Brexit: the Glaring Adoption of Populism in Europe Keely Eshenbaugh, Phd Candidate University of Nevada, Reno Abstract

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Brexit: the Glaring Adoption of Populism in Europe Keely Eshenbaugh, Phd Candidate University of Nevada, Reno Abstract Brexit: The Glaring Adoption of Populism in Europe Keely Eshenbaugh, PhD Candidate University of Nevada, Reno Abstract The rejection of elites and spread of right-wing populism is a threat to democracy. This chapter will discuss Brexit, the UK’s referendum that terminated their EU membership, to demonstrate how narratives of institutional arrangements, policy transparency, and the dismissal of elites have captured the attention of labor and business organizations in the UK. In order to discuss the dangers that Brexit poses to democracy, it is first important to understand who the elites are and why the public is critical of elites in populist social movements. Elites: A Group Defined by Power Political elites have been defined broadly as people “at or near the top of the pyramid of national power” (Putnam, 1976). While scholars have argued more specific definitions of the characteristics and goals of elites, all definitions include the criteria that political elites are individuals that have the means and ability to influence national politics by being close to the top. Embodying Meisel’s ‘three C’s’ – cohesion, consciousness, and conspiracy – many believe that elites and elite theories must be centered around a small group of individuals that run everything seamlessly (Meisel, 1964). However, there are no defining characteristics of elites embedded in Meisel’s C’s that stipulate cohesion can only come from a group of ten or less or that perfect cohesion is a goal of elites. Similarly, a definition that elites are “the leadership [of a body politics] and the social formations from which leaders typically come, and to which accountability is maintained, during a given generation” loses validity by adding social approval to the requirements of elites (Lasswell, Lerner, & Rothwell, 1952). As Putnam suggests, the 1 importance of size, composition, and autonomy should be left for empirical studies of elite theory. As power is central to the influence and importance of elites, there are two categories of power that can be distinguished: first is the power to influence individuals over other individuals and second is the ability to influence decision making (Dahl, 1968). While these two forms of power can reinforce and strengthen one another, political power dominantly comes from the second form of power, influencing decisions (Putnam, 1976). Steven Lukes’ first face of power, the open face, emphasizes transparency and obvious deliberation in the decision making process, contributing to Dahl’s assertion (Lukes, 1974). As the first face is commonly thought of as having a democratic nature, the second face of agenda setting (to allow or ban policies from the agenda) and third phase, insidious manipulation, are commonly used by elites in more discrete settings. For example, the political power of the senior population less commonly refers to the ability of the older generation to influence the younger generation and more commonly refers to the older generation’s ability to secure favorable retirement policy like Social Security. Studying how the elite wield their power using direct and/or indirect influence is an area of the study of elite theory that should take the number of actors, environment, public opinion, anticipated reactions and more into consideration (Friedrich, 1937). Classic elitists Mosca, Pareto, and Michels share five principle assumptions about elites. First, political power is distributed unequally. Those with the “highest indices in their branch of activity” are referred to as the elite who can be governing or non-governing (Pareto, 1966). The governing elite are active in and have the ability to influence political life while the non- governing elite does not have a significant role. Pareto does not expand on the relationship between these two classes of elites, but simply identifies there is a difference. Second, all 2 individuals can be classified dichotomously as those with significant political power and those without (Pareto, 1966). Third, elites are not only isolated individuals, but they know one another and operate in a makeshift exclusionary club (Meisel, 1964). Elites generally share backgrounds with similar interests, education, wealth, and maybe even familial pedigrees. Fourth, successful elites are chosen from pools of other elites. Fifth, because elites are self-perpetuating, they are essentially autonomous and do not have to answer to anyone outside of the group (Mosca, 1939). Dominating the masses, classic elite theorists believe that elites are isolated from the rest of society, are chosen from within their own ranks, and only serve the interests of other elites as an “iron law” (Michels, 1959). But why do we see that the political elites vary from one country to another? Mosca answers, “the varying structure of ruling classes [elites] has a preponderant importance in determining the political type, and also the level of civilization of the different peoples’”, such as in feudal societies where elites have military valor while modern bureaucratic elites have wealth (Mosca, 1939). Starting in the twentieth century, scholars have been trying to identify a typology that elites in particular regime types, regions, and development of political-economic structures can be categorized into. The ‘Western’ elites and ‘Soviet’ elites were proposed, but missed the nuances between Western states as well as non-Western and non-Communistic elites (Aron, 1950). Authoritarian, totalitarian, cartel, and liberal elites were also outlined as a possible typology, shining light on the absence of a liberal elite that could have rescued Germany during World War II (Dahrendorf, 1967). Robert Putnam later added consensual, competitive, and coalescent “types'' that respectively related policy choices and political procedures to communist, stable democratic, and multi-ethic democratic regimes ( Putnam, 1976; Burton & Higley, 2001). Other categories of elites have been posed more recently, but none of them have found popular 3 acceptance in the field. The role of the elites has changed dramatically as societies become more politically complex; making it more challenging to separate the general social structure from elite activities. This complication has challenged many of the elite theories that have been observed in the 20th century (Blondel & Müller-Rommel, 2009). Internal Splintering Bordering the literature on coalition characteristics and social networks, elite groups vary in their internal differentiation and integration. Differentiation is a process where groups of elites become more specialized in their offerings, diverse in their organizational structure, and numerous (Keller, 1979). Integration includes the internal unity or structure of the elite group itself; similar to Meisel’s ‘three C’s’ ( Putnam, 1976; Meisel, 1964). In this sense, four subtypes of elites can be assumed: strong integration with wide differentiation, strong integration with narrow differentiation, weak integration and wide differentiation, and weak integration with narrow differentiation (Burton & Higley, 2001). Strong integration with wide differentiation, or the consensual elite, has a lot of elites that are locked into a network that operates in many sectors. The group recognizes one another as legitimate elites and provides connections and access to central decision-makers. The idiocratic elite, strong integration with narrow differentiation, is very centralized with an elite group that pledges allegiance to the mission of their monopolistic movement. With weak integration and wide differentiation, the fragmented elite often disagree with one another’s goals but find security in pluralism. Lastly, the divided elites have weak integration and narrow differentiation. The divided elites seek to destroy the other camp by any means possible to ensure their power continues to dominate the arena. Recognizing different structures of power, wide differentiation supports a more representative regime type where elite groups take turns dominating. Similarly, 4 strong elite integration creates a stable environment for politics to operate in. Burton and Higley map these regime traits onto the four types of political elites, creating the table below (Burton & Higley, 2001). Table A: Political Elites and Regime Type (Taken from Burton & Higley, 2001) Elite Integration Strong Weak “Consensual elite” “Fragmented elite” Wide Stable Unstable Representative Regime Representative Regime Elite Differentiation “Ideocratic elite” “Divided elite” Narrow Stable Stable Unrepresentative Regime Unrepresentative Regime This typology was designed to help with the lack of empirical studies about elites and elite control. Being able to identify an elite is not possible by only looking at top position-holders in large organizations or corporations. Some CEOs may have a lot of wealth and influence in their sphere, but do not translate it into political power. Others may not be the President of a large organization, but have connections to make critical phone calls to influence policy. Organizational-positional identification of elites is complex, but can become easier with the use of interviews, informants, network analyses, and snowball sampling (Burton & Higley, 2001). Discerning boundaries is another conflict of uncovering the motives of elites because their business is often kept secret for reasons of personal gain or deliberate sabotage. Exactly as Mosca pointed out, elites usually do not have to answer to anyone outside of their group (Mosca, 1939). The ‘elite
Recommended publications
  • A Consequence of the European Social and Democratic Deficit Mavrozacharakis, Emmanouil; Tzagkarakis, Stylianos Ioannis; Kamekis, Apostolos
    www.ssoar.info Brexit: a consequence of the European social and democratic deficit Mavrozacharakis, Emmanouil; Tzagkarakis, Stylianos Ioannis; Kamekis, Apostolos Erstveröffentlichung / Primary Publication Arbeitspapier / working paper Empfohlene Zitierung / Suggested Citation: Mavrozacharakis, E., Tzagkarakis, S. I., & Kamekis, A. (2017). Brexit: a consequence of the European social and democratic deficit.. https://nbn-resolving.org/urn:nbn:de:0168-ssoar-51586-8 Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Dieser Text wird unter einer CC BY-SA Lizenz (Namensnennung- This document is made available under a CC BY-SA Licence Weitergabe unter gleichen Bedingungen) zur Verfügung gestellt. (Attribution-ShareAlike). For more Information see: Nähere Auskünfte zu den CC-Lizenzen finden Sie hier: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/4.0 https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/4.0/deed.de Brexit: A consequenceof the European social and democratic deficit EmmanouilMavrozacharakis, Sociologist, Political Scientist, PhD Candidate, Department of Political Science, University of Crete Stylianos IoannisTzagkarakis, Political Scientist, PhD Candidate, Department of Political Science, University of Crete ApostolosKamekis, Political Scientist, PhD Candidate, School of Medicine, University of Crete Abstract The outcome of the recent referendum in the UK was straightforwardly affected by the policies followed by the EU. The main factors in which eurosceptics-populists had used in order to collect votes were both the immigration crisis (and the consequent EU policies) and the European political reactions to the economic crisis which increases EU powers, under the German supervision, and decreases national sovereignty. Although these two factors may seem different, they are directly linked as long as they comprise an outcome of the social and democratic deficit of the EU which increased concerns about the future effects in the UK and offered the opportunity for the cultivation of populist ideas.
    [Show full text]
  • Democratic Deficit, European Constitution, and a Vision of the Federal Europe: the EU’S Path After the Lisbon Treaty**
    JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL AND AREA STUDIES 53 Volume 17, Number 2, 2010, pp.53-70 Democratic Deficit, European Constitution, and a Vision of the Federal Europe: The EU’s Path after the Lisbon Treaty** Nam-Kook Kim** and Sa-Rang Jung With the implementation of the Lisbon Treaty in December 2009, it has become more feasible to envisage a federal Europe through the establishment of an ‘ever closer union’ as a political entity. Although the recent EU appears more like confederal or intergovernmental than federal, the Lisbon Treaty makes it possible to postulate that the future integration process of the EU would be its advance toward a federal state. On the verge of ramification toward either a federal Europe or a durable confederation, the EU faces a critical agenda of democratic deficit, i.e., a lack of vertical accountability between European political elites and voluntarily participating European citizens. The current status of the EU is obviously unique in its structure of multi level governance. Sometimes this structure is evaluated positively, but the study of former confederations also indicates that a confederate system is not durable, and rather unstable and impermanent. If the EU wants to move in a federal direction beyond confederation, it should answer the question of democratic deficit, that is, how to find European citizens who are loyal enough to sustain an independent political community. This paper discusses a possible route for the EU after the Lisbon Treaty, especially with respect to issues related to the democratic deficit and to the necessity of devising a European constitution. Keywords: Federal Europe, Confederation, Democratic Deficit, European Constitution, Lisbon Treaty 1.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Austin Prather Can the EU Survive Populism?
    1 Austin Prather Can the EU Survive Populism? Introduction Frustrated with the status quo, economic inequality and the failure of institutions, a wave of populism has swept over the globe as the masses have rallied behind leaders such as Donald Trump in the United States and Nigel Farage in Britain who claim they represent the interests of the people better than the established political and economic elites who have controlled democratic governments for generations. Populism, it seems, has become popular. This is especially true in the European Union, where concerns grow that it could rip the Union apart. Yet scholars and experts have struggled to accurately define populism. Some consider it an ideology, a doctrine, or a tactic to help win elections. Although there is not quite a consensus, most scholars have described it as a “thin ideology” that pits the “pure people” against the nefarious and “corrupt elite” (Mudde, 2017). Because of a lack of core values, populism can often be found in combination with other ideologies. It can appear in far-right, nationalistic political groups as in Hungary under Viktor Orbán or extremely left groups like Hugo Chavez in Venezuela. Regardless of where populist parties fall on the political spectrum, scholars generally agree that it cripples transnational institutions such as the European Union because populist leaders often pursue policies that (1) stress national sovereignty and (2) lead to the deterioration of institutions (Bryder, 2009). Examining three case studies highlights that populism is a threat to the integration of the European community, although it is unlikely to lead to its complete demise.
    [Show full text]
  • The European Union's Democratic Deficit and Options for EU
    EUC Working Paper No. 14 Working Paper No. 22, August 2014 The European Union’s Democratic Deficit and st Options for EU Democracy in the 21 Century Dexter Lee EU Centre in Singapore ABSTRACT The European Union (EU) is widely acknowledged as a successful example of economic and political integration of nation states today - a slate of democratic institutions such as the European Parliament have also been developed and European citizens now possess extensive political and civil rights by virtue of the introduction of European citizenship. Nevertheless, the EU is said to suffer from a so called “democratic deficit” even as it seeks deeper and closer integration. Decades of institutional design and elite closed-door decisions has taken its toll on the inclusion and integration of European citizens in social and political life, with widening socio-economic inequalities and the resurgence of extreme-right parties in the wake of the debt crisis in the Eurozone. This paper attempts to evaluate the democratic development of the EU through the use of a process-oriented approach, and concludes at the end with discussions on the various options that the EU and its citizens can take to reform democratic processes and institutions in Europe. The EU Centre in Singapore is a partnership of 13 EUC Working Paper No. 22 THE EUROPEAN UNION’S DEMOCRATIC DEFICIT This paper attempts to evaluate the democratic AND OPTIONS FOR EU DEMOCRACY IN THE 21ST development of the EU through process-oriented CENTURY approach, and concludes at the end with discussions on how proposed reforms should DEXTER LEE1 concentrate on enhancing democracy of and by the people.
    [Show full text]
  • THE LISBON TREATY – a STEP FORWARD to a MORE DEMOCRATIC EUROPEAN UNION? (Paper Given to the European Forum Cyprus, Athens, 13-15 January 2011)
    Heinz-Jürgen Axt THE LISBON TREATY – A STEP FORWARD TO A MORE DEMOCRATIC EUROPEAN UNION? (Paper given to the European Forum Cyprus, Athens, 13-15 January 2011) The Lisbon Treaty promises to improve European Union policy making in three aspects: more democracy, more efficiency and more transparency. I will concentrate on the democratic aspect in my paper. It is a widespread and very popular common saying that the European Union is suffering from a democratic deficit. I will discuss the democratic quality of the EU and will analyse which innovations with respect to democracy have been offered by the Lisbon Treaty. I will therefore proceed as follows: First, I will describe some characteristics of the assumed democratic deficit of the EU. Secondly, I will refer to some controversial theoretical interpretations of the democratic deficit – but will do so very concisely, of course. Thirdly, I will recap the historical developments which led to the Treaty of Lisbon. Fourthly, I will present and evaluate the innovations of the Lisbon Treaty which have an impact on the democratic quality of the European Union. And finally, I will draw some conclusions. 1 1. THE “STANDARD VERSION” OF THE DEMOCRATIC DEFICIT Even if we concede that the EU is not a state, democratic norms are relevant for the Union. This implies that democracy must be adapted to the distinctiveness of the EU. As the nation state does not seem to be a correct and sufficient benchmark for the EU, the question arises: What is the EU? Obviously the EU is more than a loose confederation but less than a strong federation.
    [Show full text]
  • Cure for Democratic Deficit in the Eu: the Lisbon Treaty?
    CURE FOR DEMOCRATIC DEFICIT IN THE EU: THE LISBON TREATY? – WITH COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF THE FRENCH, GERMAN AND HUNGARIAN CONSTITUTIONAL COURT’S “LISBON-JUDGMENTS” – by Miklós Klenanc CEU eTD Collection LL.M. SHORT THESIS COURSE: EU Constitutional Law PROFESSOR: Dr. Ronan McCrea Central European University 1051 Budapest, Nador utca 9. Hungary © Central European University March 28, 2011 Table of Contents Abstract ...............................................................................................................................iii Introduction .......................................................................................................................... 1 Chapter One: The democratic deficit – What it is about?....................................................... 4 1.1 Theoretical concept ..................................................................................................... 4 1.2 Rising concerns about democratic legitimacy in the European Communities ............... 5 Chapter Two: Democratic deficit in the European Union....................................................... 9 2.1 Different democratic deficits – “Why the public should be worried by the EEC’s democratic deficit?” .......................................................................................................... 9 2.2 Democratic deficit in typical approach....................................................................... 14 Chapter Three: Democratic deficit in action – From a legalistic point of view ....................
    [Show full text]
  • EU Parliamentary Democracy: How Representative? Sophia Russack
    No 2019/07, May 2019 EU parliamentary democracy: how representative? Sophia Russack Summary To what extent does the European Parliament really represent EU citizens? This paper first briefly introduces the most crucial characteristics of the EP (with regards to its internal organisation, its rights and tasks, as well as the electoral procedure), and then highlights the most important differences between the EP and its national counterparts: how national parties translate into European groupings; the (dis)connection between the European executive and legislative branches; and electoral (dis)connections. Finally, it investigates the idea for institutional reform introduced to improve the representative character of the EP – the Spitzenkandidaten procedure. It finds that the attempt to transform the EU (as a hybrid sui generis entity) into a full fledged parliamentary system does not make the EP a better representative of the EU electorate. Sophia Russack is a Researcher at CEPS Institutions unit. This paper is a chapter in the book Representative Democracy in the EU: Recovering Legitimacy which is published with Rowman & Littlefield International in May 2019, as part of the “Towards a Citizens’ Union” (2CU) project of the European Policy Institutes Network (EPIN), co-funded by the Erasmus+ Jean Monnet Programme of the European Commission. CEPS Policy Insights offer analyses of a wide range of key policy questions facing Europe. As an institution, CEPS takes no position on questions of European policy. Unless otherwise indicated, the views expressed are attributable only to the author in a personal capacity and not to any institution with which she is associated. 978-94-6138-734-9 Available for free downloading from the CEPS website (www.ceps.eu) CEPS ▪ Place du Congrès 1 ▪ B-1000 Brussels ▪ Tel: (32.2) 229.39.11 ▪ www.ceps.eu Contents Introduction ....................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Part I: Literature Review
    Prospects for e-democracy in Europe Part I: Literature review STUDY Science and Technology Options Assessment EPRS | European Parliamentary Research Service Scientific Foresight Unit (STOA) February 2018 - PE 603.213 Prospects for e-democracy in Europe Literature review Study IP/G/STOA/FWC/2013-001/LOT 8/C4 February 2018 Abstract A long-standing and continuing democratic deficit of the European Union is detected in public and scholarly debate. This democratic deficit is explained by the complex and mutually reinforcing mix of institutional design features of the EU and it is held to contribute to a lacking sense of European citizenship and the negative and nation-oriented public discourse around the EU. It is still believed by many that the perceived democratic deficit of the European Union indicates the need for fostering a European public sphere as a space of debate across national public spheres. Moreover, there is a consensus that the new modes of political communication and participation via the internet can play a role in that respect. Redressing the democratic deficit is obviously a daunting task which cannot be accomplished through the introduction of e-participation tools alone. Far-reaching expectations of a fundamental reform of modern democracy through the application of online participatory tools are vanishing after two decades of e-democracy. However, if properly designed and implemented, e- participation has the potential to contribute to accountability and transparency, trans-nationalisation and politicisation of public debates, and the improvement of exchanges and interactions between EU decision-making and European citizens. A common critique on e-participation practices at the EU-level is that they are a successful civic instrument but not a convincing policy instrument.
    [Show full text]
  • The Democratic Deficit in the European Union 26 MEGAN CAMPBELLUC Santa Barbara
    Claremont-UC Undergraduate Research Conference on the European Union Volume 2009 Claremont-UC Undergraduate Research Article 5 Conference on the European Union March 2012 The eD mocratic Deficit in The urE opean Union Megan Campbell University of California, Santa Barbara Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.claremont.edu/urceu Part of the European Law Commons Recommended Citation Campbell, Megan (2009) "The eD mocratic Deficit in The urE opean Union," Claremont-UC Undergraduate Research Conference on the European Union: Vol. 2009, Article 5. DOI: 10.5642/urceu.200901.05 Available at: http://scholarship.claremont.edu/urceu/vol2009/iss1/5 This Chapter is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals at Claremont at Scholarship @ Claremont. It has been accepted for inclusion in Claremont-UC Undergraduate Research Conference on the European Union by an authorized administrator of Scholarship @ Claremont. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Claremont-UCUndergraduat e Research Conference on the European Union 25 3 THE DEMOCRATIC DEFICIT IN THE EUROPEAN UNION Megan Campbell 1. INTRODUCTION Foll owing the creation of what is known as the Europ ean Union with th e signing of the Treaty on European U nion in 1993 , debate about th e politi cal sphere of the Union has been in creasingly co ncern ed w it h th e dem ocratic defi cit. T he European U nion (E U or th e Union) is ;l dem ocracy both by d efault, as it is a collectio n of democracies, and th rou gh Eu­ rop ean elections.
    [Show full text]
  • The European Union Democratic Deficit: Substantive Representation in the European Parliament at the Input Stage
    Miriam Sorace The European Union democratic deficit: substantive representation in the European Parliament at the input stage Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Sorace, Miriam (2018) The European Union democratic deficit: substantive representation in the European Parliament at the input stage. European Union Politics, 19 (1). pp. 3-24. ISSN 1465- 1165 DOI: 10.1177/1465116517741562 © 2018 by SAGE Publications This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/87625/ Available in LSE Research Online: April 2018 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final accepted version of the journal article. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. The European Union democratic deficit: Substantive representation in the European Parliament at the input stage Miriam Sorace European Institute, London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK Abstract The analysis compares voters’ preferences in economic policy to political parties’ economic written parliamentary questions during the 2009–2014 term of the European Parliament.
    [Show full text]
  • A Solution to the Democratic Deficit?
    The European Citizens’ Initiative: A Solution to the Democratic Deficit? Erik E. Chömpff Leiden University Public Administration: International and European Governance Master Thesis Date: 29.06.2016 Supervisor: Dr. A.L. Dimitrova Second Reader: Dr. R. de Ruiter Word Count: 15371 Abstract In 2009 the Treaty of Lisbon entered in to force and with it introduced for the first time in the European Union’s (EU) history a model for direct democracy, the European Citizens’ Initiative (ECI). The ECI was designed in part, as a tool of direct democracy to counter the democratic deficit. This thesis sought to identify if the introduction of the ECI was able to succeed in its mission of reducing the democratic deficit in the EU. This thesis used a comparative case evaluation to examine the design of the ECI with the agenda initiatives instruments of Austria, Spain and Poland. The ECI and the agenda initiatives were evaluated on five elements of direct democracy: list of exclusions, entry hurdles, time limits, quorum and follow-up to agenda initiatives. Through this comparative evaluation, Results indicate that the design of the ECI and similar agenda initiatives, have not been very successful in creating civic engagement and giving citizens a viable tool for legislative participation. The main findings for the ECI to be unsuccessful are; the difficulty of the signature collecting process, the lack of political effort to make the ECI successful and the difficulties of implementing direct democracy on a continental scale. Keywords: agenda initiative, democratic deficit, direct democracy, European Citizens’ Initiative, European Union. 2 Table of contents 1.
    [Show full text]
  • The EU, Democracy and Institutional Structure: Past, Present and Future
    Maurer School of Law: Indiana University Digital Repository @ Maurer Law Articles by Maurer Faculty Faculty Scholarship 2018 The EU, Democracy and Institutional Structure: Past, Present and Future Paul Craig Indiana University Maurer School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/facpub Part of the Organizations Law Commons, and the Political Theory Commons Recommended Citation Craig, Paul, "The EU, Democracy and Institutional Structure: Past, Present and Future" (2018). Articles by Maurer Faculty. 2761. https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/facpub/2761 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Articles by Maurer Faculty by an authorized administrator of Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The EU, Democracy and Institutional Structure: Past, Present and Future Paul CRAIG** 1. Introduction It is commonp[ace to bemoan the EU's democratic deficiencies, as attested to by the wea[th of [iterature discussing the issue from a variety of perspectives. This chapter is not a [iterature review. To the contrary, it advances my own view on the issue, a[beit one that is informed by existing scho[arship. The ensuing ana[ysis is predicated on the assumption that a principal, a[beit not exclusive, cause for concern about EU democracy isthe mismatch, or absence of fit, between voter power and political responsibility. EU decision-making isstructured such that voters cannot determine the shape or direction of EU policy in the manner that occurs to a greater extent within Member States.
    [Show full text]