreign corporation in exchange for shares of the foreign corporation can have disastrous U.S. estate tax consequences for the non-U.S. domiciliary on death. When Intended Estate Planning Results in an Accidental nversion Inversion ROBERT H. MOORE AND MICHAEL J. BRUNO not implemented properly, this structure This article will discuss one varia - For many years, could result in an “inversion” that would tion of the “inversion” transaction, the most common structure for non-U.S. result in the foreign corporation being which involves the transfer of shares by individuals 1 to hold U.S. business assets, treated as a U.S. corporation, for all pur - non-U.S. individuals of an existing U.S. such as U.S. real estate, has been to hold poses of the Code. In that case, the non- Subchapter C corporation owning U.S. such assets directly under a U.S. corpora - U.S. individual would not be protected real estate to a newly formed foreign tion and then to have the shares of the U.S. from U.S. federal estate tax. Given that corporation in exchange for shares of corporation owned by a foreign corpora - non-U.S. domiciliaries 2 have only a the foreign corporation (“Share Inver - tion. If implemented properly, this struc - $60,000 exemption on the value of their sion”). It then describes the effect of the ture protects the non-U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 8: Taxation of International E-Trade: Russian Particularities
    Chapter 8 Taxation of international e-trade: Russian particularities Alexander Pogorletskiy and Sergei Sutyrin*1 Abstract Tax rates on e-commerce in Russia should remain moderate, given the small size of its digital trade operations (so the rise in tax revenues from higher rates would be small) and substantial growth prospects (so future tax revenues from a developed sector could be quite large). The Russian Federation’s (Russia’s) taxation of e-commerce activities presents two important challenges. First, consumer goods purchased directly from foreign online sellers enjoy significant tax advantages compared to imports purchased in Russian retail outlets, undermining the profitability of Russian importers and reducing tax revenues. Second, the value-added tax (VAT) levied on foreign exporters of electronic services creates uncertainty because the legal definition of electronic services is unclear and impedes the operations of multinational companies in Russia because VAT is taxed on intra-firm imports of services. Russian authorities are establishing effective automated systems for collecting taxes and customs duties on cross-border e-commerce, calculating VAT compensation to exporters and accounting for receipts from online stores. These systems will help to prevent abuse of the tax system, as well as reduce the cost of compliance by firms. * The contents of this chapter are the sole responsibility of the authors and are not meant to represent the position or opinions of the WTO or its members. 180 CHAPTER 8 Introduction The basic idea developed by the authors is that the tax regulation Issues of tax regulation on of international e-trade should be international e-trade transactions implemented very cautiously.
    [Show full text]
  • An Interpretation of Equity with Special Reference to Individual Tax Rates
    An interpretation of equity with special reference to individual tax rates S Kalideen orcid.org/0000-0002-4268-6042 Thesis submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree Doctor of Philosophy in Taxation at the North-West University Promoter: Prof K Coetzee Graduation ceremony: October 2019 Student number: 25947494 ABSTRACT The primary aim of taxes is to collect enough revenue to finance public administration and affect redistribution of income especially in developing countries. Ideal tax reform strategies should include tax base broadening, rationalization of tax rates and an overhaul of the tax laws to address the issues of equity, efficiency and simplicity. Historically, taxation has enjoyed much favour with economists either analysing equity principles or searching for the optimal tax structure. Depending on the affiliations of the economists of the era, tax systems were either progressive or proportional and levied on income or consumption. Early economists raised the issue of equity while efficiency concerns were introduced later and the trade-off between these two principals were analysed to ascertain an acceptable compromise. The South African tax system has been frequently amended on a piecemeal basis resulting in individual taxpayers contributing proportionally more every year. When equity and efficiency requirements are seen to be lacking, taxpayers may feel aggrieved resulting in non-compliance. Recently personal income tax reform, particularly in the developing world has favoured proportional rather than progressive tax systems. In an effort to simplify their tax systems numerous countries, particularly those situated in Eastern Europe have adopted a version of the Hall-Rabushka flat tax. The adoptive jurisdictions have deviated from the recommended pure consumption based flat rate tax with a basic exemption to a fixed flat rate income tax to satisfy vertical equity principles.
    [Show full text]
  • Globalization, Tax Competition, and the Welfare State
    POLITICSPHILIPP GENSCHEL & SOCIETY Globalization, Tax Competition, and the Welfare State PHILIPP GENSCHEL Does globalization undermine the fiscal basis of the welfare state? Some observers are not convinced. They claim that aggregate data on Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development countries show no drop in tax levels and conclude from this that tax competition is not a serious challenge for the welfare state. This conclusion is unwarranted. The article shows that tax competition systematically constrains national tax autonomy in a serious way. It prevents governments from raising taxes in response to rising spending requirements and from detaxing labor in response to growing unemployment. 1. THE CONVENTIONAL WISDOM AND ITS CRITICS During the 1990s, there was a lot of concern in Europe that globalization would undermine the fiscal basis of the welfare state. Newspapers were full of dire warn- ings from policy makers who saw the coming of “cut throat tax competition”1 and bemoaned the loss of “billions of Euro” to unfair tax poaching.2 G-7 summits, the European Commission, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) issued alarmist reports on “harmful tax competition.”3 Scholars warned of “beggar-thy-neighbor policies”4 and an impending “race to the bottom” that would force “down the share of total government revenue gener- ated by taxes on business and capital income.”5 “In equilibrium, the tax rate on An earlier version of this article was presented at the American Political Science Association’s Annual Meeting in Washington, D.C., 31 August-3 September 2000. The article grew out of a joint project with Steffen Ganghof.
    [Show full text]