One the Prying Eyes of the Natural Scientist

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

One the Prying Eyes of the Natural Scientist Cambridge University Press 0521827124 - William Stanley Jevons and the Making of Modern Economics Harro Maas Excerpt More information one The Prying Eyes of the Natural Scientist William Stanley Jevons (1835–1882) isunquestionably one of thegreat minds inthe history of economics. Today, he is remembered as one of the “fathers” of the so-called marginalist revolution in economics. Withhis Theory of Po- litical Economy (1871), decisions of economic agents came to be analysedby means of thecalculus, interms ofdeliberations over marginalincrements of utility. In this “mechanics of utility and self-interest” (TPE2 90), economic agents – whetherintheir roleof consumers, workmen, or other – came to be seen as maximising utilityfunctions. Themarginalist revolution was a definitive breakwith the labour theory of value–value came to be iden- tifiedwith exchange value, and this was identifiedwith marginal utilities, not with the costs ofproduction. Jevons isalso rememberedforhis inno- vative contributions to theempirical, statistical study of the economy. He ardently propagated the use of graphstopictureand analyse statisticaldata. He introducedindex numberstomake causalinferences about economic phenomena. In short, there isnoparticleof economicscience, theoretical or empirical,towhich Jevons did not make important contributions that are, today,consideredrevolutionary. Jevons is one of the fathersof modern economics, indeed. This summary evaluation of the importance of Jevons’s contributions to economics contrasts starkly with the image wegain fromasuperficial glance at hiscontemporaries. In his lifetime, Jevons was well valued as an able statistician, but many of the leading contemporary political economists consideredhis pursuits in mathematical economics as obscuring thesubject. It was only the younger generation of scientists and economists – likeGeorge Darwinand FrancisYsidro Edgeworth – whoappreciated thenovelty and 1 © Cambridge University Press www.cambridge.org Cambridge University Press 0521827124 - William Stanley Jevons and the Making of Modern Economics Harro Maas Excerpt More information 2 William Stanley Jevons and the Making of Modern Economics fruitfulness ofhis ideas.1 It is worthquoting from John StuartMill’s fa- mous letter to Cairnes on Jevons’s Theory to illustrate his reservations (Mill 17:1862–3):2 I have not seen Mr. Jevons’s book, but as far as I can judge from such notices ofitashave reached me, I do not expect thatIshall thinkfavourably ofit. He is a man of some ability, but he seems to have a mania for encumbering questions with useless complications, andwith a notation implying the existence of greaterprecision inthe data than the questions admitof. Mill (1806–1873) was not alone in his judgement.Reviewsof the book – from, amongst others, Alfred Marshall (1842–1924)and John Elliot Cairnes (1823–1875)–were quite sceptical.3 Henry Sidgwick (1838–1900), thegreat utilitarian philosopher, downplayed the importance of Jevons’s use of the calculus whileacknowledging the importance ofhisnew utility theory of value.4 In the 1875 re-edition of John Elliot Cairnes’s influential Lectures on the Character and Logical Method of Political Economy,Cairnes even wrote that the work ofhis “able friend” did not give himanyreason to alter the views on methodhe had expressed as early as 1857.Reservations to the Theory weremade not only by those whom Jevons explicitly attacked –theclassical economists – but also by political economists of the historical school, such as Cliffe Leslie(1825–1882)and John KellsIngram (1823–1907), who favoured detailedhistorical explanations over theoryabstractedfrom historicaldetail, whether expressed verbally or mathematically. These conflicting appraisals from past andpresent leave us with an enigma ofhow to evaluate Jevons’s place inthe history of economics. Using Roy Weintraub’s recent distinction between the body and the image of ascience 1 See also Schabas (1990), Chapter 7. 2 Mill, Letter 1698, 5 December 1871,toCairnes. 3 In lateryears, Marshall admitted that he was angry about the bookfor two reasons. Firstly, he hadbeen thinking along the lines of Jevons; secondly, being an ardent admirer ofRicardo and theClassicalSchool, he feltthat injustice hadbeen done to them inthe Theory.See Schabas (1989). Amore general account of the reception of the Theory istobe foundin Schabas (1990). Inoue’s recent collection ofreviewsof Jevons’s work corrects the impression that the general response to the Theory was negative. This was farfrom the full picture.See Inoue (2002, 2:187–297). 4 Sidgwickfully acknowledged theadditional challenge Jevons’stheory of utilityposed to classicalpolitical economy that had come under severe pressure with William Thornton’s On Labour and John StuartMill’ssubsequent “recantation” of the wage fund theory. For Thornton’s influence on economictheory, see, for example, Chaigneau (1997), Donoghue (1998), Ekelund and Thornton (2001), Vint (1994), and White (1994b). © Cambridge University Press www.cambridge.org Cambridge University Press 0521827124 - William Stanley Jevons and the Making of Modern Economics Harro Maas Excerpt More information The Prying Eyes of the Natural Scientist 3 (2002, 1–2)–that is, between its substance andits perceived methodsand history –this book traces these conflicting appraisalsof Jevons back to thecontrasting images ofpolitical economy that were defendedbyJevons himself andhiscontemporaries. From an evaluation of these contrasting images, itmaybeunderstoodwhyand to what extent Jevons can be seen as one of the fathersof modern economics. Hence, myfocus isonthe changing methodsofpolitical economy, not on thechanges in its theoretical content.Beforegoingintoanydetail,itwillbeusefulto brieflyreviewexisting appraisalsof Jevons’s work. Jevons’s Place in the History of Economics Muchhas been written about Jevons’s place inthe history of economics. Starting withKeynes’sandRobbins’s centenary appraisalsof Jevons, these studies have considerably deepened ourknowledge and understanding of Jevons’s work and thecontextin whichit was produced. In his beautiful and dense essay on Jevons, Keynes paid equally high tribute to the Theory and to Jevons’s statistical studies. At home as well inabstract theory as inthe “black arts ofinductive economics”, Jevons was, according to Keynes, “the first theoretical economist to surveyhis materialwith the prying eyes and fertile, controlledimagination of the natural scientist” (Keynes [1936] 1988, 66).Robbins even wenttotheextreme when he noted that the “sheer genius” of Jevons’s “capacityin handling facts”,morethan the Theory, was perhaps his “most conspicuous claimtofame” (Robbins [1936] 1988, 101). Keynes’s portrayal of Jevons – as scrutinising the data, spending “hours arranging hischarts, plotting them, sifting them, tinting them neatly with delicate palecolours liketheslides of the anatomist, and all thetime poring over them andbrooding over them to discover their secret” ([1936] 1988, 66)–rightly describes himaspursuing an anatomy,orphysiology,of society, althoughKeynes’s account ismore imaginative than informative.Scientists use instruments and experiments to let the data speak,and thismight be only vaguely inferredfrom Keynes’s description. Moreover, Keynes seems to have meant this description only for Jevons’sempirical studies, whereas it was generally considered that his most important innovation was the introduction of aspecific instrument – thecalculus – into economics. Collison Blackdeliveredhis centennial commemoration of Jevons’sfirst airing ofhismarginalist ideas in his “Notice of aMathematical Theory of © Cambridge University Press www.cambridge.org Cambridge University Press 0521827124 - William Stanley Jevons and the Making of Modern Economics Harro Maas Excerpt More information 4 William Stanley Jevons and the Making of Modern Economics PoliticalEconomy” (readin 1862 to sectionFof the British Association for theAdvancement ofScience (BAAS)). In 1962, Blackhadjust recently discov- ered a wealth of materialinthe possession of Jevons’sgranddaughter,Mrs Kone¨ kamp, whichprovided newinsight into Jevons’s lifeandwork. Con- trary to what might perhaps beexpectedfrom Black’smodestywithregard to hiseminent predecessors, hisandKone¨ kamp’sedition of these papers, from 1972 through to 1981, have greatly contributed to a renewedinterest inJevons’s work. Various detailed studies appearedregarding exactly what Jevons’s contribution was to the so-called marginalist revolution (see, espe- cially, Black et al. 1973). His contribution to the development of statistics and econometrics is discussedin detail inseveralhighly valuable studies (e.g., Stigler 1982; Aldrich 1987, 1992; Morgan 1990). His relation to his predeces- sorsand successors has also been extensively examined (e.g., Bostaph and Shieh 1986;Schabas 1989, 1990;Kim 1995;Peart 1993, 1995a, 1996; White 1989, 1991b, 1994a, 1994b, 2004b). From these in-depth studies, a muchricherim- age emerges of Jevons as one of the foundersof“modern economics” –asin thetitleofBlack’s contribution to the Bellagioconference on themarginal- ist revolution in economics (Black et al. 1973). Thetermechoes Robbins’s depiction of marginalist economictheory as theunifying coreof modern economics (White 2004). The Bellagioconference on themarginalist revolution deserves some special attention. Obviously, not only was Jevons’s work addressed, but also themore generalissue ofwhether there was any unifying coreatall inthe work of thethree founding fathersof the “marginalist revolution”,aswas once
Recommended publications
  • Marginal Revolution
    MARGINAL REVOLUTION It took place in the later half of the 19th century Stanley Jevons in England, Carl Menger in Austria and Leon walras at Lausanne, are generally regarded as the founders of marginalist school Hermann Heinrich Gossen of Germany is considered to be the anticipator of the marginalist school The term ‘Marginal Revolution’ is applied to the writings of the above economists because they made fundamental changes in the apparatus of economic analysis They started looking at some of the important economic problems from an altogether new angle different from that of classical economists Marginal economists has been used to analyse the single firm and its behavior, the market for a single product and the formation of individual prices Marginalism dominated Western economic thought for nearly a century until it was challenged by Keynesian attack in 1936 (keynesian economics shifted the sphere of enquiry from micro economics to macro economics where the problems of the economy as a whole are analysed) The provocation for the emergence of marginalist school was provided by the interpretation of classical doctrines especially the labour theory of value and ricardian theory of rent by the socialists Socialists made use of classical theories to say things which were not the intention of the creators of those theories So the leading early marginalists felt the need for thoroughly revising the classical doctrines especially the theory of value They thought by rejecting the labour theory of value and by advocating the marginal utility theory of value, they could strike at the theoretical basis of socialism Economic Ideas of Marginalist School This school concentrated on the ‘margin’ to explain economic phenomena.
    [Show full text]
  • Energy As a Factor of Production: Historical Roots in the American Institutionalist Context Antoine Missemer, Franck Nadaud
    Energy as a Factor of Production: Historical Roots in the American Institutionalist Context Antoine Missemer, Franck Nadaud To cite this version: Antoine Missemer, Franck Nadaud. Energy as a Factor of Production: Historical Roots in the American Institutionalist Context. Energy Economics, Elsevier, 2020, 86, pp.104706. 10.1016/j.eneco.2020.104706. halshs-02467734 HAL Id: halshs-02467734 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-02467734 Submitted on 26 Feb 2021 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. - Authors’s post-print - - published in Energy Economics (2020), 86, 104706 - ENERGY AS A FACTOR OF PRODUCTION: HISTORICAL ROOTS IN THE AMERICAN INSTITUTIONALIST CONTEXT - * Antoine MISSEMER † Franck NADAUD - Full reference: MISSEMER, Antoine and NADAUD, Franck. 2020. “Energy as a Factor of Production: Historical Roots in the American Institutionalist Context”. Energy Economics, 86, 104706. [https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2020.104706] The pagination of the published version is indicated in the margin. - Abstract The relationship between energy and economic output is today discussed through the decoupling issue. A pioneering historical attempt to measure this relationship can be found in contributions by F. G. Tryon et al. at the Brookings Institution in the 1920s-1930s, in the American institutionalist context.
    [Show full text]
  • Journal of Energy History Revue D'histoire De L'énergie Les Économistes Et La Fin Des Énergies Fossiles (Antoine Missemer
    Journal of Energy History Revue d’histoire de l’énergie AUTHOR Antonin Pottier Les économistes et la fin des Centre International de énergies fossiles (Antoine Recherche sur l’Environnement et le Missemer, 2017) Développement (CIRED), École des Hautes Études en Bibliographic reference Sciences Sociales (EHESS), Antoine Missemer, Les économistes et la fin des énergies fos- France siles (1865-1931) (Paris : Garnier, 2017). POST DATE Abstract 06/02/2020 In Les économistes et la fin des énergies fossiles, ISSUE NUMBER Antoine Missemer explores the different ways by which JEHRHE #2 economists have made fossil fuels an object of eco- SECTION nomic analysis, in the period that runs from The Coal Reviews Question by William Stanley Jevons to Harold Hotelling’s KEYWORDS 1931 paper. He is interested in the fear of resource Coal, Oil, Industry, exhaustion and its impact on industrial development, Knowledge, Public policy but also reports on the theories that pay attention to DOI the economic activities of fossil fuels producers. in progress Plan of the article TO CITE THIS ARTICLE → The Coal Question as an autonomising work Antonin Pottier, “Les → Discussion of the autonomisation thesis économistes et la fin des → American conservationism énergies fossiles (Antoine → Nature as an asset Missemer, 2017)”, Journal of → A retrospective object? Energy History/Revue d’Histoire de l’Énergie [Online], n°2, published 06 february 2020, consulted XXX, URL: http:// energyhistory.eu/node/123 ISSN 2649-3055 JEHRHE #2 | REVIEWS P. 2 POTTIER | LES ÉCONOMISTES ET LA FIN DES ÉNERGIES FOSSILES (ANTOINE MISSEMER, 2017) analysis? Antoine Missemer seeks to engage with these questions in his research.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics, Psychology, and the History of Demand Theory
    Economics, Psychology, and the History of Consumer Choice Theory Paper for Conference on The History of Recent Economics (HISRECO) University of Paris X June 22-24, 2007 D. Wade Hands Department of Economics University of Puget Sound Tacoma, WA 98416 USA [email protected] May 2007 Version 2.0 13,693 Words Draft for discussion purposes only. Please do not quote. Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy Conference in Istanbul, Turkey, in November 2006 and at the Whittemore School of Business and Economics, University of New Hampshire, in February 2007. I would like to thank John Davis, Harro Maas, and a number of people in the audience at Istanbul and UNH for helpful comments. 0. Introduction The relationship between psychology and consumer choice theory has been long and tumultuous: a veritable seesaw of estrangement and warm reconciliation. Starting with the British neoclassicism of Jevons and Edgeworth, and moving to contemporary economic theory, it appears that psychology was quite in, then clearly out, and now (possibly) coming back in. If one moves farther back in time and takes the view that the classical tradition was grounded in a natural – and thus non-social, non-mental, and non– psychological – order (Schabas 2005), then the scorecard becomes out, in, out, and (possibly) back in. A tumultuous relationship indeed. The purpose of this paper is to provide a critical examination of this turbulent relationship. The argument is presented in three parts. The first section provides a summary of the standard story about the relationship between psychology and consumer choice theory from the early neoclassicals to the present time.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economics of W.S.Jevons
    THE ECONOMICS OF W.S.JEVONS Sandra Peart London and New York First published 1996 by Routledge 11 New Fetter Lane, London EC4P 4EE This edition published in the Taylor & Francis e-Library, 2005. “To purchase your own copy of this or any of Taylor & Francis or Routledge’s collection of thousands of eBooks please go to www.eBookstore.tandf.co.uk.” Simultaneously published in the USA and Canada by Routledge 29 West 35th Street, New York, NY 10001 © 1996 Sandra Peart All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or utilized in any form or by an electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publishers. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Peart, Sandra. The economics of W.S.Jevons/Sandra Peart. p. cm.—(Routledge studies in the history of economics; 9) Includes bibliographical references and index. 1. Jevons, William Stanley, 1835–1882. 2. Economists—Great Britain—Biography. 3. Economics—Great Britain—History—19th century. I. Title. II. Series. HB103.J5P4 1996 95–51459 330.157–dc20 CIP ISBN 0-203-02249-1 Master e-book ISBN ISBN 0-203-20445-X (Adobe eReader Format) ISBN 0-415-06713-8 Truth is the iron hand within the velvety glove, and the one who has truth & good logic on his side will ultimately overcome millions who are led by confused and contradictory ideas.
    [Show full text]
  • The Psychologicaltendency in Recent Political Economy (1892)
    document 14 The Psychological Tendency in Recent Political Economy (1892) Conrad Schmidt* Source: Conrad Schmidt, ‘Die psychologische Richtung in der neueren Natio- nal-Oekonomie’, Die Neue Zeit, 10. 1891–2, 2. Bd. (1892), h. 41, s. 421–9, 459–64. Introduction by the Editors There is much irony in the fact that just as Marx was working to complete Capital, and then Engels to make Volumes ii and iii of Capital available, a new approach to economic theory, beginning from a viewpoint exactly the opposite of Marx’s, was emerging in Britain and continental Europe. The so- called ‘marginalist revolution’, a response to the disintegration of the Ricardian * Conrad Schmidt (1863–1932) was a German economist and journalist. In the mid-1880s he studied in Berlin and received his doctorate in 1887 in Leipzig with the thesis Der natürliche Arbeitslohn (The Natural Wage), in which he compared the wages and exploitation theories of Johann Karl Rodbertus and Karl Marx. Schmidt rejected Marx’s theory as an unproven hypothesis in favour of Rodbertus’s views, which were based on the assumption of natural rights. After further study, Schmidt revised this judgement and became a follower of Marxism. In 1889 he published a book for the so-called ‘prize-essay competition’, in which Engels challenged the economists to explain how the formation of an average rate of profit could be made compatible with law of labour value – a solution finally revealed with the publication of the third volume of Capital in 1894. Schmidt’s book was called The Average Rate of Profit on the Basis of Marx’s Law of Value (Schmidt 1889), and gave rise to a lively correspondence between him and Engels.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 36, the Rise of Marginalism: the Philosophical Foundations of Neoclassical Economic Thought
    Portland State University PDXScholar Working Papers in Economics Economics 5-19-2014 Working Paper No. 36, The Rise of Marginalism: The Philosophical Foundations of Neoclassical Economic Thought Emily Pitkin Portland State University Follow this and additional works at: https://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/econ_workingpapers Part of the Economic History Commons, and the Economic Theory Commons Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Citation Details Pitkin, Emily. "The Rise of Marginalism: The Philosophical Foundations of Neoclassical Economic Thought, Working Paper No. 36", Portland State University Economics Working Papers. 36. (19 May 2014) i + 14 pages. This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access. It has been accepted for inclusion in Working Papers in Economics by an authorized administrator of PDXScholar. Please contact us if we can make this document more accessible: [email protected]. The Rise of Marginalism: The Philosophical Foundations of Neoclassical Economic Thought Working Paper No. 36 Authored by: Emily Pitkin A Contribution to the Working Papers of the Department of Economics, Portland State University Submitted for: EC 460, “History of Economic Thought” 19 May 2014; i + 14 pages Prepared for Professor John Hall Abstract: This inquiry examines the works of the early thinkers in marginalist theory and seeks to establish that certain philosophical assumptions about the nature of man led to the development and ultimate ascendance of neoclassical thought in the field of economics. Jeremy Bentham’s key assumption, which he develops in his 1781 work, A Fragment on Government and an Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation, that men are driven by the forces of pain and pleasure led directly to William Stanley Jevons and Carl Menger’s investigation and advancement of utility maximization theory one hundred years after Bentham, in 1871.
    [Show full text]
  • Theories of Economic System
    Theories of Global Economic System 1 • Mercantilism deals with the economic policy of the time between the Middle Ages and the age of laissez faire or as some scholars put it, 16th to 18th century (Viner, 1968; Kuhn 1963). • The period under which mercantilism held sway was not uniform in Europe. • It began and ended at quite different dates in the various countries and regions of Europe (Heckscher, 1955). • Mercantilism promoted governmental regulations of a nation’s economy for the purpose of augmenting state power at the expense of rival national powers. • It was the economic counterpart of political absolutism. • The 17th century publicists, most notably - Thomas Mun in England, Jean-Baptiste Colbert in France, and Antonio Serra in Italy – never, however, used the term themselves; it was given currency by the Scottish economist, Adam Smith in his Wealth of Nations(1776) 2 • Eli Heckscher (1955) identified the environment out of which mercantilism evolved as: – The ruin or disintegration of the universal Roman Empire – the rise and consolidation of states, limited in territory and influence though sovereign within their own borders, which grew up on the ruins of the universal Roman Empire. – Henceforth, the state stood at the centre of mercantilist endeavours as they developed historically: the state was both the subject and object of mercantilist economic policy. – The state had to assert itself in two opposing directions. On the one hand, the demands of the social institutions of the confined territories had to be defended against the universalism characteristic of the Middle Ages. On the other hand , the state had to assert its economic independence.
    [Show full text]
  • Downloaded from 443/Energyineconomicgrowth.Pdf, on May 1, 2015
    UC Berkeley UC Berkeley Electronic Theses and Dissertations Title The Ecological Keynesian: Energy, Money, and Oil Cycles in the Global System Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/66w9g7d6 Author Sager, Jalel Publication Date 2015 Peer reviewed|Thesis/dissertation eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California The Ecological Keynesian: Energy, Money, and Oil Cycles in the Global System by Jalel Marti Sager A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Energy and Resources in the Graduate Division of the University of California, Berkeley Committee in charge: Professor Richard B. Norgaard, Chair Professor Daniel M. Kammen Professor Paul Pierson Spring 2015 The Ecological Keynesian: Energy, Money, and Oil Cycles in the Global System Copyright © 2015 by Jalel Marti Sager Abstract The Ecological Keynesian: Energy, Money, and Oil Cycles in the Global System by Jalel Marti Sager Doctor of Philosophy in Energy and Resources University of California, Berkeley Professor Richard B. Norgaard, Chair This dissertation focuses on energy-centered great power nations in the 20th and early 21st centuries—the United States, Great Britain, and China—and the economic waves created by their changing rates of energy production. Its goal is a better explanation of energy’s entanglement with global production, trade, and monetary systems, and of the crises linking them in the 1970s and 2000s. The post-Bretton Woods monetary-energy regime receives special attention, as does its future, given trajectories of key nations and the need to move toward low-carbon energy sources. I proceed by integrating ecological economic and political economic thought, focusing on work of William Stanley Jevons and John Maynard Keynes that addresses key integrated macroeconomic-resource questions.
    [Show full text]
  • Marshall Library of Economics William Stanley Jevons Papers
    Marshall Library of Economics William Stanley Jevons Papers Identity code Jevons 1 Description level 2 Content Summary These 4 hand-drawn charts or graphs were deposited in the Marshall Library by "Mr Keynes" in 1936, according to a note on the envelope which contained them. This annotation is the only indication of their being by William Stanley Jevons. Summary They were almost certainly prepared by Jevons in 1860-1 for his proposed "Statistical Atlas" of about 28 diagrams. However this work was never published in full, only 2 diagrams being published at Jevons' Expense. [See 'Papers and Correspondence of William Stanley Jevons' ed. R D Collinson Black and Rosamund Könekamp for RES, vol.1 (1972)] Summary Other similar material is to be found in the archives of the Royal Statistical Society. Note William Stanley Jevons was born in Liverpool in 1835, son of Thomas and Mary Ann (nee Roscoe). His father was in the iron trade. He went to the Mechanics Institute High School, Liverpool in 1846 and in 1850 to University College School, London. In 1851 he entered University College London to study chemistry and mathematics. Recommended as assayer to new mint in Sydney, Australia 1854-9. Re-enrolled at University College London 1859, graduated BA 1860 with Ricardo Scholarship, MA 1863 with a gold medal. 1866-1875 Professor of Logic and Mental and Moral Philosophy and Cobden Lecturer on Political Economy at Owens College, Manchester. Resigned due to ill-health and the same year was appointed Professor of Political Economy at University College London, which post he held until 1880.
    [Show full text]
  • Bastiat As an Economist
    SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE! “The Independent Review does not accept “The Independent Review is pronouncements of government officials nor the excellent.” conventional wisdom at face value.” —GARY BECKER, Noble Laureate —JOHN R. MACARTHUR, Publisher, Harper’s in Economic Sciences Subscribe to The Independent Review and receive a free book of your choice* such as the 25th Anniversary Edition of Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government, by Founding Editor Robert Higgs. This quarterly journal, guided by co-editors Christopher J. Coyne, and Michael C. Munger, and Robert M. Whaples offers leading-edge insights on today’s most critical issues in economics, healthcare, education, law, history, political science, philosophy, and sociology. Thought-provoking and educational, The Independent Review is blazing the way toward informed debate! Student? Educator? Journalist? Business or civic leader? Engaged citizen? This journal is for YOU! *Order today for more FREE book options Perfect for students or anyone on the go! The Independent Review is available on mobile devices or tablets: iOS devices, Amazon Kindle Fire, or Android through Magzter. INDEPENDENT INSTITUTE, 100 SWAN WAY, OAKLAND, CA 94621 • 800-927-8733 • [email protected] PROMO CODE IRA1703 PREDECESSORS Bastiat as an Economist F CARLOS RODRI´GUEZ BRAUN AND MARI´A BLANCO conomists have not been kind to their French colleague Fre´de´ric Bastiat (1801–50), recognizing him as a mere publicist. J. S. Mill said that he “shines E as a dialectician” but lamented his “parti pris of explaining away all the evils which are the stronghold of socialists” (1972, 1665).
    [Show full text]
  • Redalyc.Biology and Economics: Metaphors That Economists Usually
    Ecos de Economía ISSN: 1657-4206 [email protected] Universidad EAFIT Colombia García Callejas, Danny Biology and Economics: Metaphors that Economists usually take from Biology Ecos de Economía, vol. 11, núm. 24, abril, 2007, pp. 153-164 Universidad EAFIT Medellín, Colombia Disponible en: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=329027260007 Cómo citar el artículo Número completo Sistema de Información Científica Más información del artículo Red de Revistas Científicas de América Latina, el Caribe, España y Portugal Página de la revista en redalyc.org Proyecto académico sin fines de lucro, desarrollado bajo la iniciativa de acceso abierto Biology and Economics: Metaphors that Economists usually take from Biology Danny García Callejas Ecos de Economía No. 24. Medellín, abril de 2007, pp. 153-164 Danny García Callejas Introduction. I. Economists and Biology: Some Origins. II. Direct links between Economics and Biology. III. Some Ideas from Economics and Biology. IV. Some Examples: From Biology to Economics and vice versa. Conclusions. References. Abstract: Adam Smith, Alfred Marshall, Stanley Jevons, Karl Marx, Francois Quesnay and Joseph Schumpeter all have at least one thing in common: they used biological metaphors when speaking about economics. Nonetheless, today, this relation subsists and biology and economics are viewed as complementary sciences that have a lot to gain from joint research in fields like: evolutionary economics, economic growth, cognitive economics and environmental and ecological economics, among others. This paper, divided in four sections, will show this conclusion and explain that biology and economics are more sisters than strangers. Key words: biology, economics, evolution, metaphors. Resumen: Adam Smith, Alfred Marshall, Stanley Jevons, Karl Marx, Francois Quesnay y Joseph Schumpeter tienen todos algo en común: todos usaron metáforas relacionadas con la biología cuando hablan de economía.
    [Show full text]